* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Chapter 14: Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly:
Market penetration wikipedia , lookup
Grey market wikipedia , lookup
Market (economics) wikipedia , lookup
Family economics wikipedia , lookup
Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Comparative advantage wikipedia , lookup
Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup
Chapter 10 Economics of Taxation: Definition of tax incidence: the manner in which the burden of a tax is shared among participants in a market. How Taxes on Sellers Affect Market Outcomes 1. If the government requires the seller to pay a certain dollar amount for each unit of a good sold, this will cause a decrease in supply. 2. The supply curve will shift up by the amount of the tax. 3. The quantity of the good sold will decline. 4. Buyers and sellers will share the burden of the tax; buyers pay more for the good and sellers receive less (because of the tax). Case Study: Can Congress Distribute the Burden of a Payroll Tax? 1. FICA (Social Security) taxes were designed so that firms and workers would equally share the burden of the tax. 2. This type of payroll tax will simply put a wedge between the wage the firm pays and the wage the workers will receive. 3. It is true that firms and workers share the burden of this tax, but it is not necessarily 50-50. Elasticity and Tax Incidence 1. When supply is elastic and demand is inelastic, the largest share of the tax burden falls on consumers. 2. When supply is inelastic and demand is elastic, the largest share of the tax burden falls on producers. 3. In general, a tax burden falls more heavily on the side of the market that is less elastic. 4. a. A small elasticity of demand means that buyers do not have good alternatives to consuming this product. b. A small elasticity of supply means that sellers do not have good alternatives to producing this particular good. Case Study: Who Pays the Luxury Tax? a. In 1990, Congress adopted a new luxury tax. b. The goal of the tax was to raise revenue from those who could most easily afford to pay. c. Because the demand for luxuries is often relatively more elastic than supply, the burden of the tax fell on producers and their workers. Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly: The Concept of Imperfect Competition: Refers to market structures between perfect competition and monopoly More than one seller, but too few to create a perfectly competitive market Other conditions of perfect competition, such as the requirement of a standardized product or easy entry/exit are not satisfied Monopolistic Competition: Characterized by Three Fundamental Characteristics: 1. Many buyers and sellers 2. Easy entry and exit 3. Differentiated products Definition: Monopolistic Competition: A market structure in which there are many firms selling products that are differentiated, yet are still close substitutes, and in which there is free entry and exit. Each firm produces a differentiated product in a monopolistic competitive market; thus each firm faces a downward sloping demand curve. Therefore it will not lose all of its customers if it raises its price. We know that whenever a firm faces a downward sloping demand curve, its marginal revenue curve lies below the demand curve. The relationship between the demand and marginal revenue curves is illustrated below. Monopolistic Competition in the Short Run: The constraints of a monopolistic competitor are very similar to a monopoly: 1. Its current technology of production 2. The prices for inputs 3. The downward sloping demand curve Profit case: The restaurant marketplace in Beverly Hills is a good example of a monopolistically competitive market. Every restaurant offers a different menu and special dishes, but still has to compete with other comparable restaurants. Further, each restaurant sells a somewhat unique product; therefore the restaurants are not perfectly competitive and can raise their price and not lose all customers. A monopolistically competitive firm (as does any other firm) maximizes its profit by producing the level of output where MR = MC. MR = MC at point output level Qo. In monopolistic competition the price is determined by the amount that customers are willing to pay to buy Qo units of output. Under monopolistic competition, firms can earn positive or negative economic profit in the short run Monopolistic Monopolistic Competition Competition in in the the Short Short Run Run Dollars Dollars $70 $70 AA MC MC ATC ATC dd1 1 30 30 MR MR11 250 250 Homes HomesServiced Serviced per perMonth Month The monopolistically competitive firm illustrated above faces a downward sloping demand curve d1 and marginal revenue MR1. MR = MC at 250 units per month and a price of $70 per unit. Therefore the firm illustrated above earns a short-run profit of $10,000 ($40*250), represented by the blue shaded rectangle. Monopolistic Competition in the Long Run Economic profits will not last due to