Download economics in action

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Art auction wikipedia , lookup

Artificial intelligence in video games wikipedia , lookup

The Evolution of Cooperation wikipedia , lookup

Evolutionary game theory wikipedia , lookup

Chicken (game) wikipedia , lookup

Prisoner's dilemma wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
THIRD EDITION
ECONOMICS
and
MICROECONOMICS
Paul Krugman | Robin Wells
Chapter 14
Oligopoly
WHAT YOU
WILL LEARN
IN THIS
CHAPTER
• The meaning of oligopoly, and why it
occurs
• Why oligopolists have an incentive to act
in ways that reduce their combined
profit, and why they can benefit from
collusion
• How our understanding of oligopoly can
be enhanced by using game theory,
especially the concept of the prisoners’
dilemma
• How repeated interactions among
oligopolists can help them achieve tacit
collusion
• How oligopoly works in practice, under
the legal constraints of antitrust policy
The Prevalence of Oligopoly
• In addition to perfect competition and monopoly, oligopoly
and monopolistic competition are also important types of
market structure.
 They are forms of imperfect competition.
• Oligopoly is a common market structure.
 It arises from the same forces that lead to monopoly, except in
a weaker form.
 It is an industry with only a small number of producers.
 A producer in such an industry is known as an oligopolist.
• When no one firm has a monopoly, but producers
nonetheless realize that they can affect market prices, an
industry is characterized by imperfect competition.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Is It An Oligopoly or Not?
• To get a better picture of market structure, economists often
use a measure called the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index, or
HHI.
 The HHI for an industry is the square of each firm’s share of
market sales summed over the firms in the industry.
 For example, if an industry contains only 3 firms and their
market shares are 60%, 25%, and 15%, then the HHI for the
industry is:
HHI = 602 + 252 + 152 = 4,450
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Is It An Oligopoly or Not?
• According to Justice Department guidelines, an HHI below
1,000 indicates a strongly competitive market, between
1,000 and 1,800 indicates a somewhat competitive
market, and above 1,800 indicates an oligopoly.
• In an industry with an HHI above 1,000, a merger that
results in a significant increase in the HHI will receive
special scrutiny and is likely to be disallowed.
Some Oligopolistic Industries
Understanding Oligopoly
• Some of the key issues in oligopoly can be understood by
looking at the simplest case, a duopoly.
• An oligopoly consisting of only two firms is a duopoly. Each
firm is a duopolist.
• With only two firms in the industry, each would realize that
by producing more, it would drive down the market price.
• So each firm would, like a monopolist, realize that profits
would be higher if it limited its production.
• So how much will the two firms produce?
Understanding Oligopoly
• One possibility is that the two companies will engage in
collusion. Sellers engage in collusion when they cooperate to
raise each others’ profits.
• The strongest form of collusion is a cartel, an agreement by
several producers to obey output restrictions to increase
their joint profits.
• They may also engage in noncooperative behavior, ignoring
the effects of their actions on each others’ profits.
Understanding Oligopoly
• By acting as if they were a single monopolist, oligopolists can
maximize their combined profits.
 So, there is an incentive to form a cartel.
• However, each firm has an incentive to cheat—to produce
more than it is supposed to under the cartel agreement.
 So, there are two principal outcomes: successful collusion or
behaving noncooperatively by cheating.
• When firms ignore the effects of their actions on each
others’ profits, they engage in noncooperative behavior.
 It is likely to be easier to achieve informal collusion when
firms in an industry face capacity constraints.
Competing in Prices vs. Competing in Quantities
• Firms may decide to engage in quantity competition or price
competition.
• The basic insight of the quantity competition (or the Cournot
model) is that when firms are restricted in how much they
can produce, it is easier for them to avoid excessive
competition and to “divvy up” the market, thereby pricing
above marginal cost and earning profits.
• It is easier for them to achieve an outcome that looks like
collusion without a formal agreement.
