Download sugar act (1764)

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Diplomacy in the American Revolutionary War wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
SUGAR ACT (1764)
On April 5, 1764, Parliament passed a modified version of the Sugar and Molasses Act (1733),
which was about to expire. Under the Molasses Act colonial merchants had been required to pay a tax of six
pence per gallon on the importation of foreign molasses. But because of corruption, they mostly ignored the
taxes and ruined the intention of the tax — that the English product would be cheaper compared to the
French West Indies. This hurt the British West Indies market in molasses and sugar and the market for rum,
which the colonies had been producing in quantity with the cheaper French molasses. The First Lord of the
Treasury, and Chancellor of the Exchequer Lord Grenville was trying to bring the colonies in line with regard
to payment of taxes. He had beefed up the Navy presence and instructed them to become more active in
customs enforcement. Parliament decided it would be wise to make a few adjustments to the trade
regulations. The Sugar Act reduced the rate of tax on molasses from six pence to three pence per gallon,
while Grenville took measures that the duty be strictly enforced. The act also listed more foreign goods to be
taxed including sugar, certain wines, coffee, pimiento, cambric and printed calico, and further, regulated the
export of lumber and iron. The enforced tax on molasses caused the almost immediate decline in the rum
industry in the colonies. The combined effect of the new duties was to sharply reduce the trade with
Madeira, the Azores, the Canary Islands, and the French West Indies (Guadalupe, Martinique and Santo
Domingo (now Haiti)), all important destination ports for lumber, flour, cheese, and assorted farm products.
The situation disrupted the colonial economy by reducing the markets to which the colonies could sell, and
the amount of currency available to them for the purchase of British manufactured goods. This act, and the
Currency Act, set the stage for the revolt at the imposition of the Stamp Act.
The Sugar Act was passed by Parliament on April 5, 1764, and it arrived in the colonies at a time of
economic depression. It was an indirect tax, although the colonists were well informed of its presence. A
good part of the reason was that a significant portion of the colonial economy during the Seven Years War
was involved with supplying food and supplies to the British Army. Colonials, however, especially those
affected directly as merchants and shippers, assumed that the highly visible new tax program was the major
culprit. As protests against the Sugar Act developed, it was the economic impact rather than the
constitutional issue of taxation without representation that was the main focus for the colonists.
New England ports especially suffered economic losses from the Sugar Act as the stricter enforcement
made smuggling molasses more dangerous and risky. Also they argued that the profit margin on rum was
too small to support any tax on molasses. Forced to increase their prices, many colonists feared being
priced out of the market. The British West Indies, on the other hand, now had undivided access to colonial
exports. With supply of molasses well exceeding demand, the islands prospered with their reduced
expenses while New England ports saw revenue from their rum exports decrease. Also the West Indies had
been the primary colonial source for hard currency, or specie, and as the reserves of specie were depleted
the soundness of colonial currency was threatened.
Two prime movers behind the protests against the Sugar Act were Samuel Adams and James Otis, both of
Massachusetts. In August 1764, fifty Boston merchants agreed to stop purchasing British luxury imports,
and in both Boston and New York there were movements to increase colonial manufacturing. There were
sporadic outbreaks of violence, most notably in Rhode Island. Overall, however, there was not an immediate
high level of protest over the Sugar Act in either New England or the rest of the colonies. That would begin
in the later part of the next year when the Stamp Act was passed.
Stamp ACT (1765)
The Stamp Act of 1765 (short title Duties in American Colonies Act 1765; 5 George III, c. 12) was
a direct tax imposed by the British Parliament specifically on the colonies of British America. The
act required that many printed materials in the colonies be produced on stamped paper produced
in London and carrying an embossed revenue stamp. These printed materials were legal
documents, magazines, newspapers and many other types of paper used throughout the colonies.
Like previous taxes, the stamp tax had to be paid in valid British currency, not in colonial paper
money. The purpose of the tax was to help pay for troops stationed in North America after the
British victory in the Seven Years' War. The British government felt that the colonies were the
primary beneficiaries of this military presence, and should pay at least a portion of the expense.
The Stamp Act met with great resistance in the colonies. The colonies sent no representatives to
Parliament, and therefore had no influence over what taxes were raised, how they were levied, or
how they would be spent. Many colonists considered it a violation of their rights as Englishmen to
be taxed without their consent—consent that only the colonial legislatures could grant. Colonial
assemblies sent petitions and protests. The Stamp Act Congress held in New York City, reflecting
the first significant joint colonial response to any British measure, also petitioned Parliament and
the king. Local protest groups, led by colonial merchants and landowners, established connections
through correspondence that created a loose coalition that extended from New England to
Georgia. Protests and demonstrations initiated by the Sons of Liberty often turned violent and
destructive as the masses became involved. Very soon all stamp tax distributors were intimidated
into resigning their commissions, and the tax was never effectively collected.
