* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download uppsatsfinal - Lund University Publications
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
STV004 Tutor: Ole Elgström Department of Political Science The Merchant and the Guardian - Ideological Economism: A Challenge to the Welfare State? Philip Thörn Abstract In this essay I try to sort out whether or not the welfare state is being challenged. My theoretical approach is based on the assumption that there has been a shift in the state-market relationship; the market has gained influence, while the state has lost influence. I approach the issue by examining and comparing the international and the Swedish academic debate on whether or not the welfare state is being challenged. When examining the international debate I have tried to include as many of the “big players” as possible. When studying the Swedish debate I have mainly focused scholars associated with: SNS and SOFI. Quite surprisingly the Swedish debate on the matter differs substantially from the international debate. There is more or less a consensus in the international debate that the challenge to the welfare state is ideological rather than economical. The Swedish debate, however, primarily concerns whether or not an extensive public sector is economically sustainable. I present a number of reasons why the Swedish debate differs: economists increased influence in the political debate; a window of opportunity; path-dependency; boundary ordering device and also the question of responsibility for the 1991 crisis. Key words: welfare state, State-Market relationship, European social models, public sector, growth Table of contents 1. Introduction 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 Aim of this study Method and Material Definitions Theoretical Framework – A Change in the StateMarket Relationship? 4 5 5 7 8 2. The International Debate – A Challenge to the Welfare State? 11 3. The Swedish Debate – Growth and the Public Sector 17 4. Summary 23 5. Explaining the Discrepancy 24 6. Bibliography 30 1. Introduction “The second principle is that organisation of social insurance should be treated as one part only of a comprehensive policy of social progress. Social insurance fully developed may provide income security; it is an attack upon Want. But Want is one only of five giants on the road of reconstruction and in some ways the easiest to attack. The others are Disease, Ignorance, Squalor and Idleness” Sir William Beveridge According to Susan Strange and Richard Rosecrance, the world has changed. Independent states used to be the key actors in the world and national governments used to be in control of domestic politics as well as the domestic economy. This is no longer true. There has been a change in the State-Market relationship; the market has gained influence, while the state has lost influence. Some argue that this change in the State-Market relationship, what one might call globalization, have had serious consequences for the European Social Models. “There has been a ‘disembedding’ of the market from the institutions that had made up post-war socio-economic order of the Keynesian welfare state” (Apeldoorn, 2000, p. 235). The re-launch of Europe, the Single European Market, can be seen as an attempt to mitigate the effects of increased globalization, but it can also be seen as an attempt by liberal forces to force change upon the welfare models of Continental and Nordic Europe. However, the social models of Europe have proven very resistant, despite the challenge from globalization, much due to the public support of the national social models. The importance of path dependency has shown to be very strong However, the very notion that there is a challenge to the European Social Models (welfare states) is disputable. Within the international political economical academic research the debate on whether or not an extensive public sector, welfare state, is growth inhibiting remains unresolved. Many would argue that the side providing the most plausible arguments, is in fact the one arguing that there is no correlation between the size of the public sector and growth (Palme, 2004, p.83) In fact, most scholars would argue that the choice between this or that system has more to do with ideological and political considerations rather than economic concerns (Sapir, 2005, p.10). This is a fact, however, that I would argue is not reflected in the academic debate in Sweden. The norm is rather to point out that “economic determinism” – globalization – forces upon Sweden a dismantling of the way too extensive welfare model. In, what most international scholars would argue to be, an ideological debate economic science is being used as political arguments for cutting back on the welfare system and public sector. Why is it that the Swedish debate still revolves around the internationally already settled issue, whether or not an extensive public sector is growth inhibiting? 4 1.1 Aim of this study The aim of this study is firstly to sort out whether or not, according to the international and Swedish political economical research, there is a challenge to the welfare state. Is there an endogenous, exogenous, economical, ideological or in fact no challenge at all? Secondly, I investigate if the Swedish political economical debate concerning the welfare state diverges from the international debate. By comparing the two debates I hope to find an answer to this question. Thirdly, I try to explain the possible differences between the international and Swedish debate on the challenges to the welfare state. Are there differences due to academic traditions or are the differences due to something else? My questions are: 1. Is the welfare state being challenged? What does the international debate say, and what does the Swedish debate say? 2. If there is a discrepancy between the international and Swedish debate on the welfare states’ future, why is this? 3. Why does the Swedish debate still revolve around the internationally already settled issue whether or not an extensive public sector is growth inhibiting? 1.2 Method and Material In his “Case study and theory in Political Science” Harry Eckstein identifies five types of case studies: 1) configurative-idiographic, where the ambition is to investigate a case without use of theory 2) disciplined-configurative, where theory is being used 3) heuristic, the ambition is to try out new theoretical ideas on a preliminary basis 4) plausibility probe, which is a form of “first test” before a more thorough investigation and 5) crucial case analysis, where the case is chosen since its been identified as ideal for testing the theory (Eckstein, 1975). My study concerns mainly the heuristic type, due to the fact that my ambition is to try and sort out the issue of whether or not globalization poses a threat to the welfare state or not, but also why the Swedish debate differs so substantially from the international debate. I have chosen to conduct a qualitative comparative study. Since my ambition is to try and sort out why the Swedish debate differs from the international debate I believe a qualitative method is the most fruitful approach as “qualitative methods …are most appropriately employed where the goal of research is to explore people’s subjective experiences and the meanings they attach to those experiences” (Marsh&Stoker, 2002, p.199). Scholars using qualitative methods often use interviews as a mean to explore subjective perceptions “Finally, qualitative methods draw particular attention to contextual issues, placing an interviewee’s attitudes and behavior in the context of their individual biography and the wider social setting” (Marsh&Stoker, 2002, p.199), but I have chosen not to. Due to the fact that the Swedish debate has been quite dramatic and passionate, there has been no problem 5 identifying the protagonists’ subjective perceptions of this matter. The relatively extensive empirical material, exclusively consisting of research material, has given me the opportunity of reaching a deeper insight and has allowed me to focus on the academic arguments as well as other potential reasons of disagreement. I believe a comparative qualitative study is the best approach for my study and offers the best opportunity to reach an understanding “By making the researcher aware of unexpected differences, or even surprising similarities, between cases, comparison brings a sense of perspective to a familiar environment and discourages parochial responses to political issues. Observations of the ways in which political problems are addressed in different contexts provides valuable opportunities for policy learning and exposure to new ideas and perspectives” (Marsh&Stoker, 2002, p.249). I have chosen to analyze the Swedish academic debate in contrast to the international debate due to two reasons: 1.) The availability of access to primary material 2.) Sweden offers an interesting case since it is has already been intensively scrutinized by international scholars “Most Europeans welfare states experienced some serious challenges of some kind or another in 1980’s or 1990’s. It has not gone unnoticed in the academic and media world that the Nordic welfare states were among these. Sweden, in particular, has come under closer international scrutiny, with observations of problems often mixed a dose of schadenfreude, perhaps to compensate for previous envy at, or disbelief of, the social and economic success of her welfare model” (Kuhnle, 2001, p.103). My selection of research material (my empirical evidence) is based on what I consider to be the main actors in the international and Swedish debate. In the international debate I have tried to include all the ‘big players’ such as Atkinson, Dowrick, Esping-Andersen, Liebdfried, Piersson, Streeck and Scharpf. The question of whom is to be included in this exclusive group is of course ultimately a subjective matter. However, after having analyzed the debate for a longer period of time I have found that there seem to be a general consensus that they are in fact to be regarded as the ‘big players’. In the Swedish debate I have found that the most active participants in the debate are scholars associated with the to the two organizations: Swedish Center for Business and Policy Studies (SNS) - a liberal think-tank and promoter of research – and Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI) – a research institute linked to Stockholm University. The Swedish debate has been on-going, with various levels of intensity, for more than two decades but these two organization have in one way or the other somehow constantly been involved. Simply put, SNS is the proponent of a ‘dismantling’ of the Swedish welfare state, and is suggesting a move in the direction of a more market pillar oriented welfare state, while SOFI is proposing a preservation of the Swedish welfare state, and its current reliance on the state pillar. I have chosen to divide my disposition into four different sectors. The first part addresses my methodological considerations, theoretical approach and the aim of my study. The second part is a presentation and analysis of the international debate concerning the welfare state. The third part is a presentation and analysis of the Swedish debate concerning the welfare state. I have chosen to present the Swedish debate in chronological order, since I am making a point out of this in my 6 conclusion, and also to present only those parts that are of interest to my study due to the immense amount of material and in order to get a good flow in language and disposition. The fourth part is a brief summary. In the fifth part I give answer to my questions (with a focus on my third point), explain why the debates diverge, present my conclusions and discuss the theoretical implications of my study. 