easy entry/exit. Where a monopoly market has barriers to entry, a monopolistically competitive market does not. Therefore we should expect any economic profit to be reduced to zero due to entry of new firms: Monopolistic competition allows firms to profit or incur losses in the short run. However, in the long run, easy entry and exit will ensure that, in the long run, there is no economic profit. Monopolistic Competition in the Long Run Dollars MC ATC $40 E d MR2 100 200 d2 Homes Serviced per Month The individual firm’s demand curve “d” shifts to the left to “d2” when new firms enter the market, and each firm eventually earns zero economic profit. Point “E” represents the long run equilibrium at which price ($40) equals ATC. Excess Capacity under Monopolistic Competition: In the long run, a monopolistic competitor will operate with excess capacity—that is, it will produce too little output to achieve minimum cost per unit. The monopolistic competitor will always produce with P> minimum ATC in the long run, unlike perfectly competitive firms, which, in the long run, produce at an output level where P = minimum ATC. Perfectly competitive markets are more efficient, have lower prices but they produce a standardized product. If we wish to enjoy the benefit of differentiated products, we, as a society must bear the price. Definition: Nonprice Competition: Any action a firm takes to increase the demand for its product, other than cutting its price; advertising, free gifts, etc. Oligopoly: An oligopoly market is characterized by: 1. 2. 3. 4. Few firms A standardized or a differentiated product Strategically interdependent firms Difficult entry Today’s music industry is an example of an oligopoly. “The Big Five,” (WMG, EMI, Sony Music, UMG, and BMG) control over 80% of all the musical titles released in the world. The market for soft drinks is also considered an oligopoly market. Definition: Oligopoly: A market structure in which a small number of firms are strategically interdependent. These strategically interdependent firms produce the dominant share of output in the market. Economies of Scale: Natural Oligopolies Some industries remain oligopolies due to economies of scale. When these industries reach the output level where the long run average total cost (LRATC) in at minimum, they have reached the minimum efficient scale. Definition: The minimum efficient scale (MES): The level of output at which economies of scale are exhausted and minimum LRATC is achieved. Depicted above is the LRATC curve for a hypothetical firm. Economies of scale cause LRATC to decrease as output increases, constant returns to scale results in no change in LRATC as output increases, and diseconomies of scale cause LRATC to increase as output increases. It is important to note where MES is located. If the minimum efficiency scale for the firm depicted above is 10,000 units and 500,000 units are demanded in the market, then the market is not a monopoly. However, if the MES for a firm is 125,000 and market demand is 500,000, then we can assume very few firms coexist in that market and the market might be an oligopoly. Why Oligopolies Exist: Reputation as a barrier: In several markets, such as the markets for soft drinks and breakfast cereals, it is difficult for a new entrant to enter the market when a natural oligopoly already exists due to the loyalty consumers’ exhibit to well advertised and established brands. Strategic barriers: Oligopolists often use strategies to keep out potential competitors. Government-created barriers: Oligopolies commonly lobby politicians to defend their market dominance (US Steel example). Oligopoly Behavior: Strategic interdependence is the essence of oligopoly The MC = MR rule, as we used it for other types of markets, is largely invalid in the analysis of oligopoly. The Game Theory Approach: Definition: Game theory: An approach to modeling the strategic interaction of oligopolists in terms of moves and countermoves. Firms do not know which response its rivals will make The firm needs to be able to measure the effect of each possible response (this becomes difficult when many firms are at “play”); therefore the fewer firms at play the better estimate How well do “players” control the game? 1. Every game depends on the number of players—they greater the number of firms the more difficult it becomes to anticipate the next move. 2. The firms with the larger amount of cash will better be able to fund advertising, research, or development. 