While the colonial legislatures were acting, the ordinary citizens of the colonies were also voicing
their concerns outside of this formal political process. There were massive protests in
Massachusetts, Rhode Island, New York, New Hampshire, Maryland, and Pennsylvania. Grenville
was replaced as Prime Minister on July 10, 1765, by Lord Rockingham, the first lord of the
treasury. News of the mob violence began to reach England in October. At the same time that
resistance in America was building and accelerating, conflicting sentiments were taking hold in
Britain. Some wanted to strictly enforce the Stamp Act over colonial resistance, wary of the
precedent that would be set by backing down.
Others, feeling the economic effects of reduced trade with America after the Sugar Act and an
inability to collect debts while the colonial economy suffered, began to lobby for a repeal of the
Stamp Act. A significant part of colonial protest had included various non-importation agreements
among merchants who recognized that a significant portion of British industry and commerce was
dependent on the colonial market. This movement had spread through the colonies with a
significant base coming from New York City where 200 merchants had met and agreed to import
nothing from England until the Stamp Act was repealed.
Quartering ACT (1765)
Quartering Act is the name of at least two 18th-century acts of the Parliament of
Great Britain. “Quartering” literally means the buildings, houses, barracks, or
rooms occupied by military personnel or their families. These Quartering Acts
were used by the British forces in the American colonies to ensure that British
soldiers had adequate housing and provisions. These acts were amendments to
the Mutiny Act, which had to be renewed annually by Parliament. Originally
intended as a response to problems that arose during Britain's victory in the
Seven Years War they later became a source of tension between inhabitants of
the Thirteen Colonies and the government in London.
Lieutenant-General Thomas Gage, commander-in-chief of forces in British North
America, and other British officers who had fought in the French and Indian War,
had found it hard to persuade colonial assemblies to pay for quartering and
provisioning of troops on the march and he asked Parliament to do something.
Most colonies had supplied provisions during the war, but the issue was disputed
in peacetime. The Province of New York assembly passed an act to provide for
the quartering of British regulars, which expired on January 1, 1764.[2]The result
was the Quartering Act of 1765, which went far beyond what Gage had
requested. The colonies disputed the legality of this Act since it seemed to violate
the Bill of Rights 1689 which forbid taxation without representation and the
raising or keeping of a standing army without the consent of Parliament. No
standing army had been kept in the colonies before the French and Indian War,
so the colonies asked why a stand-in army was needed after the French had
been defeated.
This first Quartering Act (citation 5 Geo. III c. 33) was given Royal Assent on
March 24, 1765, and provided that Great Britain would house its soldiers in
American barracks and public houses, as by the Mutiny Act of 1765, but if its
soldiers outnumbered the housing available, would quarter them "in inns, livery
stables, ale houses, victualing houses, and the houses of sellers of wine and
houses of persons selling of rum, brandy, strong water, cider or meth Eglin", and
if numbers required in "uninhabited houses, outhouses, barns, or other
buildings." Colonial authorities were required to pay the cost of housing and
feeding these troops.
When 1,500 British troops arrived at New York City in 1766 the New York
Provincial Assembly refused to comply with the Quartering Act and failed to
supply billeting for the troops. The troops had to remain on their ships. For failure
to comply with the Quartering Act, Parliament suspended the Province of New
York's Governor and legislature in 1767 and 1769. In 1771, the New York
Assembly allocated funds for the quartering of the British troops.
This act expired on March 24, 1767
Declaratory ACT (1766)
Parliament then agreed to repeal the Stamp Act on the condition that the Declaratory Act
was passed. On March 18, 1766, Parliament repealed the Stamp Act and passed the
Declaratory Act.
In other words, the Declaratory Act of 1766 asserted that Parliament had the absolute
power to make laws and changes to the colonial government, "in all cases whatsoever",
even though the colonists were unrepresented in the Parliament.
Normally the economic activity in the colonies wouldn't have caused such an outcry, but
the English economy was still suffering from its post-war depression from the Seven
Years War. Another reason that the Stamp Act was repealed was the fact that George
Grenville, the Prime Minister who had enacted the Stamp Acts, had been replaced by
Rockingham. Rockingham was more favorable towards the colonies, and furthermore he
was rather antagonistic to any policy that Grenville had enacted. Rockingham invited
Benjamin Franklin to speak to Parliament about colonial policy, and he portrayed the
colonists as in opposition to internal taxes (which were derived from internal colonial
transactions) like the Stamp Act called for, but not external taxes (which were duties laid
on imported commodities). Parliament then agreed to repeal the Stamp Act.
