Download Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Competition law wikipedia , lookup

Marginalism wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Perfect competition wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
In this chapter, look for the answers to these
questions:
• Why do monopolies arise?
• Why is MR < P for a monopolist?
• How do monopolies choose their P and Q?
• How do monopolies affect society’s well-being?
• What can the government do about monopolies?
• What is price discrimination?
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Monopoly
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE
• While a competitive firm is a price taker, a
monopoly firm is a price maker.
• A firm is considered a monopoly if . . .
– it is the sole seller of its product.
– its product does not have close substitutes.
• In this chapter, we study monopoly and
contrast it with perfect competition.
• The key difference:
A monopoly firm has market power, the
ability to influence the market price of the
product it sells. A competitive firm has no
market power.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
• The fundamental cause of monopoly is
barriers to entry.
• Barriers to entry have three sources:
– Ownership of a key resource.
– The government gives a single firm the exclusive
right to produce some good.
– Costs of production make a single producer more
efficient than a large number of producers.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Monopoly Resources
Government-Created Monopolies
• Although exclusive ownership of a key
resource is a potential source of monopoly, in
practice monopolies rarely arise for this reason.
• Governments may restrict entry by giving a
single firm the exclusive right to sell a
particular good in certain markets.
• Patent and copyright laws are two important
examples of how government creates a
monopoly to serve the public interest.
Example: DeBeers owns most of the world’s
diamond mines
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
1
Natural Monopolies
Figure 1 Economies of Scale as a Cause of Monopoly
Cost
• An industry is a natural monopoly when a single
firm can supply a good or service to an entire
market at a smaller cost than could two or more
firms.
• A natural monopoly arises when there are
economies of scale over the relevant range of
output.
• Example: 1000 homes need electricity.
• ATC is lower if one firm services all 1000 homes
than if two firms each service 500 homes.
Average
total
cost
Quantity of Output
0
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION
AND PRICING DECISIONS
Figure 2 Demand Curves for Competitive and Monopoly
Firms
(a) A Competitive Firm’s Demand Curve
• Monopoly versus Competition
Price
(b) A Monopolist’s Demand Curve
Price
– Monopoly
•
•
•
•
Is the sole producer
Faces a downward-sloping demand curve
Is a price maker
Reduces price to increase sales
Demand
– Competitive Firm
•
•
•
•
Demand
Is one of many producers
Faces a horizontal demand curve
Is a price taker
Sells as much or as little at same price
0
Quantity of Output
0
Quantity of Output
Since a monopoly is the sole
producer in its market, it faces
the market demand curve.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
A Monopoly’s Revenue
Table 1 A Monopoly’s Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue
• Total Revenue
• P × Q = TR
• Average Revenue
• TR/Q = AR = P
• Marginal Revenue
• ∆TR/∆ Q = MR
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
2
Figure 3 Demand and Marginal-Revenue Curves for a Monopoly
A Monopoly’s Revenue
Price
• A Monopoly’s Marginal Revenue
• A monopolist’s marginal revenue is always less
than the price of its good.
• The demand curve is downward sloping.
• When a monopoly drops the price to sell one more unit,
the revenue received from previously sold units also
decreases.
• When a monopoly increases the amount it sells, it
has two effects on total revenue (P × Q).
• The output effect—more output is sold, so Q is higher.
• The price effect—price falls, so P is lower.
If a monopoly wants to sell
more, it must lower price.
$11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
–4
Price falls for ALL units sold.
This is why MR is < P.
Demand
(average
revenue)
Marginal
revenue
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Quantity of Water
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Profit Maximization
Figure 4 Profit Maximization for a Monopoly
• A monopoly maximizes profit by producing the
quantity at which marginal revenue equals
marginal cost (MR = MC).
• It then uses the demand curve to find the price
that will induce consumers to buy that quantity.
Costs and
Revenue
2. . . . and then the demand
curve shows the price
consistent with this quantity.
