Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Professor Milica Uvalic Department of Economics Faculty of Political Sciences University of Pergugia Via Pascoli 20 06123 Perugia Italy [email protected] Federal Republic of Yugoslavia (FRY) M. Uvalic Working Paper 18/01 2 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This paper was revised in October 30, 2000 for publication in Southeast Europe and Black Sea Studies, Volume 1, Number 1, Summer 2000. This paper is associated with a project in the ESRC ‘One Europe or Several?’ Programme. The project is lead by Professor Saul Estrin and is entitled ‘Economic Impact of Exclusion from EU and EMU: Balkans and Baltics’, Reference Number L213 25 2003. Details can be found on the ‘One Europe or Several?’ website www.oneeurope.ac.uk. 3 The Federal Republic of Yugoslavia (FRY) is today the country in Southeastern Europe (SEE)1 that is undoubtedly in the worst overall situation. Throughout the 1990s, delays in fundamental economic and political reforms and numerous accompanying problems have positioned it among the countries that lagged behind most in the transition to a market economy and multiparty democracy. Moreover, the Kosovo conflict has had disastrous consequences for FRY’s economy. In addition to the direct, immediate costs due to loss of human life and physical damage to industrial capacity and the transportation, energy and communications infrastructure, the conflict will have a number of indirect longer-term effects, including substantial loss of gross domestic product (GDP) over the next decade. Although FRY has been the country in the region most heavily affected by the NATO bombardments, for political reasons it has not been included, for over a year, in the Stability Pact for Southeastern Europe, adopted 10 June 1999. It is only recently, after the elections held on September 24, 2000, which brought victory to the democratic opposition alliance DOS (Democratic Opposition of Serbia) and Mr. Vojislav Kostunica as new President of FRY, that political circumstances in the country are radically changing, in this way also determining a turnaround in international strategies. At the meeting in Bucharest on October 26, 2000, FRY was officially admitted to the Stability Pact, while initiatives are in course which should allow the re-admission of FRY into major international organizations (the United Nations, the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank). The paper discusses the main characteristics of the Yugoslav economy today, concentrating primarily on Serbia as the largest part of the Yugoslav economy, and not considering Kosovo since it has de facto been taken over by UNMIK (UN Interim Administration Mission in Kosovo). The paper examines the country’s initial conditions in 1989, external shocks during the 1990s, macroeconomic performance over the past decade and progress made in economic reforms, followed by some concluding remarks. INITIAL CONDITIONS FRY consists of two republics, Serbia with its two provinces (Vojvodina and Kosovo)2 and Montenegro, but in 1989, when the transition to a market economy began in Central 1 For the purposes of this paper, Southeastern Europe includes Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, FYR Macedonia, Romania and FRY. 2 According to UN Security Council Resolution 1244, the region of Kosovo is to remain under the sovereignty of the Yugoslav federation, in spite of some main functions being taken over by UNMIK. 4 and Southeastern Europe, these two republics were still a constituent part of the Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia (former Yugoslavia). At that time, former Yugoslavia had a number of advantages with respect to other SEE countries. Although some of these advantages applied only to the country as a whole,3 others were equally important for its republics. Former Yugoslavia held a special position in international economic and political relations, from which all its republics in one way or another benefited. It was not a member of CMEA (Council for Mutual Economic Assistance) but had concluded several trade agreements with the European Economic Community (EEC), and of all SEE countries, it had the largest share of its trade with the EEC. Its privileged position with major international financial organizations, its relative openness and the adoption of joint ventures legislation in 1967 enabled a substantial entry of foreign capital.4 Thanks to an early start in market-oriented reforms, Yugoslavia was the most reformed socialist economy. Despite the preservation of some systemic features of socialist economy, such as the prevalence of nonprivate (social) property and state paternalism, the positive effects of four