Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
DANISH INSTITUTIONAL COMPETITIVENESS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY John L. Campbell Department of Sociology Dartmouth College, USA and International Center for Business and Politics Copenhagen Business School, Denmark and Ove K. Pedersen International Center for Business and Politics Copenhagen Business School, Denmark May 2005 Prepared for the Danish Funktionærernes og Tjenestemændenes Fællesråd. 2 Executive Summary DANISH INSTITUTIONAL COMPETITIVENESS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Despite high taxes, a large welfare state, hefty regulations, and a very open economy, Denmark continues to compete successfully against the other advanced capitalist economies. This paper argues that Denmark’s success has been based in large part on its institutional competitiveness–its capacity to achieve socioeconomic success as a result of the competitive advantages that firms derive from operating within a particular set of political, economic, and cultural institutions. It shows that there is no one best way to achieve success in today’s global economy. Notably, low taxes, limited government spending, and light regulatory burdens are not necessary prerequisites for success. The institutional basis for Denmark’s labor market policy, vocational training and skill formation policy, and structural policy are given as examples of ways in which Denmark has become institutionally competitive and, therefore, achieved remarkable success during the late 1990s and early twenty-first century. 3 DANISH INSTITUTIONAL COMPETITIVENESS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Denmark is noted for its extraordinarily high tax rates, large welfare state, and hefty regulatory burden on business.1 Yet Denmark continues to compete successfully against the other advanced capitalist economies on a broad range of economic, social, and fiscal dimensions. This is so even though Denmark is a very open economy and, therefore, vulnerable to the competitive pressures of economic globalization.2 This is puzzling from a neoliberal perspective. According to neoliberals, countries are supposed to need exactly the opposite tax, welfare, and regulatory policies in order to compete successfully in the global economy. Why? Because high taxes, welfare spending, and regulatory burdens are said to drive away investment capital that is needed for developing new technologies, products, and industries, improving labor productivity, stimulating economic growth, and otherwise enhancing national competitiveness (McKenzie and Lee 1991; Ohmae 1995, 1990).3 How has Denmark managed to defy the neoliberal prescription and still be so successful? This paper argues that Denmark’s success has been based to a significant degree on its institutional competitiveness, by which we mean its capacity to achieve economic success as a result of its political, economic, and cultural institutions. Institutional competitiveness stems from the benefits that firms derive from operating within a particular set of institutions—benefits that afford them advantages over their competitors. For example, if firms operate where training and educational systems offer nationally coordinated apprenticeship programs rather than just general education, then their employees may be better trained to begin with and may have greater opportunities for upgrading their skills throughout their careers (Thelen 2004). If firms operate where finance capital tends to come from banks rather than stock markets, then they are often less pressured to maximize profit in the short term and more likely to take a more patient view that emphasizes increased market share, investment in research and development, and long-term growth (Dore 2000; Zysman 1983). If firms operate where labor unions are well organized rather than weak, where centralized corporatist rather than firm-level wage bargaining is the norm, and where works councils exist, then firms are more likely to experience cooperative relations with their employees, take part in subsidized job creation and training programs for the long term unemployed, and participate in active labor market programs that further improve the skills of workers (Martin and Swank 2004; Molina and Rhodes 2002; Schmitter and Lehmbruch 1979; Streeck 1997, 1991) In turn, if a highly skilled labor force, patient investment capital, cooperative labor-management relations, and the like enable firms to produce high quality goods, 1 Some of the material in this paper is drawn from Campbell (2004) and Campbell et al. (2006) and from Pedersen (2006). 2 By economic globalization we mean the increased mobility of capital, labor, goods, and services across national borders. 3 A similar argument about capital flight was made earlier by scholars on the left (e.g., Block 1980; Kalecki 1971; Lindblom 1977; Prezworski and Wallerstein 1988). 4 pursue long-term investment and productivity growth strategies, and use teams of workers and managers to collectively solve production and other problems—all in ways that enhance their international competitiveness—then these firms are institutionally competitive. In other words, their competitive advantage stems from the institutions within which they operate. This is not to say that institutions are the only basis by which firms compete. But they are an important aspect of competitive advantage. The paper proceeds as follows. First, we discuss the general institutional conditions that have enabled small countries like Denmark to succeed economically in the post-World War II era. These include the capacities for policy learning and flexibility that stem from democratic corporatism and that have been accompanied by a variety of welfare programs designed to protect people from the potential difficulties associated with deindustrialization and increased international economic competition. Second, we explain why domestic institutions are so important for affecting how countries compete in today’s global economy. We argue that different types of capitalism enjoy different institutional advantages when it comes to such competition and that there is no one best way to achieve economic success. Third, to illustrate the point, we briefly compare the performance of Denmark and the United States during the 1990s. Despite the fact that they were very different institutionally, they achieved remarkably impressive and similar levels of success. Finally, we provide several examples of how institutions helped Denmark achieve its economic success during the last twenty years. Specifically, we discuss the institutional underpinnings of labor market policy, vocational training and skill formation policy, and structural policy. PREREQUISITES FOR SMALL-COUNTRY COMPETITIVE SUCCESS It has long been recognized that small advanced capitalist countries with open economies, like Denmark, are fundamentally different from large ones. Large countries can define and bend the rules of the international political economy to suit their purposes, but small countries cannot. Hence, small countries are both more vulnerable to changes in the international political economy and must be capable of flexible adjustment to order to respond to international challenges, such as today’s more volatile markets, shorter product life-cycles, rapidly changing production and information technologies, and increased international competition. In turn, flexible adjustment requires political and economic actors to engage in policy learning. Unless small countries can do this they are not likely to be successful economically. That is, their economic competitiveness will erode (e.g., exports will decline, productivity will deteriorate, unemployment will rise, etc.). In the end, they may also be unsuccessful politically in the sense that they experience much political instability as a result of their economic problems (Katzenstein 1984, 1985, 2002; Senghass 1985). What are the key capacities for learning and flexible adjustment that small advanced capitalist countries possess? Since at least the Second World War these consisted of a set of institutions known as democratic corporatism, which contained three elements: an ideology of social partnership expressed at the national level; a centralized and concentrated system of interest groups; and voluntary and informal coordination of 5 conflicting objectives through continuous political bargaining among labor and business groups, state bureaucracies, and political parties. The classic example was national-level collective wage bargaining between labor and business peak