Download The Non-Existent Hand Joseph Stiglitz Keynes: The Return of the

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Recession wikipedia , lookup

Systemic risk wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Economic bubble wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Nouriel Roubini wikipedia , lookup

Global financial system wikipedia , lookup

Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup

Early 1980s recession wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Globalization and Its Discontents wikipedia , lookup

Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup

Keynesian Revolution wikipedia , lookup

Keynesian economics wikipedia , lookup

Post-war displacement of Keynesianism wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
The Non-Existent Hand
Joseph Stiglitz
Keynes: The Return of the Master by Robert Skidelsky Allen Lane, 213 pp, £20.00,
September 2009, ISBN 978 1 84614 258 1
It has become a commonplace to say, in the aftermath of the Great Recession, that ‘we
are all Keynesians now.’ If this is so, then Keynes’s great biographer, Robert Skidelsky,
should have much to say about the recession, its causes and the appropriate cures. And
so indeed he does. I share with Skidelsky the view that, while most of the blame for the
crisis should reside with those in the financial markets, who did such a poor job both in
allocating capital and in managing risk (their key responsibilities), a considerable
portion of it lies with the economics profession. The notion economists pushed – that
markets are efficient and self-adjusting – gave comfort to regulators like Alan
Greenspan, who didn’t believe in regulation in the first place. They provided support for
the movement which stripped away the regulations that had provided the basis of
financial stability in the decades after the Great Depression; and they gave justification
to those, like Larry Summers and Robert Rubin, Treasury secretaries under Clinton,
who opposed doing anything about derivatives, even after the dangers had been exposed
in the Long-Term Capital Management crisis of 1998.
We should be clear about this: economic theory never provided much support for these
free-market views. Theories of imperfect and asymmetric information in markets had
undermined every one of the ‘efficient market’ doctrines, even before they became
fashionable in the Reagan-Thatcher era. Bruce Greenwald and I had explained that
Adam Smith’s hand was not in fact invisible: it wasn’t there. Sanford Grossman and I
had explained that if markets were as efficient in transmitting information as the free
marketeers claimed, no one would have any incentive to gather and process it. Free
marketeers, and the special interests that benefited from their doctrines, paid little
attention to these inconvenient truths.
While economists who criticised the ruling free-market paradigm often still employed,
as a matter of convenience, simple models of ‘rational’ expectations (that is, they
assumed that individuals ‘rationally’ used all the information that they had available),
they departed from the ruling paradigm in assuming that different individuals had
access to different information. Their aim was to show that the standard paradigm was
no longer valid when there was even this seemingly small and obviously reasonable
change in assumptions. They showed, for instance, that unfettered markets were not
efficient, and could be characterised by persistent unemployment. But if the economy
behaves so poorly when such small realistic changes are made to the paradigm, what
could we expect if we added further elements of realism, such as bouts of irrational
optimism and pessimism, the ‘panics and manias’ that break out repeatedly in markets
all over the world?
Of course, one didn’t have to rely on theoretical niceties in order to criticise the faith in
unfettered markets. Economic and financial crises have been a regular feature of
capitalist economies; only the period of strong financial regulation after the Second
World War was almost totally free of them. As financial market regulations were
stripped away, crises became more common: we have had more than 100 in the last 30
years.
The present crisis should lay to rest any belief in ‘rational’ markets. The irrationalities
evident in mortgage markets, in securitisation, in derivatives and in banking are mindboggling; our supposed financial wizards have exhibited behaviour which, to use the
vernacular, seemed ‘stupid’ even at the time. If we are to design policies to prevent
crises or to deal with them when they occur, it is essential to understand the critical
flaws in the standard paradigm. It is here that Skidelsky goes astray.
Skidelsky makes much of the distinction between risk and uncertainty. Risk refers to
situations in which we have good statistical data so that we can talk meaningfully about
the probability that a particular event will happen, like the probability of a 70-year-old
man dying within the next year. Uncertainty refers to situations in which we have no
statistical basis to go on. Clearly, the investment banks and rating agencies relied too