3. Brainpower: the degree to which the firm understands the market they are playing. The Prisoner’s Dilemma: Definition: Payoff Matrix: A table showing the payoffs to each of two players for each pair of strategies they choose. Jane confesses Jane does not confess Bob confesses Bob does not confess Jane gets 3 years Bob gets 3 years Jane gets 4 months Bob gets 4 years Jane gets 4 years Bob gets 4 months Jane gets 6 months Bob gets 6 months The prisoner’s dilemma is a game situation like that in an oligopoly market. In this example Bob and Jane committed a felony punishable by up to 4 years in prison. The prisoner’s dilemma focuses on the non-cooperative strategy Bob and Jane pursue when arrested and placed in separate rooms. The police tell Bob and Jane separately that if they confess and their partner in crime does not, they will get 4 months in jail and their partner will get 4 years. At the same time both Bob and Jane recognize that if they both confess they will each get 3 years. However, if Bob and Jane trusted each other (colluded) they would both only serve 6 month sentences. Definition: Dominant strategy: A strategy that is best for a firm no matter what strategy its competitor chooses. Simple Oligopoly Games: Definition: Duopoly: An oligopoly market with only two sellers When is cheating likely? 1. Difficulty in observing other firm’s prices: in markets where it is difficult for firms to monitor the prices charged by their competitors. Retail auto sales Retail jewelry sales 2. Unstable market demand: Often in markets in which prices are constantly changing it is more difficult to evaluate firms’ actions. 3. A large number of sellers: Cheating will often go undetected in larger markets. Resource Economics Definition: Product markets: Markets in which firms sell goods and services to households or other firms. In product markets, households demand the products and firms supply them. Definition: Factor markets: Markets in which resources—capital, land, labor, and natural resources—are sold to firms. In factor markets, firms demand land, labor, and capital and households are the suppliers. Competitive Labor Markets: Definition: Perfectly competitive labor market: A market with many indistinguishable sellers of labor and many buyers, and that involves no barriers to entry or exit. A labor market is considered perfectly competitive if it satisfies three conditions: 1. There are many buyers (firms) and sellers (households) of labor in the market. 2. All workers in the market appear the same to firms. 3. There are no barriers to entering or leaving the labor market. Firms in Labor Markets: The demand side of a labor market includes all firms hiring labor in that market. These firms may, but do not necessarily, compete in the same product market. Therefore product markets and labor markets do not always have the same constituents. For example: Volvo uses the Swedish labor market to manufacture their vehicles for sale in the US product market. GM uses the US labor market to manufacture their cars and sells them in the US product market. Demand for Labor by a Single Firm: Definition: Derived demand: The demand for an input that arises from, and varies with, the demand for the product it helps to produce. The demand for labor is a derived demand—it arises from, and will vary with, the demand for the firm’s output. Therefore the demand for labor for a firm will increase when the demand for their product increases, and vice versa. Goals and Constraints: In competitive labor markets, each firm is a wage taker: it takes the market wage rate as a given. The firm in a competitive labor market has no choice about what rate to pay, but can only decide how many workers to hire at the going wage for its labor. The firm (hiring in a perfectly competitive labor market) faces three constraints: 1. Its technology: Determines how much output the firm can produce with each quantity of labor. 2. The market price: The product market tells the firm how much it can sell its output for. 3. The market wage rate: The labor market tells the firm how much it must pay each worker. The firm’s Employment Decision When Only Labor is Variable: Marginal Revenue Product: Definition: Marginal revenue product: The change in revenue from hiring one more worker. The marginal revenue product (MPR) of labor is the change in total revenue from hiring one more worker. Mathematically, MRP is calculated by dividing the change TR in total revenue ( TR ) by the change in employment ( L ) MRP L Recall: Marginal Product of Labor: The additional output produced when one more worker is hired (1) (2) Total (3) (4) Price (5) Total (6) (7) Wage Quantity product Marginal per unit revenue Marginal (W) of Labor (quantity) Product of Revenue Labor Product (MPL) (MRP) 0 0 $4 $0 30 $120 $60 1 30 $4 $120 60 $240 $60 2 90 $4 $360 40 $160 $60 3 130 $4 $520 31 $124 $60 4 161 $4 $644 23 $92 $60 5 184 $4 $736 12 $48 $60 6 196 $4 $784 6 $16 $60 7 200 $4 $800 Column (1): Column (2): Column (3): Column (4): Column (5): Column (6): Column (7): The number of workers hired The quantity produced each day Marginal product of labor (MPL) Price per unit (constant at $4) Total revenue (Price*quantity) Marginal revenue product of labor Wage When output is sold in a competitive market, the MRP can be calculated by multiplying the marginal product of labor by the price of output: MRP = MPL * P Recall that marginal product of labor (MPL) is the rise in output when a firm hires another worker—therefore