Download PDF

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economics of digitization wikipedia , lookup

Heckscher–Ohlin model wikipedia , lookup

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Criticisms of the labour theory of value wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Determining Willingness to Adopt Mechanical Harvesters among Southeastern Blueberry
Producers
Blueberry consumption in the U.S. has increased threefold over the decade from 2000 to 2010
followed by a fourfold increase in acreage plantings in the Southeastern region (Perez et al.,
2011; Morgan et al., 2011). During the same period, the machine harvesting technology of high
value Southeastern blueberry cultivars, such as Rabbiteye (Vaccinium ashei) and Southern
Highbush (Vaccinium corymbosum X darowii) destined for the fresh market has also improved.
Fresh market blueberry harvesting in the Southeast is generally characterized by high demand for
large workforces needed to hand pick each ripened blueberry over a six to eleven week ripening
window. Labor costs are estimated to be as high as 1,300 worker hours/hectare, representing
about 60 percent of average operating costs (Brown et al. 1983; Safley, Cline, and Mainland,
2006).
Previous studies have shown that shortages of agricultural workers, either through
attrition or immigration enforcement mechanisms, lead to increases in agricultural worker wages,
and an increased interest in labor saving machine technologies (Borjas, 2003; Zahniser et al.
2008). These factors accompanied by the improvement in the technology of blueberry harvesters
have made machine harvesting a viable alternative to manual harvesting. The objective of this
study is to determine factors motivating the adoption of mechanical harvesting (MH) technology
among blueberry farmers in the Southeast. The study uses survey and wage data from the four
largest Southeastern blueberry growing states of Florida, Georgia, Mississippi, and North
Carolina. The unique contribution of the study to the existing literature on significant factors that
influence agricultural technology adoption patterns is the inclusion of historical wage variation
as a proxy for labor uncertainty related to worker attrition or enforcement related worker
shortages.
Background Information on Southeastern Blueberry Industry
Southeastern blueberry farmers allocate their land between two primary cultivars, Rabbiteye and
Southern Highbush, for their characteristics and ripening windows. Because commercial
blueberries are self-sterile, farmers then select two or more varieties within that cultivar based on
chilling hour restrictions, soil preferences, and pollination capabilities. The native Rabbiteye
cultivar has a mature orchard life of between 20 to 25 years with five years from planting until
full production, and five years of declining production. A Southeastern U.S. rabbiteye orchard
may yield between 6,000 and 10,000 lbs/acre per year in its prime production years, with
variations largely dependent on weather conditions and management intensity. Rabbiteye
varieties ripen between April to August in the Southeast, with Florida harvest starting in early
April and moving north and east as the spring and summer progresses. Southern Highbush
cultivars also have an orchard life of between 20-25 years, but the plants are smaller, not as
vigorous, and more sensitive to organic matter and low pH levels. Southern Highbush varieties
may yield between 3,000 to 8,000 lbs/acre per year in prime production years, with variations
largely dependent on weather conditions and management intensity. Southern Highbush ripens
earlier than Rabbiteye and is available for the fresh market from March to June in the Southeast.
The fruit of the Southern Highbush cultivar is often bigger and has a softer flesh and skin, thus
more suited to the fresh market but more easily bruised, than the rabbiteye fruit (Braswell et al.,
2009).
Modern, over the row, mechanical Blueberry harvesters, such as the Korvan or BEI
series, run every five to seven days with three to five passes per orchard for each cultivar. A
similar harvesting schedule is followed if hand harvesting. The price of a mechanical harvester
ranges between $100,000 to $200,000 depending on functionality, and has a useful lifespan of
around 20 years. Mechanically harvested fruit shows a 31.6 percent decrease in price per flat for
fresh blueberries and a 49.1 percent decrease in price per lb. for processed blueberries versus
hand harvested fruit (Safley, Cline, and Mainland, 2006). Because harvesting machines are
inferior to hand-picking in terms of discerning between ripe and unripe berries, average machine
harvesters yield is 70 percent of average hand-picking yields due to droppage (Morgan, et
al.2011). Furthermore, while mechanical blueberry harvesters are considered a labor saving
technology, there is still a need for a human workforce to break the berry clusters prior to the
onset of the marketable harvest process. Laborers are needed for grading, sorting, and cleaning
remnants of berries broken from mechanical tines within a berry cluster.