The Declaratory Act asserted that Parliament "had, hath, and of right ought to have, full
power and authority to make laws and statutes of sufficient force and validity to bind the
colonies and people of America ... in all cases whatsoever". The phrasing of the act was
intentionally unambiguous, and although many in Parliament felt that taxes were implied
in this clause, some other Parliament members and many of the colonialists did not.
Many of the colonists were busy celebrating their political victory (the repealing of the
Stamp Act) to notice that the Declaratory Act subtley hinted that more acts would be
coming. This Declaratory Act was copied almost word for word from the Irish Declaratory
Act, an act which put Ireland in a position of bondage to their crown. The same fate was
to come to The Thirteen Colonies. Other colonists, however, were outraged.
When in 1767 this modernised British Parliament,committed by now to the principle of
parliamentary sovereignty unlimited and unlimitable, issued a declaration that a
parliamentary majority could pass any law it saw fit, it was greeted with an out-cry of
horror in the colonies. James Otis and Sam Adams in Massachusetts, Patrick Henry in
Virginia and other colonial leaders along the seaboard screamed "Treason" and "Magna
Carta"! Such a document, they insisted, demolished the essence of all their British
ancestors had fought for, took the very savour out of that fine Anglo-Saxon liberty for
which the sages and patriots of England had died.
Thus the Declaratory Act can be seen as a predecessor to future acts that would further
incite the anger of the American colonists and eventually lead up to the American
Revolutionary War. References to it, especially to the phrase "in all cases whatsoever",
can be found, among other places, in the Declaration of Independence.
Townshend Acts (1767)
The Townshend Acts were a series of acts passed beginning in 1767 by the Parliament of Great Britain
relating to the British colonies in North America. The acts are named for Charles Townshend, the Chancellor
of the Exchequer, who proposed the program. Historians vary slightly in which acts they include under the
heading "Townshend Acts", but five laws are frequently mentioned: the Revenue Act of 1767, the Indemnity
Act, the Commissioners of Customs Act, the Vice Admiralty Court Act, and the New York Restraining Act.
The purpose of the Townshend Acts was to raise revenue in the colonies to pay the salaries of governors
and judges so that they would be independent of colonial control, to create a more effective means of
enforcing compliance with trade regulations, to punish the province of New York for failing to comply with
the 1765 Quartering Act, and to establish the precedent that the British Parliament had the right to tax the
colonies. The Townshend Acts met with resistance in the colonies, prompting the occupation of Boston by
British troops in 1768, which eventually resulted in the Boston Massacre of 1770.
According to the British Constitution, British subjects could not be taxed without the consent of their
representatives in Parliament. Because the colonies elected no members of the British Parliament, many
colonists viewed Parliament's attempt to tax them as a violation of the constitutional doctrine of taxation only
by consent. Some British politicians countered this argument with the theory of "virtual representation",
which maintained that the colonists were in fact represented in Parliament even though they elected no
members. This issue, only briefly debated following the Sugar Act, became a major point of contention
following Parliament's passage of the 1765 Stamp Act. The Stamp Act proved to be wildly unpopular in the
colonies, compelling Parliament to repeal it the following year.
The first of the Townshend Acts, sometimes simply known as the Townshend Act, was the Revenue Act of
1767. This act represented the Chatham ministry's new approach for generating tax revenue in the
American colonies after the repeal of the Stamp Act in 1766. The British government had gotten the
impression that because the colonists had objected to the Stamp Act on the grounds that it was a direct (or
"internal") tax, colonists would therefore accept indirect (or "external") taxes, such as taxes on imports. With
this in mind, Charles Townshend, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, devised a plan that placed new duties
on paper, paint, lead, glass, and tea that were imported into the colonies. These were items that were not
produced in North America and that the colonists were only allowed to buy from Great Britain.
To better collect the new taxes, the Commissioners of Customs Act of 1767 established the American Board
of Customs Commissioners, which was modeled on the British Board of Customs. The American Customs
Board was created because of the difficulties the British Board faced in enforcing trade regulations in the
distant colonies. Five commissioners were appointed to the board, which was headquartered in Boston. The
American Customs Board would generate considerable hostility in the colonies towards the British
government. According to historian Oliver M. Dickerson, "The actual separation of the continental colonies
from the rest of the Empire dates from the creation of this independent administrative board.” Another
measure to aid in enforcement of the trade laws was the Vice Admiralty Court Act of 1768.
Townshend knew that his program would be controversial in the colonies, but he argued that, "The
superiority of the mother country can at no time be better exerted than now." The Townshend Acts did not
create an instant uproar like the Stamp Act had done two years earlier, but before long, opposition to the
program had become widespread.
Tea Act (1773)
The Tea Act was an Act of the Parliament of Great Britain to expand the British East India
Company's monopoly on the tea trade to all British Colonies, selling excess tea at a reduced price.