MPL * Price (P) will be the corresponding increase in revenue. Notice how the MRP values in column (6) rise and then fall—we have come to expect increasing returns to labor (or rising MPL) at lower levels of labor followed by diminishing returns to labor (or declining MPL) at higher levels of employment. Also note that with price constant at $4, MPL will have the same behavior as MRP. The Cost of an Additional Worker: The Profit Maximizing Employment Level: The marginal approach to profit states that a firm should take any action that adds more to its revenue that to its cost. When evaluating whether or not to hire one more worker, the profit maximizing firm uses the marginal approach to profit. The firm must decide whether the increased revenue is greater than the wage paid to the new laborer. The general rule: Hire another worker when MRP>W, but not when MRP<W. Note in the table above that revenue increases by $120 (MRP) and costs increase by $60, the amount paid as wage (W). Clearly revenue (MRP) is greater than costs (W) MRP>W, thus hiring an employee allows the firm to profit. Note that MRP>W continues until the firm hires the sixth laborer, where MRP<W. Therefore the firm should not hire the sixth worker. Dollars $200 The ProfitMaximizing Employment Level 150 100 Wage 60 50 MRP 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Number of W orkers To maximize profit, the firm should hire the number of workers such that MRP = W—that is, where the MRP curve intersects the wage line. The Firm’s Labor Demand Curve: When labor is the only variable input, the downward-sloping portion of the MRP curve is the firm’s labor demand curve, telling us how much labor the firm will want to employ at each wage rate. The optimum level of employment will always depend on the wage rate. The Firm’s Labor Demand Curve Dollars Firm’s Labor Demand Curve W1 A W1 B W2 n1 n2 W2 Number of Workers As the wage rate varies, the firm moves along its MRP curve in deciding how many workers to hire. As a result, the downward sloping portion of the MRP curve is the firm’s labor demand curve. It shows how many workers will be demanded at each wage rate. The firm’s employment decision when several inputs are variable: We still optimize profit by satisfying the condition that MRP =W With more than one variable input, the marginal product of labor and the marginal revenue product (of labor) will depend on other inputs the firm uses. The firm’s labor demand curve with more than one variable input: When the wage rate declines inputs besides labor are demanded Whether the firm can vary just labor, or several inputs simultaneously, the optimal level of employment will satisfy the MRP = W rule, and the firm’s labor demand curve will slope downward: A decrease in the wage rate will cause an increase in employment. Definition: The Market Demand for Labor: The curve indicating the total number of workers all firms in a labor market want to employ at each wage rate. It is found by horizontally summing across all firms’ individual labor demand curves. Note that the market demand curve slopes downward just as the individual firms’: a decline in wage rate causes each firm to acquire more laborers and at the same time quantity demanded increases throughout the market. Shifts in the labor demand curve: (a) Typical Firm Hourly Wage $10 (b) Labor Market Hourly Wage A B n2 Number of Workers B D D 2d 1d n1 A L2 L1 N1 N2 Number of Workers A change in the wage rate will cause a move along a labor demand curve When something other than wage rate changes the labor curve will shift The following would cause a shift from 1d to 2 d : 1. Advances in technology 2. Lowering in the prices of inputs 3. Increase in price of output Will all cause the individual firm’s demand for labor to increase A Change in the price of the Price of Firm’s Output Recall: Demand for labor will increase when the demand for a firms outputs increases (demand for labor is a derived demand) MRP = P * MPL A rise in selling price of a firm’s output causes MRP to be greater at each level of employment The MRP curve and the labor demand curve would then shift up and to the right. The market demand for labor increases. Therefore: The effect of a change in output price on labor demand depends on whether many firms in the labor market also share the same product market. When they do, a rise in output price will shift the market labor demand curve rightward; a fall in output price will shift the market demand curve leftward. A Change in technology/A Change in the Price of another Input: Definition: Complementary input: An input whose utilization increases the marginal product of another input. Definition: Substitute input: An input whose utilization decreases the marginal product of another input. When many firms in a labor market acquire a new technology, the market labor demand curve will shift rightward if the technology is complementary with labor and leftward if the technology is substitutable for labor. When