The price per pound received by the producer declines as the harvest season progresses
throughout the year, with Floridian Southern Highbush receiving the highest price per pound for
domestic blueberries in March, and prices decreasing as other Southeastern regions begin
producing. By mid-summer Southeastern blueberry farmers are competing with Northern, Great
Lakes, and Western blueberry regions and farm-gate prices continue their decline (Williamson
and Lyrene, 2004). Thus, there is an incentive for profit maximizing blueberry producers to
harvest fresh market blueberries as early in their respective season as possible to take advantage
of early season prices.
For most of the 50 year history of cultivated blueberry production in the Southeast, there
has been a relatively accessible, documented, undocumented, or H2-A 1 work visa workforce for
hand harvesting during the spring and summer seasons (Martin, 2003). By 2007, 75 percent of
the hired farmworkers in the fruit, vegetable, and horticulture crops (FVH, includes berries) were
undocumented despite the creation of the E-Verify system ten years earlier by the Illegal
Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996 (IIRIRA) (Calvin and Martin,
2010). In fact IIRIRA has not effectively decreased the supply of undocumented farmworkers,
nor increased the supply of native born workers, but has increased the burden of potential fines
for hiring undocumented farmworkers on producers, increasing their financial liability
(Devadoss and Luckstead, 2008). National legislation such as IIRARA coupled with state
legislations, such as the 2011 Beason-Hammon Alabama Taxpayer and Citizen Protection Act,
Senate Bill 56 which caused 40,000 to 80,000 undocumented and documented Alabama laborers
to leave the workforce, cause FVH producers to worry about farm labor shortages. These labor
shortages in turn induce labor wage increases and lead producers to reevaluate their production
methods toward labor saving mechanization (Passel and Cohn, 2011; Huffman, 2012).
Anecdotally, the Congressional testimony of Georgia blueberry farmer C. Horner in 2011
demonstrates the difficulties blueberry farmers in the Southeast have with labor scarcity; he
testified that even after hiring native workers and applying for H2-A work visa authorized
workers, he was still forced to hire 60 unauthorized farmworkers of the 67 needed to harvest his
blueberry orchard (Horner, 2011).
1
H2-A work visas are temporary visas granted by petition “for agricultural employers who anticipate a shortage of domestic
workers to bring nonimmigrant foreign workers to the U.S. to perform agricultural labor or services of a temporary or seasonal
nature.” (U.S. Department of Labor, 2009).
Previous Work
Hicks (1932) proposed the hypothesis of induced innovation as a way to demonstrate that
increases in the prices of factors of production incentivize innovations in order to decrease those
specific factor costs. This hypothesis is often used in the context of factor prices for labor
spurring labor saving innovations. Samuelson (1965) observes the tautology of Hick’s (1932)
hypothesis in a dynamic setting: a rational cost-minimizing entrepreneur will eventually choose
factors of production that minimize costs. Samuelson advanced Hick’s theory by postulating that
capital relative to labor as a ratio of the factors of production induces innovation, rather than
Hick’s notion that labor and capital are perfect substitutes and innovations are introduced as a
way for a profit maximizing entrepreneur to minimize labor costs. Samuelson demonstrated that
an entrepreneur experiences long-run equilibrium when both factors of the capital/labor ratio are
increasing. Thus, as there exists a long-term trend of increasing costs of labor, research into
innovations that are either labor saving or labor augmenting are necessary to maintain
capital/labor ratio equilibrium. He suggested that all machines are in fact invented to improve
efficiency, but also that machines do not work in a vacuum and require human operators in order
to be truly profit maximizing.
Kislev and Petersen (1981) hypothesized that there are two main reasons for the switch
from manual labor in agriculture to machine labor. These reasons are technical changes in
agriculture that are developed by agricultural researchers to render labor less efficient than
machines, and manual laborers leave the agricultural sector as a market phenomenon due to
wage increases in a substitute labor sector (such as construction or service), and as a result
agricultural operators are forced to switch from manual labor to machinery. However, Kislev
and Petersen (1981) fail to recognize the causal effect of the switch from manual labor to
machine labor in agriculture: low wage, low skill labor being coerced out of the market due to
governmental policies regarding low-skill immigration and immigration status enforcement.