1.3 Definitions -Welfare state: According to Esping-Andersen welfare states are always ‘politics against markets’, and Liebdfried’s states that “In the social sciences, however, the term ‘welfare state’ has now been commonly used for some time to connotate that higher degree of legitimate state intervention aimed at increasing public welfare – with the US liberal type of society as the implicit contrast, and the UK somewhere in-between” (Leibfried, 2001, p1). However Esping-Andersen refines his argument and argues that there are actually different types of welfare states with different foundational pillars: the Scandinavian model (state pillar), the Continental model (family pillar) and the Liberal model (market pillar), which suggests that a country can have a welfare state system without a high degree of state intervention. I will be using Esping-Andersen’s three model system as origin for my analysis (I will develop Esping-Andersen’s typology further in section 2). -Globalization: I will be using a definition of globalization corresponding to the notion that there has been a shift in the state-market relationship; the market has gained influence while the state has lost influence. This notion is based upon what Susan Strange identifies as three major changes in the world economy: 1) Technological change 2) Mobile capital 3) Transborder communications (Strange, 2000, p.60f). This argumentation is supported by Rosencrance “Today and for the foreseeable future, the only international civilization worthy of the name is the governing economic culture of the world market” (Rosencrance, 1996, p.45). According to this definition of globalization the world is interdependent and is inhabited by more actors than states. States have lost power, not to other states, however, but to the global market – the world economy (an economic structure). I will develop this matter further in the section Theoretical framework. -Nordic/Scandinavian model: Some scholars choose to use the label Nordic model while others prefer the Scandinavian model. Since my study focuses on Sweden, which is included in either label – both definitions are essentially used for describing countries that have welfare states with the state as the foundational pillar – I have chosen to respect the authors’ choice of preference thus using both labels. In a more technical analysis a more thorough investigation of why different labels are being presented would have been needed, but since my study is conducted on a rather high level of abstraction this is not needed. 7 1.4 Theoretical Framework - A Change in the StateMarket Relationship? Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R. D Underhill have highlighted three interrelated theoretical problems in IPE: 1). the relationship between the economical and political domain 2). the levels of analysis must be addressed and 3). the role of the state. In turn these problems lead us on to the structure-agent problem and the question of actors: are structures more important than agents and are states the most important actors or not? (Stubbs&Underhill, 2000, p. 16) The key disagreement according to Frieden and Lake has to do with two relationships: a) international and domestic political economies and b) state and social forces. When you combine these two relationships, four different perspectives arise: international political, international economical, domestic institutional and domestic societal (Frieden&Lake, 2000, p. 8f). The domestic institutional and the domestic societal look inside nation-states for explanations of the international political economy. While the institutional perspective emphasizes the importance of national policymakers and domestic institutions (North 2000, p.47ff), the societal perspective stresses the importance of economic and socio-political actors (Eichengreen 2000, p.37ff). International political focuses on the relationship between states and the constraints imposed on these by the global structure (Krasner 2000, p.19ff), while international economic emphasizes the importance of constraints external to individual nations and puts socio-economic factors ahead of political (Strange 2000, p. 60). It should here be noted that most scholars recognise that all theories are ideal types and are incapable of fully understanding the complexity of reality. At the end of the day the issue being analysed plays the most importance part for whether choosing this or that dimension and/or perspective. Since my study is focused on the sustainability of welfare states, on an international level, I find it more fruitful to work with the theories emphasizing the international level rather than the more domestic ones. A good illustration of the contending international perspectives is offered by Krasner and Strange, in an interesting debate in the Review of International Political Economy (RIPE), regarding whether the world has changed or not. Krasner argues that challenges to the state are not new. Transnational flows have existed in all ages and our trend is not historically unique, no matter whether we are talking about trade, finance or diseases. Globalization is nothing new but has been a reoccurring phenomenon throughout history. According to Krasner there has been no theoretical breakthrough and no paradigmatic shift, the debate is still revolving around the classic ideas of Realism, Liberalism and Marxism (Krasner, RIPE 1994:1, p. 14). Marxism, although an interesting theory, lacks empirical evidence and nothing implies that actors (states) are instantiated by some larger institutional whole, structure. States continue to be the most important actors on the international arena and therefore the “real” debate is between liberalism and realism. The current trend is not globalism but rather regionalism: major states cooperate temporarily, not in an attempt to make new friends, but out of fear of mutual destruction. 8 Strange’s response to this is a harsh “Wake up, Krasner! The world has changed”(Strange, RIPE 1994:2, p.209ff). According to Strange many scholars suffer from myopia and prefer to fit fact into theory, rather than re-examining the theory’s when evidence shows that it is no longer valid. Although the changes we are experiencing today - globalism, international trade, FDI etc - has had its predecessors in history, it is the extent of these phenomena which is new (Strange, RIPE 1994:2, p.210). Krasner has a point when saying not everything is new, but his fallacy appears when he is proclaiming nothing is new. Susan Strange identifies three major changes or trends in the world economy: 1.) Technological Change 2.) Mobile Capital 3.) Transborder communications (Strange, Friden&Lake 2000, p. 60ff). The advanced developed states in the world put aside political conflict and instead concentrate on getting a greater share of the world output. “Today and for the foreseeable future, the only international civilization worthy of the name is the governing economic culture of the world market” (Rosencrance, 1996, p.45). The modern state does not seek to “combine or excel in all economic functions, from mining and agriculture to production and distribution” (Rosencrance, 1996, p.47), but instead it chooses to specialise in its core activities and modern technology. The world of Krasner is a zero sum game where one state’s loss is the other state’s gain. The world of Strange is interdependent and is inhabited by more actors than states, and states have lost power but not to other states but to the global market – the world economy (an economic structure). These changes in the world order constitute, according to some research, serious threats to the welfare state. “Flexible labor and welfare laws will be more likely to bring in foreign technology and investment than rigid welfare and employment requirements. As governments seek to institute more labor flexibility – in hiring, wages, and hours worked – some domestic workers may react unfavourably if benefits are reduced: but all workers do not oppose flexibility. Skilled and office workers have different interests from those who perform routine tasks on an assembly line ... In any event, virtualization calls for a restructuring of state and labor policies to meet international economic requirements.” (Rosecrance 1999, p. 91). Dani Rodrik argues in his “Sense and Non-Sense in Globalization Debate” that many of the proposed risks of fundamental change are in fact exaggerated. His main argument is that “social welfare programs and openness to trade have grown handin- hand, each reinforcing the other. The social insurance programs carried out by government have helped mitigate the disruptions caused by international trade and solidified coalitions in favour of economic openness” (Rodrik, 2000 p.461). Rodrik furthermore highlights the fact that there is a strong correlation between the degree of exposure to international trade and the importance of the government in the economy: At the one end you have countries like the US and Japan, which have the lowest trade shares in GDP and at the same time the lowest shares of spending on social protection. At the other end you have countries like Denmark, Netherlands and Sweden, which have large governments in part as a result of their attempt to minimize the social impact of openness to the international economy (Rodrik, 2000, p.465). A key challenge, though, is “… the ideological onslaught against the 9 welfare state has paralyzed many governments and made them unable to respond to the domestic needs of a more integrated economy” (Rodrik, 2000, p.464) Strange agues that the state in fact most willingly gave the market a more prominent position “What the Retreat of the state was saying was not just that the powers and responsibilities of state governments were being eroded, but why this was so. It was due, I argued, to the structural forces in a predominately market economy set free, not by blind chance, but by the conscious decisions of governments, more especially of the government of the United States” (Strange 2000, p.85). Why? Because the state, especially the Anglo-Saxon states that in many important aspects are market-oriented, realized they had a lot to gain by doing it (Strange 1996, p.1ff) Also according to Wofgang Streeck this major change in the State-Market relationship was initiated by the US: The changes in the international position of the United States that has exhausted its capacity to act as a benevolent hegemon has gradually given rise to in the 1970’s to a domestic move away from the New Deal compromise to a political economy that sought competitiveness through deregulation and de-unization and abandoned the social democratic principle that wages and social conditions were to be taken out of competition. After the final defeat of the Labor Law Reform Act in 1978, the Federal Reserve could feel free to respond to the second oil crisis with a dramatic increase in interest rates, ending inflation at the price of de-industrialization and causing a further, probably irreversible decline in union organization. In the early 1980’s, with effectively