
1 The theory of dense linear order without end
... We have the following theorem about dense linear order without endpoints: Theorem 1. The theory of dense linear order without endpoints is ℵ0 categorical. Theorem 1 implies the following corollary: Corollary 1. (Q, <) is the only countable model up to isomorphism. Proof of theorem 1. Let (M,
... We have the following theorem about dense linear order without endpoints: Theorem 1. The theory of dense linear order without endpoints is ℵ0 categorical. Theorem 1 implies the following corollary: Corollary 1. (Q, <) is the only countable model up to isomorphism. Proof of theorem 1. Let (M,
Midterm #3: practice
... (a) Modulo 323, what do we learn from Euler's theorem? (b) Using the Chinese remainder theorem, show that x144 1 (mod 323) for all x coprime to 323. (c) Compare the two results! Bonus: Can you come up with a strengthening of Euler's theorem? ...
... (a) Modulo 323, what do we learn from Euler's theorem? (b) Using the Chinese remainder theorem, show that x144 1 (mod 323) for all x coprime to 323. (c) Compare the two results! Bonus: Can you come up with a strengthening of Euler's theorem? ...
s01.pdf
... Numerical analysis is the study of methods used to generate approximate solutions to mathematical problems. Many problems in engineering and science are most suitably formulated in mathematical terms. Only the simplest problems can be solved using analytical techniques and approximate solutions must ...
... Numerical analysis is the study of methods used to generate approximate solutions to mathematical problems. Many problems in engineering and science are most suitably formulated in mathematical terms. Only the simplest problems can be solved using analytical techniques and approximate solutions must ...
Idiosynchromatic Poetry
... Ramsey theory is generally concerned with problems of finding structures with some kind of homogeneity in superstructures. Often a structure contains an homogeneous substructure of a certain sort if it is itself large enough. In some contexts the notion of size can not only be interpreted as cardina ...
... Ramsey theory is generally concerned with problems of finding structures with some kind of homogeneity in superstructures. Often a structure contains an homogeneous substructure of a certain sort if it is itself large enough. In some contexts the notion of size can not only be interpreted as cardina ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.