B
Monopoly
price
1. The intersection of the
marginal-revenue curve
and the marginal-cost
curve determines the
profit-maximizing
quantity . . .
Average total cost
A
Demand
Marginal
cost
Marginal revenue
0
Q
QMAX
Q
Quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Profit Maximization
A Monopoly’s Profit
• Comparing Monopoly and Competition
• Profit equals total revenue minus total costs.
• For a competitive firm, price equals marginal cost.
• P = MR = MC
• For a monopoly firm, price exceeds marginal cost.
• Profit = TR – TC
• Profit = (TR/Q – TC/Q) × Q
• Profit = (P – ATC) × Q
• P > MR = MC
• Remember, all profit-maximizing firms set
MR = MC.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
• The monopolist will receive economic profits
as long as price is greater than average total
cost.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
3
Figure 5 The Monopolist’s Profit
A Monopoly Does Not Have an S Curve
Costs and
Revenue
A competitive firm
takes P as given
has a supply curve that shows how its Q
depends on P
Marginal cost
Monopoly E
price
B
Monopoly
profit
Average total cost
Average
total D
cost
A monopoly firm
C
Demand
is a “price-maker,” not a “price-taker”
Q does not depend on P;
rather, Q and P are jointly determined by
MC, MR, and the demand curve.
Marginal revenue
0
Quantity
QMAX
So there is no supply curve for monopoly.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Figure 6 The Market for Drugs
THE WELFARE COST OF
MONOPOLY
Costs and
Revenue
Price
during
patent life
Price after
patent
expires
Marginal
cost
Demand
Marginal
revenue
Monopoly
quantity
0
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Competitive
quantity
• In contrast to a competitive firm, the monopoly
charges a price above the marginal cost.
• From the standpoint of consumers, this high
price makes monopoly undesirable.
• However, from the standpoint of the owners of
the firm, the high price makes monopoly very
desirable.
Quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
The Deadweight Loss
Figure 7 The Efficient Level of Output
Price
Marginal cost
Value
to
buyers
• Because a monopoly sets its price above
marginal cost, it places a wedge between the
consumer’s willingness to pay and the
producer’s cost.
Cost
to
monopolist
Value
to
buyers
Cost
to
monopolist
0
• This wedge causes the quantity sold to fall short of
the social optimum.
Demand
(value to buyers)
Quantity
Value to buyers
is greater than
cost to seller.
Efficient
quantity
Value to buyers
is less than
cost to seller.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
4
The Deadweight Loss
Figure 8 The Inefficiency of Monopoly
Price
Deadweight
loss
Marginal cost
• The Inefficiency of Monopoly
• The monopolist produces less than the socially
efficient quantity of output.
Monopoly
price
Marginal
revenue
0
Demand
Monopoly Efficient
quantity quantity
Quantity
• The deadweight loss caused by a monopoly is
similar to the deadweight loss caused by a tax.
• The difference between the two cases is that the
government gets the revenue from a tax,
whereas a private firm gets the monopoly
profit.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Increasing Competition with Antitrust
Laws
PUBLIC POLICY TOWARD
MONOPOLIES
• Government responds to the problem of
monopoly in one of four ways.
– Making monopolized industries more competitive.
– Regulating the behavior of monopolies.
– Turning some private monopolies into public
enterprises.
– Doing nothing at all.
• Antitrust laws are a collection of statutes aimed
at curbing monopoly power.
• Antitrust laws give government various ways to
promote competition.
• They allow government to prevent mergers.
• They allow government to break up companies.
• They prevent companies from performing activities
that make markets less competitive.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Increasing Competition with Antitrust
Laws
• Two Important Antitrust Laws
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Regulation
• Government may regulate the prices that the
monopoly charges.
• Sherman Antitrust Act (1890)
• Reduced the market power of the large and powerful
“trusts” of that time period.
• The allocation of resources will be efficient if price
is set to equal marginal cost.
