Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
The Potential Capability of the New Endogenous Growth Theory (NGT) in Explaining Growth: Review of Theoretical and Empirical Literature Adrino Mazenda PhD Candidate, Department of Economics, University of Fort Hare Email: [email protected] Abstract The paper discusses the new endogenous growth theory and its empirics in explaining the growth process. The compilation will show the theory’s perspective of technological change as a driver of economic improvement. It will also depict how this growth can be persistent in the long run. The causes of technological improvement and the practical measures that have to be undertaken as triggers of a successful implementation of the model in reality are also discussed. Finally empirical evidence on envisaged growth components will be reviewed. Keywords: Technology, Innovation, R&D, New Growth Theory, Economic Growth 1 1.1 Introduction The godfathers of economics such as Thomas Malthus, Adam Smith and David Ricardo provided many of the basic ingredients that appear in modern theories of economic growth. These ideas include the basic approaches of competitive behaviour and equilibrium dynamics, the role of diminishing returns and its relation to the accumulation of physical and human capital, the interplay between per capita income, technology growth and economic growth (Muradzikwa, Smith and de Villiers, 2006: 415). The Endogenous Growth Model otherwise known as the New Growth Model was developed in the 1980s. Its emergence was a direct consequence of the criticism of neoclassical failures. In the neoclassical model, various principles failed to be explained: i. Savings rate and technological progress ii. Why do growth patterns for some countries show sustained increase, despite the fact that they display a rising capital to labour ratio? iii. Why has the neoclassical prediction of per capita income convergence failed? iv. Why is there an increase in the economic gap between rich and poor nations? v. What lies behind medium to long term acceleration and deceleration in growth? Paul Romer, in 1986, primarily led efforts to overcome the above mentioned anomalies by including endogenous factors of production, production functions and technological innovations. 1.2 Assumptions The endogenous model assumes constant marginal product of capital at the aggregate level or at least that the limit of marginal product of capital does not tend toward zero. In other word the theory explains marginal returns to capital to be constant or increasing such that total product will be continuously increasing but would not likely diminish (Mankiw and Romer, 1991). This does not imply, though, that large firms are more productive than small ones because at firm level the marginal product of capital may still be diminishing. Perfect competition assumption, which is a pillar of the neoclassical theory, is relaxed and some degree of monopoly power is thought to exist. Under this assumption, there is a dissection of all economic sectors into the production sector which is responsible for the manufacture of final 2 output and the research and development that is responsible for the development of ideas continuously. The research and development sector is assumed to make monopoly profits by selling ideas to production firms. Technology, synonymous with ‘knowledge’, is neither an ordinary good (being rival and excludable), nor a public good (being non-rival and nonexcludable), but non-rival and partial excludable good (Mankiw and Romer, 1991). 1.3 Theory According to Mankiw and Romer (1991), the real value of the endogenous growth model will emerge from its attempt to model endogenous component of technological progress as an integral part of the theory of economic growth. In this articulation, the implication is that the current technology is insufficient to be a driver of long term economic growth. Thus for any economy, the status quo alluding to knowledge is both unfavourable and undesirable for the occurrence of growth. The endogenous growth theory and its proponents believe improvements in productivity can be linked to a faster pace of innovation and extra investment in human capital. This is in the presence of industrialization, resulting in economy-wide increasing returns to scale (Todaro and Smith, 2013). Each industry produce with perfect returns to scale and each firm’s capital stock include its knowledge which is a public good and spill-over to other firms on the economy. The theoretical notation of the theory is formally presented as: Q = ALαKβ Where: Q = Total production (the monetary value of all goods produced in a year) .L = Labour input K=Capital input A= Total factor productivity 3 α and β are output elasticity for labour and capital, respectively. These values are constants determined by available technology. Output elasticity measures the responsiveness of output to a change in levels of either labour or capital used in production (Todaro and Smith, 2013). For example if α = 0.15, a 1% increase in labour would lead to approximately a 0.15% increase in output. If α + β = 1, the production function has constant returns to scale. That is, if L and K are each increased by 10%, Y increases by 10%. Thus α + β < 1 implies that returns to scale are decreasing. If α + β > 1 returns to scale are increasing (Todaro and Smith, 2013). Romer (1993:81) asserts that, if it is assumed that the number of researchers producing knowledge is constant, the model will predict that all growth is due to technological progress. That is to say the capital-labour (K/L) ratio, the stock of knowledge and output, all grow at a constant rate. Without technical progress, there will be no growth. Proponents of the new endogenous growth theory argued that there is a need to nurture innovativeness and provide a basis for inventiveness. The new growth model predicts positive externalities and spill-over effects from the development of a high valued knowledge economy. Technological change is no longer seen as an “exogenous black box” factor as was implied by the neoclassical models (Muradzikwa et al, 2006: 415). In the new growth theory, the presence of imperfect competition or monopolistic markets is