deregulated, worldwide integrated capital markets, the destruction of American trade unions paid off handsomely in that it gave the United States, the ‘flexible’ markets and the ‘confidence’ of financial investors required to underwrite an expansionist fiscal policy that has been ironically characterized as ‘Keynesianism in one country’. From the perspective of other capitalist countries, that term would appear to have carried a particularly ominous connotation. As the French socialist government after 1981 was soon to find out under the watchful eyes of other political elites, the dynamics of the international political economy after the second oil shock were governed by the old Roman imperial maxim, quod licet Jovi non licet bovi. Keynesianism had ceased to be universally available; it had become limited to just one, but to only one, country (Streeck 1992, p.210-211). Andew Martin addresses the issue in his “What Does Globalization Have to do With the Erosion of Welfare States? Sorting Out the Issues”, and his conclusions in many aspects join forces with Streeck’s ideas. Martin argues that when the US chose to abandon Bretton-Woods and the Keynesian objective of full employment and replaced it with the monetarian principle, whose main objective is low inflation (essentially the preservation of the value of capital), the rest of the capitalist countries could do nothing but follow (Martin, 1996, p.31). Simply put: one economic regime, Keynesianism, has been replaced by another, monetarianism. My conclusion is that there has been a change in the State-Market relationship: the market has gained influence, while the state has lost influence. But the question of whether or not this really poses a threat to the WS or not remains. 10 2. The International Debate - A Challenge to the Welfare State? “Capitalism is the astounding belief that the most wickedest of men will do the most wickedest of things for the greatest good of everyone” John Maynard Keynes Bastiaan van Apeldoorn argues in his “The Political Economy of European Integration” that there has been a major transformation of Western European capitalism the past two decades. “There has been a ‘disembedding’ of the market from the institutions that had made up post-war socio-economic order of the Keynesian welfare state” (Apeldoorn, 2000, p. 235). There has been a primacy of negative integration (market liberalization) over positive integration (providing public goods at a European level) (Apeldoorn, 2000, p.235). He furthermore argues that the “re-launch” of Europe, the Single European Act (SEA) and the Maastrich Treaty, was more due to the influence of the European Round Table of Industrialist (ERT), a very powerful capitalist lobby group, and not so much due to the political will of the member states. One of his main points is that there was actually three rival projects for the re-launch of Europe: 1) the Neo-liberal project; according to which the stagflation of the Europeam economy ‘Eurosclerosis’ was the result of institutional rigidities – excessive government intervention, too powerful trade unions, overburdened welfare state, etc. Their (global financial capital, TNCs with global reach) motive for a re-launch of Europe, was the dream of a free market with less state intervention. 2) the Neo-Mercantilist Project; according to which the economical problems of Europe was due to excessive fragmentation (especially in comparison with US or Japan), and subsequently insufficient economies of scale. Their (former national champions e.g. Volvo, ‘would-be European champions’) motive for a re-launch of Europe, was the dream of a strong regional economy with a sufficient internal market, with industrial policies aimed at promoting the European champions. 3) the Social-Democratic Project, according to which unbridled globalization was a threat to the European model of society, with its traditions of a mixed economy and high levels of social protection . The hope was that the SEA would fill two functions “ … regaining some democratic control of the global financial markets as well as paving the way to a federal political union that could then further advance the cause of organizing European space” (Apeldoorn, 2000, p. 239f). The result, however, was more a combination of all three projects rather than the materialization of either one of them – what Apeldoorn refers to as the Embedded Liberalism Synthesis. The neo-liberal project, although the primacy lies with freedom of capital and markets, stopped short of “… disembedding the European model.” Why is this? On the one hand, change does not happen over night, it takes 11 time. On the other hand “… a pure neo-liberal strategy would also undermine the long-term accumulation prospects of industrial capital, which still needs the state to educate the workforce, to provide the infrastructure, to pursue macroeconomic policies that favour growth and investment, to maintain social and political stability etc” (Apeldoorn 2000, p.240). Another interesting result is that a transnational discourse has been established, and that this discourse has come to focus on word ‘competitiveness’, appealing equally to neo-liberals, neo-mercantilists and social democrats, but defined in neoliberal terms. The liberal definition of competitiveness influence is also acknowledged by the EC “vital factor for the competitiveness of the European Industry” calling for a “radical rethink of all relevant labour market systems – employment protection, working time, social protection and health and safety – to adapt them to a world which will be organized differently” (Apeldoorn, 2000, p. 241). European welfare states espouse a number of different models of solidarity, but in all there exists a fundamental dedication to basic social citizenship, to “pooling social risks” collectively (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p. 7). The welfare state is in fact a social contract with the citizens, and the impact of path dependency should not be underestimated. Esping-Andersen in fact argues that there lies an obstacle to possibly any reform to these institutions. Welfare systems are according to EspingAndersen built on three pillars: markets, families and government (state), and the real world of welfare is the product of how these three pillars interact. If one pillar fails, there is either the possibility that the responsibility is absorbed in the two remaining pillars, or alternatively that unsolved welfare problems mount (EspingAndersen, 2002, p.13). Esping-Andersen identifies tree welfare models, based on what is their pillar of foundation: 1) the Scandinavian Welfare Model, which puts its emphasis on the government pillar. It has actively ‘de-familiarized’ welfare responsibilities (hoping to unburden the family, at the same time increasing the individual’s independence). It has also ‘de-commodified’ the citizens, thereby trying to minimize the degree to which individuals’ welfare depends on their fortunes in the market. “…the crowding out of markets in the pursuit of welfare is attached to a ‘crowding in’ policy of maximizing citizens’ employability and productivity” (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p.14) 2) the ‘Liberal’ Welfare Model (Ireland, UK and US) ,which puts its emphasis on the market pillar. The basic idea is that only the needy should be subject to benefits and state intervention, while the middle-class is encouraged to opt into the private welfare market. There has been a shift from needs-test towards a work-conditional benefit system in recent years. One of the overriding goals is to reduce public taxation and expenditure, and in Britain this have to some extent been successful, especially regarding long-term pension expenditures. However, welfare services that the government is not paying for is handed over to the private citizen “… and it is doubtful whether there are any real total cost savings to be gained” (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p.15). “The total welfare resource allocation (as a percentage o GDP) in Scandinavia is not greater that in the United States. The difference is simply a matter of the public-private expenditure mix” (Esping-Andersen, 1999). 3) the Continental European Welfare Model, which puts its emphasis on the family pillar (to what extent, however, very 12 much depending on the country – most powerfully in Southern Europe, and by far the least in Belgium and France). The security of the chief (male) breadwinner is of fundamental importance and this familialist bias is additionally reinforced by the dominance of social insurance. Employment-linked social insurance protects well those with stable, lifelong employment (men). The model is highly vulnerable to employment stagnation and to high inactivity rate, at the same time as it is facing costly pension commitments and serious fiscal constraints. Continental Europe is stuck in a ‘welfare-without work’ trap, where jobs in the market economy growth is made difficult by high wage floors and contribution burdens. “Expanding employment among women and older workers becomes sine non qua for long term sustainability” (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p.17). Esping-Andersen main conclusion is that the welfare state, and the European social model is challenged - but not threatened, and definitely not on the verge of extinction as some would argue. The welfare is too traditionally rooted for ever being seriously threatened, but perhaps challenged and in need of reform (Esping-Andersen, 2002 p. 7, Hemerijck, 2002, p.175). Anton Hemerijck develops Esping-Andersens thesis that the welfare state is in need of a reform in his “Self-Transformation of European Social Model(s)”. He however shifts the focus from the problem oriented question “What sort of new welfare architecture is required in the face of the strains of transformation?” to the ‘political-institutional’ “What kinds of policies are feasible and fair, given the tremendous differences in welfare state design and in decision making structures across Europe?” Hemerijck suggests that the major problem the welfare states are facing is the ‘Service Sector Trilemma’ - “Since the mid -1970’s European economies , with the notable exception of the Netherlands and Iceland, have experienced substantial employment deceline in the exposed sectors, especially in agriculture, mining, manufacturing, and transport. Sweden and Finland stand out in terms of suffering a continous loss in industrial employment. The decline of jobs in the exposed sectors is probably less related to competition from Third World markets than to the removal of regional barriers concerning the free movement of capital, firms, goods, and services by the completion of the European internal market” (Hemericjk, 2002, p.183). De-industrialization, the rise of the service sector, and the fiscal constraints that derive from EMU lead to a situation where the welfare goals of high levels of employment, income equality, and fiscal restraint can no longer be achieved simultaneously – this problematic situation is known as the Service Sector Trilemma Hemerijck identifies what problems the different models are facing due to the Service Sector Trilemma. The main problem confronting the Scandinavian Model is that financing the welfare state is made more difficult due to high capital mobility, the fiscal and budgetary constraints that ageing and European monetary integration impose, and increased political