decades of economic reforms were experienced throughout the country. Also, the Yugoslav federal government in 1988-90 applied some important measures for transition to a market economy (Uvalic, 1992). Although short-lived, since disintegration entailed new legislation for successor states, the measures nevertheless had positive and long-lasting effects.5 Important differences existed among the Yugoslav republics regarding trade orientation, openness, level of development and relative economic weight within the federation. There were notable differences also in the levels of development of the two republics that would later form FRY. In the late 1980s, Serbia and Montenegro had a gross material product (GMP)6 per capita below the Yugoslav average, but Serbia was still considered one of the more developed republics, as was its province Vojvodina, while Montenegro and the province of Kosovo were among the least developed. In 1989 their joint GDP per head at PPP (purchasing power parity) was $4,731, or around half of that in Slovenia (Kekic, 1996: 15). In 1989-90 Serbia and Montenegro accounted for the highest share of 3 In the late 1980s, Yugoslavia was the largest, most populous and most developed country in SEE (Uvalic, 1997c). One of the oldest examples of Yugoslav cooperation with foreign partners dates from 1954, when the first agreement was concluded between the car manufacturers Zastava (Kragujevac, Serbia) and Fiat (Italy). 5 For example, the 1988 legislative changes liberalizing firm entry enabled the creation of numerous new small firms in the private sector; similarly, the 1990 privatization law enabled the first ownership changes throughout the country. 4 5 Yugoslav territory (38 per cent), population (44 per cent), GMP (40 per cent), investment (40 per cent), employment (40.6 per cent) and unemployment (50.6 per cent), and even of the country’s exports (31.8 per cent) and imports (34.4 per cent), mainly due to Serbia’s major relative weight in the Yugoslav federation (Uvalic, 1997b). Serbia was the republic that by 1989 had concluded the most contracts with foreign partners (33 per cent of the total), though it lagged behind Slovenia in terms of value of foreign direct investment (21 per cent of the total). Its exports to the CMEA, though low (8 per cent), were double that of Slovenia. Laza Kekic has calculated an overall index of initial conditions in the late 1980s in all socialist economies that considers such indicators as dependence on CMEA trade, per capita income, share of services in GDP and previous reforms. His findings suggest that not only Yugoslavia, but all its republics were ahead of other SEE countries. The overall index for Serbia and Montenegro was 19, compared to 15 for both Albania and Romania and 13 for Bulgaria; the maximum index was 24 for Slovenia (Kekic, 1996). On the eve of the country’s breakup, Serbia and Montenegro therefore held a relatively favorable position in the SEE region. What, if anything, has remained of these advantages? Several negative developments have fundamentally affected FRY’s economic situation in the meantime, practically dissolving most — if not all — of the advantages the country enjoyed ten years ago. EXTERNAL SHOCKS Since the early 1990s, the Yugoslav economy has been negatively affected by a number of external shocks, primarily the disintegration of the Yugoslav federation, several armed conflicts and various sanctions by the international community. Though these shocks are by their nature considered “external,” all have been caused, directly or indirectly, by internal policies of the Serbian/Yugoslav government.7 6 GMP, or “social “product” in Yugoslav terminology, is the value added of “productive” sectors of the economy, thus excluding “nonproductive” sectors such as education, health, defense, banking and other services. 7 The disintegration of former Yugoslavia could have been prevented by more flexibility on the Serbian side and a willingness to collaborate more constructively with the other republics in finding a solution for Yugoslavia’s transformation. Military conflicts in which Serbia has been directly or indirectly involved have been a deliberate choice of its government, since all four wars could have been prevented, even that in Kosovo. UN sanctions would never have been imposed had the Yugoslav government used peaceful means for resolving some of the most burning political issues. To blame “external shocks” for the catastrophic situation in the country today, as is frequently done by the Yugoslav government, is to ignore its own responsibility for dragging the country into such a deep economic, political and social crisis. 