Marra, Pannell, and Abadi Ghadim (2003) emphasize that there is not a unifying theory
on risk preferences, uncertainty, and adoption of agricultural innovations. Studies such as
Shapiro, Brorsen, and Doster (1992) discovered that adopters of double cropping techniques
were more likely to be self-described as risk averse which directly contradicts Marra and
Carlson’s (1990) findings that adopters of double cropping are less likely to be risk averse using
an Arrow-Pratt risk formula based on perceived variability in prices and quantities.
Straub (2009) suggests that adoption is not just an individual act, but also has a social
context based on emotional and cognitive concerns. Individuals make their adoption decisions
based on the perception of the technology that they have constructed, which is molded by their
communication and socioeconomic status. Thus, early adopters are often distinguished from late
adopters by having access to broader amounts of information, higher socioeconomic status,
higher educational attainment levels, and are less risk averse than their counterparts.
Napasintuwong and Emerson (2004) used a Morishima Elasticity of Substitution (MES)
model to demonstrate changes in price and quantity ratios on relative factor share. They
conclude that capital (mechanization) is a substitute for both self-employed labor and hired labor
in the Florida agricultural market, particularly when the prices of labor increase due to
immigration legislation. However, if capital becomes less expensive due to innovation and
availability and is adopted, labor becomes a complement of capital and employment could also
rise.
Zahniser, Hertz, Dixon, and Rimmer (2008) used a simulation based model to look at the
effects immigration legislation would have on the agricultural sector and the implications for the
substitution of farm machinery for labor. They estimate that there is almost zero substitution
between foreign born farmworkers (authorized or unauthorized) and native born farm workers.
Thus, simulated policies that affect immigration, particularly unauthorized farm labor, would
decrease the long-run agricultural output of the U.S. by 1.7-3.5 percent. Furthermore,
agricultural sectors that rely heavily on farm labor, like FVH, would experience larger decreases
in output and exports than non-labor intensive sectors like oilseeds and grains.
Borjas (2003) used simulation based models to generate wage effects of a purely native
born male workforce from 1980 to 2000. He then compared those simulated wage effects with
the actual wage data using a native and immigrant (documented and undocumented) workforce
over the same period. During that period, Borjas (2003) calculated an eleven percent increase in
the labor supply of working males and estimated an own factor price elasticity for labor between
-0.3 and -0.4. Borjas (2003) distinguishes workers by their level of educational attainment and
notes that employment competition between natives and immigrants exist exclusively within the
parameters of these levels. Within the lowest level of educational attainment, high school
dropouts, he states that the immigration influx from 1980 to 2000 decreased wages by 8.9
percent for this group.
Calvin and Martin (2010) use Borjas’ (2003) simulations to demonstrate that historical
influxes of immigrant farmworkers lead to a decrease in overall farmworker wages to the benefit
of capital owners by an estimated $8 billion annually. However, due to enforcement
mechanisms on farmworkers such as E-Verify, increased border enforcement and deportations,
and local legislation such as Alabama SB56, wages demanded by farmworkers have recently
increased, renewing interest in mechanical harvesters.
Daberkow and McBride (2003) researched the adoption decisions of American farmers to
precision agriculture (PA) technologies using a logistic regression model to determine farm and
producer characteristics of those who adopt. They categorize their independent variables into
farm size, human capital, risk and risk preference, tenure, labor supply with regards to income,
credit constraints, and location factors.
With regards to farm size Just and Zilberman (1983) determined that the fixed expenses
of lumpy agricultural technology adoption can often dissuade smaller landholders from adopting
new technologies as compared to larger landholder’s adoption decisions. They surmise that
larger landholders often have the ability to experiment with the technology on a portion of their
fields before complete adoption, in effect testing the technology, while smaller landholders feel
required to use the technology on their entire operation if the technology is a large fixed expense.