associations, including especially trade union confederations and national employers associations, as organized and moderated by the state. Indeed, business, labor, and government were the three groups whose cooperation lay at the heart of these tri-partite corporatist arrangements (e.g., Pedersen 1993; Schmitter 1979; Schmitter and Lehmbruch 1979; Shonfield 1965; Zysman 1983). Through the institutions of democratic corporatism small countries pursued a twin strategy. First, they accepted international liberalism (e.g., economic openness and low tariffs) in the belief that to do otherwise would trigger retaliation from larger countries in the form of trade barriers to small country exports and higher prices for small country imports, both of which would undermine the international competitiveness of small countries. Second, they adopted policies of domestic compensation, which meant the development of generous welfare programs (e.g., transfer payments, manpower policies, active labor market policies, incomes policies, etc.) to buffer their populations from the potentially harmful effects of international liberalization and, more recently, the transition from manufacturing to service-based economies as well as the subsequent effects of deindustrialization (e.g., Cameron 1978; Iversen and Cusak 2000; Katzenstein 1985). Recently, domestic compensation policies have been viewed as especially important for small countries in an increasingly global economy (e.g., Garrett 1998; Swank 2002). THE IMPORTANCE OF INSTITUTIONS Why are institutions so important? Institutions condition the strategic interactions that are central to the behavior of economic actors—particularly the strategic interactions that are involved in a number of important coordination problems that any advanced capitalist society must confront. These coordination problems include, for example, managing industrial relations, labor markets, vocational training, corporate governance, technology innovation, investment, inter-firm relations, and customer relations. Strategic interactions vary according to the institutional context within which they occur. In this sense, and speaking broadly, there are two institutionally distinct types of capitalism—liberal and coordinated market economies (Hall and Soskice 2001a, 2001b; see also Albert 1993). Liberal market economies (LME), such as the United States and Britain, coordinate their activities primarily through markets and corporate hierarchies where actors respond to price signals and make strategic decisions accordingly. Coordinated market economies (CME), such as Germany, Austria, Switzerland, and Japan, coordinate their activities more through non-market relationships, such as informal networks and other collaborative arrangements, notably the institutions of democratic corporatism. CMEs also have bigger welfare states and public sectors and higher tax burdens than LMEs. Different institutional arrangements lead to different yet relatively stable systems of industrial relations, labor markets, vocational training, technology innovation, investment, inter-firm relations, and customer relations. In brief, LMEs are based on a model of shareholder capitalism where the interests of corporate shareholders 6 are put first and where short-term firm profitability is the guiding principle. CMEs are based on a model of stakeholder capitalism where the interests of all of the firm’s stakeholders are considered in decision making, and where business is more patient and less obsessed with short-term profitability (Dore 2000; Roe 2003). Stakeholders are all those actors with a vested interest in the firm’s success, including investors, employees, customers, suppliers, and the local community in which the firm operates. The distinction between LME and CME has been criticized for being too broad and, therefore, missing important sub-types of capitalism (Zeitlin 2003; see also Crouch and Streeck 1997; Hollingsworth and Boyer 1997). Of particular relevance for this paper is an important sub-type of CME, which we call the negotiated economies (NE). These include, for example, Denmark, the Netherlands, Finland, and Norway. NEs share many features with the general CME type. In fact, they have evolved out of this type. However, NEs have developed several unique characteristics over the last twenty years that distinguish them from the classic CME. First, the old centralized form of corporatism in these countries was transformed into a more decentralized form. Second, the policy learning process in these countries was opened up in pluralist fashion to a wider array of interests beyond just labor and capital. This facilitated a more inclusive and on-going dialogue among a broad range of actors that helped to mobilize political consensus around national strategies for international competitiveness (Kjær and Pedersen 2001; Pedersen 2006a). Third, the old corporatist arrangements were transformed into a set of institutions perhaps best described as lean corporatism, which contained three additional elements: an ideology that emphasized the need for adapting to international competition by means of national strategies designed to enhance the comparative advantages of specific industries and firms; a multi-level system of interest groups and firms participating in policy learning and implementation processes at both national and sub-national levels; and a system of voluntary political exchanges in both centralized and decentralized forums that fine tune policies and institutions to help firms adapt to international competition (Molina and Rhodes 2002; Pedersen 2006a; Traxler et al. 2001;Visser and Hemerijck 1997). To put all of this into somewhat broader terms, NEs, as a sub-type of CMEs, are based on a model of stakeholder capitalism where the interests of the firm’s stakeholders are well represented in national, regional, and local strategies for the enhancement of comparative advantage for firms and industries alike. NEs try to develop comparative advantages by decision making involving firms, business associations, labor unions, other interest groups, politicians, and state bureaucrats in a generalized system of political exchange and decision making (Pedersen 2006a, 2006b). Given the attention to stakeholders, CMEs—and especially NEs—provide capacities for policy learning, national leadership, and coordination across policies through deliberations and discussions that help a wide variety of actors reach collective understandings and agreements with each other. Deliberative institutions, such as corporatist negotiations, public commissions, think tanks, and policy institutions, are important because they facilitate consensus building and the formation of national strategies that then boost common understandings of international competition and other 7 kinds of national challenges.4 In other words, deliberation enhances the capacity of actors to cope with new or unfamiliar challenges by enabling them to develop a common diagnosis of the situation and agree to a collective response. It enhances the capacity of actors to coordinate interests and act in common. It enhances the capacity of actors to establish a culture—a set of shared understandings—that facilitates the search for the public good. And it enhances support among business and other groups for social policies that build social cohesion and trust (Martin and Swank 2004). This sort of deliberation, trust, and cooperation, which is formally institutionalized and culturally sanctioned, provides the possibility for the sort of learning and flexible adjustment often required of small countries operating in global markets. Indeed, economists have recognized that, all else being equal, countries with high levels of trust tend to perform better economically than countries with low levels of trust (Zak and Knack 2001). A brief example illustrates the point. During the period of stagflation in the 1970s and early 1980s, countries with centralized corporatist bargaining tended to be more successful in controlling inflation and promoting growth than countries without such institutions. Why? Long-standing corporatist institutions facilitated deliberation between workers and employers that resulted in collective agreements to restrain both wage demands and prices. These agreements were based on a certain level of trust that had been forged through cooperation over many years (Lindberg and Maier 1985). Several further points require attention. First, there is no one best practice when it comes to national economic performance. That is, different types of capitalism each possess different institutional