Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Sectoral analysis of the Russian economy Svetlana Ledyaeva Aalto University School of Business What we have learned from previous lecture • Decline of the price of oil at the world market and the role of Mikhail Gorbachev`s reforms were important in the collapse of Soviet Union. • Transition reforms were quick, rather spontaneous and have led to a rather deep crisis in the Russian economy. • However, in the period 1999-2013 due to the rise of oil price in the international market and “not bad” macroeconomic policy, Russian economy started to grow. Learning outcomes of this lecture • Transformation of Russian industrial structure in recent two decades. • Industrial aspects of privatization and ownership in Russia. • Concept of Dutch disease – fundamental theoretical concept of Russian economic development. • Dutch disease in Russia. Role of industries in Soviet Economy (4) • Soviet times: one of the world's three top manufacturers of heavy industrial products (including aviation and arms) + richness in natural resources. • Unbalanced economic structure (agriculture, light industries and services were neglected). • Plan allocation of industries. 5 year central plans: First plan 19281933; Last plan (12th) 1986-1990. • Prices were determined by government: Soviet enterprises obtained raw materials such as oil, gas, and coal at prices below world market levels, encouraging waste. • Transportation costs were heavily subsidised, so it encouraged inefficient allocation of some industries. Industrial structure of Soviet Russia (5) Russia’s deviations from “normal” structures of market economies were substantial: • • • • the greater shares of heavy industry, the low shares of services, the high shares of food, consumption, the underutilization of foreign trade. • These structural distortions contributed to the stagnation and decline of the planned economies. Restructuring process of the Russian economy (Yasin 1996) (6) Volume of GDP Stabilization Passive phase Active phase Equillibrium in the low point of crisis Time Restructuring process and dynamics of output of main idustrial sectors in Russia (Yasin 2013) (7) Fuel and energy Level of output Metallurgy Food Chemistry&petrochemistry Met. Food Forestry Chem. Machine and metal processing Forest processing Construction materials Mach. Constr.mat. Consumer goods Years Passive phase Active phase Changes in industrial structure during transition: Summary (8) • The output of natural resource-based sectors fell by about 30-40% during 1992–1994, other industrial sectors declined by roughly 50-60%. As a result the weight of natural resources- based sectors in the economy increased. • A significant shift from goods production towards the service sector, usually neglected by Soviet planners. In 2003 for Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) service sector accounted for about 46% of GDP (in 1991 - around 30%), and share of industrial production in GDP has fallen from around 54% to about 41%. • The share of raw-materials-producing sectors in industrial output and exports has risen sharply, while the share of processing industries has contracted. Indices of industrial production, % to previous year (9) 120.0 100.0 80.0 Industrial production 60.0 Extraction of natural resources 40.0 Processing industries 20.0 Gas, electricity and water distribution 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 0.0 140.0 120.0 100.0 80.0 Extraction of natural resources 60.0 Extraction of fuel and energy resources 40.0 Extraction of other resources 20.0 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 0.0 Indices of industrial production, processing industries; % to previous year (10) 160.0 Processing industries Including 140.0 Food, tabacco and beverages Textile and garment manufacturing 120.0 Leather, leather goods and shoes manufacturing Wood processing and manufacturing goods from wood 100.0 Pulp and paper manufacturing; publishing and polygraphic activities 80.0 Coke and petrochemicals manufacturing Chemical manufacturing 60.0 Rubber and plastic goods manufacturing Other non-metallic mineral goods manufacturing 40.0 Metallurgy and ready metal