With regards to educational attainment Koundouri, Nauges, and Tzouvelekas (2006) use
a two-stage Probit model to determine that levels of education are significant in modeling
irrigation adoption decisions among Greek currant farmers. They correlate educational
attainment to extension service visits and information access and find positive significance to the
probability of adopting irrigation technologies. Koundouri, Nauges, and Tzouvelekas (2006)
infer that higher educational attainment and access to extension information decreases the value
of waiting to adopt a technology until another farmer has tested it.
With regards to off-farm income Fernandez-Cornejo, Hendricks, and Mishra (2005)
modeled the adoption decision process of converting to herbicide tolerant (HT) soybeans in the
U.S. using a variety of human capital variables. They found significance with age, number of
children in the household, farm typology, and off-farm income. Fernandez-Cornejo, Hendricks,
and Mishra (2005) concluded that the probability of adoption of HT soybeans is positively
explained by off-farm income, and that the elasticity of off-farm income with respect to the
probability of adoption is close to one. While adopting HT soybean seed is divisible, as opposed
to adopting a lumpy agriculture technology, the findings concerning off-farm income constitute a
contribution to adoption literature in American agriculture.
Ghadim, Pannell, and Burton (2005) use Tobit and probit modeling to distinguish
between risk perceptions and risk preferences and assert that both are significant factors in
explaining adoption decisions, according to their study on chickpea adoption in Australia. They
found that risk-averse farmers tended away from adoption of a complementing chickpea crop.
They also suggested farmers believed that the risk associated with chickpea adoption is greater
than the benefits of crop diversification, thus the perception of the risks associated with chickpea
adoption is significant.
With regards to credit constraints Feder (1980) states that the larger the credit constraint
associated with either the technology being adopted or the factors of production, the more risk
averse the farmer becomes decreasing the probability of adoption. Conversely, the presence of
credit availability increases the probability of adoption by the farmer, as well as investing in a
larger farm.
Data and Methods
Data for this study was collected from a 2011 Blueberry Industry Survey of the Southeastern
Region. It was distributed through mail from February 22, 2011 to March 1, 2011 to 692
members of blueberry grower associations in Florida, Georgia, North Carolina and Mississippi,
states which represent the majority of blueberry production in the Southeast. Of the 692
blueberry farms that were mailed surveys, 234 responded for a response rate of 33.8 percent.
The 2007 Census of Agriculture calculated 2,145 blueberry farms in the Florida, Georgia, North
Carolina and Mississippi, thus the 234 respondents to the Blueberry Industry Survey represent
10.9 percent of blueberry farms in these select states. Additionally, the 2007 Census of
Agriculture estimated 20, 792 acres of tame blueberries within the four selected states. The 234
survey respondents aggregated blueberry acreage is 12,386 acres, which represents 59.6 percent
of total blueberry acreage in the four surveyed states. (USDA Census of Agriculture, 2009).
Wage data was acquired from Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS)
Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages (QCEW). The wage data represents county level
average weekly wage data reported quarterly based on the North American Industry
Classification System (NAICS). This study used the Natural Resources and Mining industry
supersector, which includes the agriculture industry subset, NAICS 11, being the only county
level quarterly wage data available (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2013). The data was
collected from 2001 to 2010 for the harvest period which for the Southeast is the second and
third calendar quarters. The quarterly data was then weighted according to Cooperative
Extension publications on blueberries harvesting times to generate a harvest-period average
wage for each state. Florida wage data is only represented by the second quarter (April through
June) wage data (Williamson and Lyrene, 2004). Georgia wage data is a weighted average of 75
percent second quarter and 25 percent third quarter wage data (Scherm and Krewer, 2003).
Mississippi (Braswell et al., 2009) and North Carolina (Safley, Cline and Mainland, 2006) wage
data are simple averages of second quarter and third quarter wage data.