capacities for coping with market challenges. And each set of capacities may have unique advantages when it comes to competing in the global economy. In other words, LMEs and CMEs each have their own unique comparative institutional advantages. On the one hand, LMEs are typically more adept at large-scale radical innovation. This is because firms in LMEs can quickly shed or acquire labor, close down production facilities at will, and rapidly shift large amounts of capital from one sector to another with little opposition from stakeholders. For instance, these are some of the reasons why the United States managed to launch whole new industries like computers, microwave telecommunications, and biotechnology that have contributed significantly to its global competitiveness. On the other hand, CMEs are better at incremental innovations, such as adopting breakthrough technologies developed elsewhere or continuously improving existing products and production processes, in ways that enable them to provide very high quality products and services, often in relatively small batches or specifically tailored to a customer’s needs.5 This is because firms in CMEs receive extensive institutional support for, among other things, life-time vocational training and close labor-management collaboration not just for wage bargaining, but also 4 Think tanks in the CME, and especially the NE, context are not very similar to think tanks in LMEs. In LMEs, such as the United States and Britain, think tanks are far more partisan politically and actively seek to promote particular policy positions over others with little interest in forging a political consensus (Stone 1996). In other words, LME think tanks are not “deliberative” in the inclusive and cooperative way we mean here. In contrast, think tanks in the CMEs are less politically biased and more deliberative (e.g., Mentzel 1999). 5 This innovative capacity is often referred to as either flexible specialization (Piore and Sabel 1984) or diversified quality production (Streeck 1991). 8 for the organization of shop floor activity, the adoption of new flexible production technologies, and the like. Hence, Japan and Germany are known for their application of computerization and robotics to automobile assembly, which enabled them to compete internationally on the basis of high-quality cars and trucks. In Denmark, the biotechnology firm, Novo Nordisk, has used micro-processing technologies, invented elsewhere, in the development of new self-regulating insulin injection systems for diabetics; Bang and Olufsen has combined the latest television, stereo, and computer technologies with modern Danish designs to produce products for the high-end consumer electronics market; and NEG Micon has adapted special materials technologies from abroad to the development of wind turbines. In all of these cases, incremental innovation has enabled these firms to compete very successfully in world markets. But the point is that each type of capitalism may have certain unique capacities that help it succeed economically, depending on the goals of its leaders. Success may be achieved in different ways in different types of capitalism. Second, in terms of state policy making, LMEs are better at formulating policies that sharpen market competition whereas CMEs are better at formulating policies that reinforce the capacities of actors for non-market coordination and deliberation (Hall and Soskice 2001b, pp. 45-51). This difference becomes manifest in many ways. For example, LMEs tend to favor antitrust policies that preserve competition whereas CMEs often permit cartelization (e.g., Djelic 1998). Similarly, given their emphasis on market forms of coordination, LMEs are less likely than CMEs to engage in targeted industrial policies that are designed to enhance the comparative advantages of specific industries or firms (Katzenstein 1985). And insofar as LMEs have smaller welfare states and emphasize coordination of economic activity through the market rather than through deliberative mechanisms, they tend to have higher levels of social inequality than CMEs. In particular, one type of CME—the negotiated economies—are among the most egalitarian societies in the world (e.g., United Nations 2004). As a result, we suspect that CMEs, and especially NEs, also have higher levels of social cohesion and trust than LMEs (e.g., Katzenstein 2000; Zak and Knack 2001). Third, all types of capitalism develop institutional complementarities (Hall and Soskice 2001b, p. 17). That is, all types of capitalism consist of complex sets of political and economic institutions that evolve incrementally over time. Once developed, these institutions fit together such that the functioning of one depends on and enhances the functioning of the others. In other words, institutions evolve in ways that make them functionally interdependent on each other.6 This is especially important for both public and private decision makers to understand because it means that altering one institution— particularly if this is done in a radical fashion—can trigger a series of ripple effects among other institutions, perhaps with unintended and undesirable consequences. Finally, it is common to hear today that the key to national economic success is the pursuit of a neoliberal program. As noted earlier, this means doing three things. It 6 This does not mean that institutions are functional in the sense that they necessarily guarantee the most efficient outcome. It simply means that for one to operate it depends on the continued functioning of the others. This is true for both LMEs and CMEs 9 means reducing taxes on business and investors that, according to neoliberalism, undermine investment. It means reducing welfare programs that allegedly sap the initiative of workers and otherwise distort labor markets and raise the cost of labor. And it means reducing the expensive regulatory burden on business that is also said to undermine productive investment. In sum, cutting taxes, welfare, and regulation is supposed to reduce the costs of doing business and, therefore, improve the competitiveness of firms and the over all performance of national economies. However, as we have explained, while firms and national economies can compete on the basis of comparative cost advantage, they can also compete on the basis of comparative institutional advantage (Hall and Soskice 2001b). In other words, countries may actually fail to compete on the basis of their comparative cost profile, but still do very well thanks to their comparative institutional profile, which may provide them with, for instance, an exceptionally well-trained labor force, state-of-the-art infrastructure, the latest technologies, flexible labor markets, patient investment capital willing to support innovation, advanced research and development programs, social cohesion, political stability, and other things that very much help firms compete in today’s global economy. The importance of institutional competitiveness may be at least as important as cost competitiveness. After all, why else would firms continue to invest as they do in countries with high labor and other costs when other options are available?7 Why else would firms in countries with corporatist bargaining tend to support social welfare programs for their workers as well as other government policies that contribute to social equality and inclusion (Martin and Swank 2004)? And why else would firms seek to defend codetermination and works council arrangements that require them to participate in corporatist deliberations in the first place (Thelen 2000)? DANISH AND AMERICAN SUCCESS IN THE 1990s The notion that there is no one best practice or single route to economic success requires some elaboration. Different types of capitalism can achieve comparable levels of success albeit by doing so in very different ways. Recent Danish and American experiences illustrate the point. To begin with, Denmark is a negotiated economy while the United States is a liberal market economy. Consistent with this characterization, table 1 shows that the level of central government spending as a percentage of GDP in Denmark was substantially higher than it was in the United States in the 1990s. The same was true for social expenditures. And the level of taxation, including the tax burden on capital, was also much higher in Denmark than it was in the United States. Nevertheless, both countries exhibited remarkably similar performance during the last decade. Table 1 about here 7 Recently, some Chinese clothing manufacturers have forsaken the benefits of cheap domestic labor and outsourced the production of up-scale clothing, such as silk blouses and dresses, to Italy because Italian workers, although more expensive, have better skills and greater concern for quality control, thanks to extensive apprenticeship programs, when it comes to processing these fine materials (Harney 2005). 