the price of some other input decreases, the market labor demand curve may shift rightward or leftward. It will shift rightward if that other input is complementary with labor and leftward if the other input is substitutable for labor. Automated phone systems are substitutable for human operators but complementary with skilled technicians who program and maintain the automated systems. The introduction of these new technologies shifted the market demand for telephone operators to the left while simultaneously shifting the market demand for the skilled technicians to the right. Shifts in the Labor Demand Curve: An increase in Will cause the market labor demand curve to: Demand for the firm’s output shift rightward The price of a complementary input Shift leftward The price of a substitutable input Shift rightward The number of firms in the market Shift rightward Technology If a new input is complementary with laborshift rightward If a new input is substitutable for laborshift leftward Note that a decrease in each case above would shift the labor demand curve in the opposite direction. Labor Supply: Individuals as Wage Takers In a competitive labor market, each seller is a wage taker; he or she takes the market wage rate as given. Reservation Wages: Definition: Reservation wages: The lowest wage rate at which an individual would supply labor to a particular labor market. . Market Labor Supply: Definition: Labor supply curve: A curve indicating the number of people who want jobs in a labor market at each wage rate. The higher the wage rate, the greater the quantity of labor supplied. Shifts in the Market Labor Supply Curve: A movement along LS 1 in (a) from point C to point D represents a change in the wage rate A shift from LS 1 to LS 2 in (b) depicts an increase in labor supply in the market. A market labor supply curve will shift when something other than a change in the wage rate causes a change in the number of people who want to work in a particular market. A Change in the Market wage rate in other labor markets: As long as some individuals can choose to supply their labor in two different markets, a rise in the wage rate in one market will cause a leftward shift in the labor supply curve in the other market. Changes in the Cost of Acquiring Human Capital: An increase in the cost of acquiring human capital needed to enter a labor market— say, due to an increase in school fees, fewer scholarships, or longer schooling requirements—will shift the labor supply curve leftward; a decrease in the cost of acquiring human capital will shift the labor supply curve rightward. Population Changes: Population growth will shift the labor supply curve rightward, and migration from a region will shift the labor supply curve leftward. Shifts in the Labor Supply Curve: An increase in Tastes for work in a market Population Human capital costs Will cause the market labor supply curve to Shift rightward Shift rightward Shift leftward The wage rate in an alternative market Shift leftward Note that a decrease in each case above would shift the labor supply curve in the opposite direction. The long-run labor supply curve tells us how many (qualified) people will want to work in a labor market at each wage rate, after all adjustments have taken place. Specifically, all those who want to acquire new skills or who want to move to another location have done so. The long-run labor supply response is more wage elastic than the short-run labor supply response The forces of supply and demand will drive a competitive labor market to its equilibrium point—the point where the labor supply and labor demand curves intersect. In the short run, a shift in labor demand moves us along a short run labor supply curve. In the long run, the resulting increase in the wage rate will cause the short-run labor supply curve to shift as well. Wage rates, like that prices of goods and services, act as market signals—leading workers to move to areas where their work is most valued. When the labor demand curve shifts, the wage rate will overshoot its long-run equilibrium value. But as the signal begins to work, the temporary overshooting of the wage rate subsides. Chapter 19: International Trade Definition: Exports: Goods and services produced domestically, but sold abroad. Definition: Imports: Goods and services produced abroad, but consumed domestically. Definition: Absolute advantage: The ability to produce a good using fewer resources than another country. A country has an absolute advantage in a good when it can produce it using fewer resources than another country. Definition: Comparative advantage: The ability to produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another country. A nation has a comparative advantage in producing a good if it can produce it at a lower opportunity cost than some other country. Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantage: Suppose that China and the United States produce only two goods: suits and computers: Chinese currency is the yuan (CNY) and US currency is the dollar ($), we will associate each country with its currency. Costs of Production: Per suit Per computer China 2,000 CNY 10,000 CNY United States $500 $1,000 For each additional computer China produces, it has to divert 10,000 yuan’s from the suit industry. Since each suit costs China 2,000 CNY to produce, and each computer cost 10,000 to produce, the production of one additional computer costs China 10,000/2,000 = 5 fewer suits. The table below indicates the opportunity costs of suits in terms of computers forgone and computers in terms of suits forgone for China and the United States: Opportunity costs: Per suit Per computer China 1/5 computer 5 suits United States ½ computer 2 suits In China the opportunity cost of a computer is 5 suits; in the United States the opportunity cost of another computer is just 2 suits, therefore the US has a comparative advantage in manufacturing computers. In the United States, the opportunity cost of another suit is ½ a computer while in China the opportunity cost of another suit is just 1/5 a computer, thus China has a comparative advantage in producing suits. Specialization and World Production Using the table above we know; If China produces 10 more suits it would have to sacrifice the production of 2 computers (recall China has a comparative advantage in producing suits). If the United States produced 4 more computers it would have to forgo producing 8 suits (recall the US has a comparative advantage in producing computers). A small change in production Suit Production China +10 United States -8 World +2 Computer Production -2 +4 +2 In this example, China and the United States each specialize production in products in which they hold a comparative advantage. If countries specialize according to comparative advantage, a more efficient use of given resources occurs. That is, with the same resources, the world can produce more of at least one good, without decreasing production of any other good. Gains from International Trade: As long as opportunity costs differ, specialization and trade can be beneficial to all involved. This remains true regardless of whether the parties involved are nations, states, counties, or individuals. It remains true even if one party has an all around absolute advantage or disadvantage. The Gains from Specialization and Trade Production Loss from Exports (-) or gain from imports (+) China: Suits +10 -9 Computers -2 +3 United States: Suits -8 +9 Computers +4 -3 Net gain +1 +1 +1 +1 The Terms of Trade: Definition: Terms of trade: The ratio at which a country can trade domestically produced products for foreign-produced products. For example (using the data above): note that China imports 3 computers in exchange for 9 suits. The 9/3 ratio defines terms of trade. Turning Potential Gains into Actual Gains: Definition: Exchange rate: The amount of one currency that is traded for one unit of another currency. Prices in China and the United States with an Exchange Rate of 8 CNY for $1 Per suit Per computer China 2,000 CNY ($250) 10,000 CNY ($1,250) United States $500 (4,000 CNY) $1,000 (8,000 CNY) Now you can clearly see that a suit produced in China costs (USD $250) less than a suit produced in the United States (USD $500). Therefore Americans will prefer to buy suits from China. On the other hand, a computer produced in China costs 10,000 CNY while a computer produced in the United States will only cost 8,000 CNY. Therefore China will prefer to buy computers from the United States. When consumers are free to buy at the lowest prices, they will naturally buy a good from the country that has a comparative advantage in producing it. That country’s industries respond by producing more of that good and less of other goods. In this way, countries naturally tend to specialize in those goods in which they have a comparative advantage. The Sources of Comparative Advantage: Countries often specialize in products based on their own particular endowments of natural resources. But natural resources are not the only basis for comparative advantage. Country Specialty resulting from Natural resources or Climate Saudi Arabia Oil Canada Timber United States Grain Spain Olive oil Mexico Tomatoes Jamaica Aluminum ore Italy Wine Countries often develop strong comparative advantages in the good they have produced in the past, regardless of why they began producing those goods in the first place. Country Japan United States Switzerland Korea Hong Kong Great Britain Specialty not resulting from Natural resources or Climate Cars, consumer electronics Software, movies, music Watches Steel, ships Textiles Financial services Objections to Free Trade China United States Price (Dollars) Price (Dollars) Supply F P' N Supply PT P N B A P C D T E Q 2 QN Demand Demand Quantity Q of Suits 3 Q’ Q’ 2 N Q’ 3 Quantity of Suits Before trade, the Chinese suit market is in equilibrium at point E, and the U.S. market is in equilibrium at point F. When trade