6 Disintegration The breakup of the Yugoslav economic union in 1991 had a number of very negative consequences for FRY. The immediate effects included a strong inflationary impact on Serbia because of the monetary independence of the other republics, which unloaded their dinar holdings in the Serbian market; the segmentation of monetary channels and serious payment problems following the breakup; a reduced currency area; and lower revenues for the federal government due to the breakup of the customs union. Other consequences with even more long-lasting effects included the loss of supplies of goods and inputs at low prices from the other republics and the loss of a large protected market in other parts of the country; disruptions caused by the termination of traditional links between partners or by the introduction of trade barriers by the newly created states; diminished interest by foreign investors due to the market’s small size; and very high political risk. All these effects of disintegration had a disastrous impact on FRY’s macroeconomic indicators (see below). Wars Over the last eight years, FRY has been directly or indirectly involved in four wars in Slovenia (1991), Croatia (1991-92), Bosnia and Herzegovina (1992-95) and Kosovo (1998-99). Already the wars in Croatia and Bosnia and Herzegovina have meant enormous direct costs for FRY in terms of loss of human lives, the expense of maintaining refugees and substantial military expenditure, while the conflict in Kosovo has physically damaged much of the county’s transportation and energy infrastructure and its productive capacity. These wars have had also several indirect consequences that negatively affect macroeconomic stabilization, economic recovery and systemic reforms, effectively postponing the transition to a market economy. The consequences of the most recent war in Kosovo have been particularly devastating. Estimates of the conflict’s overall costs for FRY vary widely, ranging from $30 billion to $100 billion (the latter is the Yugoslav government’s official estimate). According to the G17, a group of independent experts from Belgrade, total costs amount to $30 billion. The direct costs include around $4 billion in physical damage (the destruction of industrial capacity accounts for about 70 per cent of the physical damage); $2.3 billion in lost human capital; and the remaining $23 billion in the loss of potential GDP due to physical damage, expected to be felt over the next ten years (Group 17, 1999). Though 7 some of these estimates have been revised, since the initial scenarios were overpessimistic, undoubtedly long-term costs will still be substantial. Serbia’s road and railway connections have been seriously disrupted, while trade on the Danube has come to a standstill (though there is an inland channel used by ships, and a few bridges have been repaired). Severe heating problems were expected due to electricity and heating fuel shortages, although some energy provisions have been provided by Russia, and the overall situation has been less dramatic than initially thought. Sanctions Because of its involvement in several armed conflicts, during the past eight years FRY has been subject continuously to numerous and varied sanctions by the international community (Babic, 1999). The UN imposed its first embargo in late 1991 because of the Serb-Croat conflict in Croatia. After the war moved to Bosnia and Herzegovina, sanctions were reinforced in May 1992, to be partially removed only in November 1995 thanks to the Dayton Peace Accords. What remains in force is the “outer wall” of sanctions, which essentially blocks FRY’s reentry into international organizations, such as the UN, the Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe (OSCE), the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). It also prevents FRY’s participation in all EU programs of assistance for countries in transition (Uvalic, 1997a). It is to be lifted only once certain political conditions are fulfilled.8 The most recent package of sanctions was imposed because of violence in Kosovo, initially in a limited form in May 1998, but reinforced on 30 March 1999 to include an air traffic ban and an oil and trade embargo. MACROECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Yugoslav macroeconomic performance has been extremely variable the past decade, although the long-term trend points to a general deterioration of most macroeconomic indicators, especially after the Kosovo conflict. After the breakup of the Yugoslav economic union, the economy virtually collapsed within a few years. By the end of 1993, GMP had fallen to 43 per cent of its 1989 level, whereas expansionary monetary and fiscal policies necessary to finance the war 8 The main conditions include cooperation with the Hague Tribunal for war criminals in former Yugoslavia, democratization, respect for human rights and the resolution of succession issues of former Yugoslavia. 