Competing in Prices vs. Competing in Quantities
 The logic behind the price competition (or the Bertrand
model) is that when firms produce perfect substitutes and
have sufficient capacity to satisfy demand when price is
equal to marginal cost, then each firm will be compelled to
engage in competition by undercutting its rival’s price until
the price reaches marginal cost—that is, perfect
competition.
GLOBAL COMPARISON
Europe Levels the Playing Field for Coke and Pepsi
• In the United States, Coke and Pepsi have maintained
relatively similar market shares: 44% versus 32% in 2004.
• In that same year, thanks to the exclusivity deals that Coke
regularly signed with shops, bars, and restaurants across
Europe, Coke’s market shares in Europe were several times
Pepsi’s, as you can see in the following graph—that is, until
European regulators finally made their move, also in 2004.
• Not surprisingly, Pepsi applauded the change in European
policy toward exclusive dealing.
GLOBAL COMPARISON
Europe Levels the Playing Field for Coke and Pepsi
Coke and Pepsi
Market Shares
Coke
75%
Pepsi
68%
60%
51%
50
44%
32%
25
5%
6%
5%
Belgium
France
Germany
0
United States
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
The Great Vitamin Conspiracy
• In the late 1990s, some of the world’s largest drug
companies agreed to pay billions of dollars in damages to
customers after being convicted of a huge conspiracy to rig
the world vitamin market.
• The conspiracy began in 1989 when the Swiss company
Roche and the German company BASF began secret talks
about setting prices and dividing up markets for bulk
vitamins sold mainly to other companies.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
The Great Vitamin Conspiracy
• How could it have happened? The main answer probably
lies in different national traditions about how to treat
oligopolists.
• The United States has a long tradition of taking tough legal
action against price-fixing. European governments,
however, have historically been much less stringent.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Bitter Chocolate?
• Millions of chocolate lovers around the world have been
spending more and more to satisfy their cravings, and
regulators in Germany, Canada, and the United States have
become suspicious.
 They are investigating whether the seven leading chocolate
companies—including Mars, Kraft Foods, Nestle, Hershey, and
Cadbury—have been colluding to raise prices.
 The amount of money involved could well run into the billions
of dollars.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Bitter Chocolate?
• Many of the nation’s largest grocery stores and snack
retailers are convinced that they have been the victims of
collusion.
• They claim that the chocolate industry has responded to
stagnant consumer sales by price-fixing, an allegation the
chocolate makers have vigorously denied.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Bitter Chocolate?
• What’s clear is that chocolate candy prices have been
soaring, climbing by 17% from 2008 to 2010, while sales fell
by about 7%.
 Chocolate makers defend their actions, contending that they
were simply passing on increases in their costs.
• However, critics claim that the price of cocoa beans, the
main ingredient in chocolate, was stable from 2003 to 2007
and that sugar prices were similarly stable during that time,
except for a brief spike in 2005, a period in which chocolate
prices were rising.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
• To prove collusion, there must be some evidence of
conversations or written agreements.
• Such evidence has emerged in our chocolate case.
 According to the Canadian press, 13 Cadbury executives
voluntarily provided information to the courts about contacts
between the companies, including a 2005 episode in which a
Nestle executive handed over a brown envelope containing
details about a forthcoming price hike to a Cadbury
employee.
• And, according to affidavits submitted to a Canadian court,
top executives at Hershey, Mars, and Nestle met secretly in
coffee shops, in restaurants, and at conventions to set
prices.
The Prisoners’ Dilemma
• When the decisions of two or more firms significantly affect
each others’ profits, they are in a situation of
interdependence.
• The study of behavior in situations of interdependence is
known as game theory.
• The reward received by a player in a game—such as the
profit earned by an oligopolist—is that player’s payoff.
• A payoff matrix shows how the payoff to each of the
participants in a two-player game depends on the actions of
both. Such a matrix helps us analyze interdependence.
A Payoff Matrix
Ajinomoto
Produce 30 million
pounds
Ajinomoto makes $180
million profit.
