Download Policy Reforms after the Crisis Norman Chan

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Recession wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Nouriel Roubini wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
367
Policy Reforms after the Crisis
Norman Chan
The title of this session is supposed to be policy reforms after the 2008–09 financial crisis. I think there’s a big question about the title because I’m not quite
sure the crisis is over yet. But in order to discuss policy reforms, it makes a lot
of sense to try to understand the causes of the crisis. If you can’t diagnose the
root causes of the crisis, it will be very hard to try to prescribe the right kind of
medicine to cure the problem.
There are a lot of theories, books, and articles written about the crisis, why
it happened, when it did, and the kind of lessons to be learned. I’m offering an
Asian perspective from Hong Kong, several thousand miles from here. We may
not see things exactly the way you see it here, but I think it’s worthwhile to
offer my perspective on the root cause of the global financial crisis and the more
recent European debt crisis.
Figure 1 shows that the average debt level of the United States, United
Kingdom, Germany, and France in 1980 was 165 percent of GDP. But by 2010,
the average ratio in these industrial countries had risen to roughly 320 percent. The chart also shows that the rising indebtedness of these economies was
attributable sometimes to household debt, sometimes to corporate debt, and
sometimes to government debt. The question it raises for me is, What are the
underlying reasons for this rising indebtedness? Why did people begin borrowing a lot more than they used to?
Many theories place some of the blame on financial innovation, referring
specifically to securitization providing greater ease in obtaining credit, especially households seeking home finance. Interest rates also were following a
declining trend since the 1990s, therefore increasing the affordability of leverage. During this period of great moderation, economic prosperity, job security,
and employment income grew and were taken for granted, which in turn led to
increased excessive risk-taking by households and corporations. Another theory, articulated by Ken Rogoff, is that the widespread practice of giving tax
concessions to companies using finance over equity increased reliance on borrowing and led to excessive leverage.
368 ASIA ECONOMIC POLICY CONFERENCE
ASIA’S ROLE IN THE POST-CRISIS GLOBAL ECONOMY
F i g u r e 1
Rising Indebtedness of Industrial Economies
A United States
B United Kingdom
Percent of GDP
400
Total nonfinancial
Private nonfinancial
Public
1960
1970
300
1980
1990
2000
2010
400
Total nonfinancial
Private nonfinancial
Public
300
200
200
100
100
0
C Germany
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
0
D France
Percent of GDP
400
Total nonfinancial
Private nonfinancial
Public
1985
Percent of GDP
1990
300
1995
2000
2005
2010
Percent of GDP
400
Total nonfinancial
Private nonfinancial
Public
300
200
200
100
100
0
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
0
Source: Bank for International Settlements.
But I would highlight another factor, which I would call market failure. Figure 2 illustrates the Greek situation by plotting the spread of 10-year Greek
common bonds over the German bund together with the level of Greek government debt. During the early part of the 1990s the market demanded a very
high premium for lending to the Greek government, about 18 percent, but this
spread gradually came down as Greece made moves toward joining the euro.
Once Greece joined the euro zone in 2001, the convergence play kicked in, and,
strangely, the market treated Greek sovereign debt as a triple-A rated entity.
In fact, Greece’s spread was only 20 basis points over the bund for a prolonged
period over a couple of years. It’s only after the collapse of Lehman Brothers in
early 2010, when the market suddenly woke up to the fact that the Greek fiscal
position was not sustainable, triggering the European debt crisis.
Some would call this a prolonged period of mispricing of risk, but I would
call it market failure. What does that mean? My view is that this situation
CHAN | PANEL DISCUSSION | POLICY REFORMS AFTER THE CRISIS 369
F i g u r e 2
Market Failure: The Greek Example
ECU/EUR Billions
Basis Points
350
3500
3000
Greek government debt
(right scale)
Greek 10-year sovereign yield
spread over German bund
(left scale)
300
250
2500
January 2001
Greece joined euro
2000
200
1500
150
1000
100
500
50
0
93
94
95
96
97
98
99 00
01
02
03 04 05 06
07
08 09
10
11
0
created tremendous problems for Greece, not only for the capital market and
for creditors, but also for the debtor, Greece. Why? Because Greece for a long
time was under an illusion—based on feedback from the markets—that piling
up bigger and bigger debt was okay, and it was very affordable because the market was demanding only a few 20 basis points over the cost of German bunds. So
borrowing by the government was pretty okay. That led to even weaker fiscal
discipline over the years, and the result, as we now know, has been devastating.
Figure 3 shows the indebtedness of U.S. households, as measured by the
ratio of home mortgage and other consumer debt to disposable income. The
debt-to-income ratio started to rise steadily in the 1980s. The pace picked up
after 2000, mainly due to home finance, not consumer credit. The ratio peaked
at 1.3, compared to a 50-year average of 0.8. After the bursting of the housing bubble in 2006 and 2007, household balance sheets were badly damaged.