10 Table 2 compares Danish and U.S. performance on several social, economic, and fiscal measures. Among the social indicators, GDP per capita in Denmark, while a few thousand dollars less than in the United States, was still among the very highest in the world. Both countries were extremely prosperous, particularly in view of their virtually identical and very high scores on the U.N. Human Development Index. However, Denmark outperformed the United States in impressive fashion in other ways. It had much less income inequality, gender-based wage inequality, poverty, and illiteracy than the United States. In fact, Denmark was recently ranked first in the world in terms of the government’s effectiveness in reducing income inequality—a point to which we will return later (World Economic Forum 2003, Danish country profile, p. 42). Table 2 about here Among the economic indicators, table 2 reveals that the performance of these two countries was again very close. The notable exception was a somewhat higher GDP growth rate in the United States. Nonetheless, the Danish growth rate was a very respectable 2.7 percent. And although the official American unemployment rate was slightly lower this figure fails to take into account the fact that a comparatively large number of poor, uneducated, young, males—that part of the population most likely to be unemployed—were in prison in the United States and, therefore, were not counted among the officially unemployed. Indeed, the rate of incarceration in the United States was roughly ten times greater that of the incarceration rate in Western Europe during the 1990s. Accounting for this fact could add between one and two percentage points to the U.S. unemployment rate, which would mean that Denmark actually did better than the United States in minimizing real unemployment (Western and Beckett 1999). Finally, among the fiscal indicators in table 2, Denmark had a larger government budget surplus than the United States although it had more national debt as a percentage of GDP. Of course, Denmark has continued to pay down its debt and maintain a budget surplus of about 1 percent of GDP through 2004. In contrast, the United States, largely through a combination of income tax reductions and expansive military spending, has managed to replace its budget surpluses of the 1990s with deficits running as high as 4.4 percent of GDP by 2004—deficits that have contributed to a skyrocketing national debt somewhere in the vicinity of 7 trillion dollars (The Economist 2005, p. 97). The point is that two countries with extremely different tax, welfare, and regulatory institutions achieved remarkably similar—and impressive—levels of success during the 1990s on most indicators. The question, then, is just how did Denmark do so well, especially given its high level of taxation and government spending? After all, neoliberals argue that in order to compete successfully in today’s global economy countries must cut taxes and government spending—especially if they are very open to the global economy as Denmark is. In this regard, Denmark’s performance vis-à-vis the United States is all the more impressive in view of the fact that Denmark is a considerably more open economy than the United States.8 As noted earlier, we believe 8 In 1999, trade in goods was 67.8 percent of GDP in Denmark compared with only 19.8 percent in the United States. Similarly, gross foreign direct investment was 13.3 percent of GDP in Denmark and only 11 that much of Denmark’s success is attributable to its institutional competitiveness (Campbell and Hall 2006; Pedersen 2006a, 2006b). EXAMPLES OF DANISH INSTITUTIONAL COMPETITIVENESS A full-blown and systematic analysis of all of Denmark’s institutional capacities for competitive success is beyond the scope of this paper, but a few examples are worth examining briefly. We discuss labor market policy, structural policy, and vocational training and skill formation policy. We leave for another time discussions of how institutional competitiveness can also be derived from things like bank-based investment, stakeholder capitalism, and the like. Labor Market Policy In the area of labor market policy, the Danish approach has generally involved a blending of elements from the ideal typical LME and CME. Danish labor market policy during the 1990s has been described as a system of “flexicurity” and consists of three basic dimensions (Madsen 2004, 2006).9 First, by European standards Danish employees in the private sector have rather limited levels of employment protection. Hence, employers have much latitude to hire and fire workers in response to market signals as is typical of LMEs. In this regard, Denmark and Britain have the most flexible labor markets in the European Union (World Bank 2003, p. 36). And among the OECD countries only Hungary, Switzerland, Ireland, and Britain provide their workers less protection against being firing than does Denmark (OECD 2004, p. 72).10 As a result, job mobility is quite high in Denmark compared to many other countries (Auer and Cazes 2003, table 2.1.). However, workers are not left alone to manage such employment uncertainties. So, second, Denmark offers generous unemployment policies, health insurance, and other welfare benefits, as if often the case in CMEs, to ensure that when workers become unemployed they have a social safety net that is substantial enough to protect them and their families from some of the worst problems associated with unemployment. Unemployment policies are generous in Denmark compared to most other EU and OECD countries, including those with large welfare states, such as Sweden, Germany, and the Netherlands (Hansen 2000, p. 33). Third, and again reminiscent of CMEs, Denmark developed in the early 1990s a set of active labor market policies established in law that help workers obtain new skills and training so that they can return to work. Workers also receive assistance and encouragement in locating job opportunities for which they can apply. Insofar as today’s global economy requires greater reliance on skills, learning, and labor market flexibility 5.2 percent of GDP in the United States. And gross private capital flows across its borders were 25.4 percent of GDP in Denmark and only 13.6 percent in the United States (World Bank 2001, Table 6.1). 9 For a detailed discussion of the many dimensions of flexicurity, see Wilthagen and Tros (2004) and Ferrera et al. (2001). 10 The same is not true for workers in the public sector, who are more difficult to fire given a variety of legal and contractual protections. This, of course, is not a problem for private sector firms. 12 (Powell 2001), the flexicurity system is especially well equipped to help Denmark compete globally. In recent years, as a result of labor market reforms and corporatist bargaining, important elements of the welfare programs, the active labor market policies, and the system of collective agreements have been decentralized to the regional level and occasionally even to the level of single firms and companies. This has infused the system with an additional element of institutional flexibility that seems to better fit the needs of employers—many of whom are small and medium sized companies who are trying to adjust to the global economy (Wilthagen and Tros 2004). In particular, training for workers in the local labor market is tailored more specifically to the needs of local employers thereby facilitating a more efficiently operating labor market. Indeed, it appears that this decentralized flexicurity system has contributed significantly to Denmark’s relatively low unemployment rates during the 1990s (Madsen 2006). The point, of course, is that without welfare and active labor market policies, and without wage and other agreements between unions and employers’ organizations Danish economic performance in this regard would not likely have been as impressive as it was. Hence, the flexicurity system constitutes a vital component of Denmark’s institutional competitiveness. It is the basis of one of the most flexible labor markets among the advanced capitalist countries (Estevez-Abe 2001, p. 154; Wilthagen and Tros 2004; Wilthagen 1998). In addition to the flexicurity system, the Danish labor market has benefited from several additional institutional sources of