crucial in driving economic growth. It enables a circumstance of increasing returns to factor inputs, thus explains why economic growth has not converged to a steady state as advocated by the neoclassical model. It also explains the existence of divergence and cross country growth comparisons (Lucas, 1990: 92). This is further explained by industrial nations today, where the stock of new capital is increasing at levels far greater than the labour force. Evident in developing countries is that population increases do not lead to increased economic growth rates but actually in developed economies where increased investment has escalated economic growth. The new growth theory refute former notions that large populations are a generator of economic growth (Romer, 1991 in Muradzikwa et al, 2006); instead, technology as an endogenous factor in the production function is the prima facie motor of economic growth. Much in the same vein as this, the neoclassical theory implies that poor nations are supposed to grow at faster rates than rich ones as new investment is far from reaching its level of diminishing marginal returns and the 4 labour force is still experiencing positive growth. This implies an eventual convergence towards world -wide steady state. Empirical evidence, on the other hand, shows the opposite that is a widening gap between rich and poor countries (Lucas, 1990: 93). In a nutshell, the addition of knowledge as factor of production raises the return on investment, which made Romer (1993) to conclude that there are five basic facts that can be attributed to economic growth: i. There are many firms in a market economy, thus there is essentially competition. ii. Discoveries differ from other inputs that many people can use at the same time. This fact means that information or knowledge is a non-rival good; every firm or agent can utilize knowledge at a given time. iii. Physical attributes can be replicated. In competitive market economy, the production function has homogeneity of degree one. iv. Technological advances require people and their effort. Technological change does not occur solely with the advance of time but through human activities and discoveries. v. Many individuals and firms have power and earn monopoly rents on ideas and knowledge. This information can be excludable, at least temporarily. This allows firms a certain monopoly power. 2. Implications of the New Endogenous Growth Theory 2.1 Human capital. New growth models suggest that investment in human capital may have significant positive externalities. Not only does education allow individuals to adapt faster to new technologies, it also allows for higher specialization in higher occupations and thus higher returns (Helpman, Elhanan and Rangel, 1999). Furthermore, it facilitates the accumulation of knowledge through learning by doing. Knowledge therefore provides a strong rationale for investment in education and training. 5 2.2 Public infrastructure. Investment in public infrastructure may raise the productivity of private capital. This includes both materials such as roads and railways and immaterial such as education and property rights (Helpman and Rangel, 1999). 2.3 Research and development. Research and development allows for new and better products. Success of research and development is dependent on the level of human capital and structures that provide incentives to innovate and invent; thus engage in research. High levels of human capital encourage a faster diffusion of knowledge and technology. Well educated people learn faster. Incentives such as patents allow for return on research and development (Helpman, Elhanan and Rangel, 1999). 2.4 Trade reform International trade increased the size of the market and in turn the extent of competition in the goods market. Increased market size allows for larger amounts of devotement to research and development and for greater returns to this investment. It may also allow for the exploitation of economies of scale. Increased competition forces firms and individuals to continuously innovate and stay ahead (Muradzikwa et al, 2006: 417). 3. Empirical Evidence Empirical analysis on the NGT and the growth process is made subject to an assessment of growth determinants. 3.1 Investment Using cross country regression for five industrialised countries for the period 1870-1987 and in twenty –four OECD countries for the period 1950-1992, Xu (2000) finds a positive long- run effect of investment on growth for four industrialized countries and fourteen OECD countries. Bond et al (2004) utilised time series annual data in 98 countries for the period 1960-1998 in prediction of investment and output growth rate per worker. In the short run, an increase in the 6 share of investment yields a higher growth rate of output per worker in the steady state. In the long-run investment was found to be statistically significant in explaining growth. Bosworth and Collins (2003) concluded on the usefulness of capital stock to investment rate in explaining output growth. R2 for capital stock was found to be high in the regression analysis results, as compared to a very little correlation on mean investment rate. 3.2 Trade Openness Theoretical literature on endogenous growth provides three mechanisms through which trade openness may affect growth, namely the domestic rate of innovation, amount of technology that can be transferred and the adoption of technologies from more advanced countries (Cameron, Proudman and Redding, 1998). Sachs and Warner (1995) investigated on the importance of trade openness as a major determinant of cross country growth. Economic indicators where used to distinguish between closed and open economies. Results of the study suggested that openness is important because it allows poor countries to catch up with the rich, whereas being closed to trade results in stagnation at the lower income level. An empirical study of growth through trade in Nigeria for the period from 1975-2012 was carried by Ibraheem et al (2013). OLS regression analysis was used as an estimation technique. Results of the study indicate that total trade, FDI flow and exchange rate contributed positively to growth, while degree of openness of the economy was found to have contributed negatively to growth. 