Download FRBSF E L CONOMIC ETTER

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Nouriel Roubini wikipedia , lookup

Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup

Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup

Financial crisis wikipedia , lookup

Japanese asset price bubble wikipedia , lookup

Economic bubble wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER
Number 2008-18, June 20, 2008
Speculative Bubbles and Overreaction
to Technological Innovation
Bubbles are often precipitated by perceptions of real improvements in the productivity and underlying profitability
of the corporate economy. But as history attests, investors
then too often exaggerate the extent of the improvement
in economic fundamentals.
— Greenspan (2002)
The magnitude of short-term movements in asset
prices remains a challenge to explain within a framework of rational, efficient markets. Numerous empirical studies have shown that stock prices appear
to exhibit “excess volatility,” that is, prices move too
much to be explained by changes in the underlying
fundamentals, such as dividends or cash flows.Another
prominent feature of asset prices is the intermittent
occurrence of sustained run-ups above estimates of
fundamental value, so-called speculative bubbles, that
can be found throughout history in various countries
and markets (see Lansing 2007).
The dramatic rise in U.S. stock prices during the late
1990s, followed similarly by U.S. house prices during
the mid-2000s, are episodes that have both been
described as bubbles.The former was accompanied
by a boom in business investment, and the latter by a
boom in residential investment. Both booms were
later followed by falling asset prices and severe retrenchments in the associated investment series, as
firms and investors sought to unwind the excess
capital accumulated during the bubble periods.
Coincident booms in asset prices and investment
also occurred during the late 1920s—a period that
shares many characteristics with the late 1990s. In particular, both periods witnessed major technological
innovations that contributed to investor enthusiasm
about a “new era.” This Economic Letter examines
some historical links between speculative bubbles,
technological innovation, and capital misallocation.
Bubbles and new era enthusiasm
Shiller (2000) argues that investors overreact to
technological innovations. He shows that major stock
price run-ups have generally coincided with the
emergence of some superficially plausible “new era”
theory in the popular culture that extols the virtues
of new technology. New era economic thinking is
then used to justify a meteoric rise in asset prices and
the abandonment of traditional valuation metrics.
Figure 1 depicts four major run-ups in the real
(inflation-adjusted) S&P 500 stock index. Shiller
associates each run-up with the following technological advances that contributed to new era enthusiasm:
–Early 1900s: High-speed rail travel, transatlantic
radio, long-line electrical transmission.
–1920s: Mass-production of automobiles, travel by
highways and roads, commercial radio broadcasts,
widespread electrification of manufacturing.
–1950s and 60s:Widespread introduction of television, advent of the suburban lifestyle, space travel.
–Late 1990s:Widespread availability of the internet,
innovations in computers and information technology, emergence of the web-based business model.
In comparing the late 1920s with the late 1990s,
Gordon (2006) and White (2006) emphasize the
simultaneous occurrence of major technological
innovations, a productivity revival, excess capital
investment, and a stock market bubble fueled by
speculation.The September 7, 1929, edition of Business
Week remarked, “For five years at least, American
business has been in the grip of an apocalyptic holyrolling exaltation over the unparalleled prosperity of
the ‘new era’ upon which we, or it, or somebody has
entered.” Along similar lines, the March 8, 1999,
cover story of Business Week proclaimed,“The hightech industry is on the cusp of a new era in computing in which digital smarts won’t be tied up in
Figure 1
Real S&P 500 index (in logarithms)
FRBSF Economic Letter
a mainframe, minicomputer, or PC. Instead, computing will come in a vast array of devices aimed
at practically every aspect of our daily lives.”
2
Number 2008-18, June 20, 2008
Figure 2
Real business investment and real stock price index
(each series normalized to 100 at investment peak)
Business investment and the stock bubble
From 1996 until its peak in 2000, real business investment expanded at an average compound growth rate
of 10% per year—about 2.5 times faster than the
growth rate of the U.S. economy as a whole. Much
of the surge in business investment in the late 1990s
was linked to computers and information technology.
During these years, measured productivity growth
picked up, which was often cited as evidence of a
permanent structural change—one that portended
faster trend growth going forward.Widespread belief
in the so-called “new economy” caused investors to
bid up stock prices to unprecedented levels relative
to corporate earnings.
The investment boom of the late 1990s now appears
to have been overdone. Firms overinvested in new