Methodology
Producers are assumed to be rational-decision makers and utility maximizer with regard
to their technology adoption decision. Random utility theory as presented by McFadden (1980)
indicates that perceived utility is maximized conditional to economic constraints. This perceived
utility is measured individually for choice j using the following model:
=
xij′ β + ε ij
(1) U
ij
where U ij is the utility of individual i using the choice j , xij is a vector of farm and farmer
characteristics augmented with other important economic variables used in the labor-saving
technology decision process, β is a vector of parameters, and ε ij is the random disturbance term
associated with choice j . The probability that choice j is made is simply stated as
Pr(U ij > U ik ) for all j ≠ k as a function of explanatory variables in a discrete choice process. This
discrete choice process:
(2)
1, if U ij > U ik ; mechanical harvesters are adopted and utilized
Yi = 
0, otherwise; mechanical harvesters are not adopted
is modeled using a binary logistic regression (logit) model. This binary logit model then
provides probabilities of MH technology adoption using the discrete choice and the vector of
explanatory variables. The binary logit model estimates likelihood of adoption using:
n
(3)
 n

Prob(=
Yi 1=
x) L  ∑ x′β
=

 i =1

∑ x′β
e i=1
n
∑ x′β
1 + e i=1
where L() represents a logistic distribution (Liao, 1994). Using this specification, we can
estimate the expected probabilities of both financial characteristics and personal beliefs have on
the mechanical blueberry adoption decision.
Explanatory variables in (3) include farmer characteristics, farm characteristics, financial
characteristics and county-level wage rate. Farmer characteristics include variables like age,
experience, education level, risk preferences. Farm characteristics include labor costs and
production level. The latter is used to account for the fact that the first 3 to 5 years of production
(because early low yields) do not justify MH utilization. Financial characteristics include the
level of financing, on- and off-farm income and transfer of ownership. The average of the
harvest-period wage rate for the last two years prior to 2010 (the year for which the data was
collected in the survey) was also included. Finally, historical standard deviation of wage data is
used as a broad proxy for labor uncertainty. Definitions and summary statistics of variables used
in the logistic regression are presented in Table 1.
Dummy variables for farmers who produce only one or both rabbiteye and Southern
Highbush cultivars are included to control for the differences between the two cultivars, in
particular given that rabbiteye cultivars are historically better suited to machine harvesting.
Results
Preliminary results from the logistic regression show that farmer characteristics such as age and
experience are significant. Further both these variables show a nonlinear relationship with the
likelihood of adoption. In other words, the likelihood of adoption is increasing at a decreasing
rate with both age and experience. Likelihood of adoption increases with increases in
production. The increase is higher in the case when the farmer produces only the rabbiteye
cultivar as compared to producing only the Southern Highbush cultivar or both cultivars. This
finding corroborates extension studies on rabbiteye production and MH technology usage
(Takeda et al. 2008). Willingness to accept risk, as a measure of risk preferences, also has a
positive relationship with the likelihood of adoption similar to previous findings (Ghadim,
Pannell, and Burton, 2005).
For farmers who have both cultivars in production an increase in the standard deviation
of wages increases the likelihood of adoption. This finding supports our hypothesis that
increased variation in wages, indicating increased labor uncertainty, causes an increase in the
likelihood of MH technology adoption. However, increases in harvest-period wages decreases
the likelihood of MH technology adoption. Increases in labor costs also decrease the likelihood
of MH technology adoption. One argument for these findings is that this could be a temporal
bias: the farmer may have already decided to maintain hand harvesting in future seasons,
regardless of labor cost.
Percentage of financed land and establishment costs, gross sales, plans to transfer
ownership, and number of crop insurance purchases all had little explanatory influence. Also the
likelihood of MH technology adoption increases with lower educational attainment levels.
All findings should be noted as preliminary results and not to be used without the authors’
consent.
References
Borjas, G. J. (2003). The labor demand curve is downward sloping: reexamining the impact of
immigration on the labor market. The quarterly journal of economics, 118(4), 1335-1374.
Braswell, John, Steven Stringer, Blair Sampson, and David Ingram. (2009) “Establishment and
Maintenance of Blueberries” Mississippi State Extension Bulletin
Brown, G.K., Marshall, D.E., Tennes, B.R., Booster, D.E., Chen, P.,Garrett, R.E., O'Brien, M., S
tuder, H.E., Kepner R.A., Hedden, S.L., Hood, C.E.,Lenker, D.H., Millier, W.F., Rehkugl
er, G.E., Peterson, D.L., Shaw, L.N. (1983)Status of harvest mechanization of
horticultural crops (Amer. Soc. Agr. Eng,St. Joseph, MI) Paper no. 83-3
Calvin, Linda amnd Philip Martin. (2011) “The U.S. Produce Industry: Labor-Intensive
Commodities in a Global Market” American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 94, no.