8 triggered one of the highest hyperinflations ever recorded in world history.9 The monetary reconstruction program implemented in early 1994 by the governor of the central bank, Dragoslav Avramovic, initially succeeded in halting hyperinflation, introducing a convertible dinar and reversing the trend of declining output. These positive results, however, were soon undermined by problems essentially caused by the absence of systemic change, which put strain on stability (Avramovic, 1995). Inflation remained high the next few years, since further progress in monetary stabilization was achieved only in 1997 and 1998, when average retail price inflation dropped to 18.5 per cent and 29.8 per cent, respectively (see Appendix Table 1). Growth rates from 1994 to 1997 were higher than in several other SEE countries, but in 1998, GMP increased by only 2.6 per cent. Due to the country’s unregulated status in international financial institutions and its high political risk, there has been a very limited inflow of foreign finance. From 1990 to 1998, foreign direct investment (FDI) amounted to a bit over $1 billion, almost entirely due to the 1997 privatization of Serbian Telecom, of which 49 per cent was sold to Italian and Greek partners. Sluggish export performance after the lifting of the sanctions in 1996-97 determined a large current account deficit, which has been somewhat reduced but remains far above the danger level — $1.2 billion in 1999, corresponding to 9.4 per cent of GMP (EIU, 2000: 9). Foreign exchange reserves are only around $300 million, while the country’s gross external debt in 1999 was $14.1 billion (EIU, 2000). After the Kosovo conflict, all economic indicators worsened notably in 1999. Real GMP declined by 19.3 per cent, as did GMP per capita by 20 per cent and industrial production by 21.5 per cent. Exports decreased by as much as 50 per cent and imports by around 30 per cent (see Appendix Table 1). The country’s GMP in 1999 dropped to around 40 per cent of its 1989 level. Inflation has been increasing — in September 1999, a 12.4 per cent monthly rate was recorded — though the annual inflation rate in 1999 has not exceeded 50 per cent. The government has decreed a price freeze, forcing enterprises to lower prices to their mid-October 1999 level, which seems to have only provoked shortages, thus repressing inflationary pressures instead of reducing them. The black market exchange rate in mid-January 2000 was more than three-and-a-half times the official rate (approaching 22 dinars to the Deutschmark, in comparison to the official rate of 6 dinars to the Deutschmark), rising further to 32-35 dinars to the Deutschmark in late 9 The average annual retail price inflation in 1993 amounted to 116.5 trillion, which corresponds to a 15-digit inflation rate (EIU, 1995: 28). 9 September 2000.10 Because of very low reserves, if radical economic reforms are not implemented, a serious international liquidity crisis is expected by 2001 (Pitic et al., 1999). FRY has become one of Europe’s poorest countries. In 1999, with an estimated GDP per capita at the PPP rate of around $2,580, it was only marginally better off than Albania ($2,420) and behind all other countries in the SEE region (EIU, 2000: 30). By December 1999, the average net Yugoslav salary had declined to DM 95, down from DM 167 a year earlier, and was not even sufficient to buy half of the average basket of goods. For years, pensions and salaries have been paid after several months’ delay, frequently in kind, while the last few months they have been paid with coupons for electricity (which, ironically, at present is being rationed). The official unemployment rate is close to 30 per cent, but this figure neglects another 20 per cent in surplus labor, those who are officially employed but effectively without work. Around 90,000 workers alone have lost their jobs due to the destruction of industrial facilities during the recent war. ECONOMIC REFORMS Progress in institutional reforms has been extremely slow and disappointing, since strong anti-reform forces are still influential, and vested interests impede radical change. This refers primarily to Serbia, since Montenegro has tried to implement more radical measures in several areas which are under its own competence (and not those of the federation). According to the author’s own rough estimates of EBRD’s three groups of transition indicators — markets and trade, enterprise privatization, financial institutions — in 1997 FRY lagged behind the other SEE countries in most fields (Uvalic, 1997c). Very little progress