productive capacity in an effort to satisfy a level
of demand for their products that proved to be unsustainable. Gordon (2003) documents the many
transitory factors that boosted the demand for technology products during the late 1990s.These include:
telecom industry deregulation, the one-time invention of the World Wide Web, the surge in equipment
and software demand from the now-defunct dotcoms,
and a compressed personal computer replacement
cycle heading into Y2K.
Caballero et al. (2006) argue that rapidly rising stock
prices provided firms with a low-cost source of funds
from which to finance their investment projects.The
resulting surge in capital accumulation served to
increase measured productivity growth which, in
turn, helped to justify the enormous run-up in stock
prices. Figure 2 shows that the trajectory of the
S&P 500 stock index, both before and after the
bubble peak, is strikingly similar to the trajectory of
business investment.
On January 13, 2000, near the peak of the stock
bubble, Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan raised the
possibility that investors might have overreacted to
recent productivity-enhancing innovations: “When
we look back at the 1990s, from the perspective of
say 2010...[w]e may conceivably conclude from that
vantage point that, at the turn of the millennium, the
American economy was experiencing a once-in-acentury acceleration of innovation, which propelled
forward productivity, output, corporate profits, and
stock prices at a pace not seen in generations, if ever.
Alternatively, that 2010 retrospective might well
conclude that a good deal of what we are currently
experiencing was just one of the many euphoric
speculative bubbles that have dotted human history.
And, of course, we cannot rule out that we may look
back and conclude that elements from both scenarios have been in play in recent years.”
Residential investment and the housing bubble
Figure 3 shows that one can observe similar comovement between asset prices and investment in the
U.S. housing market. From 2001 to 2006, house prices
nearly doubled, rising much faster than the underlying fundamentals, as measured by rents or household
income. An accommodative interest rate environment, combined with a proliferation of new mortgage
products (loans with little or no down payment,
minimal documentation of income, and payments for
interest-only or less), helped fuel the run-up in house
prices. At the time, Fed Chairman Greenspan (2005)
offered the view that the financial services sector had
been dramatically transformed by advances in information technology, thus enabling lenders “to quite
efficiently judge the risk posed by individual applicants and to price that risk appropriately.” Feldstein
(2007), citing a number of studies, argues that the
rapid growth in subprime lending during these years
was driven in part by “the widespread use of statistical risk assessment models by lenders.”
The subprime lending boom was later followed by
a sharp rise in delinquencies and foreclosures, the
collapse of numerous mortgage lenders, massive writedowns in the value of securities backed by subprime
mortgages, and record-setting levels of unsold new
homes. In retrospect, enthusiasm for a “new era” in
credit risk modeling appears to have been overdone.
Persons (1930 pp. 118–119) describes the fallout from
an earlier era of rapid credit expansion as follows:
“It is highly probable that a considerable volume of
sales recently made were based on credit ratings only
justifiable on the theory that flush times were to
FRBSF Economic Letter
Figure 3
Real residential investment and real house price index
(each series normalized to 100 at investment peak)
3
Number 2008-18, June 20, 2008
lation....The discovery of America was made possible
by a loan based on the collateral of Queen Isabella’s
crown jewels, and at interest, beside which even
the call rates of 1919–1920 look coy and bashful.
Financing an unknown foreigner to sail the unknown
deep in three cockleshell boats in the hope of discovering a mythical Zipangu [land of gold] cannot,
by the widest exercise of language, be called a ‘conservative investment.’”
Kevin J. Lansing
Senior Economist
References
continue indefinitely….When the process of expanding credit ceases and we return to a normal
basis of spending each year...there must ensue a
painful period of readjustment.”
Conclusion
History tells us that periods of major technological
innovation are often accompanied by speculative
bubbles as investors overreact to genuine advances
in productivity. Excessive run-ups in asset prices
can have important consequences for the economy
as firms and investors respond to the price signals,
resulting in capital misallocation. Lansing (2008)
shows that even from the narrow perspective of a
theoretical model, it remains an open question
whether speculative behavior is harmful to society.
On the one hand, speculation can magnify the
volatility of economic and financial variables, thus
harming the welfare of those who are averse to uncertainty and fluctuations. On the other hand, speculation can increase investment in risky ventures, thus
yielding benefits to a society that suffers from an
underinvestment problem. It should be noted, of
