Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:14 Page 1 A joint initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians University’s Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research Bulletin Volume 18 No. 1 January 2008 STRIVING FOR CONTINUOUS EDUCATION If industrialised countries cannot compete on the wages of their labour with the emerging lowcost countries, they have to compete with the quality of their skills. That’s where continuous education comes in. Stefan Wolter shows why this is crucial. (page 6) PERSISTENCE OF EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION IFO NEWS Protecting employment can be too much of a good thing. As some countries have shown, most notably the UK and Denmark, loosening up a bit on this kind of protection can do wonders for employment levels. And still employment protection persists in many countries. Björn Bruegemann explains what role involuntary dismissal plays on this. (page 7) (p. 4-5) CESIFO INTERNATIONAL SPRING CONFERENCE (p. 5) EEAG REPORT 2008 ON SUBSIDISING EDUCATION Bas Jacobs has shown that more redistributive governments should subsidise education more. Then, he took this a step further and examined the role of the earnings function on subsidising education. Now, he tackles the life-cycle interactions between education, labour market performance, and retirement. (page 8) (p. 2) RESEARCH SEMINARS (p. 6) MUNICH SEMINARS (p. 3) FEATURED RESEARCHERS Björn Bruegemann (p. 7) Claudia M. Buch (p. 3) Bas Jacobs (p. 8) Alexander Kemnitz (p. 3) Marko Koethenbuerger (p. 7) Rigmar Osterkamp (p. 7) Ulrich Woitek (p. 8) Stefan Wolter (p. 6) THE 2008 EEAG REPORT ON THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY This year’s EEAG Report, the seventh in the series, contains unconventional views on some of the most pressing issues on the European economic horizon: globalisation and global warming. On the former, the report asserts that it may be good for employment levels in Western Europe; on the latter, that the current measures to curb global warming may be not only ineffective but even counterproductive. (page 2) DECISION-MAKING IN HOUSEHOLDS For several thousand years, we have improvised regarding decision-making in our households. Now help is on the way. Alexander Kemnitz is applying rigorous scientific methods to exploring the inefficiencies and possible solutions in this area. (page 3) GLOBALISATION’S GROWING PAINS Growing income disparities, persistent unemployment and workers’ perceived insecurity are all often attributed to globalisation. Policymakers are under pressure to “do something”. Just what can be done and what it effects can be is part of the research Claudia Buch will pursue while at CES. (page 3) THE OLD AND THE NEW Ulrich Woitek’s interests range from quantitative economic history to applied macroeconometrics, ie the past and the now. Monetary policy issues in the 1930s or the anthropometric history of Switzerland fascinate him as much as estimation techniques for Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium models. (page 8) Online version of this issue available at www.cesifo.de bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:14 Page 2 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 7TH MUNICH ECONOMIC SUMMIT EUROPE IN THE GLOBAL COMPETITION FOR Nobody disputes that, in an era of increasing globalisation, with low-wage jobs and low-cost manufacturing readily available around the globe, Europe must rely increasingly on innovation to stay ahead. Innovation, in turn, depends primarily on the quality and quantity of talent available. What is less clear is what can be done to nurture, attract and retain such talent. That will be the theme of the 7th Munich Economic Summit, which will be held on June 5 and 6, 2008, in Bavaria’s capital city. One puzzle is that while the unskilled are ready to even risk their lives to get into Europe, highly skilled professionals seldom deign to even try for a European visa: the best educated prefer Canada, Australia, the United States or Singa- TALENT Europe’s job markets grow ever larger. pore. It appears that a combination of lethargic economies, stifling regulations and powerful national lobbies all conspire to make many of the continent’s economies unattractive. These same factors prompt many of the Europe-grown talents to pack their bags and turn their backs on the home country. Germany loses doctors to Britain, Britain loses engineers to Australia, Eastern Europe many of its best brains to the rest of the world. Business leaders are understandably anxious as gaps in Is the Blue Card proposed by the European Commission the solution to attract talent? Can European governments harmonise their immigration policies? Can the need for more immigration be reconciled with the toxic mood towards foreigners prevailing in many European countries? And once you nurture or lure this talent, what can be done to retain it? Are higher salaries a solution? Or a more innovative culture, open to exploring and exploiting new fields? The Munich Economic Summit is organised by the CESifo Group and the BMW