tax resistance. Falling tax revenues during the 1990’s has led to sharp fall in public employment, which needs to be compensated by an increase in private sector jobs. “This is where the trilemma raises its head: the Nordic countries face the hard choice between liberalizing private services, which entails more wage inequality, or a continued adherence to equality which, under conditions of budget constraint, implies more unemployment” (Hemerijck, 2002, p. 13 185). The Anglo-Saxon Model is far less threatened by long-term problems of financial sustainability, but is instead facing severe problems of income polarization and ever increasing inequalities regarding access to social insurance. Radical labour deregulation has also made it impossible to reach cooperative arrangements between management and trade unions. The model is also suffering from an inability to produce a well-trained labour force (Hemerijck, 2002, p.185). The Continental European Problem consists mainly in its chronic inability to stimulate employment growth. The obstacle to private jobs lies in high wage floors, due to high fixed labour costs, while public employment is constrained by the fiscal constraints of supporting a very large inactive population (Hemericjk, 2002, p.186). Esping-Andersen argues that there is no convergence towards a European social model and that the different member states are locked in their own pathdependencies “In the light of the diversity of national welfare system, it is additionally fruitless to contemplate a single design for all nations even if they do face rather similar problems. Just as no EU Member State is likely to privatize its welfare state, neither is a radical welfare regime change likely to occur. The institutional framework of national welfare systems are historically’locked in’ and any realistic move towards common objectives must presume that such, if accepted, will be adapted to national practice” (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p.25). With 25 models there cannot exist a single ‘European social model’ towards which Member States of the European Union could possible converge in the next decade, however with the OMC there seem to be at least an opening to the rigidity of the path dependant welfare systems of Europe (Sapir, 2005, p.12) “More important is the experience gained through peer review. OMC stimulates an understanding of national contexts, whereby policy makers are able to assess why some solutions can or cannot be transposed to their own national context” (Hemerijck, 2002. p.211). Leibfried agrees with Esping-Andersen and Hemerijck in that the prospect of a single European social model is not very plausible, and that the different national models will prevail “The welfare state does not follow a unified logic, nor does its reforms. The different reform paths pursued are, in turn, influenced and shaped by a series of factors: the partisan complexion of government, the power resources and aggregation capacity of trade unions and employers, the system of interest mediation, the room for manoeuvre granted by a nation’s polity and, last but not least, the institutional legacy of the welfare state regime – including the different sets of problems associated with each regime” (Leibfried, 2001, p. 5). Leibfried recognises that “the welfare state is having hard times” (Leibfried, 2001, p.5), but when he recapitulates the development from the 1970’s and onwards he is not very impressed by the arguments put forward by the welfare states antagonists. When addressing the market liberal ideas that the welfare state is hampering economic growth and is an inefficient economic institution, Leibfried refers to Atkinson’s classic study “The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State”. Atkinson’s conclusion is agnostic – he finds no empirical evidence of the size of welfare state affecting growth or economic performance (Atkinson, 1999, p.184) (I will elaborate further on this matter in the following section the Swedish Debate). Leibfried concludes with “This is a story about reconfiguring the welfare state, about it being ’locked in’ by past needs and deeds, not about its crisis and demise” 14 (Leibfried, 2001, p. 5). Fritz Scharpf also finds the European social models to be far too differentiated, why a standardized solution is impossible. “As a consequence, national welfare states differ greatly in their vulnerability to international economical pressures, and in the specific problems that they need most urgently to address. They differ also in the policy options that they could reach under the path-dependent constraints of existing policy legacies and under the institutional constraints of existing veto positions” (Scharpf, 2001, p.145). When Stein Kuhlnes assesses the Nordic welfare states in ”The Nordic welfare state in a European context: dealing with new economic and ideological challenges in the 1990’s” he reaches the following conclusions: 1) the Nordic and the European welfare states are likely to stay 2) the Nordic welfare state model can be a “vital shock absorber” and probably mitigated the economic crisis of the 1990’s (Kuhlnes, 2001, p. 116). “The Finnish experience may teach other governments a lesson: an advanced universalistic, welfare state is not a handicap when a sudden, unexpected economic crisis occurs. On the contrary, the type and the format of the welfare state amy have helped the Nordic countries, and Finland especially, more rapidly through the ‘crisis than a welfare state of another, less comprehensive, type might have done, and with less social damage” (Kuhlnes, 2001, p. 116). Kuhlnes conclusion is that the Nordic welfare states are likely to reform in the direction of a less generous welfare state, and a slightly different mix of welfare provision. He even suggests that the World Bank, perhaps the very symbol of a world wide capitalist market economy, exclaim “Look to Scandinavia”, especially Finland, when providing policy advice to countries undergoing economic crisis (Kuhlne, 2001, p. 119). André Sapir has tried to categorize the European social models in attempt to better address the problems Europe are facing. By using an analytical box, with one axis for equity and another axis for efficiency, he divides the different European social models into four broad categories: ‘Continentals’ (Low efficiency, High equity); ‘Mediterraneans’ (Low efficiency, Low equity); ‘Nordics’ (High efficiency, High equity) and ‘Anglo-Saxons’ (High efficiency, Low equity). Sapirs focus lie on Mediterraneans and Continental social models, due to the fact that “The combined GDP of countries with inefficient models account for two-thirds of the entire EU and 90 percent of the Eurozone” (Sapir, 2005, p.1), while the “Nordics enjoy an envious position, with a social model that delivers both efficiency and equity, whereas Mediterraneans live in a society that delivers neither efficiency nor equity” (Sapir, 2005, p.9). Thus quite naturally much focus lies on the future of the Continental and Mediterranenan models and in what future direction their models will head. Once again it is being stressed that the choice between this or that system has more to do with ideological preferences rather than economic necessities. “This suggest that both Nordic and Anglo-Saxon models are sustainable, while Continental and Mediterranean models are not and must be reformed in the direction of greater efficiency by reducing disincentives to work and to grow. On the other hand, there is no reason a priori to assume that such reform must go handin-hand with changes in terms of equity. It is perfectly possible for the Continental model to become more like the Nordic one, and for the Mediterranean model to 15 become more like the Anglo-Saxon model” (Sapir, 2005, p.10). Andrew B. Atkinson’s extensive work “The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State” offers also some interesting input. First of all he argues that there is no evidence of public sector expenditure being growth inhibiting “The studies of the aggregate relationship between economic performance and the size of the welfare state reviewed here do not yield conclusive evidence. The results of econometric studies of the relationship between social transfer spending and growth rates are mixed: some finding that high spending on social transfers leads to lower growth, other find the reverse. The largest of the estimated effects – in either direction – do not, however, seem believable” (Atkinson, 1999, p.184). But he furthermore argues that we should not expect economists to be without a political agenda “The future of the welfare state is a highly political issue … Calls by economists for rolling back the welfare state are themselves part of the political process; we have not just endogenous politicians but also endogenous economists, whose behaviour has to be explained” (Atkinson, 1999, p. 187). My conclusion is that in the international academic research there seems to be a consensus that the major threat to the welfare state is not economical but political. The shift in the state-market power relationship does have implications for the European social models and the different types of welfare state, but this challenge must not be exaggerated. Rather than forcing them to rebuild from their very foundation, the shift forces the social models to do some readjustments of the already existing systems. Some models are also more challenged than others; while the Anglo-Saxon and Scandinavian models seem to be in rather good shape (Sapir, 2005, p. 10), the Continental models are facing difficulties. Using EspingAndersens typology, it seems like the state and the market pillars are more accustomed to cope with this state-market shift, than the family pillar. All models are facing problems, however; the Continental models have an insufficient job growth at the same time suffering from severe financial constrain; while the AngloSaxon models have problems with income equality and increasing poverty rate and an insufficient numbers of educated people and the Scandinavian models suffers from high rates of unemployed. Most scholars, however, seem to rule the AngloSaxon and Scandinavian models efficient, perhaps in need of some reformation but this is nothing that can not be solved within the existing systems. The international debate revolves around what course of direction the countries with Continental models will take – an acute issue since these countries account for two-thirds of EU’s GDP. Focus lies on whether they will move towards the Anglo-Saxon models (market pillar) or will they move towards the Scandinavian models (state pillar). This choice of direction, however, has more to do with ideological preferences rather than economic necessities – due to the fact that both models are considered efficient. There seem to be reasons no to forget Atkinson’s “warning” of endogenous economists, with intentions of affecting the political agenda. In the international debate there seems to be a consensus that the future of the welfare state lies in the hands of domestic politics. 