course, that the theoretical model abstracts from
numerous real-world issues that would affect welfare.
One such issue is financial fraud, which has typically
accompanied historical bubble episodes. Indeed, the
proliferation of fraudulent stock-offering schemes in
England during the famous price run-up of shares
in the South Sea Company led the British government to pass the so-called “Bubble Act” in 1720
(see Gerding 2006).
Regarding the merits of speculation, Meeker (1922,
p. 419), the economist of the New York Stock
Exchange, wrote: “Of all the peoples in history, the
American people can least afford to condemn specu-
[URLs accessed June 2008.]
Caballero, R.J., E. Farhi, and M.L. Hammour. 2006.
“Speculative Growth: Hints from the U.S. Economy.”
American Economic Review 96, pp. 1,159–1,192.
Feldstein, M.S. 2007. “Housing, Credit Markets, and the
Business Cycle.” NBER Working Paper 13471.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w13471
Gerding, E.F. 2006. “The Next Epidemic: Bubbles and
the Growth and Decay of Securities Regulation.”
Connecticut Law Review 38(3), pp. 393–453.
Gordon, R.J. 2003.“Hi-Tech Innovation and Productivity
Growth: Does Supply Create Its Own Demand?”
NBER Working Paper 9437. http://www.nber.org/
papers/w9437
Gordon, R.J. 2006. “The 1920s and the 1990s in Mutual
Reflection.” In The Global Economy in the 1990s, eds.
P.W. Rhode and G.Toniolo. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, pp. 161–192.
Greenspan,A. 2000.“Technology and the Economy.”
Remarks. New York City, January 13. http://www.
federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2000/
200001132.htm
Greenspan, A. 2002. “Economic Volatility.” Remarks.
Jackson Hole, WY, August 30. http://www.
federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002/
20020830/default.htm
Greenspan, A. 2005.“Consumer Finance.” Remarks.
Washington, DC,April 8. http://www.federalreserve.gov/
BoardDocs/speeches/2005/20050408/default.htm
Lansing, K.J. 2007.“Asset Price Bubbles.” FRBSF Economic
Letter 2007-32 (October 26). http://www.frbsf.org/
publications/economics/letter/2007/el2007-32.html
Lansing, K.J. 2008.“Speculative Growth and Overreaction
to Technology Shocks.” FRBSF Working Paper 2008-08.
http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/
2008/wp08-08bk.pdf
Meeker, J.E. 1922. The Work of the Stock Exchange. New
York: Ronald Press.
Persons, C.E. 1930 “Credit Expansion, 1920 to 1929, and
Its Lessons.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 45, 94-130.
Shiller, R.J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
White, E.N. 2006. “Bubbles and Busts:The 1990s in the
Mirror of the 1920s.” In The Global Economy in the
1990s, eds. P.W. Rhode and G.Toniolo. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, pp. 193–217.
ECONOMIC RESEARCH
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF SAN FRANCISCO
PRESORTED
STANDARD MAIL
U.S. POSTAGE
PAID
PERMIT NO. 752
San Francisco, Calif.
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120
Address Service Requested
Printed on recycled paper
with soybean inks
Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Economic Letter
DATE
11/2
11/23
11/30
12/7
12/14
1/18
1/25
2/1
2/8
2/15
2/22
2/29
3/7
3/14
3/21
4/11
4/18
5/9
6/6
6/13
NUMBER
07-33
07-34
07-35
07-36-37
07-38
08-01
08-02
08-03
08-04-05
08-06
08-07
08-08
08-09
08-10
08-11
08-12
08-13-14
08-15
08-16
08-17
TITLE
Labor Force Participation and the Prospects for U.S. Growth
Financial Globalization and Monetary Policy
Fixing the New Keynesian Phillips Curve
The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy
Sovereign Wealth Funds: Stumbling Blocks or Stepping Stones...?
Publishing FOMC Economic Forecasts
Publishing Central Bank Interest Rate Forecasts
2007 Annual Pacific Basin Conference: Summary
Prospects for the Economy in 2008
Recent Trends in Economic Volatility: Conference Summary
Economic Conditions in Singapore and Vietnam: A Monetary...
The Economics of Private Equity Investments: Symposium Summary
Assessing Employment Growth in 2007
The Corporate Bond Credit Spread Puzzle
Falling House Prices and Rising Time on the Market
Are Global Imbalances Due to Financial Underdevelopment...?
The Financial Markets, Housing, and the Economy
Small Business Lending and Bank Competition
Retirement Savings and Decision Errors: Lessons from Behavioral...
Did Large Recalls of Chinese Consumer Goods Lower U.S. Imports...?
AUTHOR
Daly/Regev
Spiegel
Dennis
Yellen
Aizenman/Glick
Rudebusch
Rudebusch
Glick
Yellen
Notzon/Wilson
Yellen
Lopez
Regev
Christensen
Krainer
Valderrama
Yellen
Laderman
Armour/Daly
Candelaria/Hale
Opinions expressed in the Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.This publication is edited by Judith Goff, with
the assistance of Anita Todd. Permission to reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Permission
to photocopy is unrestricted. Please send editorial comments and requests for subscriptions, back copies, address changes, and
reprint permission to: Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, CA
94120, phone (415) 974-2163, fax (415) 974-3341, e-mail [email protected]. The Economic Letter and other publications
and information are available on our website, http://www.frbsf.org.