has been made since then, while in some areas there has been a reversal in policies, deteriorating the situation further. As recently stated by Vladimir Gligorov, the economic policy and institutional development pursued by the Yugoslav government can be viewed as moving in a retrograde fashion, with centralization, nationalization, antiliberalization, anti-stabilization and corruption as its main features (Gligorov, 1999). Regarding EBRD indicators on markets and trade, the Yugoslav government has continuously implemented measures of strong administrative control rather than 10 Not surprisingly, at the beginning of November 1999, Montenegro decided to introduce a parallel currency, the Deutschmark, on its way (possibly) towards full independence. 10 liberalization. Price liberalization has been partial, even reversed on several occasions by general or selective price freezes. The foreign exchange system, even after the lifting of sanctions in late 1995, remained subject to restrictions such as widespread import and export licenses, import quotas, high import duties and associated charges, nonconvertibility of the dinar and rationing of foreign exchange. The government recently adopted a competition law, but since the economy remains highly monopolized, it seems clear the law is not being implemented. As for the second group of EBRD indicators, only small-scale privatization has been partially implemented, resulting mainly in widespread ownership by insiders, who, given the enormous losses in much of the economy, today own worthless shares in highly undercapitalized enterprises. Large enterprises have still not been privatized or restructured (Serbian Telecom is the major exception), though current financial constraints may compel the government to start selling shares in the most profitable enterprises, such as the Serbian oil industry company, NIS. Finally, little progress has been made in reforming banks and other financial institutions. A serious liquidity crisis continues throughout the banking sector. Banks are heavily burdened by enormous amounts of bad loans, and the unresolved problem of citizens’ “frozen” foreign currency savings, because of lost confidence, prevents the inflow of new deposits (which are kept instead under mattresses or abroad). The fall 1999 measures towards major centralization, imposing the merger of some 22 Serbian banks within Beobanka, a major bank, run counter to the liberalization of banking operations applied elsewhere. Although there is a market for government securities, due to delays in privatization, a stock exchange for enterprise shares is not yet operational. Undoubtedly, the main problem with the Yugoslav economy is the lack of fundamental systemic change. Yet, it is too simplistic to say, as is sometimes done, that economic transformation never got started in FRY. Many important laws, which seem fully in line with requirements for transition to a market economy, have formally been adopted. Some were taken over from the legislation of former Yugoslavia, while others were elaborated after 1991. These include a company law, several privatization laws, a bankruptcy and liquidation law, a competition law, a new law on foreign direct investment providing major incentives to investors, a value-added tax law and even an investment funds law currently in draft form (Federal Ministry, 1999). However, some of these laws contain provisions that clearly point to an unwillingness to abandon pre-1989 institutions. Others simply are not put into practice, or are implemented in a highly selective way — primarily 11 in favor of state-owned enterprises and a dozen others that are private but protected by the state. To illustrate the point, we can take the example of privatization as a pillar of the present transition. So far, FRY has had at least half a dozen privatization laws.11 Nevertheless, the reluctance to abandon the old concept of “social property” has led to solutions that do not ensure the implementation of quick, comprehensive and compulsory privatization, as proposed in 1996 by governor Avramovic (Avramovic and Uvalic, 1996). Some of the most profitable Serbian enterprises have been excluded for now from privatization, or were privatized ten years ago, often using opaque methods that enabled asset stripping and the transfer of substantial amounts of money to private bank accounts abroad. Under the most recent Serbian legislation, some 75 state-owned enterprises, which are among the largest and most profitable firms and represent 35 per cent of the Yugoslav economy’s total capital, are for the moment excluded from privatization, to be privatized according to a “special government program.” Thus, little has been privatized: at