Foundation Herbert Quandt, in partnership with The Times of London. THE 2008 EEAG REPORT firms from international competition, a tendency that has outspoken advocates in some quarters. For that reason, argue the report’s authors, industrial policy should be located at the regional and EU level, and reduced at the national level. The European Economic Advisory Group at CESifo will release its seventh yearly report on February 26th in Brussels, followed by launch ceremonies in several other European capitals. Under the title Europe in a Globalised World, the report provides a comprehensive forecast for the European economy in 2008, which, on account of the upheavals caused in international financial markets by the subprime crisis in the United States, makes a global perspective more relevant than ever. A crucial issue in this regard is how large and persistent the depreciation of the US dollar against the euro will be, an issue analysed in depth in Chapter 2 of the Report. The independent nature of the report’s authors—seven high-ranking scholars from seven European countries— enables them to offer fresh and unconventional views for policy-makers. One of these unconventional views, nonetheless firmly based on sound economic reasoning and data, posits that the impact of increased economic integration with low-wage economies on Western European jobs is, on the whole, beneficial. Its message is that, when all effects are taken into account, globalisation is more likely to raise than reduce employment, as it will tend to dismantle rigidities in Europe’s labour markets. Another chapter argues against using industrial policy to protect European The final chapter addresses global warming from a fresh perspective: the supply side. Without a proper analysis of supply-side effects, demand-reducing measures, hitherto regarded as self-evident solutions, risk not only being ineffective, but even counterproductive. The EEAG Group consists of Lars Calmfors (Stockholm University, chairman), Gilles Saint-Paul (U. of Toulouse), Giancarlo Corsetti (European University Institute, Florence), Michael Devereux (U. of Oxford), Jan-Egbert Sturm (KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich), Xavier Vives (IESE Business School), and Hans-Werner Sinn (Ifo Institute and University of Munich). bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:14 Page 3 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 GLOBALISATION’S LABOUR PAINS DECISION-MAKING IN HOUSEHOLDS Buch Kemnitz are under pressure to either directly raise new barriers to the integration of markets through protectionist measures or to regulate labour markets. There is no doubt that the present wave of globalisation exerts an impact on labour market volatility. Just how it exerts which impacts is something Claudia M. Buch, of Tübingen University, is focusing part of her research efforts on. The increasing integration of international markets, facilitated through deregulation and technological progress, has changed the economic landscape. Emerging countries account for an increasing share of world production, and relative prices of capital and labour have changed. Shifts in the relative earnings of capital and labour are in particular troubling for the labour market performance in developed countries. Growing disparities of income or—in many continental European countries—persistent unemployment are often attributed to the increasing integration of the world economy. Survey evidence also suggests that a growing degree of integration into international markets increases workers’ perceived insecurity. Shifts in the relative supply of labour and a perceived increase in the instability of employment have increased political pressure to alleviate the negative consequences of globalisation. Policymakers Claudia Buch’s research aims at analysing the consequences of globalisation for labour market stability from a macroand microeconomic perspective. The focus will be on three questions: Has the volatility of key labour market indicators such as employment and wages changed over time? Do developments at the industry-level and at the aggregated level differ? What is the impact of an increased integration of markets on labour market volatility? How does the growing integration of international capital markets affect labour market risks? Claudia M. Buch holds the chair for International Finance and Macroeconomics at the University of Tübingen. She is also the Scientific Director of the Institute for Applied Economic Research and a member of the Council of Economic Advisers to the German Ministry of Economics and Labour. She holds an MBA from the University of Wisconsin and a Master of Economics from the University of Bonn. Her PhD and her post-doctoral degree (Habilitation) are from the University of Kiel. sponsored by Deutschlands große Tageszeitung MUNICH SEMINARS BMW Niederlassung München Wegweisend und voller Wertschätzung für Sie. Chaired by Hans-Werner Sinn (CESifo) and Marc Beise (Süddeutsche Zeitung) Sponsored by BMW Niederlassung München Monday, 6 pm, CESifo Conference Centre, Ludwig-Erhard-Hall, Poschingerstr. 