goods manufacturing Machine and equipment manufacturing 20.0 Electrical, electronic and optical equipment manufacturing Transport vehicles and equipment manufacturing 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 0.0 Other manufacturing Indices of industrial production, % to 1991 (11) 120 100 80 Industrial production 60 Extraction of natural resources 40 Processing industries 20 Gas, electricity and water distribution 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 0 140 120 100 Extraction of natural resources 80 60 Extraction of fuel and energy resources 40 Extraction of other resources 20 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 0 Indices of industrial production, processing industries; % to 1991 (12) 250 Processing industries Food, tabacco and beverages 200 Textile and garment manufacturing Leather, leather goods and shoes manufacturing Wood processing and manufacturing goods from wood Pulp and paper manufacturing; publishing and polygraphic activities 150 Coke and petrochemicals manufacturing Chemical manufacturing Rubber and plastic goods manufacturing 100 Other non-metallic mineral goods manufacturing Metallurgy and ready metal goods manufacturing Machine and equipment manufacturing 50 Electrical, electronic and optical equipment manufacturing Transport vehicles and equipment manufacturing Other manufacturing 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 0 Indices of industrial production, % of 2007, 2009, 2010, 2013 and 2015 to 1991 (13) Industry %, 2007 to 1991 %, 2009 to 1991 %, 2010 to 1991 %, 2013 to 1991 %, 2015 to 1991 85 76 82 89 88 Extraction of natural resources; including: 105 103 107 111 113 Extraction of fuel and energy resources 117 116 120 124 126 Extraction of other resources 67 57 60 68 70 Processing industries; including: 83 70 78 89 86 Food, tobacco and beverages 87 89 91 99 104 Textile and garment manufacturing 28 22 24 25 22 Leather, leather goods and shoes manufacturing 27 26 32 31 27 Wood processing and manufacturing goods from wood 54 42 47 54 50 126 106 109 117 110 Coke and petrochemicals manufacturing 78 79 84 92 97 Chemical manufacturing 91 82 91 110 117 Rubber and plastic goods manufacturing 113 121 151 200 207 Other non-metallic mineral goods manufacturing 64 41 47 55 52 Metallurgy and ready metal goods manufacturing 100 82 92 103 97 64 42 49 54 44 148 94 112 131 120 59 41 52 69 68 104 83 100 103 100 89 87 89 88 86 Industrial production (total) Pulp and paper manufacturing; publishing and polygraphic activities Machine and equipment manufacturing Electrical, electronic and optical equipment manufacturing Transport vehicles and equipment manufacturing Other manufacturing Gas, electricity and water distribution Industrial structure of GDP in 1960 for Soviet Russia, % (Shumkov 2010) (14) 2.02 2.97 5.4 17.86 3.8 15.31 1.3 0 0.25 5.1 6.03 0.85 18.12 11.7 6.88 2.4 Net taxes Agriculture and forestry Fisheries Mining Manufacturing Electricity and water Construction Trade and repair Hotel and restaurants Transport and communications Finance Leasing property State governance, military security Education Healthcare Other public utilities, social services Industrial structure of GDP in 2010 for modern Russia, % (Shumkov 2010) (15) 2.06 4.11 2.52 1.53 14.88 3.87 0.19 9.4 3.87 7.87 7.99 15.08 0.87 17.88 5.46 2.41 Net taxes Agriculture and forestry Fisheries Mining Manufacturing Electricity and water Construction Trade and repair Hotel and restaurants Transport and communications Finance Leasing property State governance, military security Education Healthcare Other public utilities, social services 100% 90% 80% 70% Industrial structure of Russian GDP, 2002-2014 (Rosstat data) (16) 12 13 2 3 3 5 2 3 2 5 2 3 2 5 9 3 60% Net taxes 12 9 1 14 15 14 15 9 8 3 3 9 10 1 1 2 3 2 4 2 3 2 4 2 3 2 4 2 3 2 5 8 8 9 10 3 4 4 9 8 8 1 1 1 10% 15 15 14 14 2 3 3 6 5 19 18 17 17 17 5 5 5 3 3 3 15 5 3 16 15 14 6 6 8 10 5 5 5 4 4 3 5 3 1 3 2 5 1 3 2 2 3 3 2 4 3 5 6 6 provision of other municipal, social and personal services Health and social services Education 4 11 4 8 1 17 40% 20% 2 4 3 8 1 20 14 Households activities 50% 30% 13 5 3 16 5 4 11 10 4 3 8 7 1 1 17 6 3 16 10 10 10 4 4 5 Real estate