heavily on flawed statistical models, as did the regulators. Those models gave them
confidence that the risk of a serious problem was negligible, something that might
happen once in a million years.
But much of the behaviour that led to the crisis (the irrational and sometimes predatory
lending, the excesses of leverage and other forms of risk-taking) did not depend on this
distinction. More important, for instance, were the incentives, which encouraged banks
to take on too much risk, and induced them not to think too deeply about the flaws in
their statistical models. Flawed incentives, inadequate regulation and a lack of scruples
also help explain the abusive lending practices that played so large a role in the crisis.
In accounting for the crisis, we have to explain both the bubble and why, after the
bubble burst, the economy went into a deep recession. We also have to explain the
massively inefficent capital allocation, the high level of volatility and the persistence of
unemployment. The distinction between risk and uncertainty, unfortunately, gives us
little insight into the failures in the labour market: why the usual laws of supply and
demand, which should result in full employment, have failed to work.
It should be clear that the failure of financial markets is at the centre of this crisis, but as
Skidelsky points out, Keynes himself had little to say about financial markets and their
management and regulation. One of the criticisms of the General Theory is its simplistic
treatment of capital markets (some progress has been made in rectifying this over the
last 75 years). Accordingly, it might be thought that Keynes’s views were of only
limited relevance in this crisis, beyond his general scepticism as to the ability of markets
to correct themselves. That view of Keynes is wrong, however, because this is an
economic as well as a financial crisis: there is an insufficiency of global aggregate
demand. Explaining why this is so is more difficult than Skidelsky seems to suggest. It
is not just a matter of the intrinsic uncertainty of the future. Standard economic theory –
the theory of demand and supply that is taught in classrooms around the world – says
that if prices (including the price of labour, or wages, and the price of capital, or the
interest rate) are fully flexible and markets function as they should, then even with such
uncertainty there should be full employment. Wages or interest rates might not be the
same as they would be in the absence of uncertainty, but markets would still ensure full
employment.
Markets in capitalist systems don’t work that way, though, and the question is why?
Skidelsky does not offer much insight here, not even as to what Keynes might have said
about it. Those who today see themselves as following in the tradition of Keynes –
especially in subscribing to his view that government action is needed to help maintain
full employment – are referred to as new Keynesians. One strand of (new)
Keynesianism argues that unemployment persists because wages and prices are rigid. It
isn’t hard to understand why many economists were attracted to this theory. In the
standard demand and supply model, if there is an excess supply of labour (i.e.
unemployment), the reason must be that (real) wages are too high. This theory may not
only misinterpret Keynes, but may also be potentially dangerous, because of its obvious
policy implications. If unemployment is caused by real wages being too high, the
obvious remedy is to lower wages. Hence the standard call of conservative economists
for more ‘labour market flexibility’, ensuring that the wages of workers – which have
stagnated in the US for a quarter of a century – will drop even further. But traditional
Keynesian economics argues that what matters is aggregate demand, and that lower
wages reduce aggregate demand. The current crisis demonstrates what can happen:
countries with stronger systems of social protection and less labour market flexibility
have, in many ways, fared better.
Skidelsky’s discussion of the various explanations that economists have come up with,
both for wage and price rigidity and as to why the economy does not quickly adjust to
‘equilibrium’, is too unquestioning, too undiscriminating. There is, for instance, a silly
theory that says prices are rigid because of the costs of changing price lists (the cost of
printing new menus in restaurants would be an example); but these costs pale in
comparison to those of hiring and firing workers or increasing or decreasing production.
Other theories that have become more widely accepted since Keynes’s death are given
scant attention by Skidelsky. Efficiency wage theory, which argues that wages affect
productivity, so that it doesn’t benefit firms to pay low wages, isn’t even mentioned.
There is an alternative view (also labelled new Keynesian) as to why an economy can
be trapped for so long in a state of under-utilising resources: the debt-deflation theory
originally formulated by an American contemporary of Keynes, Irving Fisher, and more
recently developed by Greenwald and me. It perceives the key market failures to be not