3: 471-476
Daberkow, Stan G., and William D. McBride. (2003) "Farm and operator characteristics
affecting the awareness and adoption of precision agriculture technologies in the
US." Precision Agriculture 4.2: 163-177.
Devadoss, Stephen, and Jeff Luckstead. (2008) "Contributions of Immigrant Farmworkers to
California Vegetable Production." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 40.3:
879-94.
Feder, Gershon. "Farm size, risk aversion and the adoption of new technology under
uncertainty." Oxford Economic Papers 32.2 (1980): 263-283.
Fernandez-Cornejo, Jorge, Chad Hendricks, and Ashok Mishra. "Technology adoption and offfarm household income: The case of herbicide-tolerant soybeans." Journal of
Agricultural and Applied Economics 37.3 (2005): 549.
Ghadim, A. K. A., Pannell, D. J., & Burton, M. P. (2005). Risk, uncertainty, and learning in
adoption of a crop innovation. Agricultural Economics, 33(1), 1-9.
Hicks, J. R. (1932). Marginal productivity and the principle of variation.Economica, (35), 79-88.
Horner C. 2011. p. 4. Testimony. Hearing on America’s Agricultural Labor Crisis: Enacting a
Practical Solution. Subcommittee
on Immigration, Refugees, and Border Security
U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Judiciary. October.
Huffman, W. E. (2012). The Status of Labor-Saving Mechanization in US Fruit and Vegetable
Harvesting. Choices, 27(2).
Just, Richard E., and David Zilberman. "Stochastic structure, farm size and technology adoption
in developing agriculture." Oxford Economic Papers 35.2 (1983): 307-328.
Kislev, Yoav, and Willis Peterson. (1981) "Induced innovations and farm
mechanization." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63, no. 3: 562-565.
Koundouri, Phoebe, Céline Nauges, and Vangelis Tzouvelekas. "Technology adoption under
production uncertainty: Theory and application to irrigation technology." American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 88.3 (2006): 657-670.
Liao, T. F. (1994). Interpreting probability models: Logit, probit, and other generalized linear
models (No. 101). Sage.
Marra, M. C., & Carlson, G. A. (1990). The decision to double crop: An application of expected
utility theory using Stein's theorem. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 72(2),
337-345.
Marra, Michele, David J. Pannell, and Amir Abadi Ghadim. (2003)"The economics of risk,
uncertainty and learning in the adoption of new agricultural technologies: where are we
on the learning curve?." Agricultural systems 75, no. 2 : 215-234.
Martin, P., & Calvin, L. (2010). Immigration Reform: What Does It Mean for Agriculture and
Rural America?. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy,32(2), 232-253.
Martin, P. (2003). Managing labor migration: Temporary worker programs for the 21st
century. Institute for Labour Studies. Geneva: ILO.
McFadden, D. (1980). Econometric models for probabilistic choice among products. Journal of
Business, S13-S29.
Morgan, Kimberly, Harald Scherm , Jim Olmstead, Jeff Williamson, Gerard Krewer, Fumi
Takeda, Dan MacLean, Rob Shewfelt, Charlei Li, Anish Malladi and Paul Lyrene (2011)
Cost Comparison of Hand and Mechanical Harvest of new “crispy” flesh Florida
Cultivars. Working Paper
Napasintuwong, Orachos, and Robert D. Emerson. (2004) "Labor Substitutability in Labor
Intensive Agriculture and Technological Change in the Presence of Foreign
Labor." Selected Paper for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics
Association Annual Meeting, Denver, CO. August.
Passel, Jeffrey S., and D. Cohn. (2012) "US foreign-born population: How much change from
2009 to 2010." Pew Research Center, Washington, DC (2012, January) Retrieved from
http://www. pewhispanic. org/files/2012/01/Foreign-Born-Population. pdf.
