* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download PDF
Survey
Document related concepts
Infection control wikipedia , lookup
Childhood immunizations in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Transmission (medicine) wikipedia , lookup
African trypanosomiasis wikipedia , lookup
Germ theory of disease wikipedia , lookup
Sociality and disease transmission wikipedia , lookup
Transcript
Policy Tools for Managing Biological Pollution Risks from Trade Carson J. * Reeling and Richard D. † Horan * Corresponding author Department of Economics and Environmental Science and Sustainability Program Western Michigan University [email protected] † Department of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics Michigan State University Selected Poster prepared for presentation at the 2015 Agricultural & Applied Economics Association and Western Agricultural Economics Association Joint Annual Meeting, San Francisco, CA, July 26-28 Copyright 2015 by Carson J. Reeling and Richard D. Horan. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice a appears on all such copies. Policy Tools for Managing Biological Pollution Risks from Trade Carson J. Reeling1 and Richard D. Horan2 | 1Department of Economics and Environmental and Sustainability Studies Program, Western Michigan University 2Department of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics, Michigan State University INTRODUCTION RESULTS The spread of infectious livestock diseases from live animal movement can be considered a form of “biological pollution.” Prior literature assumes trade-related biological pollution externalities are unilateral (i.e., importers can spread disease to neighbors, but cannot be infected by other importers) and arise solely from trade of infected goods. Their results suggest uniformly-applied trade-based policies can efficiently manage disease risks. However, trade is only part of the externality, and importers may be at risk from infection by other importers. 1. Social planner’s first-order conditions (FOCs) for input vi ∊ {xi, zi, ai} and bi: We find the problem is more analogous to nonpoint source pollution problems: • Biological pollution is stochastic and largely unobservable at reasonable cost; • Myriad choices generate external risks – not just trade choices. Some choices: • Produce only public risk-management benefits (not included in prior work); • Produce both public and private risk management benefits: trade-related biological pollution is a “filterable externality” (private risk management incentives not included in prior trade models), and spillovers may be bilateral; • Heterogeneous importers generate heterogeneous disease risks. We reframe trade-related biological pollution as nonpoint source pollution and explore efficient policy design. The nonpoint literature suggests efficiency may be attained by directly targeting all choices that contribute to emissions (not just trade decisions) or by indirectly targeting these choices via a performance-based proxy, a pollution production function that depends on these choices. • Private FOCs ignore the biological pollution externality, yielding vi = vi0 in Fig. B. • Externality arises from ei, which depends only partly on trade decisions (xi, zi). • Size of externality is smaller when risks are filterable; distance between privately-optimal risk mitigation and social optimum is smaller when mitigation has private benefits (blue line in Fig. B) than when mitigation has no private benefits (red line in Fig. B). 2. Efficiency can be attained through • Individual-specific tax on ei: a “risk-based tax” (analogous to a NPS performance proxy tax) or • Individual-specific taxes on xi, zi, ai (analogous to NPS input taxes). 3. Strategic complementarities may arise due to presence of e–i in Ωi; may cause multiple Nash equilibria. • Prices alone may not yield efficient outcome in such settings. • Command-and-control instruments (e.g., minimum requirements on zi) may be required in addition to incentives. • These will not be binding, but align importers’ expectations of others’ behavior around the efficient outcome FIG. A. BIOLOGICAL POLLUTION PROCESS A MODEL OF DISEASE RISKS Disease flow • Importers, indexed by i = 1, … , N, within a region purchase a share xi ∊ [0, 1] of animals from a risk-free region and the rest from a risky region. • Importer i can invest in surveillance, zi ∊ [0, 1], and abatement effort, ai ∊ [0, 1]. Surveillance prevents diseased animals from being introduced into one’s own herd, and infected animals are culled if detected. Abatement prevents disease from leaving one’s herd to infect neighboring importers and non-importers. • We consider two cases (see Fig. A): 1. Unilateral spillovers (no bilateral externalities in Fig. A) – importer i can spread disease to neighbors, but cannot be infected by other importers. • The social expected net benefits from live animal trade are Risky region 1 – x–i 1 – xi 2. Bilateral spillovers – importer i can spread disease to neighbors, and vice versa. We assume here importers can invest in biosecurity, bi ∊ [0, 1], to protect themselves from spread of infection by neighbors. • The social expected net benefits from live animal movements are where now individual importers suffer biological pollution spillovers from their neighbors’ choices, e-i. Importers can reduce the probability of damage by investing in biosecurity bi. xi z–i zi FIG. B. THE ABILITY TO FILTER RISKS SHRINKS EXTERNALITIES UNDER UNILATERAL SPILLOVERS Riskfree region Disease risk abatement x–i Bilateral Externalities Importer i’ s farm ai b–i bi ai where ei = ei(xi, zi, ai) is the probability disease spreads from i’s herd: the “biological pollution production function”. Optimal taxes are smaller when risks are filterable (see Fig. B) Externality is from spread, and therefore occurs at this point Neighboring importers’ (–i ) farms a–i Nonimporting producers a–i Magnitude of externality when risks are not filterable Magnitude of externality when risks are filterable CONCLUSIONS ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Our findings contrast with prior trade literature in three ways: (1) Incentives must target the externality directly or all choices contributing to the externality – targeting only trade choices is inefficient; (2) Efficient incentives are importer-specific, and the magnitude of efficient incentives is smaller for choices (like trade choices) for which importers have private incentives for risk mitigation; and (3) Bilateral spillovers imply the possibility of multiple Nash equilibria and the need for additional, commandand-control policy instruments for efficiency. We gratefully acknowledge funding from the USDA National Institute of Food and Agriculture, Grant #2011-67023-30872, grant #1R01GM100471-01 from the National Institute of General Medical Sciences (NIGMS) at the National Institutes of Health, and NSF grant #1414374 as part of the joint NSF-NIH-USDA Ecology and Evolution of Infectious Diseases program. The contents of the paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily represent the official views of USDA or NIGMS.