16 3. The Swedish Debate – Growth and the Public Sector ”An economist is an expert who will know tomorrow why the things he predicted yesterday didn't happen today.” Laurence J. Peter In 1985 Walter Korpi published an article in Ekonomisk Debatt called ”Welfare politics and economic growth: a comparative study of 18 OECD-countries”. Korpi investigates whether or not the market liberal hypothesis, that countries with an extensive public sector are suffering from lower rates of growth than countries with less extensive public sectors, have any empirical back-up. (Korpi, 1985, p. 192). Korpi’s focus in his cross-country survey of GDP-growth per capita lies on the post WWII time period (1950-60’s) and he tries to address the methodological considerations by singling out a number of control variables for his study: 1) Ratio of the population in the agricultural sector 2) potential for market intervention (distribution of political power) 3) Size of the public sector 4) Tax leverage 5) Income distribution. By including these control variables in his study Korpi hopes to better isolate the impact of public sector interference in the market mechanisms. Korpi’s conclusion is that market liberal hypothesis has no empirical back-up. Instead he finds the empirical evidence to be pointing in quite the opposite direction – countries with an extensive public sector and welfare state are performing slightly better than more market oriented countries (Korpi, 1985, p. 201). Assar Lindbeck does not agree with Korpi, and in a reply “Welfare, taxes and and growth” also published in Ekonomisk Debatt, he offers an alternative explanation. Lindbeck criticises Korpi for his lack of understanding of the profound methodological problems associated with this kind of studies (Lindbeck, 1985, p. 204). First of all he does not find Korpi’s attempt to isolate the impact of the public sector from other factors that might have influenced countries growth rate, very convincing. Secondly, he finds Korpi’s choice of time period to be strongly biased – this particular time period experienced exceptional growth rates, at the same time that the public sectors expanded rapidly. According to Lindbeck these two phenomena have no correlation. Finally, Lindbeck argues that Korpi’s study tries to address too many variables at the same time, why it is hard to establish any plausible causal relationship. By addressing a fewer number of variables, a higher level of credibility would be achieved (Lindbeck, 1985, p.214). Lindbeck’s point of view would soon reach a greater audience when the so called Lindbeck commission (Per Molander, Torsten Persson, Olof Peterson, Agar Sandmo, Birgitta Swedenborg and Niels Thygesen were also members of the commission) was appointed by the liberal government in 1992. The commission’s main objective was to investigate what reforms needed to be done in Sweden in 17 order to enhance Sweden’s economic performance “The report emphasizes that good policy advice is not enough; it is also necessary to analyse and reform the institutions which continually produce undesired outcomes with respect not only to macroeconomic stability but also economic efficiency and growth. The proposed institutional reforms are designed to restore a highly competitive market system and to facilitate a responsible fiscal stabilisation programme” (Lindbeck et al., 1993, p.1). The commission’s conclusion, which is concretised in 113 specific policy advice, suggests that the Swedish model is not economically sustainable, is growth inhibiting and is an important reason why Sweden is lagging behind other developed countries (Lindbeck et al, 1993, p.34f). Korpi published in 1995 ”Is Sweden lagging behind?”, an anthology where he tries to summarize the debate concerning whether or not Sweden is economically lagging behind other developed countries (the debate in the book originally took place in Ekonomisk Debatt during the years 1990-91). Korpi’s main point is that the notion that Sweden is lagging behind other developed countries lacks empirical evidence and is based on sloppy analysis not addressing the methodological considerations in a correct way. “Most unfortunately, this popular but academically incorrect picture of Sweden as an underperforming country has established itself in the academic world and proven to be very persistent” (Korpi, 1995, p.127). Lars Bergman’s, Ulf Jakobsson’s, Mats Persson’s and Hans Tson Söderström’s reply to Korpi in the anthology is that his argumentation and analysis is biased and is suffering from lack of objectivity. When trying to make cross country comparative studies four methodological issues needs to be addressed, according to Bergman et al.: 1) unit of production (e.g. GDP per capita, GDP per worked hour etc.) 2) preference of time period 3) preference of countries 4) weighing of countries production (e.g. are all countries given the same weigh, or are countries given various amount of weigh depending on their size) (Bergman et al., 1995, p. 149). Bergman et al. argue that Korpi consciously chooses to address these methodological considerations in a way that strongly favours his notion that Sweden is not lagging behind other developed countries growth wise. When addressing the matter more objectively and methodologically correct the result is quite the opposite – Sweden is lagging behind, and needs to make serious reforms in order to catch-up with other developed countries (Bergman et al., 1995, p. 148ff). What is interesting for my study is how well this debate corresponds with the one taking place 1985 between Korpi and Lindbeck. In many aspects it is the same debate, how to address the methodological considerations and how easily the results are tilted in either direction depending on one’s preference of time variables, GDP units, selection of countries and so forth. As we shall see, this ‘second round’ of debate however, would not be the end of it. Agell et al. vs. Henrekson&Fölster soon assured a continuance of this passionate debate. Another economist I find important to include, before I move on to the Agell et al. vs. Henrekson&Fölster debate, is Ulf Jakobsson. His contribution in “The Economists in the Public Debate – are they doing any good?” addresses what he considers to be massive changes in the Swedish economic policy during the late 1980’s and the 1990’s: 1) deregulation of financial markets (mobile capital) 2) historically low inflation 3) a halt in the expansion of the public sector 4) 18 reformation on the tax-system 5) floating currency and a central bank with an inflationary target (Jakobsson, 1996, p.167). These points are perhaps not very controversial, but he furthermore argues that Sweden is suffering from a long term decline in welfare and that Sweden is suffering from an economic underperformance. He suggests that it would have been impossible for Sweden to “keep on going along the same old track” (Jakobsson, 1996, p.168). According to Jakobsson the Swedish model, the way we know it, is experiencing the last days of its existence “Due to the fact that the structural change that took place during the 1980’s and the beginning of the 1990’s can be seen as the end for the postwar Swedish model, it is of the uttermost importance that we broaden the discussion to include the economists’ relationship to this very model” (Jakobsson, 1996, p. 169). According to Jakobsson’s ways of reasoning there is no way the Swedish model can continue to exist without the Rehn-Meidner model – the Swedish version of Keynesianism that was the norm until the 1990’s – and thus a radical rethinking of the model is necessary (Jakobsson, 1996, p. 188). This argumentation does not correlate with the international debate where the norm seems to be – a continuance of the Swedish social model is very much possible, also without a continuance of the Rehn-Meidner model (Keynesianism). In their essay “Growth and the public sector: A critical review essay” Jonas Agell, Tomas Lindh and Henry Ohlsson review the theoretical and empirical evidence on the relation between growth and the public sector. The authors find that there is no positive, negative or non-existent relation between the public sector and growth – a cross-country regression is easily tilted from positive to negative by just introducing control variables for initial GDP “many growth models, with the neoclassical one as a prime example, imply the existence of a catching-up effect: economies which initially have a relatively low level of GDP have a tendency to grow faster than richer countries, which are closer to their steady-state (Agell et al. 1997, p.40)” and dependent population “According to the life cycle theory of consumption countries with a large percentage of pensioners will have a relatively low savings ratio (savings are essentially for investment, which in turn are essential for growth). Moreover, micro-econometric studies of the pattern of wages over an individual’s life cycle strongly suggests that demographic structure can also be significant for a country’s aggregate stock of human capital (according to many empirical studies, an inverse U is a good description of changes in human capital over an individual’s life cycle)” (Agell et al. 1997, p.45). Their conclusion is that “… it is no longer obvious that Sweden is lagging behind” and “One message is that it is not possible to prove that there is a clear-cut causal connection from observations of public sector size to economic growth. In saying so, we do not claim that public sector growth does not pose growth problems: nor do we claim that normal growth performance implies that the public sector is necessarily of the right size. Both questions deserve a serious discussion, but preferably one which is free from ideological overtones and preconceived ideas about the nature of the world” (Agell et al. 1997, p.47). Their conclusion is that size of the public sector has more to do with distributional issues, or ideological one could argue, rather than economical growth issues. Staffan Fölster and Magnus Henrekson do not agree. They argue that Agell et al. 19 base their conclusion on empirical studies, and on their own regressions, without evaluating the econometric problems that arise (Fölster&Henrekson, 1999, p.337). According to Fölster and Henrekson, Agell et al. focus their theoretical review on the growth effects of taxes and certain growth-promoting public programs, largely ignoring potentially negative growth effects of public programs. Furthermore Agell et al.’s selection of countries is biased and problematic due to the fact that they mix rich and poor countries in their survey. Finally, they argue that no attempt is made to try and address the simultaneity problems that arise (Fölster&Henrekson, 1999, p. 354). Fölster and Henrekson conduct an own empirical study, where they try to address the methodological problems they have identified (I will not give an detailed explanation of the econometric methodological discussion in this essay due to lack of space) and find Agell et al.’s agnostic conclusion to be not plausible. Agell et al’s approach does not take into consideration the econometric that arise, and hence a bias towards agnostic conclusions is inescapable. Fölster and Henrekson conclusion is that “While we do not claim that our analysis settles the issue: we do find a tendency toward a more robust negative growth effect of large public expenditures in rich countries, compared to studies where these econometric problems were ignored or treated more cursorily” (Föslster&Henrekson, 1999, p. 354). Agell et al.’s reply to Fölster and Henrekson criticism is harsh. By “re-estimating their growth equation using theoretically valid instruments, we find that the growth effect of the public sector is statistically insignificant, and much smaller than the point-estimates that they report (Agell et al., 1999, p.359)”. Agell et al. once again stress the fact that it is very difficult to find any empirical or theoretical solid evidence for the notion that the size of the public sector affects growth. The problem is that the size of the public sector affects growth via a standard supply side relation, while growth affects the size of the public sector via the income elasticity of the demand for public sector activities (Agell et al., 1999, p. 360). The problem lies in identifying what is driving what - to identify exogenous variables that affect the demand relation but not the supply relation. This identification is something that Agell et al. deem to be a very hard, perhaps even impossible, task. Agell et al. defend their (and Atkinson’s and Slemrod’s) agnostic position with the convincing argument that there are no easy ways of addressing the econometrics problem arising when trying to assess whether or not a large public sector is promoting or inhibiting growth (Agell et al., 1999, p. 360). An international academic brave enough to enter the lions den - the Swedish debate concerning the size of the public sector and growth – is Steve Dowrick. In his article “Swedish Economic Performance and Swedish Economic Debate: A View from Outside” Dowrick wants to “…comment in particular on the fundamental question of whether the international evidence allows us to judge that Swedish growth has been below par”, but also to comment on the papers by Agell, Henrekson and Korpi (Dowrick, 1996, p. 1772). Dowrick identifies six methodological issues that need to be addressed: 1. What performance measure is relevant? 