Produce 40 million
pounds
Ajinomoto makes $200
million profit.
Produce 30
million
pounds
ADM
ADM makes $180
million profit
Ajinomoto makes $160
million profit.
ADM makes $150
million profit
Ajinomoto makes $150
million profit.
Produce 40
million
pounds
ADM makes $200
million profit
ADM makes
$160million profit
The Prisoners’ Dilemma
• Economists use game theory to study firms’ behavior when
there is interdependence between their payoffs.
• The game can be represented with a payoff matrix.
 Depending on the payoffs, a player may or may not have a
dominant strategy.
• When each firm has an incentive to cheat, but both are worse
off if both cheat, the situation is known as a prisoners’
dilemma.
The Prisoners’ Dilemma
• The game is based on two premises:
1) Each player has an incentive to choose an action that
benefits itself at the other player’s expense.
2) When both players act in this way, both are worse off
than if they had acted cooperatively.
The Prisoners’ Dilemma
Louise
Don’t confess
Louise gets 5-year
sentence.
Confess
Louise gets 2-year
sentence.
Don’t
confess
Thelma
Thelma gets 5-year
sentence.
Louise gets 20-year
sentence.
Thelma gets 20-year
sentence.
Louise gets 15-year
sentence.
Confess
Thelma gets 2-year
sentence.
Thelma gets 15-year
sentence.
The Prisoners’ Dilemma
 An action is a dominant strategy when it is a player’s best
action regardless of the action taken by the other player.
Depending on the payoffs, a player may or may not have a
dominant strategy.
 A Nash equilibrium, also known as a noncooperative
equilibrium, is the result when each player in a game
chooses the action that maximizes his or her payoff given
the actions of other players, ignoring the effects of his or her
action on the payoffs received by those other players.
Overcoming the Prisoners’ Dilemma
Repeated Interaction and Tacit Collusion
• Players who don’t take their interdependence into account
arrive at a Nash, or noncooperative, equilibrium.
 But if a game is played repeatedly, players may engage in
strategic behavior, sacrificing short-run profit to influence
future behavior.
 In repeated prisoners’ dilemma games, tit for tat is often a
good strategy, leading to successful tacit collusion.
Overcoming the Prisoners’ Dilemma
Repeated Interaction and Tacit Collusion
• Tit for tat involves playing cooperatively at first, then doing
whatever the other player did in the previous period.
• When firms limit production and raise prices in a way that
raises each others’ profits, even though they have not made
any formal agreement, they are engaged in tacit collusion.
How Repeated Interaction Can Support Collusion
Ajinomoto
Tit for tat
Ajinomoto makes $180 million
profit each year.
Always cheat
Ajinomoto makes $200
million profit 1st year,
$160 profit each later
year.
Tit for tat
ADM
ADM makes $180
million profit each year.
Ajinomoto makes $150
million profit 1st year,
$160 million profit each
later year.
ADM makes $150
million profit 1st year,
$160 million profit each
later year.
Ajinomoto makes $160 million
profit each year.
Always cheat
ADM makes $200
million profit 1st year,
$160 million profit
each later year.
ADM makes $160
million profit each year.
The Kinked Demand Curve
 An oligopolist who believes she will lose a substantial
number of sales if she reduces output and increases her
price, but will gain only a few additional sales if she
increases output and lowers her price away from the tacit
collusion outcome, faces a kinked demand curve—very flat
above the kink and very steep below the kink.
 It illustrates how tacit collusion can make an oligopolist
unresponsive to changes in marginal cost within a certain
range when those changes are unique to her.
The Kinked Demand Curve
Price, cost
marginal
revenue
W
Tacit collusion
outcome
MC
P*
1
MC
2
X
1. Any marginal
cost in this
region
Y
MR
D
Q*
Z
2. … corresponds to this level of
output
Quantity
FOR INQUIRING MINDS
Prisoners of the Arms Race
• Between World War II and the late 1980s, the United States
and the Soviet Union were locked in a struggle that never
broke out into open war. During this Cold War, both
countries spent huge sums on arms, sums that were a
significant drain on the U.S. economy and eventually proved
a crippling burden for the Soviet Union, whose underlying
economic base was much weaker.