• Clayton Antitrust Act (1914)
• Strengthened the government’s powers and authorized
private lawsuits.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
5
Figure 9 Marginal-Cost Pricing for a Natural Monopoly
Price
If regulators set P = MC, the
natural monopoly will lose money.
Average total
cost
Loss
Regulated
price
Average total cost
Regulation
• In practice, regulators will allow monopolists to
keep some of the benefits from lower costs in
the form of higher profit, a practice that
requires some departure from marginal-cost
pricing.
Marginal cost
Demand
0
Quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Public Ownership
Doing Nothing
• Rather than regulating a natural monopoly that
is run by a private firm, the government can run
the monopoly itself (e.g. in the United States,
the government runs the Postal Service).
• Government can do nothing at all if the market
failure is deemed small compared to the
imperfections of public policies.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
The Analytics of Price Discrimination
PRICE DISCRIMINATION
• Price discrimination is the business practice of
selling the same good at different prices to
different customers, even though the costs for
producing for the two customers are the same.
• The characteristic used in price discrimination
is willingness to pay (WTP):
– A firm can increase profit by charging a higher
price to buyers with higher WTP.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
• Price discrimination is not possible when a
good is sold in a competitive market since there
are many firms all selling at the market price.
In order to price discriminate, the firm must
have some market power.
• Perfect Price Discrimination
• Perfect price discrimination refers to the situation
when the monopolist knows exactly the willingness
to pay of each customer and can charge each
customer a different price.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
6
The Analytics of Price Discrimination
Figure 10 Welfare with and without Price Discrimination
(a) Monopolist with Single Price
• Two important effects of price discrimination:
Price
• It can increase the monopolist’s profits.
• It can reduce deadweight loss.
Consumer
surplus
Deadweight
loss
Monopoly
price
Profit
Marginal cost
Marginal
revenue
0
Quantity sold
Demand
Quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Figure 10 Welfare with and without Price Discrimination
Examples of Price Discrimination
(b) Monopolist with Perfect Price Discrimination
Price Consumer surplus and
deadweight loss have both Every consumer gets charged a
been converted into profit. different price -- the highest price
they are willing to pay -- so in this
special case, the demand curve is
also MR!
Profit
Marginal cost
•
•
•
•
•
Movie tickets
Airline prices
Discount coupons
Financial aid
Quantity discounts
Demand
Marginal revenue
0
Quantity sold
Quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Price Discrimination in the Real World
Examples of Price Discrimination
• In the real world, perfect price discrimination is
not possible:
Movie tickets
Discounts for seniors, students, and people
who can attend during weekday afternoons.
They are all more likely to have lower WTP
than people who pay full price on Friday night.
Airline prices
Discounts for Saturday-night stayovers help
distinguish business travelers, who usually have
higher WTP, from more price-sensitive leisure
travelers.
• no firm knows every buyer’s WTP
• buyers do not announce it to sellers
• So, firms divide customers into groups
based on some observable trait
that is likely related to WTP, such as age.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
7
Examples of Price Discrimination
Examples of Price Discrimination
Discount coupons
People who have time to clip and organize
coupons are more likely to have lower income
and lower WTP than others.
Need-based financial aid
Low income families have lower WTP for
their children’s college education.
Schools price-discriminate by offering
need-based aid to low income families.
Quantity discounts
A buyer’s WTP often declines with additional
units, so firms charge less per unit for large
quantities than small ones.
Example: A movie theater charges $4 for
a small popcorn and $5 for a large one that’s
twice as big.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
CONCLUSION: THE PREVALENCE
OF MONOPOLY
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Table 2 Competition versus Monopoly: A Summary Comparison
• How prevalent are the problems of
monopolies?
– Monopolies are common.
– Most firms have some control over their prices
because of differentiated products.
– Firms with substantial monopoly power are rare.
– Few goods are truly unique.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
8