5, Munich 21 January 2008 Dr. Ursula Engelen-Kefer Member of the SPD party executive Soziale Gestaltung der Globalisierung 26 May 2008 Prof. Dr. Theodor Baums Institute for Law and Finance, University of Frankfurt Räuberische Aktionäre – Was tun? 21 April 2008* Prof. Dr. Axel Weber President of the Deutsche Bundesbank *Topic to be announced 16 June 2008* Prof. Berthold Leibinger Member of the Executive Board of TRUMPF Laser- und Systemtechnik GmbH Decision-making processes within the household can be a tricky field to explore. That is exactly what Alexander Kemnitz, of the Technische Universität Dresden, is doing. He is devoting part of his research, which he will continue while at CES, to the interaction between individual specialisation in market or home production and bargaining power and the effects of non-transferable utility. Both aspects, he points out, limit the scope of agreement on Pareto-improving joint actions between spouses, the first one creating a commitment problem, the second one putting a technical upper ceiling on redistribution between partners. I plan to analyse to what extent family policy measures can help to overcome these inefficiencies, in particular with respect to fertility decisions. A further field of interest for Mr Kemnitz is economics of education. In this area, he plans to extend his research on the impact of student and graduate mobility on higher education funding. While public funding for higher education is often said to be eroded by mobility, private funding is often criticised for social selection. Mr Kemnitz wants to analyse to what extent the latter problem can be mitigated by quality improvements resulting from university competition. In that context, he would also like to consider differential tuition treatment of in- and outstate students, a feature common in the US and recently making the rounds in Germany as well. Alexander Kemnitz is a Professor of Economics at the Department of Business and Economics of the Technische Universität Dresden. He received his BA from the University of Bonn and his doctorate from the University of Mannheim. He is the author of the monograph Immigration, Unemployment, and Domestic Welfare, published in 2006. bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:14 Page 4 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 IFO NEWS IFO ECONOMIC FORECAST FOR 2008: ECONOMY TO LOSE MOMENTUM as in India and Latin America, a slowing of economic activity is expected. In 2007 the world economy expanded at a very strong 5.2%. However, the turbulence in the international financial markets point to an increase in economic risk. As the Ifo Institute correctly forecasted in December 2006, the economic upturn that commenced in 2005 continued despite the massive increase in the rate of the value added tax. The internal and external domestic forces were powerful enough to counteract the restrictive effects of fiscal policy. The main driving force continued to be foreign demand, which despite the massive appreciation of the euro vis-àvis the US dollar remained strong owing to the expanding world economy. By the time of the forecast Ifo expected a real GDP growth of 2.5%, which has been confirmed by the official data released in January. The economic upswing took place without private consumption. Consumer willingness to undergo larger purchases was massively weakened after the increase in VAT; in the second half of the year, with the increasing rate of inflation, it was clearly reduced once again. Thus, growth peaked last winter and since then has been clearly slowing. The Ifo World Economic Climate worsened significantly in the fourth quarter of 2007; assessments of both the current economic situation and the six-month outlook were revised downwards. The worsening of the Ifo World Economic Climate affected Western Europe, North America and Asia, with the sharpest decline in North America, primarily in the United States. These survey results indicate that the momentum of world economic growth will slow noticeably. In the United States, falling real-estate prices and higher interest rates will dampen the expansion of consumer spending. Investments will only gradually recover in the course of 2008 and in 2009. Housing construction spending, currently in a state of free-fall, will have a strongly dampening effect, contributing to lower GDP growth. The Japanese economy will remain on solid footing. In the euro area, the increase in GDP will slow. Because of higher inflation, the increase in consumption will be moderate; investment will also expand at a weaker pace, especially since the apex of the investment cycle seems to have already passed. In the emerging economies economic growth will cool down somewhat in the forecast period. In China the expansion of GDP will remain robust but will flatten slightly due to slower export growth. Also in the other countries of East Asia, as well At year-end 2007 the German economy was still in an upturn phase, albeit with declining momentum. In 2008 the expansion pace of aggregate output will initially weaken further because