3.3 Institutional Quality (Human Capital) La Porta, et al (2004) examined the different patterns of growth for North and South Korea. The debate was based on whether or not political institutions cause growth, and was made in the line of institutional view against development view. They argued that majority indexed of institutional quality were unsuitable to test the institutional growth- nexus and the instrumental variable techniques used to control for endogeneity were conducive to flawed regressions. In the conclusion, education (human capital accumulation) and wealth where found to result in institutional evolution. Poor countries where pitied for dodging the poverty traps in the quest of 7 alluding policies meant to promote human capital accumulation and pro-market mechanisms devoted to assure property rights. Arabi and Abdalla (2013) investigated on the impact of human capital on economic growth in Sudan for the period 1982-2009. A simultaneous model which employed the three -stage least squares technique was utilized. The model envisaged human capital with a proxy of school attainment, investment in education and health to economic growth, total productivity, foreign direct investment and human development index. Empirical results of the study showed that quality of education and health quality factor has a determinant role on economic growth. Total factor productivity which represented state of technology and human development were found to have a negative effect on economic growth. Obsolescence of technology was incriminated for the adverse effect. 3.4 Research and Development For the period 1971-1990, Coe and Helpman (1995) investigated on the effect of R&D on domestic and foreign economy for 21 OECD countries. They constructed for every country of their sample, a stock of domestic knowledge based on R&D expenditure and a foreign R&D capital stock. Results of the study showed that smaller countries benefit from foreign R&D more than large countries. Belgium was the largest beneficial followed by Ireland, Netherlands and Israel. R&D expenditure was also found to have a major impact in raising productivity in foreign countries and in the domestic economy. Coe et al, 1997 in support of his previous work on international R&D spill-overs, provided on quantitative estimates of international spill-overs for a group of 77 countries by examining the extent to which less developed countries with low R&D benefit from R&D performed in industrial countries. The period of study was from 1971-1990. The model was specified distinctively from Coe and Helpman (1995). The specification of the regression equation included a proxy for human capital, foreign R&D only is considered and the trade openness is connoted with the ratio of imports of machinery and equipment from industrial countries to GDP. Results of the study suggest that all the factors in the model specification are responsible for growth of developing countries. 8 Using theoretical and empirical evidence for the period 1975-2000 for US manufacturing industry data, Minniti and Venturini (2014) investigated on R&D policy in promoting innovation and economic growth for the US (Schumpeterian Growth). Results of the study indicated that R&D policy has a persistent impact on the rate of economic growth and the US economy rapidly adjusted to policy changes. The impact of R&D tax credits on economic growth appears to be long lasting and statically robust. R&D subsidies were associated with an increase in economic growth in the short run indicating that the policy instrument had a temporary effect. 4 Conclusions Different economic growth determinants have been reviewed to highlight on the suitability of the NGT in explaining growth. The conclusions are commonly coherent at the global and regional level and less contested than during the Solow era. Regardless of this phenomenon, econometric results are still object to criticism. New challenges on NGT emanate on growth determinants, significance, how to cope with model uncertainty, availability of data and non-linearity in growth econometrics. Continuous improvement of data quality aspects on R&D, trade and financial indicators is necessary for successful continuous application of the model in economic growth. 9 5 References Arabi, K.A.M, Abdalla, S.Z.S. (2013). The Impact of Human Capital on Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Sudan, Research in World Economy, 4 (2), 1-20. Bond, R, Hoeffler, A., Temple, J. (2001). GMM Estimation of Empirical Growth Models: CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 3048, November. Bosworth, B, Collins, SM. (2003). The Empirics of Growth: An Update, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 113-206. Cameron, G, Proudman, J, Redding, S. (1998). Productivity Convergence and International Openness, Bank of England Working Paper 77. Coe, D, Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D Spill-Overs, European Economic Review, 39, 840-888. Coe, D, Helpman, E, Hoffmaister, A.W. (1997). North and South R&D Spill-Overs, Economic Journal, 107, 130-149. Helpman, E, Elhanan, P, Rangel, L. (1999). Adjustments to New Technology: Experience and Training. Journal of Economic Growth, 4(4), 359-360. Ibraheem, N.K, Oluseyi, A., Bukola, O.H, Babatunde, A.M. (2013). Arabian Journal of Business and Management Review, 3 (5), 2-14. La Porta R, Lopez-de-Sinales F, Shleifer, A, Vishny, R.W. (1998). Law and Finance, Journal of Political Economy 106, 1110-1116. Lucas RE. (1990). Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 80 (2), 92-93 Mankiw, NG, Romer, D., Weil, DN. (1991). A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth, NY: McGraw-Hill 10 Minniti, A, Venturini, F. (2014). R&D Policy and Schumpeterian Growth: Theory and Evidence, Alma Mater Studiorum-Universita di Bologna, Department of Economics, Quaderni- Working Paper DSE N945. Muradzikwa, S, Smith, L, De-Villiers, P. (2006). Economics, Cape Town: Oxford University Southern Africa. Sachs, J, Warner, A. (1995). Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, August, 1-118. Xu, Z. (2000). Financial Development, Investment and Economic Growth, Economic Inquiry, 38 (331-336) 11