• Both nations would have been better off if they had both
spent less on arms. Yet the arms race continued for 40
years. Why?
FOR INQUIRING MINDS
Prisoners of the Arms Race
• As political scientists were quick to notice, one way to
explain the arms race was to suppose that the two countries
were locked in a classic prisoners’ dilemma.
 Each government would have liked to achieve decisive military
superiority, and each feared military inferiority.
• But both would have preferred a stalemate with low military
spending to one with high spending.
 However, each government rationally chose to engage in high
spending.
FOR INQUIRING MINDS
Prisoners of the Arms Race
• If its rival did not spend heavily, its own high spending
would lead to military superiority; not spending heavily
would lead to inferiority if the other government continued
its arms buildup.
 So, the countries were trapped.
• The answer to this trap could have been an agreement not
to spend as much; indeed, the two sides tried repeatedly to
negotiate limits on some kinds of weapons.
 But these agreements weren’t very effective.
• In the end the issue was resolved as heavy military spending
hastened the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
The Rise and Fall and Rise of OPEC
 OPEC includes 13 national governments (Algeria, Angola,
Ecuador, Indonesia, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Qatar,
Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, and Venezuela) and
it controls 40% of the world’s oil exports and 80% of its
proven reserves.
 In any given year it is in their combined interest to keep
output low and prices high.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
The Rise and Fall and Rise of OPEC
 So how successful is the cartel?
 OPEC first demonstrated its muscle in 1974: in the aftermath
of a war in the Middle East, several OPEC producers limited
their output—and they liked the results so much that they
decided to continue the practice.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
The Rise and Fall and Rise of OPEC
 By the mid-1980s, however, there was a growing glut of oil
on world markets, and cheating by cash-short OPEC
members became widespread.
 The result, in 1985, was that producers who had tried to play
by the rules got fed up and collusion collapsed.
 The cartel began to act effectively again at the end of the
1990s, thanks largely to the efforts of Mexico’s oil minister to
orchestrate output reductions.
 The cartel’s actions helped raise the price of oil from less than
$10 a barrel in 1998 to a range of $20 to $30 a barrel in 2003.
The Ups and Downs of Oil Cartels
Oligopoly in Practice
• Oligopolies operate under legal restrictions in the form of
antitrust policy.
• Antitrust policies are efforts undertaken by the government
to prevent oligopolistic industries from becoming or behaving
like monopolies.
 But many succeed in achieving tacit collusion.
• Tacit collusion is limited by a number of factors, including:




large numbers of firms
complex products and pricing scheme
bargaining power of buyers
conflicts of interest among firms
GLOBAL COMPARISON
• The European Union is
believed to be stricter in
imposing antitrust
actions than the United
States.
• Companies prefer the
American system and the
accompanying figure
clarifies why.
• In recent years, on
average, fines for unfair
competition have been
higher in the European
Union than in the United
States.
Contrasting Approaches to Anti-Trust
Regulation
Product Differentiation and Price Leadership
• When collusion breaks down, there is a price war.
• To limit competition, oligopolists often engage in product
differentiation, which is an attempt by a firm to convince
buyers that its product is different from the products of
other firms in the industry.
• When products are differentiated, it is sometimes possible
for an industry to achieve tacit collusion through price
leadership.
• Oligopolists often avoid competing directly on price,
engaging in nonprice competition through advertising and
other means instead.
Product Differentiation and Price Leadership
 In price leadership, one firm sets its price first, and other
firms then follow.
 Firms that have a tacit understanding not to compete on
price often engage in intense nonprice competition, using
advertising and other means to try to increase their sales.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Price Wars of Christmas
• The toy aisles of American retailers have often been the
scene of cut-throat competition.