Perez, A., K. Plattner, K. Baldwin, and E. Dohlman. 2011. “U.S. Citrus Production Forecast up
this Season.” Fruit and Tree Nuts Outlook. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic
Research Service FTS-346.
Safley, Charles D., William O. Cline, and Charles M. Mainland. (2006) "Evaluating the
Profitability of Blueberry Production." Blueberries: For Growers, Gardners and
Promoters : 159.
Samuelson, P. A. (1965). A theory of induced innovation along Kennedy-Weisäcker lines. The
Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(4), 343-356.
Scherm, H., and G. Krewer. "Blueberry production in Georgia: Historical overview and recent
trends." Small Fruits Review 2.4 (2003): 83-91.
Shapiro, B. I., Wade Brorsen, B., & Doster, D. H. (1992). Adoption of double-cropping soybeans
and wheat. Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics, 24, 33-33.
Straub, E. T. (2009). Understanding technology adoption: Theory and future directions for
informal learning. Review of Educational Research, 79(2), 625-649.
Takeda, Fumiomi, Gerard Krewer, Elvin L. Andrews, Benjamin Mullinix, and Donald L.
Peterson. (2008) "Assessment of the V45 blueberry harvester on rabbiteye blueberry and
southern highbush blueberry pruned to v-shaped canopy."HortTechnology 18, no. 1: 130138.
Williamson, J. G., & Lyrene, P. M. (2004). The Florida blueberry industry: A decade of growth.
In Proc. Fla. State Hort. Soc (Vol. 117, pp. 234-235).
Zahniser, Steven, Tom Hertz, Peter Dixon, and Maureen Rimmer. (2012) "Immigration Policy
and its Possible Effects on US Agriculture and the Market for Hired Farm Labor: A
Simulation Analysis." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 94, no. 2: 477-482.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Census of Agriculture. (2009) Table 34: Berries 2007 and 2002.
Accessed August 15, 2013
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2013) Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and
Hunting: NAICS 11. Accessed August 15, 2013
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2013) Quarterly Census of Employment
and Wages 2001-2010. Accessed August 15, 2013
Table 1. Variable Description and Summary Statistics
Variable Description
Type
machine harvested any blueberries in 2010, Y=1
Sample Mean
(s.d.)
Min
Max
0.36(0.48)
0
1
years growing blueberries
continuous
11.59(11.58)
0
75
Total production1
continuous
263.14(694.2)
0
4,814.5
midpoint age from scale, 6=age 65 or older
scale 1-6
55.36(8.96)
21
65
willingness to accept risk, 4=extremely willing
Likert 0-4
2.47(0.98)
0
4
number of blueberry crop insurance purchases in last 10
years, 5=purchased all 10 years
scale 1-5
2.03(1.37)
1
5
percent blueberry land/establishment costs financed
percentage
21.18(34.81)
0
100
percent of family income generated off-farm
percentage
57.16(40.93)
0
100
plan to transfer ownership of operation to a family
member, 1=plan to transfer
dummy
0.67(0.47)
0
1
highest level of education, 6=completed graduate
degree
scale 1-6
3.73(1.37)
1
6
2010 blueberry operation gross sales (before taxes) 2
8=$1M+ gross sales
scale 1-8
211.28(330.15)
10
1000
standard deviation of wages
continuous
67.41(39.64)
17.23
257.89
aggregate of 2009 and 2008 wages
continuous
1,034.87(341.46)
557.2
2365
2009 labor costs3
continuous
24.61(51.81)
0
354.30
farmer has both rabbiteye and SHB
dummy
0.244(0.43)
0
1
Total Production, rabbiteye only4
dummy
13.60(50.28)
0
450.04
number of blueberry crop insurance purchases in last 10
years, rabbiteye only
dummy
0
5
2009 labor costs, rabbiteye only5
dummy
1.96(7.82)
0
97.68
willingness to accept risk, both rabbiteye and SHB
dummy
0.67(1.26)
0
4
Note: 1, 4 measure in 1,000 lb. increments
2
measured in $1,000 increments,
0.41(0.96)
3, 5
measured in $1,000 increments