operations, leasehold and service provisioning 8 8 7 Financial activities 1 1 1 16 15 15 6 7 6 6 3 3 3 3 State administration, defence and social insuarance Transport and communications Hotels and restaurants Whole sale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles, motor-cycles, household goods and personal demand items Construction Distribution of electricity, gas and water 15 15 15 13 13 13 13 9 9 13 13 Processing manufacturing Extraction of minerals 9 9 8 7 4 4 8 9 9 Fishery 0% 4 4 3 4 3 3 3 Agriculture, hunt anf forestry 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Industrial changes in employment structure, %; 1980-2007 (17) Sector 1980 1990 1997 2007 Production sector (manufacturing industries) Agriculture and forestry Construction Service sector Including: 32,5 15 9,6 41,6 30,3 13,2 12 42,1 23,7 14,2 8,5 49,6 24 9,4 7,5 56,4 Transport and communication 9,6 7,7 7,8 8,1 Wholesale and retail trade, catering 8,3 7,8 10,6 15,6 Housing maintenance and utilities 3,9 4,3 5,2 4,8 Public health service, physical culture and social security Education, culture and art 4,8 8,2 5,6 9,6 7 11,3 7,3 10,8 Science and science services 4,5 4,2 2,2 1,2 Finance, credit, insurance, pension security Management services Others 0,5 1,8 1,3 0,5 2,4 2,4 1,2 4,3 4 1,5 7,1 2,6 Industrial changes in employment structure, %; 2005-2014 (18) 100% 3.7 3.7 3.8 3.8 3.9 3.9 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 6.8 6.9 6.8 6.8 7 7 6.8 6.8 6.7 6.6 8.9 8.7 8.8 8.8 8.6 8.4 8.2 8.1 90% Provision of other municipal, social and personal services 9 80% 70% 9 Health and social services 5.2 5.3 5.3 5.4 5.6 5.6 5.6 5.5 5.5 5.5 7.3 7.4 7.4 7.3 7.8 7.8 8.1 8.3 8.5 8.7 8 8.1 8 7.9 Education State administration, defence and social insuarance Real estate operations, leasehold and service provisioning 60% 8 7.9 7.9 7.9 8 8 Financial activities Transport and communications 50% 16.6 16.9 17.2 17.7 Hotels and restaurants 17.8 18.1 18 18.2 18.3 18.4 Whole sale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles, motor-cycles, household goods and personal demand items 40% 30% 20% Construction 7.4 7.6 7.8 8.1 2.9 2.9 2.8 2.8 17.2 16.8 16.7 16.5 7.8 7.8 8.1 8.2 8.4 8.5 Distribution of electricity, gas and water 2.8 2.8 2.9 2.9 2.9 2.9 Processing manufacturing 15.4 15.4 15.2 15.1 14.8 14.6 Extraction of minerals Fishery 10% Agriculture, hunt anf forestry 11.1 10.6 10.2 9.8 9.8 9.6 9.7 9.5 9.4 9.2 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 0% Time dynamics of employment shares by industry, %; 2005-2014 (19) 20 18 16 14 12 10 2005 2006 2007 8 2008 6 2009 2010 4 2 0 2011 2012 2013 2014 Russia (2011) and the World (2002-2010): Sectoral structure of GDP (20) Total Agriculture, forestry, fishery, hunting Industry Construction Transport and communica tions Country Financial activities, real estate Trade, hotels and restaurants Education, health care, social services Other services Russia 100 4,2 30,5 6,5 8,9 20 15,9 6,6 7,4 Belorussia 100 9,6 35,2 7,5 8 14,6 11,5 7,9 5,7 Ukraine 100 9,2 27 3,5 11,1 17,1* 15,5 9 7,6 Estonia 100 3,1 20,6 7,9 11,7 16,7 23,8 7,5 8,8 Azerbajdzhan 100 5,7 58 8,8 7 8,1 4 5 3,4 Armenia 100 22,1 17,7 13,9 6,9 15,4 10 7,9 6,1 Kazakhstan 100 5,5 33,8 7,1 10,2 15,8 18,3 5,3 4 5) ... India 100 22,8 20,3 6,2 8 14,9 13,5 14,3 China 100 10,3 39,7 6,6 4,9 10,6 12,5 4,6 10,9 Brazil 100 5,6 22,6 5 8,9 20 16,5 8,4 13 Germany 100 0,9 25,6 4,3 5,7 12 29,4 11,5 10,6 Finland 100 2,7 21,2 7 7,9 11,5 25 15,1 9,6 France 100 1,7 12,4 6,4 6,6 12,4 33,7 14,6 12,1 USA 100 1,3 17,1 4,7 ... 19,0* 33 24,9* ... Russia and the World : Sectoral structure of employment (21) Agricultur Industry e, forestry, fishery, hunting Country Year Russia Belorussia Ukraine Estonia Azerbajdzh an Armenia Kazakhstan Brazil Germany Finland USA Constructi Transport on and communic ation Total Financial activities, real estate Trade, hotels and restaurant s Education, health Other care, services social services 2011 2011 2011 2010 100 100 100 100 7,9 10,4 16,8 4,2 20,2* 25,5 16,5 21,7 7,2 8,6 4,6 8,4 9,4 7,4 6,8 9,8 18 15,5 23,9 17,4 8,6 8,4 7,5 10,4 17 16,7 14,8 15,9 11,7 7,5 9,1 11,6 2011 100 37,9 7 7,1 5,5 15,6 4,4 11,7 10,8 2011 2011 2007 2010 2010 2008 100 100 100 100 100 