 During the 2011 Christmas shopping season, Target priced the
latest Elmo doll at 89 cents less than Walmart (for those with a
coupon), and $6 less than Toys “R” Us. So extreme is the price
cutting that since 2003 three toy retailers—KB Toys, FAO
Schwartz, and Zany Brainy—have been forced into bankruptcy.
• What is happening? The turmoil can be traced back to
trouble in the toy industry itself as well as to changes in toy
retailing–in the form of Internet sales.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Price Wars of Christmas
• Besides the Internet, there have also been new entrants into
the toy business: Walmart and Target have expanded their
number of stores and have been aggressive price - cutters.
• The result is much like a story of tacit collusion sustained by
repeated interaction run in reverse: because the overall
industry is in a state of decline and there are new entrants,
the future payoff from collusion is shrinking.
 The predictable outcome is a price war.
ECONOMICS IN ACTION
Price Wars of Christmas
• Since retailers depend on holiday sales for nearly half of
their annual sales, the holidays are a time of particularly
intense price-cutting.
• Traditionally, the biggest shopping day of the year has been
the day after Thanksgiving.
 But in an effort to expand sales and undercut rivals,
retailers—particularly Walmart—have now begun their pricecutting earlier in the fall.
Summary
1. Many industries are oligopolies: there are only a few
sellers. In particular, a duopoly has only two sellers.
Oligopolies exist for more or less the same reasons that
monopolies exist, but in weaker form. They are
characterized by imperfect competition: firms compete
but possess market power.
Summary
2. Predicting the behavior of oligopolists poses something of
a puzzle. The firms in an oligopoly could maximize their
combined profits by acting as a cartel, setting output levels
for each firm as if they were a single monopolist; to the
extent that firms manage to do this, they engage in
collusion. But each individual firm has an incentive to
produce more than it would in such an arrangement—to
engage in noncooperative behavior.
Summary
3. The situation of interdependence, in which each firm’s
profit depends noticeably on what other firms do, is the
subject of game theory.
In the case of a game with two players, the payoff of each
player depends both on its own actions and on the actions
of the other; this interdependence can be represented as a
payoff matrix.
Depending on the structure of payoffs in the payoff matrix,
a player may have a dominant strategy—an action that is
always the best regardless of the other player’s actions.
Summary
4. Duopolists face a particular type of game known as a
prisoners’ dilemma; if each acts independently in its own
interest, the resulting Nash equilibrium (or
noncooperative equilibrium) will be bad for both.
However, firms that expect to play a game repeatedly tend
to engage in strategic behavior, trying to influence each
other’s future actions. A particular strategy that seems to
work well in such situations is tit for tat, which often leads
to tacit collusion.
Summary
5. The kinked demand curve illustrates how an oligopolist
that faces unique changes in its marginal cost within a
certain range may choose not to adjust its output and price
in order to avoid a breakdown in tacit collusion.
6. In order to limit the ability of oligopolists to collude and act
like monopolists, most governments pursue an antitrust
policy designed to make collusion more difficult. In
practice, however, tacit collusion is widespread.
Summary
7. A variety of factors make tacit collusion difficult: large
numbers of firms, complex products and pricing,
differences in interests, and bargaining power of buyers.
When tacit collusion breaks down, there is a price war.
Oligopolists try to avoid price wars in various ways, such
as through product differentiation and through price
leadership, in which one firm sets prices for the industry.
Another is through nonprice competition, like
advertising.
KEY TERMS
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Oligopoly
Oligopolist
Imperfect competition
Duopoly
Duopolist
Collusion
Cartel
Noncooperative behavior
Interdependence
Game theory
Payoff
Payoff matrix
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Prisoners’ dilemma
Dominant strategy
Nash equilibrium
Noncooperative equilibrium
Strategic behavior
Tit for tat
Tacit collusion
Antitrust policy
Price war
Product differentiation
Price leadership
Nonprice competition