the end of 1998, only around 37 per cent of Yugoslav GMP was produced in the private sector,12 while only 31 per cent of the active population was employed in the private, cooperative and mixed sector (including those who are self-employed in agriculture). By the end of 1998, only 20 per cent of the social sector enterprises, to be privatized according to the 1997 law, have completed the capital evaluation procedure. Other objectives of transition have been pursued just as inefficiently. Most laws are implemented in a highly arbitrary way, with different criteria applied to different segments of the economy, implying the absence of rule of law. This has had very negative and farreaching consequences, since it has contributed to the concentration of power in a handful of state-protected firms. For these enterprises, soft budget constraints have been maintained through direct and indirect privileges — selective bank credits, subsidized interest rates, exclusivity in acquiring import permits or access to foreign currency at the official exchange rate and a relaxation or canceling of tax obligations. A close relationship has been established between the political and economic elite, providing for the overlap of economic and political competencies. Until the October 2000 political 11 These include the 1990 federal privatization law adopted by the former Yugoslav government, the 1992 Serbian privatization law, the 1994 Serbian revaluation law, which practically negated previous privatization, and the new Serbian privatization law adopted in 1997. In the meantime, Montenegro has also introduced its own privatization laws in 1992 and 1996 (a third is now being prepared), while a new federal privatization law was adopted in 1996. 12 Although another 27 per cent is produced in the mixed sector, which is being privatized, it is not clear what percentage of capital in these firms is actually private. 12 changes, the directors of the 30 most important enterprises were at the same time key politicians, parliament members, ministers in the Yugoslav government and President Milosevic’s closest political collaborators. Corruption has become the key feature of economic, political and social relations. Numerous sanctions have provided authorities with an alibi for the miserable situation in society and created strong incentives for the emergence of organized crime and war profiteering. Recruited in part from criminals, a new “elite” has emerged, in which the state apparatus and organized crime have grown together (Babic, 1999). According to a 1999 report by Transparency International, FRY is among the top ten most corrupted countries in the world and the most corrupted country in SEE, with a Corruption Perceptions Index of 2 (the index ranges from 1 to 10, with the highest score indicating no corruption; Transition, 1999). Much of Serbia’s economy is conducted as part of a black or gray economy. According to different estimates, the informal economy accounts for 30 per cent-50 per cent of GDP. By mid-2000, the Milosevic government had lost all credibility, among other reasons because it has directly or indirectly been responsible for the loss of some $6.5 to $7 billion of the population’s foreign exchange savings. The sum has been confiscated from Yugoslav citizens over the last decade using various methods — foreign exchange savings “frozen” in banks of former Yugoslavia; government bonds issued for Serbia’s reconstruction but with a value eaten up by inflation; pyramid schemes offered by two major private, or rather, para-state, banks, since they were set up in collaboration with the authorities; and the 1992-93 hyperinflation, which forced citizens to sell all their foreign currency savings to survive (Dinkic, 1995). These are among the reasons why the 2000 elections ensured full victory to the DOS Presidential candidate Mr. Kostunica. The ultimate and most negative consequence of the present political and economic system in FRY, shaped throughout these years by policies strictly in the function of selfinterest of the ruling political and economic elite, is extreme social stratification — massive pauperization of large segments of the population and rapid enrichment of those individuals who until recently represented the elite in power controlling the whole country (termed “warlike entrepreneurs”; Babic, 1999). Unfortunately, this aspect of the present crisis in FRY — the extreme polarization of society — is likely to leave long-lasting negative consequences. 