Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Taxes and Development: India vs. China Roger Gordon UCSD Taxes and Economic Growth: India vs. China • What is the role of tax structure in economic growth in India? • Evolution of tax structures remarkably similar to that in China • Surprising given very different political systems • Objective of presentation – Lay out similar development of tax structures during the reforms in the two countries – Suggest a story to explain the observed interplay between taxes and economic reforms Pre-reform Economies Very Similar • Initial per capita GDP: – China – India $175 in 1979 $215 in 1991 • Dominant role for SOE’s in both countries, with a particular focus on heavy industry • Allocation decisions subject to direct government controls • Minimal international trade or FDI • Tax system had little allocative role Initial Reforms • Relax government licensing restrictions and other direct controls • Relax controls over allocation of credit • Cut tariff rates and nontariff barriers • Relax controls over exchange rate and FDI • Outcome after 14 years of reform: – China: GDP pc grew from $175 to $536 – India: GDP pc grew from $215 to $548 National taxes at beginning of reforms CHINA INDIA Corporate Tax 55% rate 50% to 55% rate Excise Taxes High and variable rates High and variable rates High Tax Rates on a Narrow Base • Revenue only from SOE’s in China • Mainly from large industrial firms in India – Excise taxes confined to manufacturing – Yet manufacturing only 16% of GDP (1991) – 67% of corporate tax from manufacturing – 40% of revenue from SOE’s Policies Used to Protect Narrow Tax Base • Protect heavy industry with tariffs. In India, average effective rate was 75% in 1990 (though reforms cut it to 15% at present) • Provide cheap credit to highly-taxed firms • Restrict hiring and firing of workers in SOE’s • Direct controls on entry and investment in other sectors – “license, permit, quota Raj” • Highly taxed industries plausibly larger, rather than smaller on net, due to tax distortions Reforms Relax Controls • When relax controls, resources (and accounting profits) shift to low-taxed sectors • Major drop in the role of SOE’s, from 68% of paid-in capital in 1992 to 28% in 2002 • Drop in size of heavy industry, e.g. capital good production falls from 25% to 7% of GDP • Expansion in size of (lightly taxed) service sector • Given large tax distortions, reallocation not necessarily an efficiency gain Resulting Fall in Tax Revenue • In China, – corporate tax revenue fell from 7.8% of GDP in 1985 to 1.5% in 1993 – Total nontariff revenue fell from 20.5% to 11.5% • In India, – excise tax revenue fell from roughly 8.4% of GDP in 1991 to 7.7% by 2004 – But corporate revenue increased from 0.9% to 2.3% – nontariff revenue up from 12.0% to 13.4% of GDP • Likely reason for difference is improved tax enforcement in India Further Economic Reform Requires Tax Reform • With relaxed controls, narrow tax base creates major distortions • Either limit relaxation of controls to preserve some tax revenue and to limit misallocations, or undertake major tax reform • China did try a retrenchment in 1988-91, but political and economic costs too high Both Countries Undertook a Major Tax Reform • After 15 years of reform, both countries largely replaced excise taxes with a VAT – 17% rate in China – 16% rate in India • Both countries broadened the tax base for indirect taxes – China imposed national taxes on non-SOE’s – India expanding excise tax base to include services and wholesale sector • Both countries cut the corporate tax rate to 33% • Growing importance of personal income tax in both countries, capturing some income from informal sector • But while easy to cut rate on heavy industry, hard to increase effective tax rate elsewhere • Revenue in China fell further, from 12.3% in 1993 to 10.1% in 1996 • With improvements in enforcement, though, revenue later grew to 17.7% in 2004 Tax Structure Now More Compatible with a Market Economy • Firms now face closer to neutral tax incentives in allocation decisions • With revenue largely unaffected by allocation, government finally has a fiscal incentive to fully support pro-market policies • In China, reforms followed by rapid and consistent economic growth • In India, a concern that national revenue still comes largely from manufacturing, plus some from service sector Taxation by State and Local Governments • If only firms mobile, incentives neutral if collect same taxes per resident, regardless of which firms enter • Effective tax rates varied dramatically by type of firm – In China, tax on profits and sales of local firms – In India, excise taxes at variable rates on local firms – Agriculture and service sector very lightly taxed Tax Competition • Incentive to protect heavily taxed firms from competition from other locations • In China, local governments encouraged entry in heavily taxed industries by providing valuable inputs and cheap credit • In India, tax competition undermines revenue collection Implications of Low Tax Revenue • Poor quality of public utilities immediately threatens further growth • Poor quality education and health care undermines longer run growth – Average education is only two years – Only 35% of age group enrolled in secondary school – One third of children have low birth weight What to Do? • Hope tax revenue improves – China’s revenue has indeed improved gradually, growing from a low of 10.1% of GDP to 17.7% now – But the economic costs of waiting can be very high • Borrow against future tax revenue. But current deficits already 10.3% of GDP • Increased use of user fees, perhaps with private provision? – Key response in China, particularly for roads, education, health, telecom – Problem that poor may do without. Use available budget to subsidize purchase by the poor? Is problem low revenue or poor incentives to provide services? • Funding for state governments not THAT low – State revenue plus transfers in India in 2002 was 9.7% of GDP – S&L current expenditures in U.S. were 12.9% of GDP – But current figure for China is 13% of GDP, yet problems remain severe there • Incentives to provide services seem poor – Voice: Key difference from China. But provides weak oversight – Exit: But mobility across States low due to language and cultural differences How can Incentives be Improved? • Note that incentives high if have user fees • Shift funding (and expenditure responsibility) to panchayats, where mobility pressures are greater • Tie intergovernmental transfers to population (or # of school kids), providing an incentive to compete to attract residents • Break down barriers to mobility – Ease restrictions on rental markets – Ease taxes and restrictions on land sales Why is Deficit so High in India? • Some debt appropriate if tax revenue will increase in future • National deficit: Response to rapid turnover of party in power? China vs. India or U.S. • State and local deficits: Soft budget constraint? – Parallel problems in China – No cases of fiscal bankruptcies – Intergovernmental grants cover any shortfalls, creating incentives to have high debt or poor infrastructure What is to be Done? • Shift to fiscal transfers based more on formulas, e.g. population • Restrict use of debt by S&L governments to capital projects, perhaps with repayment limited to resulting revenues, a third reason to have user fees • Set up clearer legal rules to handle defaults on debts of state and local governments Broader Story about Reform Process • Pre-reform, controls essential to protect narrow tax base • Reforms relax controls, improving incentives for firms, but undermining tax revenue • Pressures force move towards a more neutral tax structure • Incentives on firms and government improve, but revenue likely falls further in short-term • Can reform policies survive the resulting fiscal pressures? – Risk that poor infrastructure undermines growth – Risk of default on debt – Risk of a populist government undoing reforms