2. What deflators do we use? 3. Which derivative of the performance measure do we use? 4. Which time period is relevant? 5. What is the reference point for assessing under- or overachievement? 6. Finally, what exogenous factors are to 20 be taken into account? After having addressed these questions he concludes that “there is a stiff challenge for the proponents of the ‘lagging behind’ thesis. It is incumbent on them to explain why Swedish GDP performance was consistently reasonable over forty years and only shows a marked decline after 1990” (Dowrick, 1996, p.1778) and that there is little that suggests that high taxes and welfare spending are to blame for low growth. To summarize - Dowrick joins side with Agell et al in saying there is no correlation between the size of the public sector and growth. While much of the Swedish debate on social policy and the welfare state has concerned growth and the public sector – focus has been upon economic methodological considerations and growth theories – there has also been attempts to put focus on the, according to the international debate, more relevant issue of the political/ideological challenges the welfare state is facing . Ingalill Montanari addresses the issue of convergence in her article “Modernization, globalization and the welfare state: a comparative analysis of old and new convergence of social insurance since 1930”. Montanari studies (by examining four social insurance programmes: old age pensions; work accident insurance; sickness insurance and unemployment insurance) the tendency towards convergence of social insurance in 18 OECD countries between 1930 and 1990, a time period where most OECD countries developed from an agricultural stage to an industrial stage and finally a post-industrial stage. Her ambition is to “test the openeconomy hypothesis that smaller countries, being more exposed to international pressures than larger ones, could be expected to show higher degrees of social protection and also more convergence” (Montanari, 2001, p. 469). The convergence hypothesis is strongly rooted in the economic disciple, in accordance with the following argumentation “Behind this line of economic theorizing on market conforming criteria is the notion that, if left undisturbed, the market itself will select the most efficient institutional solutions among existing alternatives” (Montanari, 2001, p.471). Montanari analysis shows that, economics matter, but it does not determine institutional structuring “Few would deny that economic development forms a general base and sets the frame for socio-political change. At issue here is, however, if economic changes strongly restrict the range of potential alternatives for policy makers, as claimed by proponents of the industrialism … Our results indicate that such statement may have underestimated the availability of alternatives” (Montanari, 2001, p. 487). Walter Korpi and Joakim Palme argue in their article “New Politics and Class Politics in the Context of Austerity and Globalization: Welfare State Regress in 18 Countries, 1975-95” that in order to understand welfare state retrenchment, one needs to take into account the remaking of the postwar social contract of full employment, and also recognize the continued importance of partisan politics (Korpi &Palme, 2003, p. 425). “In the perspective outlined here the present retrenchment of the welfare state as well as its earlier expansion can be seen as outcomes of distributive conflict under changing relations of power among major interest groups” (Korpi&Palme, 2003, p. 441). Economics play their part but in a greater perspective, it is domestic politics (they argue class politics) that determine whether or not an expansion or retrenchment occurs “Among economic factors, 21 general government fiscal balances and levels of unemployment appear to be of some relevance, but not to the extent that they overshadow the role of partisan politics” (Korpi&Palme, 2003, p.441). However, while Palme, Korpi and Montanari’s opinions, seem to go rather hand in hand with the international welfare state debate – that is, arguing for that the real challenge to the welfare state is political/ideological, not economical – there are, as we have seen, quite a few Swedish scholars who still argue that the Swedish welfare state is unsustainable and need to be seriously reformed. I would argue that the debate, considering whether or not the size of the public sector is growth inhibiting, has been that prominent and intense, why I find it just to argue that the Swedish debate diverge from the international debate on this matter. My conclusion is that the Swedish debate continue to revolve around the internationally already settled issue of whether or not an extensive public sector is growth inhibiting or not. Substantially it is the same debate that has been on going for more than two decades – what variables are to be included in a correct analysis of growth and the public sector. On the one hand you have Lindbeck et al. who continue to argue that the, according to them, much too extensive Swedish public sector is growth inhibiting and as a result Sweden is economically lagging behind other European countries. On the other hand you have Korpi et al. who continue to argue that Swedish public sector is not too extensive and is not growth inhibiting, and Sweden is not lagging behind other developed countries – other countries have inevitably caught up, but this due to natural economic causes. I find it rather puzzling that this debate has been on going for so many years in Sweden, when most scholars outside Sweden, more or less unanimously side with Korpi et al. saying that there is no correlation between size of the public sector and growth. 22 4. Summary “Whenever you have an efficient government you have a dictatorship” Harry S Truman The international political economical research on the welfare state and the future of the European social models is extensive. However, in the international academic research there seem to be a consensus that the major threat to the welfare state is not economical but political. The shift in the state-market power relationship does have implications for the European social models and the different types of welfare state, but this challenge must not be exaggerated. Rather than forcing them to rebuild from their very foundation, the shift forces the social models to do some readjustments of the already existing systems. Some models are also more challenged than others; while the Anglo-Saxon and Scandinavian models seem to be in rather good shape (Sapir, 2005, p.10) the Continental models are facing difficulties. The Swedish debate continue to revolve around the internationally already settled issue of whether or not an extensive public sector is growth inhibiting. Substantially it is the same debate that has been on going for more than two decades – what variables are to be included in a correct analysis of growth and the public sector. On the one hand you have Lindbeck et al. who continue to argue that the, according to them, way too extensive Swedish public sector is growth inhibiting and as a result Sweden is economically lagging behind other European countries. On the other hand you have Korpi et al. who continue to argue that Swedish public sector is not too extensive and is not growth inhibiting, and Sweden is not lagging behind other developed countries. According to Korpi et al. other countries have inevitably caught up, but this due to natural economic causes, not Swedish under performance. 23 5. Explaining the Discrepancy “Cynics regarded everybody as equally corrupt... Idealists regarded everybody as equally corrupt, except themselves.” Robert Anton Wilson In this section I will primarily address the question why the international and Swedish debate diverge. First of all, however, I will briefly present my other conclusions. The welfare state is being challenged. However, this challenge is not an economic challenge but rather an ideological one. The importance of path dependency, the strong public support of re-distributive systems and, not to forget, the vagueness of the arguments suggesting that the welfare state is challenged, speaks in favor of a continuance of the welfare state. The Anglo-Saxon and the Nordic social models are considered efficient by most international scholars, while the Continental suffers from inefficiency and needs to be reformed. Furthermore, among international scholars, there also seem to be a consensus: whether the Continental social models choose to reform in the direction of the Nordic countries (more equity) or in the direction of Anglo-Saxon models (less equity) has more to do with politics than economics. Thus, both the Scandinavian and Anglo-Saxon models are sustainable, and their differences in design have more to do with ideological, rather than economic preferences. Andrew Martin concludes “Thus, in both the U.S. and Europe, my expectation is that what has been happening to welfare state is to be explained largely by the distinctive dynamics of politics within each country rather than the common pressures exerted by globalization” (Martin, 1996, p.56) The first point in this essay is that globalization poses no economical threat to the welfare state, but rather an ideological threat. In the international academic world there is more or less a consensus that the major threat the welfare state is facing is rather endogenous than exogenous – rather ideological than economical. The second point is that in Sweden the liberal economist’s ideological onslaught on the welfare state continues, and is being pursued under the banner “we must reform our system or face the economic consequences” – an argument that has little or no empirical back-up. The third point, and the focus point in this section, is that the reasons why the Swedish debate still primarily concerns the issue whether or not an extensive public sector is growth inhibiting is due to a number of reasons: 1) economists increased influence in the political debate – science policy interface 2) a window of opportunity 3) path-dependency 4) boundary ordering device 5) whom to blame? 