13 CONCLUSIONS The election of a democratic government finally opens a new era for FRY after ten years of wars, sanctions, isolation, and mismanagement. Accumulated problems in all fields are numerous, but President Kostunica has been addressing them wisely and with determination. Among the top priorities of the new government is the return of FRY into international organizations, intensifying its relations with the European Union, and finding a mutually acceptable solution for the future of the Yugoslav federation. Strong international financial support is urgently needed through all possible multilateral and bilateral channels, as otherwise the new government will not be able to carry forward the complex and numerous tasks which it must address immediately — not least, the problem of energy shortages. The new government is relying on the expertise of the nongovernmental organization G17 Plus, an expert network which has prepared, well before the September 2000 elections, a “Program of the Democratic Opposition of Serbia” (G17 Plus, 2000), officially accepted by the democratic opposition alliance DOS. This document also contains a detailed program of economic reforms, which hopefully will soon start being implemented. Although radical economic reforms are likely to be costly in the short term, they are unavoidable and must be seen in the light of substantial benefits expected in the medium and longer-term. 14 APPENDIX Table 1. FR Yugoslavia – Main macroeconomic indicators 1995 1996 1997 Real GMP growth 6.1 3.5 7.4 (%) Average retail 74.1 93.1 18.5 price inflation (%) Exports fob 1.4 1.8 2.7 ($ bn) Imports fob 2.4 4.1 4.8 ($ bn) Gross external 13.8 13.4 12.9 debt ($ bn) Source: EIU (2000). Some figures for 1999 are EIU estimates. 1998 2.6 1999 -19.3 29.8 42.0 2.9 1.5 4.8 3.3 14.0 14.1 15 REFERENCES Avramovic, Dragoslav (1995) “Reconstruction of the Monetary System and Economic Recovery of Yugoslavia, 1994: Analytic Framework, Results and Problems”, WIIW Research Report, 216. Avramovic, Dragoslav and Milica Uvalic (1996) “Demokratizacija svojinskih odnosa na liniji privatizacije” in Ekonomika, 32, 6/7: 313-318. Babic, Stojan (1999) “The Political Economy of Adjustments to Sanctions: The Case of Serbia” (Mimeo: Belgrade). Bianchini, Stefano, and Milica Uvalic (eds.) (1997) The Balkans and the Challenge of Economic Integration: Regional and European Perspectives (Ravenna: Longo Editore). Dinkic, Mladjan (1995) The Economics of Destruction: Can it Happen to You? (VIN: Belgrade). Economist Intelligence Unit (1995) Country Report — Yugoslavia (Serbia - Montenegro). ____(1999a) Country Forecast — Economies in Transition — Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union — Regional Overview. ____(1999b) Country Report — Yugoslavia (Serbia - Montenegro). ____ (2000) Country Report — Yugoslavia (Serbia - Montenegro). Ekonomist, Belgrade weekly, 1999-2000, various issues. Federal Ministry of Development, Science and Environment & Federal Bureau of Development and Economic Policy. Ekonomski Pregled (Economic Survey) (Belgrade: monthly, various issues). ____(1999) SR Jugoslavija – 1998 Ekonomski Pregled. Gligorov, Vladimir (1999) “The Kosovo Crisis and the Balkans: Background, Consequences, Costs and Prospects,” WIIW Current Analyses and Country Profiles 13. Group 17 (1999) Final Account — Economic Consequences of NATO Bombing — Estimate of the Damage and Finances Required for the Economic Reconstruction of Yugoslavia. G17 Plus (2000) Program demokratske opozicije Srbije za demokratsku Srbiju (Belgrade). Kekic, Laza (1996) “Assessing and Measuring Progress in the Transition” in Economist Intelligence Unit, Country Forecast — Economies in Transition — Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union – Regional Overview: 5-22. Pitic, Goran et al (1999) Yugoslav Economy after the War (Belgrade: Economics Institute). 16 Transition: The Newsletter about Reforming Economies. The World Bank in collaboration with the William Davidson Institute (October 1999). United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (1999) Economic Survey of Europe 2. Uvalic, Milica (1992) Investment and Property Rights in Yugoslavia: The Long Transition to a Market Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). ____(1997a) “European Economic Integration: What Role for the Balkans?” in Stefano Bianchini and Milica Uvalic (eds.) The Balkans and the Challenge of Economic Integration: Regional and European Perspectives (Ravenna: Longo Editore): 19-34. ____(1997b) “Economic Problems and Prospects of the Successor States of Former Yugoslavia” in Stefano Bianchini and Milica Uvalic (eds.) The Balkans and the Challenge of Economic Integration: Regional and European Perspectives (Ravenna: Longo Editore): 161-184. ____(1997c) “Is There a Southern Tier of Transition Economies?” Paper presented at the First Economic Workshop of the Institute for Southeastern Europe (Central European University, Budapest). 17