100 38,9 26,4 18,3 1,6 4,4 1,5 11 11,6 15,3 21,7 16,2 12,3 5,7 7,4 6,7 6,7 7 7,5 5,6 8,1 4,8 7,9 10,3 4,5 10,5 16,3 21,7 17,4 15,6 20,9 3,5 7,3 7,4 14,3 13,1 17,7 14,1 15 9,2 18,2 22,6 21,6 10,7 7,9 16,7* 11,6 10,1 13,9* Open questions Were these structural changes inevitable in Russia during transition? If no, what went wrong in your opinion? What factors determine successful development of a sector in transition? (23) • Sector’s position before transition • Size of enterprises in the industry: transition road very different in big companies and SME –consolidation of ownership • Favorable world prices • Domestic demand • Productivity (change), reorganization in companies /industry • Type of privatization and ownership (who owns which industries) • Ability to attract the funding • Whether a sector is a strategic sector (determines allowed ownership and investments) Effect of different types of privatization/ownership (24) • Nominal, insiders’ privatization didn’t mean much changes in the way the company was run, and in the industry (i.e. forestry) • State control meant not so much changes in efficiency/ productivity/ investments (i.e. gas) • New private owners who got their shares through vouchers/loans for shares/auctions made changes in management, investments, markets (i.e. oil, machinery, metals) • Foreign/mixed ownership is likely to affect industry in successful way (FDI, management practices, corporate governance , e.g. in food industry). Industrial aspects of privatization (25) Mandatory privatization (light, food industries) Privatization with the permission of the privatization ministry (larger firms, yet not operating in any of the important strategic industries) Requiring government approval for privatization (natural resources and defense) – in fact could not be privatized. Prohibited privatization education) (space exploration, health, and Industrial aspects of ownership in transition Russia (Dolgopyatova 2010) (26) High level of concentration of ownership irrespective sector or size of company. From mid 1990s – rapid growth of concentration of ownership in Russia. Corporate governance: main player – a majority (dominant) shareholder. Growth of ownership concentration: Share of dominant shareholder in the beginning of 21 st century - 25-40%; in the end of 2000s – higher than 60%. High ownership concentration – not only a Russian phenomena. The same – in some developed countries; in all transition economies. Why? Bad institutions and availability of highly profitable assets for which businessmen are ready to fight. Shleifer and Vishny (1997) argue that ownership concentration can serve as a substitute for weak investor protection rights. Therefore ownership concentration should be positively related to corporate performance especially in environments of weak legal systems. Industrial patterns of ownership distribution and concentration in the 90`s (27) • 23 largest private owners control at least 36-38% of output and employment (Guriev and Rachinsky, 2004). • The largest owners are much more strongly represented in energy, natural resources and the automotive industry. • The sectors that produce consumer goods are mostly controlled by other private domestic owners and foreigners. • Smaller domestic owners also tend to dominate manufacturing sectors. • Mid 90s: trend for industry consolidation -expansion of financial-industrial groups. These groups built mostly around natural resource industries. Ownership distribution and concentration (28) Concentration of ownership in the hands of a few major players: “+” Can reduce inefficiencies due to suboptimal firm size and cost duplication. “—”Can also result in collusion, create barriers to entry and eliminate healthy competition. Shares of different categories of owners in sales of respective sectors, beginning of 21st century (29) (data from Guriev and Rachinsky , 2004; for the sample that covers 60% of Russian industry) Breakdown of Russian industry by ownership categories in the beginning of 21st century (Guriev and Rachinsky, 2004/2005) (30) Annual sales 39 13 8 6 26 8 Oligarchs Other private domestic Foreign owners Regional Governments Russian federal government Employment 42 0% 