It was passed on May 10, 1773.
Previously, the East India Company had been required to sell its tea exclusively in London on
which it paid a duty which averaged two shillings and six pence per pound. [1] Among other
consequences, this had created a profitable opportunity for smugglers to import and distribute taxfree tea throughout the American colonies. The British parliament hoped that if the colonists had
cheap tea available, smuggling would cease.
By 1772 the Company was close to collapse due in part to contractual payments to the British
government of 400,000 pounds per year, together with war and famine in India, and economic
weakness in European markets. Benjamin Franklin was one of several people who had suggested
things would be greatly improved if the Company were allowed to export its tea directly to the
colonies without paying the taxes it was paying in London.
Many Colonists opposed the Act, not so much because it rescued the East India Company, but
more because it seemed to validate the last remaining duty imposed by the Townshend Acts of
1767, the oh-so-hated tea tax. Britain in turn yearned to quash the trade of smuggled tea to
America. Before the Act, smugglers imported 900,000 pounds of cheap foreign tea a year. The
quality of the smuggled tea did not match the quality of the dutiable East Indian Tea of which the
Americans bought 562,000 pounds per year. Although the British tea was more appealing in taste,
some Patriots encouraged the consumption of smuggled tea. All this however did little to damage
the British tea trade.
Before the Boston Tea Party occurred, the colonies did not agree with the decision to impose the
Tea Act, whereby they would be acquiescing to the payment of the tea tax. In New York and
Philadelphia, they sent the British ships with the tea on board back to Britain. In Charleston, the
colonists left the tea on the docks to rot. The Royal Governor in Boston was determined to the
leave the ships in port, even though the colonists refused to take the tea off the boat. The Boston
Tea Party soon erupted, representing a turning point in Anglo-Colonial political relations.
The Boston Tea Party most appalled British political opinion makers of all stripes. The action united
all parties in Britain against the American radicals. After the Boston tea party, Britain decided to
close down the Boston Harbor until the tea was further paid for, as provided in the Boston Port Act,
first of the so-called Intolerable Acts, or Coercive Acts as they were called by the British, passed by
Parliament in response to the Boston Tea Party. All this united many colonists even more in their
frustrations against Britain, and was one of the many causes of the American Revolution.
CURRENCY ACT (1751 & 1764)
The Currency Act is the name of several Acts of the Parliament of Great Britain that
regulated paper money issued by the colonies of British America. The Acts sought to
protect British merchants and creditors from being paid in depreciated colonial currency.
The policy created tension between the colonies and Great Britain, and was cited as a
grievance by colonists early in the American Revolution.
The first Act, the Currency Act of 1751 (24 Geo. II c. 53), restricted the emission of
paper money by the colonies of New England. These colonies had issued paper fiat
money known as "bills of credit" to help pay for military expenses during the French and
Indian Wars. Because more paper money was issued than what was taxed out of
circulation, the currency depreciated in relation to the British pound sterling. The
resultant inflation was harmful to merchants in Great Britain, who were forced to accept
the depreciated currency from colonists for payment of debts.
The Act limited the future emission of bills of credit to certain circumstances. It allowed
the existing bills to be used as legal tender for public debts (i.e. paying taxes), but
disallowed their use for private debts (e.g. for paying merchants).
The Currency Act of 1764 (4 Geo. III c. 34) extended the 1751 Act to all of the British
colonies of North America. Unlike the earlier Act, this statute did not prohibit the
colonies from issuing paper money, but it did forbid them from designating future
currency emissions as legal tender for public or private debts. This tight money policy
created financial difficulties in the colonies, where gold and silver were in short supply.
Benjamin Franklin, a colonial agent in London, lobbied for repeal of the Act over the
next several years, as did other agents.
The colonial government of the Province of New York insisted that the Currency Act
prevented it from providing funds for British troops. As a result, in 1770, Parliament gave
permission (10 Geo. Ill c. 35) for New York to issue £120,000 in paper currency for
public but not private debts. Parliament extended these concessions to the other colonies
in 1773 by amending the Currency Act of 1764 (13 Geo. III c. 57), permitting the
colonies to issue paper currency as legal tender for public debts.
The Currency Acts created tension between the colonies and the mother country, and
were a contributing factor in the coming of the American Revolution. In all of the
colonies except Delaware, the Acts were considered to be a "major grievance".
However, according to historians Jack Greene and Richard Jellison, the currency debate
was no longer really a "live issue" in 1774, due to the 1773 amendment of the Act. The
controversy's most important impact was psychological, in that it helped convince many
colonists that Parliament did not understand or care about their problems. Colonial
leaders came to believe that they, rather than Parliament, were better suited to legislate
for the colonies.