
Contra-e-Continuous Functions 1 Introduction
... Proof. If possible, suppose that Y is a discrete space. Let P be a proper nonempty open and closed subset of Y . Then f −1 (P ) is a proper nonempty e-open and e-closed subset of X, which contradicts to the fact that X is econnected. Hence the theorem follows. Theorem 3.26 If f : X → Y is contra-e-c ...
... Proof. If possible, suppose that Y is a discrete space. Let P be a proper nonempty open and closed subset of Y . Then f −1 (P ) is a proper nonempty e-open and e-closed subset of X, which contradicts to the fact that X is econnected. Hence the theorem follows. Theorem 3.26 If f : X → Y is contra-e-c ...
BOUNDED GENERATION OF S-ARITHMETIC SUBGROUPS OF
... Unfortunately, this argument does not immediately extend to the situation where the Witt index is one due to some technical problems, but mainly because of the fact that the resulting special orthogonal group in dimension n = 5 is no longer split and bounded generation of its S-arithmetic subgroups ...
... Unfortunately, this argument does not immediately extend to the situation where the Witt index is one due to some technical problems, but mainly because of the fact that the resulting special orthogonal group in dimension n = 5 is no longer split and bounded generation of its S-arithmetic subgroups ...
MILNOR`S CONSTRUCTION OF EXOTIC 7
... of the vector field around a critical point is equal to the dimensionality of the cell added at that point under a height function. Although we have only shown this for the example of the torus, it is true in general. 4.2. Reeb’s Theorem. Now we will prove Reeb’s Theorem, which is the main tool in t ...
... of the vector field around a critical point is equal to the dimensionality of the cell added at that point under a height function. Although we have only shown this for the example of the torus, it is true in general. 4.2. Reeb’s Theorem. Now we will prove Reeb’s Theorem, which is the main tool in t ...
Solved and unsolved problems in elementary number theory
... Did Pythagoras invent arithmetic dynamics? Consider the map s : N ∪ {0} → N ∪ {0}, extended to have s(0) = 0. A perfect number is nothing other than a positive integer fixed point. We say n is amicable if n generates a two-cycle: in other words, s(n) 6= n and s(s(n)) = n. For example, s(220) = 284, ...
... Did Pythagoras invent arithmetic dynamics? Consider the map s : N ∪ {0} → N ∪ {0}, extended to have s(0) = 0. A perfect number is nothing other than a positive integer fixed point. We say n is amicable if n generates a two-cycle: in other words, s(n) 6= n and s(s(n)) = n. For example, s(220) = 284, ...
decomposition of - continuity in ideal topological
... Theorem 2.9: A function f: (X, τ, I) → (Y, σ) is Iω-continuous if and only if f -1(V) is Iω-open in (X, τ, I) for every open set V in (Y, σ). Proof: Let V be an open set in (Y, σ) and f : (X, τ, I) → (Y, σ) be Iω-continuous. Then Vc is closed in (Y, σ) and f -1(Vc) is Iω-closed in (X, τ, I). But f - ...
... Theorem 2.9: A function f: (X, τ, I) → (Y, σ) is Iω-continuous if and only if f -1(V) is Iω-open in (X, τ, I) for every open set V in (Y, σ). Proof: Let V be an open set in (Y, σ) and f : (X, τ, I) → (Y, σ) be Iω-continuous. Then Vc is closed in (Y, σ) and f -1(Vc) is Iω-closed in (X, τ, I). But f - ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.