flexibility. For instance, since 1965 provisions for flexible working hours (i.e., flextime) have been part of general labor agreements in Denmark. And these provisions have been expanded since 1995. As a result, the Danish labor market is among the most flexible in Europe in this regard (EIRO 1998). Among other things, this has made it easier for families to juggle the demands of work and family, which has enabled more people, especially women with young children, to enter the labor force thereby providing employers with a larger pool of workers from which to choose. Furthermore, as discussed below, the Danish labor force is broadly skilled due to well institutionalized training and skill formation programs. Hence, workers can move with relative ease among different jobs within firms. Firms, therefore, enjoy greater flexibility in deploying workers within their organization than is often the case in other countries. Such flexibility increases the efficiency with which firms can use their workers. It is worth mentioning that the flexicurity system is a good example of the importance of institutional complementarities. The three basic institutions that form the basis of the flexicurity system—limited employment protection, welfare programs, and active labor market policies—have succeeded as a whole precisely because they are well integrated with each other. Together they constitute a functionally interdependent institutional system. In light of the earlier discussion of functional interdependence, to radically change any one of these three institutions could compromise the functioning of the others and, thus, undermine labor market performance. It could also run the risk of introducing additional negative consequences that are difficult to foresee. 13 Vocational Training and Skill Formation Policy11 An important underlying support for labor market flexibility is an extensive vocational training system that equips Danish workers with a high level of general skills. These, in turn, enable workers to move with relative ease from one job to another. Indeed, workers in Denmark spend more time in training and skill formation programs than they do in any other EU country (EUROSTAT 2003). The benefits of this system are many. To begin with, it affords Danish firms the ability to leave much decisionmaking discretion to its workers rather than having to supervise them closely in rigidly bureaucratic ways (Dobbin and Boychuk 1999). Closely related to the previous point, high levels of training enable workers to develop and make use of their own ideas and take independent initiatives in their jobs to a much greater degree than is typically the case in other countries (Goul Andersen 2003). Such independence can improve firm efficiency and productivity. Furthermore, having a well-trained work force facilitates flexibility, cooperation, and collective brainstorming both between workers on the shop floor and among shop-floor workers, engineers, managers, and others (Kristensen 1986; Kristensen and Høpner 1994). Finally, a high level of general skill training enables workers to move easily among different jobs in the firm, which also facilitates efficiency and productivity. The implications for competitiveness and innovation are considerable. The Danish vocational training system has long enabled workers to acquire new skills faster and more broadly than in many other countries. This creates incentives for firms to modernize technologically and to constantly improve their production processes and strategies if they want to prevent their most skilled workers from leaving for more interesting and promising jobs. As a result, business development and skill acquisition go hand in hand within Danish firms. This system enables firms to learn and adapt quickly to changing market opportunities and technologies. In turn, this allows them to capitalize on small, specialized niche markets. This capacity for learning also makes it easy for them to work with a wide variety of customers—both domestically and internationally—and to innovate in response to the demands and requests of these customers. Moreover, this can be done with relatively little formal research and development and without having to depend heavily on scientists and engineers (Kristensen 1996). The development of Danish wind turbines is a good example. Denmark is a world leader in the production of wind turbines. Its success stems largely from incremental innovations in wind turbine technologies that Danish firms developed through close collaborations with their customers, production workers, and engineers who continuously experimented with and developed improved blade and turbine technologies over the years. This was very much a learning process based on a well trained labor force that learned quickly through trial and error experimentation and practical experience. Much of the learning was collective in the sense that it involved considerable group brainstorming and information sharing among shop-floor workers, 11 We are indebted to Peer Hull Kristensen for his assistance with this section of the paper. 14 engineers, scientists, managers, and customers. By contrast, the United States tried to develop a wind turbine technology too, but did so in a much more hierarchically organized system that emphasized high-technology and big science as practiced, for example, at NASA and other high-profile scientific institutes, but without much involvement of shop-floor workers, potential customers, engineers, or other relevant groups. This top-down, big science approach failed to provide the foundation for a competitive wind turbine industry in the United States (Karnøe 1995). Denmark has long had an extensive apprenticeship program for high school students dating back to the 1890s as well as programs to continuously up-grade the skills of workers—especially low-skilled workers. The curriculum for these programs was worked out through corporatist deliberations between unions and employers with the state shouldering many of the costs involved. However, during the late 1980s and the beginning of the 1990s, the vocational training system underwent important changes. On the one hand, unions and managers signed training agreements through which they collaborated in upgrading the skills of blue collar workers. Training agreements permitted workers to spend more time away from work in courses and training programs of various sorts—often with state subsidies for tuition, wage supplements, and the like. These greater opportunities for training increased the level of competition among technical schools of various sorts which, in turn, elevated the quality of training being offered. Better training enabled firms to introduce new and more flexible types of work organization, such as project teams and lean production techniques. This allowed firms not only to introduce and adapt quickly to new information technologies, but also to search for continuous improvements in production processes themselves without enlarging administrative hierarchies. On the other hand, in conjunction with the active labor market policies discussed above, vocational training was made available to the unemployed on a wide-spread basis so that they can upgrade their skills while they are out of work. This enables them to return to active employment equipped with new skills and a better understanding of the new work practices and forms of organization that they are likely to encounter on the job. By creating a system that allows workers to improve their skills during downturns in the business cycle, firms are in a better position to compete when the economy improves and workers are called back to work (Kristensen and Zeitlin 2005, chap. 3). The advantages of this system are especially clear in comparison to Germany, which is also known for its high-skilled labor force (Thelen 2004). When the German economy experiences a downturn and unemployment rises, vocational training and skill up-grading for those who have lost their jobs is jeopardized. This is because the German vocational training system focuses on workers who are currently employed—not those who are unemployed. By sending unemployed workers for further training Denmark uses cyclical downturns in a more dynamic and creative way (Kristensen 2006). The ability to continuously upgrade the skills of workers, particularly in these creative ways, is one way that Denmark has met the challenges of globalization and the emergent knowledge economy so successfully (Kristensen and Zeitlin 2005, part 2). 