just in the labour market, but also in financial markets. Because contracts are not
appropriately indexed (that is to say, payments aren’t adjusted to changing economic
conditions), alterations in economic circumstances can cause a rash of bankruptcies, and
fear of bankruptcy contributes to the freezing of credit markets. The resulting economic
disruption affects both aggregate demand and aggregate supply, and it’s not easy to
recover from this – one reason that my prognosis for the economy in the short term is so
gloomy.
Keynes focused, as I’ve said, on the problems posed by an insufficiency of aggregate
demand: what happens when people want to buy less than the economy is able to
produce. Even 75 years ago, he saw the issue from a global perspective. He was
concerned, for instance, about the impact of the surplus countries – those that produced
more than they consumed – on global demand. Today, we talk about global imbalances.
The soaring imbalances of the last ten years are partly due to what happened during the
East Asia crisis of 1997-98. Countries without adequate reserves lost their economic
sovereignty as the US Treasury and IMF came to their ‘rescue’ (or, more accurately,
came to the rescue of their own banks – the same banks that have caused such
devastation to our own economies). They foisted contractionary monetary and fiscal
policies – higher interest rates, cutbacks on expenditure – on these countries, the
opposite of the policies the US adopted in the current crisis. Not surprisingly, these
contractionary policies led to recessions and depressions. To reduce the likelihood of
having to turn again to the IMF and the West, developing countries around the world
accumulated massive reserves. But while these precautionary savings may have
provided them with some security, money saved is money not spent: it contributed to a
lack of aggregate demand. Other factors also contributed to the build-up of reserves.
Low exchange rates can help promote exports. Oil exporters knew there was a
significant risk that prices would not remain at the high level they had reached, and the
prudent choice was to save a great deal of the money that they were earning. Finally,
aggregate demand was almost certainly lowered by the huge increase in inequality,
which in effect redistributed money from those who would spend it to those who didn’t,
or at least didn’t spend as much.
These factors help explain high savings ratios. But the problem of insufficiency of
demand is really a matter of the balance between savings and investment. The problem
is sometimes described as a ‘savings glut’, but could equally well be described as an
‘investment dearth’. Why did it seem that even with record low interest rates, the only
investment that could be generated was in housing for poor Americans for which they
couldn’t afford to pay? A long tradition in economics, of which Keynes was a part, has
focused on the diminution of investment opportunities. The path-breaking work of
Schumpeter, another of Keynes’s contemporaries, emphasised the role of innovation.
The world is currently faced with serious challenges that also present investment
opportunities: retrofitting the world economy to face the challenges of global warming,
or making the investment necessary to reduce global poverty. There is no shortage of
opportunities for investments with high social returns. Here, there have been both
market failures and policy failures: a failure, for instance, of governments to make
carbon emissions sufficiently costly for there to be an incentive to invest in reducing
them, or of financial markets to devise better instruments for transferring risk from
those in less developed countries to those in more advanced ones, who can better absorb
it.
The central policy message of Keynesian economics is that in a deep recession,
monetary policy is likely to be ineffective, and fiscal stimulation is required. This, the
argument goes, is because monetary authorities find it increasingly difficult to lower
real interest rates (even if nominal interest rates go to zero, deflation can mean that there
is a positive real interest rate); and even at low interest rates, investment may not be
much stimulated. It’s like pushing on a string. When interest rates were lowered after
the technology bubble burst, the effect was mostly foolish real estate investment. But,
since Keynes, our understanding of the limitations of monetary policy has increased.
For instance, even if central banks succeed in getting treasury bill rates close to zero, the
interest rates at which banks lend can remain high; and it is now recognised that
availability of credit matters as much as interest rates, especially for small and mediumsized businesses that depend on the ability and willingness of banks to lend. This is one
of the reasons there is so much focus on the recapitalisation of banks, and one of the
reasons the Bush/Obama policy of giving money to the banks but allowing them to pay
it out in dividends and bonuses did not rekindle lending as promised. Today, few look to