1. Science-Policy Interface: Is it possible for science to be neutral? When scientists give policy advice, are they influenced by their own preferences or are they capable of sticking to rational arguments? “How do discursive agents interpret, 24 synthesize, and translate existing pockets of scientific knowledge into policy discourses? Which actors are privileged by the dominant discourses, and what kind of power is exercised when certain discourses gain prominence?”(Bäckman, 2000, p.23). A democratic problem might arise if important policy decisions are handed over to “neutral” scientists, who in the name of science offer recommendations that are highly influenced by that particular scientist political preferences rather than scientific assessment. First of all, what do we mean by Science-Policy interface? “The traditional interpretation of scientific advisory is to put science as an impartial contrast to the interest oriented politics. By its impartiality and neutrality science is granted status and authority as advisory body, while politicians can legitimize policy decisions by referring to scientific expertise” (Bäckman, 2000, p.25, Skodvin, 1999, p.4). The idea is that this will regulate itself: scientists loose their noble status if they start interfering in something as trivial as everyday politics; at the same time if political decisions become too technical and without ideological foundation politicians loose legitimacy. The constructivist discursive interpretation is instead that science-policy interplay is a hybrid activity, in which research and policy agendas are mutually constructed. “The assumpition of a clear-cut boundary between core science, regulatory science and policy implicit in the concept of transscience is questioned. In contrast, the science and policy spheres are conceived as mutually constructed” (Bäckman, 2000, p.61). I will be using a hybrid science approach in my analysis of the science-policy interface in the Swedish academic debate on the welfare state. The reason of introducing this Science-policy interface theory in my conclusion is that I find it to be quite evident that the economists in the Swedish debate on the welfare state are not discussing science, but rather policy – or more accurately, ideology. Andrew Martin might have a point when he rhetorically contemplates the possibility that “It may be that the changing international environment does not necessarily impose all the imperatives invoked as reasons why the welfare state has to be rolled back or changed in various ways to meet new economic imperatives, typically summed up as competitiveness, and that such claims about globalization and competitiveness are simply new ideological smokescreens behind which old inegalitarian goals are being pursued” (Martin, 1996, p.2). Swedish economists have traditionally had a strong influence on the policy area, dating back to the first generation economists such as Knut Wikcksell, Gustav Cassel and Eli Heckscher. In recent years, however, the neo-classical paradigm has been dominating the economic field of research This neo-classical dominance has availed many economists to make more or less coherent and congruent policy statements, due to their common theoretical foundation, and they have not been the subject of much criticism from colleagues (Agell, Korpi et al. being important exceptions) (Jonung, 1996, p.9). Taking into consideration that the neo-classical theory strongly favors market-solution and disfavors centrally planned solutions, it is perhaps not very surprising to find that many Swedish economists, are inclined to prefer social models which have the market as foundational pillar and not the state. At the same time it is quite evident that many Swedish economists, due to their theoretical background – neo-classicism, have a distaste for centrally planned solutions and social models which have the state as foundational pillar. 25 2. Window-of-opportunity: Another explanation I would like to present is the idea of a window-of-opportunity. The economic crisis in Sweden in the early 1990’s had a major impact on the domestic politics and the public was seriously questioning if there perhaps was something fundamentally wrong with the way the Swedish society was being managed. Sweden had not experienced as high rates of unemployment since before WWII, which was a massive blow to the existing system and politics were in disarray. Liberals probably saw their chance to push in a market-based direction, as it is generally recognized that major crisis offers opportunity for radical change. By blaming abstract exogenous forces such as “globalization”, liberals effectively diverged attention from ideology and domestic politics, arguing in accordance with “change is being forced upon us by external forces – there is nothing we can do but adapt”. A very effective way of taking advantage of a crisis situation. Liberal economists could persuasively argue that the Sweden was being misgoverned and needed to adjust to the new terms of world capitalism. Not merely make some fine tunings of an essentially effective social model (the international debate’s conclusion), but to radically restructure the social model in a more market oriented direction. Rather than explaining that a shift from Keynesianism to monetarism (which most probably was inevitable) would be dramatic at an initial stage one found it far too tempting not to take advantage of this opportunity to promote one’s political agenda. There are also of course more subtle ways of influencing politics: By arguing that the Swedish model is not an option for the reforming countries in Continental Europe, Swedish liberal economists (Lindbeck et al.) are in fact saying that the only plausible solution for these countries is a market oriented solution – an AngloSaxon social model. Essentially this is a way for these economists to influence the domestic Swedish politics by influencing the international economical debate. If Continental European countries, which constitute 70% of EU’s total GDP, deem the Swedish model inefficient and opt for an Anglo-Saxon model, chances are that a fulfillment of the ‘Neo-liberal’ project is not far away. With an almost complete dominance of the Anglo-Saxon model in Europe, with Scandinavia as the almost only exception, one can expect a certain amount of influence to be exercised in order to make the remaining non-market models converge into this new hegemonic neo-liberal pan-European social model. “Convergence thinking has been and remains and important strand of thought in the social sciences. Among economists, hypotheses on converging trends of economic development between countries have a long standing and are still alive” (Montanari, 2001, p.470) 3. Path-dependency: Why this debate now? According to Andrew Martin’s argumentation, that when the US chose to abandon Bretton-Woods and the Keynesian objective of full employment and replaced it with the monetarian principle the rest of the capitalist countries could do nothing but follow, this shift did not happen until 1991 in Sweden. Taking this into consideration it is perhaps not that surprising that the debate is still ongoing in Sweden. Perhaps it is even more understandable if one take into account, what was stated in the introduction, that Sweden has been the subject of close scrutiny “mixed with a dose of schadenfreude, perhaps to compensate for previous envy at, or disbelief of, the social and economic success of her welfare model” (Kuhnle, 2001, p.103). Swedish 26 neo-classical economist’s are perhaps eager to show their international colleagues that they in fact are not that “naive”, and that they in fact have been well aware of the, from their point of view, chronic disease the Swedish model has been suffering from. But while the international academic research has deemed the Swedish model by and large efficient but in need of some minor reforms, the reformist liberal economists in Sweden are more extreme and are suggesting a radical restructuring of the Swedish model. The occurrence of a debate on how society shall be structured following the transformation from Keynesianism to monetarism is what one can expect and a healthy phenomenon in a modern democracy. But perhaps the Swedish debate has tendencies of panic – the debate has grown out of proportion due to Sweden’s special conditions. While this move from one economic regime to another quite naturally initiates a debate of what reforms are needed to adjust to new economic and political conditions, Swedish unique conditions - a long era of successfully managing society, political stability and a national sense of pride over a high living-standard - perhaps facilitated a more intense and heated debate than what would have been the case elsewhere. Sweden’s relatively stable political and economic system was not accustomed to these kinds of dramatic changes, why the economic regime shift accentuated an inner need of contemplative debate on the future of the Swedish welfare model. 4. Boundary ordering devices: A less conspiracy theory influenced explanation would be one that focused on the primal interest of self-interest. One explanation could be academic jealousy: “When academics give policy advice, it seems reasonable that they provide a balanced assessment of the research literature. The stunningly precise point prediction of Henrekson et al. – which was given much attention in the media – was the motivation for our recent review in this Journal” (Agell et al. 1999, p. 360). Another simple explanation to why the Swedish debate continues to revolve around the internationally already settled issue of whether or not a extensive public sector is growth inhibiting, would be because the Swedish economics involved in this debate want it to continue. Katarina Bäckman presents the idea of Boundary ordering devices, according to which it lies in academics interest to keep a debate alive. “By representing uncertainty in specific manners, both the cultural authority of science and the credibility of scientists among their peers can be sustained. The rationalist view that a reduction of scientific uncertainties is a precondition for successful policy is thereby questioned” (Bäckman, 2000, p, 62). By keeping the debate alive, especially a debate that attracts a lot of attention in media and elsewhere, one also guarantees a continued prominence of one’s area of research. The debate on growth and the public sector has been on-going for more than two decades, but essentially it is the same methodological considerations that are being discussed – what variables should one include in an analysis in order to attain a correct result – why one could suspect that there are other reasons than academic why it is not settled. When taking a look from the outside it appears a bit surprising that the debate is still stuck in it trenches, and that no real advancement is being made. One could always argue that involved parties recognize this as an essentially ideological debate, but due to their economic profession they prefer to argue in an economic jargon. But an explanation closer at hand would be that