15 Once again, the institutional complementarities involved are significant. The vocational training system is an important element in the flexicurity system that enhances the functional flexibility of the labor force. Furthermore, it is nestled within a set of active labor market policies and collective agreements between labor and management. Together they constitute a set of institutions that have helped Denmark achieve considerable economic success. Structural Policy The development of a structural policy in the last 20 years is one of the most important aspects of Denmark’s institutional competitiveness (Kjær and Pedersen 2001). By structural policy we mean the coordination of policies across a wide variety of policy areas (industrial, welfare, regulation, environment, labor market, vocational training, etc.) in ways designed to improve the competitiveness of the economy as a whole. This should not be confused with what is commonly referred to as industrial policy—the use of regulatory, fiscal, and other policies targeted more narrowly to improve the competitiveness of specific industries or firms. The development of structural policy has a rather long history beginning in the 1970s and continuing through today. At the end of the 1970s the government tried to devise a technology policy aimed at improving the technological capacities and, therefore, the competitiveness of Danish firms. Consistent with traditional forms of industrial policy, this consisted of programs targeted either at particular industries, such as encouraging them to adopt new production technologies, or at the development and improvement of technologies per se. These programs often involved various forms of cooperation between the public and private sectors. The underlying assumption was that Denmark’s competitive position in the international economy was suffering from inadequate technological development. But beginning in the mid-1980s a broader definition of Denmark’s competitive problems developed. Central to this was the concept of structural competitiveness whereby the competitiveness of Danish industry was seen as being linked to a much wider set of problems and policy areas. These involved not just inadequate levels of technological modernization and research and development, but also a debilitating orientation on the part of Danish firms to producing for low-growth rather than highgrowth markets as well as a general lack of adaptive and innovative capacities in Danish industry. Many people argued that in order to resolve these problems coordinated efforts were needed in areas other than just industrial policy. In line with this view, people also believed that there was a need to reform state administrative and regulatory structures in several policy areas. In particular, it was felt that the policy formation process and especially the policy implementation process needed to be decentralized and otherwise streamlined to reduce the sort of bureaucratic sclerosis that many people believed had prevented public policy from being more effective previously. As a result, during the late 1980s there was an increase in local and regional industrial and structural policy initiatives (Amin and Thomas 1996; Pedersen et al. 1992). 16 These often involved the coordination of industrial policy with policies in other areas, such as labor market policy, research and development policy, vocational training policy, employment policy, and administrative reforms in the public sector (Madsen 2003). Furthermore, the concept of structural problems entailed a shift in orientation from simply removing barriers to growth and adaptation in particular Danish industries to improving the competitiveness of Danish society as a whole. That is, attention was focused not just on the private sector, but also the public sector. Structural policy was viewed as involving a continuous, simultaneous, and integrated adaptation of both the public and private sectors. To illustrate the point, recall the flexicurity system mentioned above. Here various aspects of welfare policy were reformed and integrated with other policy areas. For the unemployed, receipt of unemployment benefits after a period of time was made conditional on seeking both vocational training and job placement. In other words, welfare and vocational training policies were coordinated with each other and with the needs of Danish industries and firms at the local and regional levels (Abrahamson 2006; Madsen 2006). Another example involved public sector modernization. This was perhaps clearest in the area of public sector modernization where the boundaries of the public sector were redefined in significant ways. Several programs and plans were initiated to promote experimentation with new types of public sector governance and new relations between public and private bodies, such as experiments in contracting out the provision of public services to the private sector, various forms of public utility privatization, and the establishment of contractual arrangements between ministries and government agencies (Lægreid and Pedersen 1994, 1996; Jacobsson et al. 1999). It was no longer enough to limit public expenditures and to make the public sector more efficient. One also had to consider the relationship between the public and private sector and the over all development of society. In sum, the development of structural policy was a deliberate attempt to connect and coordinate changes in one policy area with those in others for the improvement of Denmark’s institutional competitiveness over the long run (Pedersen 2006a). It is also another very good example—and perhaps the most extensive example we can offer—of the institutional complementarities and functional interdependencies that exist within the Danish economy. A NOTE ON TAXATION, GOVERNMENT SPENDING, AND THE STATE We began this paper by noting that taxation and government spending are considerably higher in Denmark than in most other advanced capitalist countries. Although there is much talk today that taxes and government spending are too high in Denmark, a few things must be kept in mind before deciding whether it is a good idea to alter the nation’s fiscal institutions. First, so far, neither high taxes nor high levels of government spending seem to have hurt Denmark’s social, economic, or fiscal performance. In fact, as we have argued, in some cases government spending has contributed to Denmark’s success, notably as parts of the flexicurity labor market institutions and the vocational training and skill formation institutions. Second, if taxes were reduced this would have to be matched with reductions in government spending unless budget deficits suddenly became acceptable politically. Of course, if such deficits 17 persisted they might increase the level of national debt and inflation. Third, if tax cuts were matched with spending cuts in order to maintain a balanced budget, then the reduced spending could undermine the sorts of labor market, training, and other institutions that have served Danish firms so well in their quest for international competitiveness. Again, a change in one institution can have significant consequences for another. It is deeply ironic, then, given the neoliberal argument, that the existing tax system can actually be viewed as a positive source of institutional competitiveness to the extent that the revenues it collects help pay for things like the flexicurity and vocational training systems as well as the transportation, telecommunication, information technology, research and development, and other infrastructures upon which firms operating in Denmark depend so heavily—especially firms in the new growth industries, such as business services, consulting, microelectronics, and pharmaceuticals.12 Denmark’s welfare institutions can also be viewed as a positive source of institutional competitiveness. We have repeatedly referred to the importance of welfare institutions to the flexicurity and vocational training systems. The Danish national health care system is another example. The fact that the government provides health care for its citizens means that firms do not have to bear these costs in the form of insurance payments or have to negotiate them during wage bargaining.13 By contrast, in the United States during the Clinton administration’s attempt to reform the health care system many large firms lobbied heavily for an expanded role for the government in the health care system precisely because they could not bear the costs of providing private insurance for their workers. Notably, U.S. automobile manufacturers supported the Clinton plan and complained that without it they would have to continue relocating their production facilities to Canada where their costs of providing health insurance for their workers were considerably lower. The fact that corporations may recognize that high taxes can underwrite a variety of government subsidies, infrastructure, and other public service benefits is likely one reason why taxes on capital have not declined significantly in recent years in the OECD (Campbell 2004, chap. 5; Kiser 2001). Hence, cutting back dramatically on either taxes or government spending could jeopardize Denmark’s institutional competitiveness. It could also create political problems insofar as tax cuts and welfare cuts may be politically unpopular with the population at large. A recent survey from Aalborg University suggests that about 85 percent of Danes are now content with their taxes. Moreover, roughly two thirds of the 12 Examples of such important infrastructure projects, financed at least in part by public funds, include the Øresund regional development project, including the Øresund bridge to Sweden, renovation of Copenhagen airport, the Great Belt Link bridge connecting eastern and western Denmark, and the Copenhagen metro system. 