monetary policy to reignite the economy. The achievement of our central banks has
been a more modest one: having brought the global economy to the brink of disaster,
they succeeded in avoiding a complete collapse by throwing enough money at the
financial system.
Fiscal policy worked, not in preventing a Great Recession, but in preventing the Great
Recession from turning into another Great Depression. But now the very actions that
saved the economies of the world have presented a new problem for fiscal policy, as
questions are being raised about governments’ ability to finance their deficits. There are
speculative attacks against the weakest countries, which find themselves caught
between a rock and a hard place. They worry that deficits will lead to higher interest
rates, not because (as is usually argued) public spending will crowd out private
spending, but because of growing ‘risk premiums’. But the effect is much the same:
more government spending will force cutbacks in private spending, with the obvious
adverse effects on the economy. The financial markets that caused the crisis – which in
turn caused the deficits – went silent as money was being spent on the bail-out; but now
they are telling governments they have to cut public spending. Wages are to be cut, even
if bank bonuses are to be kept. The Hooverites – the advocates of the pre-Keynesian
policies according to which downturns were met with austerity – are having their
revenge. In many quarters, the Keynesians, having enjoyed their moment of glory just a
year ago, seem to be in retreat.
If markets were rational, there would be an easy policy response. Spending on
investments that yielded even moderate real returns (say, of 5 to 6 per cent) would lower
long-term debt levels; such spending increases output in the short run, thus garnering
more tax revenue, and the future returns generate still more tax revenue. If markets
could be convinced, for example, that European governments can and will meet their
debt obligations, interest rates would fall, and even the countries with the highest levels
of debt would find it easy to meet their obligations. But markets are not necessarily
rational, and even when they are, they are not always well intentioned. The objective of
a speculative attack is to generate profits for the speculators, regardless of the cost to the
rest of society. They can make money by inducing panic and then feel pleased with their
‘insight’: their concerns were justified, but only because of the responses to which their
actions gave rise.
Since the time of Keynes, the ability of markets to mount such speculative attacks has
increased enormously. But governments are not powerless to tame them, and in some
cases can counter-attack, as Hong Kong did in foiling Wall Street’s famous ‘Hong
Kong double play’, when speculators simultaneously sold short both the currency and
the stock market. The speculators knew that governments traditionally respond to a
currency attack by raising interest rates, which lowers stock prices. If Hong Kong failed
to raise interest rates, they would make money by shorting the currency. If Hong Kong
did raise them to save its currency, the speculators would make money by shorting the
stock market. Hong Kong outsmarted them by simultaneously raising interest rates and
supporting the stock market by buying shares. Taxes on short-term capital gains,
regulations on the ever more powerful speculative instruments (like credit default
swaps), and – especially for developing countries – the imposition of barriers on the
uncontrolled movement of short-term capital across borders, can reduce the scope for
and returns from this kind of behaviour.
Keynes created modern macroeconomics; and as I’ve indicated, he gave short shrift to
the financial markets. We can, accordingly, only conjecture what he might have thought
about one of the critical issues of our day: how to regulate the financial sector in ways
that will make a recurrence of the present crisis less likely and increase the likelihood
that the financial sector will do what it is supposed to do: manage risk, allocate capital,
run the payments mechanism, and all at a low cost. Here, the views of Skidelsky
(immersed as he is in Keynes, the macroeconomist) are less than convincing and far
from complete. He is, for example, sceptical of regulations that attempt to prevent
excessive lending in booms (the so-called macro-prudential regulatory framework).
Towards the end of his book, Skidelsky writes that his chief argument ‘has been that
underlying the escalating succession of financial crises we have recently experienced is
the failure of economics to take uncertainty seriously’. In the end, he fails to make this
case. Overconfidence in the flawed mathematical models used by rating agencies and
investment banks did account for many of the horrendous mistakes of this particular
crisis, especially in the United States. But these models played little role in the
multitude of other bubbles, booms and crashes that have marked the past quartercentury. Western banks have repeatedly had to be bailed out because of their bad