20% 22 40% 3 6 60% 15 80% 12 100% No data Video: Russian oligarhcs https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=LiWxxMEq KCE Current tendencies of ownership concentration in industries (32) • Intensifying state ownership and control over the key industrial sectors and strategic industries in particular. • Leading vehicle for the consolidation of state ownership in Russia’s industry is a giant industrial holding Russian Technologies (Rostechnologies), which is set to acquire and control nearly 400 Russian enterprises by a presidential degree of late 2007. • Oil and gas are dominant and big: containing no more than 12 of the 100 largest companies, the oil and gas sector is responsible for almost 40% of the aggregate turnover of the top-100 Russian enterprises (many already state owned, Gasprom and Rosneft). Ability to get funding/strategic industries (33) • Development of financial institutions. • Large number of banks, but credibility was questionable, pocket banks. • State is trying to get back control over strategic industries using different strategies (i.e. oil –Yukos), limiting foreign investors etc. • Foreign investments –most reliable, but available only for certain sectors (not strategic). Limitations for foreign investors in strategic sectors – Russian Federal Law 7 May 2008 (34) • National defence sector: working with nuclear materials, activities related to weapons and other military equipment, aviation and space, coding and encryption equipment; • Natural resources sector: including exploitation of subsoil areas of federal importance, fishing; • Activity of natural monopolies (including energy sector); • Mass media sector, including television, radio broadcast and printed media covering a significant share of Russia's audience; • Telecommunications, including activities of the major telecom providers. Part 2: Dutch disease and Russia Dutch disease (36) Is the apparent relationship between the increase in exploitation of natural resources and a decline in the manufacturing sector (or agriculture). The term was coined in 1977 by The Economist : the decline of the manufacturing sector in the Netherlands after the discovery of a large natural gas field in 1959. Bad institutions: prerequisite for Dutch disease. Dutch disease vs. resource curse (37) are often used interchangeable, But: Resource curse refers to the political and social consequences of country`s high dependence on resources` export. Dutch disease refers only to the effects of the resulting currency appreciation and changes in the cost of factors of production. Dutch disease (38) (Bruno and Sachs (1982); Corden and Neary (1982)) Spending effect Tradable resource (oil) sector Tradable (manufacturing) sector The resource movement effect What happens when world oil price goes up? 1. The spending effect; 2. The resource movement effect. Non-traded sector (services) Dutch disease (39) A result: A fall in the output share of non-natural resource tradables (manufacturing sector) relative to non-tradables (mostly service sector) and resource tradables (e.g. oil industry). Is there any empirical evidence of Dutch Disease? (40) Relatively robust evidence that terms of trade increases cause real exchange rate appreciation in natural-resource-rich countries (for example Spatafora and Warner 1995). Vostroknutova, Brahmbhatt, Canuto, VoxEU 2010. Is there any empirical evidence of Dutch Disease? (41) The shrinking of the manufacturing sector in response to terms of trade: mixed evidence (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2003). Ismail (2010) finds strong evidence for Dutch Disease effects, with a 10% increase in an oil windfall/income associated with a 3.4% fall in value added across manufacturing sectors. On average in resource rich countries the tradables sector (manufacturing plus agriculture) is around 15% of GDP lower than the norm (Vostroknutova, Brahmbhatt, Canuto, VoxEU 2010). Dutch Disease is good or bad for growth? (42) Positive: -higher incomes and allowing more consumption of both non-tradables and tradables; -increased resources for investment in public goods. Negative: For Manufacturing -possess specific long-term, growth-enhancing