13 It also means that health care costs are significantly lower in Denmark than in many other countries, notably the United States. In 2002, health expenditures per capita were $2,835 (8.8% of GDP) in Denmark and $5,724 (14.6% of GDP) in the United States while the infant mortality rate (under age 5 years) per 1,000 births was 5.9 in Denmark and 8.0 in the United States (World Bank 2005). Adult life expectancy was virtually identical in 2002 at 76.6 years in Denmark and 77.0 years in the United States (United Nations 2004, p. 139). 18 population would prefer improved public services to lower taxes (Copenhagen Post 2005, p. 4). Certainly there is no groundswell of support for neoliberal reforms of either the tax system or government spending. The same is true of other Western European countries that are preserving their high corporate and other tax rates in order to continue funding social welfare programs (International Herald Tribune 2005, p. 14).14 That said, we do not mean to suggest that there either has been or is no room for change when it comes to the state. Denmark has undergone considerable public sector modernization since the 1970s. Among other things, this has entailed the streamlining of state bureaucracies, reductions in the number of personnel in some ministries, agencies, and departments, the adoption of efficiency oriented decision-making criteria (i.e., costbenefit analysis), the frequent decentralization of policy implementation, and the inclusion of a more diverse set of organized interests into the policy process. This has had two positive effects in terms of Danish competitiveness. On the one hand, by increasing state efficiency, less money needs to be spent on administrative matters and more money is available for the state to spend on programs, such as those described above, that enhance competitiveness. On the other hand, the state has also become more effective in the sense that a wider range of interests are represented in policy making and, as a result, the legitimacy of state policies is enhanced. This may be one reason why there is such wide-spread public support for state programs and such little opposition to high tax rates in Denmark. One caveat is in order. Recall that Denmark has had much less income and social inequality than the United States. This is due in part to the effectiveness of Denmark’s welfare, educational, labor market, and other institutions as well as the tax system that helps to finance them. While there may be more than one route to economic success and while success may be achieved by both LMEs and CMEs, the same may not be true when it comes to the issue of income equality, gender equality, and poverty. In this case, the CME strategy may be better than the LME strategy (Hicks and Kenworthy 1998). The important point here is that high taxes and spending per se are not necessarily sources of competitive disadvantage, as neoliberals suggest. To the contrary, labor market policy, vocational training and skill formation policy, and other policies that have benefited Danish industry cost money. Drastically altering the expenditures that support these and other programs could jeopardize Denmark’s institutional competitiveness. The same is true for taxation. Dramatic changes in the over all level of taxation could reduce the government’s revenue stream and, therefore, undermine the fiscal base upon which spending for important programs rests. Moreover, radically altering the structure of the tax system, that is, the relative balance of revenues collected from different types of taxes 14 Of course, tax regimes provide institutional opportunities for both LMEs and CMEs and can be manipulated in a variety of ways depending on the will of governments. Recently, some LMEs have simplified their tax codes, closed loopholes, and reduced rates somewhat in order to make the tax system neutral with respect to the incentives it creates for businesses in different industries. Conversely, CMEs can deliberately incorporate tax incentives, such as accelerated depression allowances for certain types of investment or tax breaks for training certain types of workers, into the tax code in order to encourage certain kinds of investment or other types of activities. In the latter case, tax policy in effect becomes a form of industrial policy. 19 (e.g., income, profit, social security, consumption, etc.) could undermine Denmark’s institutional competitiveness to the extent that the current tax structure creates incentives for investment, consumption, saving, and other activities that have apparently served Denmark well over the years. The relationship between taxation, spending, incentives, and institutional competitiveness are, of course, extremely complex and well beyond the scope of this paper. So, we offer no suggestions as to how Denmark’s fiscal institutions should be changed, if they should be changed at all. Rather we urge great caution in this regard. Insofar as fiscal institutions support and reflect the nation’s comparative institutional advantages, politicians should be sure to learn what works and what does not work in terms of Denmark’s institutional competitiveness before they start to meddle with the underlying fiscal system. Given the institutional complementarities involved, radical surgery could have disastrous consequences. CONCLUSION We have argued that Denmark’s recent success stems in large part from its institutional competitiveness. More research is required to better understand the full range of benefits associated with Denmark’s key institutions. This also entails that we learn more about the possible disadvantages of the current Danish system. CMEs and LMEs exhibit both comparative institutional advantages and disadvantages. The only way we can begin to determine these things is through systematic comparative analyses of different countries, their institutions, and the relationship between these institutions and social, economic, and fiscal performance. We need to explore more fully what works and what does not work in Denmark and in other countries. This is certainly an important prerequisite for forecasting, benchmarking, and otherwise figuring out how to adjust Denmark’s ensemble of institutions as well as public and private policies and programs in ways that will preserve and enhance the country’s comparative advantage in the years ahead. Further study also requires the examination of possible alternative explanations for Denmark’s recent success. For instance, skeptics might argue that because Denmark and the United States have very different institutional arrangements yet quite similar levels of success in many cases, institutions do not actually have much to do at all with national economic competitiveness. Perhaps both countries share similar conditions that we have not identified that have been responsible for success in both countries. For instance, an obvious possibility might be monetary policy. Interest rates were kept quite low during the 1990s in both countries. Might this not have been the key to success rather than institutions? Certainly low interest rates help create an environment that is conducive to growth insofar as it provides a supply of relatively inexpensive capital for consumers and investors. But this does not guarantee success. Notably, low interest rates per se do not ensure that firms will borrow or that, if they do, they will invest wisely in ways that eventually yield success. Furthermore, interest