begins, Americans buy the cheaper Chinese suits, driving up their price. In response, Chinese manufacturers increase output, and Chinese consumers decrease their purchases. At the world equilibrium price PT, the Chinese buy Q2 suits, American buy Q3 – Q2 Chinese suits, and the total quantity of Chinese suits produced and sold is Q3, distance CD, which shows US imports of suits, equals distance AB, which shows Chinese exports. As a result of trade, Chinese suit makers sell more units at a higher price, but Chinese consumers pay more for their suits. In the United States, suit makers are worse off, but suit buyer’s benefit from the lower price. The Impact of Trade in the Exporting Country: In our example above, we see that free trade in suits benefits Chinese suit producers and workers, but Chinese suit buyers are worse off. When the opening of trade results in increased exports of a good, the producers of the good are made better off and will support increased trade. Consumers of the good will be made worse off and will oppose increased trade. The Impact of Trade in the Importing Country: In our example above, we saw that free trade in suits harms the U.S. suit producers and workers, but US suit buyers are better off. Why? When the opening of trade results in increased imports of a product, the domestic producers of the product are made worse off and will oppose the increased trade. Consumers are better off and will favor the increased trade. How Free Trade is Restricted: Definition: Tariff: A tax on imports. In the country that imposes the tariff, producers gain and consumers lose: Tariffs decrease the volume of trade and Therefore decrease the gains from trade Tariffs China United States Price (Dollars) Price (Dollars) Supply Supply K P3 B A PT P2 PT H C L D J Demand Demand Quantity of Suits Quantity of Suits A US tariff on imports of Chinese suits raises their price in the U.S. from PT to P3. As a result of the price increase, US imports fall to KL, which equals Chinese exports of HJ. With fewer suits produced, the price in China falls to P2. Definition: Quota: The limit on the physical volume of imports. Reduces the volume of trade Raises the domestic prices of imported goods Myths about Free Trade: 1. “A high wage country cannot afford free trade with a low wage country.” More developed countries (US) have higher wages than their less developed counterparts (China). Therefore it may seem that the poorer countries can charge lower prices for their goods and that their work will displace the American workers in their field. This is incorrect for two reasons: 1) American workers are more productive than Chinese workers. It is particularly important to observe the productivity per person in each country in comparison to their wage. If a typical American can produce 80 times as much as his Chinese counterpart, but the American earns 50 times as much, then the per unit cost in America still is lower. 2) Now suppose China could produce everything at a lower cost than America. Both countries could still gain from free trade if China specialized in products in which its cost advantage was relatively large and the United States specialized in goods in which China’s cost advantage was relatively small. China would have an absolute advantage in everything, but the United States would still have a comparative advantage in some things. The mutual gains arise not from absolute advantage, but from comparative advantage. 2. “A low-productivity country cannot afford free trade with a high productivity country.” Could a less developed country be harmed by trade with a richer country? Be sure to know the differences between absolute and comparative advantage. Assume the United States could produce every good at a lower resource cost than China. Although the United States would have an absolute advantage in the production of every good, China would still have a comparative advantage in some goods. Closing off trade will make a nation, as a whole, worse off, regardless of its level of wages or productivity. 3. “In recent times, America’s unskilled workers have suffered because of everexpanding international trade.” A college education now plays an important role in the US labor market. Many unskilled workers with only a high school education have lost their jobs in the last two decades. Increased trade with low wage countries has been blamed for this trend. Economists who have looked at the relation between changes in trade patterns and the depressed earnings of unskilled American workers have concluded that foreign trade is a small contributor. Protectionism Definition: Protectionism: The belief that a nation’s industries should be protected from foreign completion. Production is most likely to reflect the principle of comparative advantage when firms can obtain funds for investment projects and when they can freely enter industries that are profitable. Thus, free trade, without government intervention, works best when markets are working well.