lending decisions.
We can’t pass laws that ensure that people won’t suffer from irrational optimism or
pessimism. We can’t even be sure that banks will make good lending decisions. What
we can do, however, is ensure that those who make mistakes bear more of the
consequences of their decisions – and that others bear less. We can ensure that those
entrusted with the care of other people’s money do not use that money for gambling.
This is true whether those decisions are based on flawed models of risk or irrational
perceptions of uncertainty. Taxpayers, workers, retirees and homeowners all over the
world suffered because of the mistakes of America’s financial markets. That is
unacceptable, and it is avoidable.
Keynes’s great contribution was to save capitalism from the capitalists: if they had had
their way, they would have imposed policies that weakened the economy and
undermined political support for capitalism. The regulations and reform adopted in the
aftermath of the Great Depression worked. Capitalism took on a more human face, and
market economies became more stable. But these lessons were forgotten. Thatcher and
Reagan ushered in a new era of deregulation, growing inequality and weakening social
protection. We are now seeing the consequences, and not just in greater instability.
Keynes’s insights are needed now if we’re to save capitalism once again from the
capitalists.
Comentario de Paul Davidson
Letters
Vol. 32 No. 10 · 27 May 2010
Joseph Stiglitz criticises Robert Skidelsky, Keynes’s biographer, for not understanding
Keynes’s theory, but in doing so reveals his own imperfect understanding (LRB, 22
April). The basis of his complaint is Skidelsky’s distinction between risk and
uncertainty. Risk, Skidelsky explains, exists when the future can be predicted on the
basis of currently existing information (e.g. probability distributions calculated from
existing market data); uncertainty exists when no reliable information exists today about
the future outcomes of current decisions, because the economic future can be created by
decisions taken today. According to Stiglitz, this is a distinction without a difference,
and ‘little insight’ into the causes of the Great Recession is gained from Skidelsky’s
emphasis on uncertainty as opposed to risk.
But this is not what Keynes believed. The classical economics of Keynes’s time
presumed that today’s economic decision-makers have reliable information regarding
all future outcomes. I have labelled this the ‘ergodic axiom’. By contrast, Keynes
argued that ‘unfortunate collisions’ occurred because the economic future was very
uncertain. ‘By very uncertain,’ he wrote, ‘I do not mean the same thing as “very
improbable”.’ No reliable information existed today for providing a reliable forecast of
future outcomes.
This is the very proposition that Stiglitz denies. All that is needed to provide better
insight into the workings of the market, he thinks, is ‘small and obviously reasonable
change in assumptions’; for example, that reliable information about the future does
exist but that different individuals have access to different information. The only
necessary policy is ‘transparency’: to make complete information about the future
available to all. The classical ergodic axiom is correct, provided one accepts that not
everyone has access to all the information that exists.
For Keynes the inability of firms and households to ‘know’ the economic future is
essential to understanding why financial crashes occur in an economy that uses money
and money contracts to organise transactions. Firms and households use money
contracts to gain some control over their cash inflows and outflows as they venture into
the uncertain future. Liquidity in such an economy implies the ability to meet all money
contractual obligations when they fall due. The role of financial markets is to assure
holders of financial assets that are traded on orderly markets that they can readily
convert these liquid assets into cash whenever additional funds are needed to meet a
contractual cash outflow commitment. In Keynes’s analysis, the sudden drying up of
liquidity in financial markets, occasioned by sudden drops of confidence, explains why
‘unfortunate collisions’ occur – and have occurred more than a hundred times in the last
30 years, according to Stiglitz.
By contrast, Stiglitz implicitly accepts the orthodox view that all contracts are made in
real terms, as if the economy were a barter economy. Consequently people’s need for
liquidity is irrelevant. Stiglitz indicates that he and Bruce Greenwald have explained
that financial markets fail ‘because contracts are not appropriately indexed’, i.e.,
contracts in our economy are denominated in money terms rather than ‘real’ terms. He
suggests that if only such contracts were made in real, rather than monetary, terms we
would not suffer the ‘unfortunate collisions’ of economic crisis. If only we lived in a
classical world, where contracts would be denominated in real terms! But in a moneyusing economy, this is impossible.
Paul Davidson
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, New York