rates were low in many countries in the European Union during this period that did not experience economic performance nearly as strong as that of Denmark and the United States. So, while monetary policy may have contributed to economic success, it is certainly not the only, or even the most important, factor. In any case, the point is twofold. First, we are not 20 arguing that institutions are necessarily the only basis for Denmark’s impressive success over the last two decades or so. Other factors may have contributed as well. Second, much more research is necessary in order to determine the degree to which Denmark’s success stemmed from its institutional arrangements or something else. As we have said, the success of small capitalist countries in the twenty-first century depends increasingly on their ability to learn and be flexible. It is important, however, to remember that collective learning, flexibility, and economic success are often rooted in an underlying normative consensus within these countries that enables business, labor, and other groups to work cooperatively together (Katzenstein 2000; Zak and Knack 2001; see also Putnam and Goss 2002, pp. 5-7). Over the years, Danish decision makers have cultivated consensus and social solidarity among various status and class groups in order to cope with geopolitical and, more recently, international economic challenges that the country has faced. This has involved, in part, the development and modification of an interdependent set of welfare, labor market, and other institutions that includes and benefits a wide range of interests (Campbell et al. 2006). Introducing sweeping changes to these institutions may run the risk not only of undermining Denmark’s institutional competitiveness, but also the underlying consensus and solidarity that have been so beneficial to Denmark in the past. This last point relates directly to the role of Danish policy makers. Over the last couple of decades, Danish leaders have tried to learn which policies do and do not work well in terms of improving the nation’s competitiveness. Such learning has facilitated political leadership insofar as policy makers have managed to figure out collectively— often through prolonged discussion and negotiation with business, labor, and other important social partners—how different policies and institutions are linked in ways that are mutually reinforcing and beneficial (Pedersen 2006b). This sort of learning, linking, and leading has helped to enhance Danish institutional competitiveness. The same is also necessary for preserving Denmark’s competitive position in the future. To shed some light on this issue, let us add a final dimension to the discussion of the institutional competitiveness. Specifically, consider knowledge regimes. A knowledge regime consists of three parts: (i) the knowledge process – how knowledge is formed and changed; (ii) knowledge organization – how the formation of knowledge is organized; and (iii) knowledge content – the kind of knowledge being produced. The point is that there are likely to be a particular knowledge regime belonging to the Danish negotiated economy. Moreover, the type of knowledge regime in place in Denmark at the moment influences which economic paradigms (knowledge content) serve as the foundation for macroeconomic and microeconomic decisions as well as political and business decisions. Consequently, there are several reasons why knowledge regimes are important – but especially in a negotiated economy. First, we believe that negotiated economies are more error-prone than are other economies, due to the fact that they include a particular element of gambling and risk. Not only are stakes higher – the survival of an entire nation including the population’s economic growth and welfare is at stake. Also, decision making depends on the capacity of the elite to interpret contemporary economic and other conditions for action, and to do so in a manner that 21 will lead to successful national strategies. And finally, being a small state, Denmark is forced by circumstances to adjust to geopolitical decisions taken by big states and to adapt to economic trends influenced by multinational concerns and international organizations. So, perhaps more than in liberal and coordinated economies, a negotiated economy operates in a high-risk environment – the future fate of a whole economy is based on the capacity of the elite to develop national strategies for adaptation. Second, we are convinced that this element of gambling reveals itself in the way that knowledge is organized in the Danish case. In contrast to other production regimes the Danish knowledge regime is characterized by three processes. First is learning. Learning is all about interpretation and monitoring. In Denmark it includes how such interpretations and monitoring of things like the international competitiveness of the Danish economy have developed slowly and over many years into a socioeconomic framework of meaning to which all the important economic and political decision makers refer when making decisions (Pedersen, 2006a,b). If the Danish negotiated economy is equipped with mechanisms that facilitate change and adaptability, then it is probably because learning within the Danish knowledge regime is collective and includes all of the most important actors; because the knowledge gained is cumulative and, as a result, experiences are stored in the collective memory; and because knowledge is utilityoriented and stored in macroeconomic and microeconomic databases, which are always updated and always accessible for all decision-makers. The important point is that a negotiated knowledge regime – in contrast to an ideal typical liberal knowledge regime – is not individual, but collective; not private, but public; and not contemporary, but filtered through the collective experiences of the past. Leading is the second process. Leading is about how knowledge is utilized. In the Danish negotiated economy the collective memory is constantly used to make decisions in which collective interests are combined with special interests. This is the first reason why leadership is important in a negotiated economy – the array of special interests must be united in one common interest. A second reason why leadership is important in Denmark is that this common interest is always formulated on the basis of an interpretation of what it takes for the nation to adapt to contemporary developments in the global economy and the geopolitical environment. In the negotiated economy, this involves considerable gambling on the part of leaders, as we suggested earlier. And the stakes are very high. Not only does leadership involve an explicit effort to provide for the collective well-being as knowledge is used in negotiations between the government and other actors, but, given the orientation of Danish policy making nowadays, it is very much future-oriented insofar as leaders seek to anticipate how the very open and vulnerable Danish political economy can best adapt to changing international economic and political circumstances. Hence, leadership in Denmark is a collective art form, one based not on personal experience or intuition alone but on a collective memory that is used to develop aggregated and systematic policy prescriptions. Indeed, making decisions for an entire economy, with consequences for an entire population, via the aggregation of an array of different interests, and by coordinating a number of different policy instruments, through an all-encompassing set of structural policies, and doing so on the 22 basis of information that is fundamentally uncertain involves considerable gambling, which may make leadership even trickier in Denmark than in other types of society. Finally, the third process is linking. Linking is the ultimate purpose of learning and leading. Linking occurs when an increasing number of policies are coordinated and when several policies are linked in social pacts or through negotiation games to become strategies for national action. In the Danish negotiated economy, linking operates on many levels. National strategies combine many policies. Negotiation systems link many levels of decision-making. Indeed, policy making increasingly requires simultaneous attention to the supranational, national and local levels as well as the level of individual corporations (Martin and Swank 2004). And, as discussed above, knowledge is used to help link and coordinate policies in order to improve Denmark’s comparative advantages by devising and taking advantage of various institutional complementarities.