To repair the balance sheets, households need to deleverage, save more, and
spend less unless there’s a rapid growth in household income, which is not happening yet. So in my view, household deleveraging in the United States will still
have some way to go, although I cannot tell at what level it will reach a stable
equilibrium.
370 ASIA ECONOMIC POLICY CONFERENCE
ASIA’S ROLE IN THE POST-CRISIS GLOBAL ECONOMY
F i g u r e 3
U.S. Balance Sheet Recession
Household Deleveraging Still Ongoing
Ratio to Disposable Income
1.3
Home Mortgage Debt
Other Consumer Debt
1.2
1.1
1.0
0.9
50-year long-run average = 0.8
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: CEIC.
Figure 4 shows the Case-Schiller index for 20 U.S. cities, together with
the inventory of existing homes and the shadow home inventory estimated by
Standard and Poor’s. As we know, since the bursting of the housing bubble,
house prices have come down quite a lot in many places, but the housing market
remains very weak, and there’s no short-term prospect of a rebound because
of this supply overhang. The supply overhang is daunting, and adds up to 16
months of supply. Of course this is a dynamic relationship, because if investor appetites pick up, the inventory will come down very quickly. Nevertheless,
this is a depressing situation because the housing market is very weak, and
has become a huge negative drag in repairing household balance sheets. That,
in turn, has a negative drag on consumption and consumer confidence. I think
this explains my view of why large fiscal stimulus packages and unconventional
monetary easing measures have not created the desired result of sustaining a
stronger economic recovery in the United States.
CHAN | PANEL DISCUSSION | POLICY REFORMS AFTER THE CRISIS 371
F i g u r e 4
U.S. Balance Sheet Recession
Huge Drag from Housing Inventory
Months
70
60
Index (Jan 2000=100)
220
Shadow Home Inventory (left scale)
Existing Home Inventory (left scale)
Case-Shiller 20-city Price Index (right scale)
200
50
180
40
160
30
140
20
120
10
0
2000
100
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Sources: CEIC, Standard and Poor’s.
So, what are the policy lessons? First, avoid excessive borrowing, clearly,
because it was the reason for the 2008–09 crisis and the current crisis facing
Europe. Of course, that’s easier said than done, because many fiscal authorities around the world have, until recently, faced a lot of political pressure to
increase spending in good times. And in bad times they have even more reasons
to increase spending. As a result, public debt has piled up along with the problem of sustainability and fiscal position. But, given what we’ve seen in Europe,
we hope we have learned from this latest crisis that even the biggest and most
advanced economies in the world are not immune from the devastation that can
result from excessive indebtedness.
The second point I want to mention as a policy lesson is to beware of the
breakdown of market discipline, which is supposed to be the final line of defense
for preventing excessive borrowing. Market discipline can and did break down
for a considerable period of time during the crisis, thereby exacerbating the
problem of excessive leverage.
372 ASIA ECONOMIC POLICY CONFERENCE
ASIA’S ROLE IN THE POST-CRISIS GLOBAL ECONOMY
The third point about quality and effective market regulatory structure has
been talked about by many. There’s a long menu of things to do on this particular point, but I think the priority is to work on rating agencies. The problem in
the United States was amplified by the flawed models used by the rating agencies in assessing the creditworthiness of some exotic financial derivative products, such as CDOs, CDO-square, and CDO-cube. The Basel committee has
done a lot of work to raise the quality and quantity of capital—they talk about
capital buffer, conservation buffer, and also the liquidity coverage ratio and stable funding ratio. All of these are designed to reduce excessive leveraging by
the financial sector and thereby in the economy, and maintain financial stability.
I’m not sure my fourth point is generally understood or accepted. I think
because the root cause of the crisis is excessive leveraging, the only way out
is deleveraging. Deleveraging is painful, but it’s inevitable. Speaking from
the Hong Kong perspective, we had a big, exaggerated housing bubble. When
the bubble burst after the Asian financial crisis in 1997, we had fast and huge
de­leveraging in the Hong Kong financial system. It was very painful, I can
assure you that. GDP contracted in Hong Kong in five quarters by 8.7 percent.
The unemployment rate rose from 2.1 percent to 8.5 percent; deflation, over five
years, amounted to a cumulative 15 percent, and housing prices fell 70 percent.
So, a huge pain was inflicted on Hong Kong and the Hong Kong economy. But
we have recovered and become a stronger, more resilient economy.
My final point is that deleveraging itself is not enough. Deleveraging must
be accompanied by restructuring at the same time, because the financial system and the real economy must be restructured to generate greater productivity and competitiveness going forward.