qualities: positive technological spillovers, learning by doing effects, or increasing returns to scale in production. -more labour intensive than natural resource industries: implications for employment. The effect for economic growth is inconlslusive. Negative: bad institutions. Dutch disease in Russia (42) Victoria Dobrynskaya & Edouard Turkisch (2009) 1999-2007 For Dutch disease: 1) The appreciation of the rouble in real terms in 1997-2007; 2) The decrease in employment in manufacturing; 3) The rise in services sector. Against Dutch disease: 1) Manufacturing production also increased. Dutch disease in Russia (43) Mironov and Petronevich, 2015, BOFIT discussing paper Russian economy reflects a combination of “Soviet” and “Dutch” diseases Main arguments: 1) Eruptive flows of export revenues have resulted in significant appreciation of the real effective exchange rate. 2) The manufacturing sector tends to shrink and is relatively small. 3) The mining and service sectors have expanded. 4) Positive significant impact of the real effective exchange rate on employment rates in the services sector. Dutch disease in Russia (44) Another opinion: FORBES`12: At the present time, one of the very few economic risks that Russia doesn’t face is Dutch Disease: its currency isn’t overvalued and, if anything, is actually trending lower against the main reserve currencies. Total natural resources rents (% of GDP) (45) Total natural resources rents are the sum of oil rents, natural gas rents, coal rents (hard and soft), mineral rents, and forest rents. Country Name 1970 Arab World Belarus Brazil Canada China Germany Euro area Estonia European Union Finland France United Kingdom India High income: OECD OECD members 1980 1989 13,5 58,3 21,0 3,1 4,7 1,7 0,4 0,6 4,5 11,7 22,6 0,7 0,9 3,3 3,1 7,9 0,2 0,4 0,6 7,3 0,5 1,5 5,0 0,5 0,1 2,3 2002 2007 2012 2014 21,6 4,2 2,2 3,3 4,3 0,1 0,2 4,9 22,6 3,4 5,1 3,6 2,3 0,2 0,3 5,3 39,0 2,6 7,6 6,6 7,5 0,3 0,4 1,2 32,4 2,5 6,3 4,5 5,8 0,2 0,3 2,6 28,5 1,9 5,0 4,6 4,0 0,1 0,2 2,7 0,6 1,7 0,3 0,5 1,6 0,2 0,6 1,5 0,2 0,7 1,1 0,1 0,6 1,4 0,2 0,4 1,5 0,1 4,6 6,3 1,2 4,8 1,3 4,3 1,5 2,8 1,7 6,0 1,2 5,6 0,7 4,9 1,3 3,5 0,8 0,6 0,7 1,6 1,4 1,3 3,7 0,9 0,7 0,8 1,8 1,5 1,3 13,9 3,5 15,3 4,5 27,1 5,8 28,3 6,3 18,7 4,6 16,2 8,1 1,0 0,8 0,6 1,6 1,3 1,1 Russian Federation Ukraine United States 1995 1,5 6,1 Time dynamics of Russian export by industry, billion USD (46) 400.0 368.9 350.0 346.5 346.1 Food and live animals Beverages and tobacco 307.4 300.0 372.0 Crude materials, inedible, except fuels 260.7 250.0 Mineral fuels, lubricants and related materials 216.5 200.0 189.6 Animal and vegetable oils, fats and waxes 190.2 Chemicals and related products, n.e.s. 150.0 149.2 100.0 99.3 72.9 50.0 0.0 52.2 51.7 56.0 38.3 40.0 28.2 31.2 Manufactured goods classified chiefly by material Machinery and transport equipment Miscellaneous manufactured articles Commodities and transactions not classified elsewhere in the SITC Growth rates of Russian export by industry between 1996 and 2013 (47) Mineral Crude fuels, Animal material lubrican and s, ts and vegetab Food Beverag inedible related le oils, and live es and , except material fats and animals tobacco fuels s waxes Chemic als and related product s, n.e.s. Manufa ctured Machin goods ery and classifie transpo d chiefly rt by equipm material ent Commo dities and transact ions not Miscella classifie neous d manufa elsewhe ctured re in the articles SITC 1996 0,9 0,2 4,8 38,3 0,0 5,3 17,7 6,2 1,3 14,0 2013 12,5 1,3 16,2 372,0 2,0 23,5 53,8 21,4 5,8 18,8 1290,2 551,8 234,1 872,6 5131,2 347,3 204,5 243,4 346,1 34,0 % growth Change in industrial structure of Russian export bw 1996 and 2014 (48) 100% 90% 15.8 3.0 1.3 4.0 10.6 Commodities and transactions not classified elsewhere in the SITC 4.7 Miscellaneous manufactured articles 1.5 80% 7.0 Machinery and transport equipment 70% 19.9 Manufactured goods classified chiefly by material 60% 50% Chemicals and related products, n.e.s. 5.9 Animal and vegetable oils, fats and waxes 69.5 40% Mineral fuels, lubricants and related materials 30% Crude materials, inedible, except fuels 43.1 Beverages and tobacco 20% Food and live animals 10% 0% 5.5 1.0 1996 3.2 3.0 2014