economists want it to be an economical and not political debate, 27 why the diagnosis would be myopia. However, even if this was the case, why not try to broaden the discussion and rally more support to one’s side? Perhaps the answer is that economists secretly dream of a scenario where they enter the political stage - Deus ex machina – solving the eternal ideological conflict with an economic formula, which proclaims one political side winner due to economic superiority. Another explanation in the name of self-interest could be: By saying that there is no correlation between the public sector and growth one disqualifies economists from much of the debate on the future of Swedish welfare state. If one agrees with Martins and Streeck’s argumentation that there has been an inevitable shift from Keynesianism to monetarism, one also suggests that the space for independent economic policy is very limited. In accordance with Martin’s and Streck’s argumentation there was not much the European countries could do but adapt to the new economic system that the US unilaterally had implemented. What is perhaps even more devastating, from an economist’s point of view, is that US’s decision to shift from Keynesianism (and abandon the Bretton-Woods system) to monetarism was essentially a political decision, not an economical decision. The US was essentially saying that they prefer low inflation rather than full employment. This is an ideological preference, not the result of economic determinism. For economists this notion, that politics influenced and provided the very foundation for economics and not vice versa, must be provocative. Even more so, for Swedish reformist economists it must be very hard to accept that the opportunity for independent economic policy for a small open economy, such as Sweden, is very limited. 5. Whom to blame? : Finally I would argue that the issue of whom to blame for the economic crisis in the beginning of the 1990’s is an important explanatory factor. No economic prognosis predicted the coming crisis (perhaps a comparison with political scientists inability to predict the demise of the Soviet Union is at place?) and a serious blow was dealt to the disciplines credibility (Jakobsson, 1996, p.168). Taking this into consideration one easily understands the liberal economists’ line of argumentation – do not blame economics, blame politics. By claiming that there is something fundamentally wrong with the Swedish social model, one can also claim freedom of responsibility. Offered the right kind of circumstances (the right kind of market oriented model) they would have been able to make the right prognosis that in turn would have enabled the right measures to be taken, and thus perhaps the crisis would have been mitigated. However, in accordance with their line of argumentation, due to these fundamental flaws in the Swedish model they were unable to deliver the right kind of prognosis and hence the crisis took on more dramatic proportions. My conclusion is that the shift in the state-market relationship poses no economic threat to the welfare state. In the international academic debate there is more or less a consensus that the market’s increased influence may force the different European social models to make some adjustments, but not any radical restructuring. Some social models are also more threatened than others; the Scandinavian and the Anglo-Saxon models are in good shape while the Continental models are in need of more thorough reform. In the international debate there is also more or less a consensus that the real challenge to the welfare state is the liberal ideological onslaught in domestic politics. The Swedish academic debate, however, 28 continue to revolve around whether or not an extensive public sector is growth inhibiting. My major point in this thesis is that the Swedish academic debate needs to be understood in an ideological context, not an economical context. I present a number of reasons why Swedish economists are inclined to engage in the political debate: economists increased influence in the political debate; a window of opportunity; path-dependency; boundary ordering device and also the question of responsibility for the 1991 crisis. Swedish economists are not without a political agenda and one shall take Atkinson’s warning seriously “The future of the welfare state is a highly political issue … Calls by economists for rolling back the welfare state are themselves part of the political process; we have not just endogenous politicians but also endogenous economists, whose behaviour has to be explained” (Atkinson, 1999, p. 187). 29 6. Bibliography Agell Jonas, Lindh Thomas, Ohlsson Henry. 1994. Tillväxt och offentlig sector. Ekonmisk Debatt 22 Agell Jonas, Lindh Thomas, Ohlsson Henry. Growth and the Public Sector: A Critical Review Essay. 1995. European Journal of Political Economy. Elsevier Agell Jonas, Lindh Thomas, Ohlsson Henry. Growth and the Public Sector: A Reply. 1999. European Journal of Political Economy. Elsevier Atkinson Anthony Barnes, 1999. The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press Beveridge, William, 1944. Full Employment in a Free Society. New York: W.W Norton Bäckstrand, Karin, 2000. What can Nature Withstand? Science, Politics and Discourses in Transboundary Air Pollution Diplomacy. Lund: Lund Political Studies Calmfors Lars et. al., 1995. Ekonomisk Politik – en vänbok till Assar Lindbeck. Stockholm: SNS Förlag Dowrick, Steve. Swedish Economic Performance and Swedish Economic Debate: A View from Outside. 1996. The Economic Journal Oxford: Royal Economic Society Eckstein Harry, 1975. Case Study and Theory in Political Science. Reading: Addison Wesley Eichengreen, Barry “The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff”ed. Frieden&Lake, 2000. International Political Economy. London: Routledge Esping-Andersen, Gösta, 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge: MA: Polity Press Esping-Andersen, Gösta 1996. Welfare States in Transition: National Adaptation in Global Economies. London: SAGE Publications Esping-Andersen, Gösta, 2002. Why we need a New Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press Frieden, Jeffrey A.&Lake David A., 2000. International Political Economy: Perspectives on Global Power and Wealth. London: Routledge Fölster Stefan, Henrekson Magnus. Growth and the Public Sector: a Critique of the Critics. 1999. European Journal of Political Economy. Elsevier Gustavsson, Jakob, 1998. The Politics of Foreign Policy Change: Explaining the Reorientation on EC Membership. Lund: Lund University Press Gustavsson Sverker, Oxelheim Lars, Wahl Nils, 2004. EU, skatterna och tillväxten. Tallin: Santérus Hansson P., Henreksson M., 1994. A new Framework for Testing the Effect of Government Spending on Growth and Productivity. Public Choice Henrekson, Magnus & Jakobsson, Ulf, 2000. Where Schumpeter was Nearly Right – the Swedish Model and Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy Henrekson, Magnus, 2001. Ägarpolitik och Ägarstrukturer I Efterkrigstidens Sverige. Stockholm: Working Paper, Stockholm School of Economics Henrekson, Magnus & Jakobsson, Ulf, 2001. The Transformation of Ownership 30 Policy and Structure in Sweden: Convergence towards the Anglo-Saxon Model? Jacobs, Jane, 1992. Systems of Survival. New York: Random House Jakobsson Ulf “Ekonomerna, prognoserna och den svenska modellen” ed. Jonung, Lars. Ekonomerna i debatten – gör de någon nytta?, 1996. Otta: Ekerlids Förlag Jonung, Lars, 1996. Ekonomerna i debatten – gör de någon nytta?. Otta: Ekerlids Förlag Keohane, Robert O.&Nye, Joseph S., 2001. Power and Interdependence. New York: Longman Korpi, Walter, 1985. Välfärdspolitik och ekonomisk tillväxt: En jämförande studie av 18 OECD-länder. Ekonomisk debatt. Korpi, Walter, 1995. Halkar Sverige efter – Sveriges ekonomiska tillväxt 18201990 i jämförande belysning. Stockholm: Carlssons Bokförlag Korpi Walter, Palmer Joakim, 2003. New Politics and Class Politics in the Context of Austerity and Globalization: Welfare State Regress in 18 Countries, 1975-95. American Political Science Review Konsten att Tala&Skriva, 1999. Lund: Department of Political Science Krasner, Stephan D. “State, Power and the Structure of International Trade” ed Frieden&Lake, 2000. International Political Economy. London: Routledge Krugman, Paul, R.&Obstfeld, Maurice, 2003. International Economics: Theory and Policy. Boston: Addison&Wesley Kuhnle, Stein “the Nordic Welfare State in a European Context: Dealing with New Economic and Ideological Challenges in 1990’s”. ed. Leibfried, Stephan. Welfare State Futures. 2001. Cambridge University Press. Leibfried, Stephan, 2001. Welfare State Futures. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Lindbeck, Assar, 1985. Välfärd, skatter och tillväxt – replik till Korpi: Välfärdspolitik och ekonomisk tillväxt. Ekonomisk debatt. Lindbeck Assar, Molander Per, Persson Torsten, Peterson Olof, Sandmo Agnar, Swedenborg Birgitta and Thygesen Niels, 1993. Options for Economic and Political Reform in Sweden. Stockholm: Institute for International Economic Studies Lindbeck Assar, Molander Per, Persson Torsten, Peterson Olof, Sandmo Agnar, Swedenborg Birgitta and Thygesen Niels, 1993. Nya villkor för ekonomi och politik SOU 1993:16. Stockholm: Norstedts Tryckeri AB Martin, Andrew, 1996. What Does Globalization Have to Do with the Erosion of Welfare States? Sorting Out the Issues. Oslo: ARENA Marsh, David&Stoker, Gerry, 2002. Theory and Methods in Political Science. New York: Palgrave&Macmillan North Douglas C. “Institutions and Economic Growth: A Historical Introduction” ed Frieden&Lake, 2000. International Political Economy. London: Routledge Palme Joakim “EU, skatterna och socialförsäkringarna” ed. Gustavsson Sverker, Oxelheim Lars and Wahl Nils, 2004. EU, skatterna och välfärden. Tallin: Santérus Förlag Review of International Political Economy (RIPE), 1994, vol.1, no. 1 and 2, London: Routledge Rosencrance Richard, 1996. The Rise of the Virtual State. Foreign Affairs July/August Rothstein, Bo, 1999. Korporatismens fall och den svenska modellens kris. Stockholm: SNS Förlag Sapir André, 2005. Globalisation and the Reform of European Social Models. 31 Bruegel: ECOFIN Informal Meeting in Manchester 2005. Scharpf, Fritz, 2002. The European Social Model: Coping with the Challenges of Diversity. Journal of Common Market Studies. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers Smith Michael, 2005. “The European Union and International Political Economy”. Ed. Jörgensen Knud Erik, Pollack Mark, Rosamond Ben. Handbook of European Union Politics. Stopford, John&Strange Susan, 1991. Rival States, Rival Firms: Competition for world market shares. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Strange, Susan, 1992. “States, Firms and Diplomacy”. Frieden&Lake: International Political Economy. London: Routledge Streeck, Wolfgang. Social Institutions and Economic Performance: Studies of Industrial Relations in Advanced Capitalist Economies. 1992. London: SAGE Publications Stubbs, Richard&Underhill Geoffrey R.D, 2000. Political Economy and the Changing Global Order. Oxford: Oxford University Press Swedenborg Birgitta, Tson Söderström Hans, 1999. Creating an Environment for Growth. Stockholm: SNS Förlag Thörn Philip, 2004. The Art of Attracting Foreign Direct Investment – A Critical Assessment of State-Firm Diplomacy and the Practices of the Invest in Sweden Agency. Lund: Department of Political Science. 32