of a dampening in investment activity owing to the many projects that were brought forward to 2007. This will mean a considerable weakening of the most important driving force of domestic demand up to now. Afterwards, however, a return to potential growth is expected because growing employment and the concomitant expansion of purchasing power in private households will stimulate consumption. The Ifo Institute expects a 1.5% rise in consumer spending, which because of the slightly growing rate of inflation is somewhat less that in the joint autumn forecast of the German economic institutes. All in all, real GDP will expand by 1.8%, but owing to more working days, by a calendar-adjusted rate of only 1.5%. The inflation rate – measured in terms of the consumer price index – will rise to 2.3%, on average for the year 2008, having stood at 2.1% in 2007. Employment will increase by an annualised 290,000 to 40 million. The unemployment rate will then amount to 8.0%. The government budget will presumably show a slight deficit since the tax revenue situation will not improve further. In 2009, overall capacity utilisation is likely to stagnate. Real GDP will increase, according to our initial estimates for 2009, by 1.5% (calendaradjusted, by 1.6%). This forecast is marked by very high risks. It is based on the assumption that the price for Brent Crude will stand at about 90 US dollars per barrel and that the exchange rate of the euro will fluctuate at around 1.45 US dollars. Because of their speculative nature, neither factor can be reliably forecast. For the economic expansion in the United States, the greatest risk lies in a further worsening of the real-estate crisis, which could lead to a further drop in housing prices. This could severely dampen the consumption of private households since the negative asset effect would be much stronger and since the rise in interest charges would be more sharply felt. Investment will also be negatively affected since business profits would be reduced and borrowing would become more restrictive. This would also have negative effects on the labour market, with the consequence that the increase in employment would be more moderate, accompanied at the same time by rising unemployment. In this risk scenario, should monetary policy react by pursuing an expansive course, the additional danger would ensue that the US dollar would depreciate even further as a result of more massive cuts in interest rates. This could lead to a worsening economic outlook in other regions, such as the euro area. bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:15 Page 5 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 CESIFO INTERNATIONAL SPRING CONFERENCE IFO INSTITUTE CALLS FOR A MORE OBJECTIVE DISCUSSION OF THE MINIMUM WAGE ISSUE In the current discussion regarding the introduction of minimum wages, the basic principle of a market economy – the regulation of supply and demand by the price mechanism – has been greatly neglected, and even called into question. Any consumer is able to understand how the goods market functions: If the price of apples increases, fewer apples are bought; if gasoline becomes more expensive, one drives less and decides to buy a more economic model next time. “With regard to the labour market, many believe they can deviate from this basic principle without any negative effects on the demand for labour”, Joachim Ragnitz and Marcel Thum of the Dresden subsidiary of the Ifo Institute point out. “How many workers a company needs depends decisively on the wage bill”, Ragnitz and Thum explain and warn of the consequences of wrongly motivated wage increases: “A workplace will only by filled if its productivity exceeds its labour cost. Wage increases that are not covered by productivity gains lead to dismissals.” Their calculations on the employment effects from an introduction of minimum wages are based on simple and fundamental market mechanisms. A minimum wage is harmless if it lies below the market wage; it leads to job losses, however, if it is clearly above this. Even with a moderate minimum wage of €4.50 in Germany, 360,000 jobs would be lost in total. This number increases to 827,000 with a minimum wage of €6.50 and to 1.1 million jobs with a minimum wage of €7.50. If, in the extreme case, the minimum wage introduced for letter carriers (€9.00 in east and €9.50 in west Germany) was introduced for all sectors of the economy, the jobs losses would amount to 1.9 million. For these calculations a conservative estimate of wage elasticity of 0.75 percent was employed. The results of a minimum wage for the labour market depend on the avoidance reactions and the absolute size of the low-wage sector. According to the most current research of the Federal Statistical Office for the wage and salary structure in the manufacturing industry and in selected service sectors in 2001, 12.8 percent of employees earned less than €7.50. Ragnitz and Thum point out that the objections raised in the public discussion to their calculations are untenable. Higher wages for low-wage earners do not stimulate overall economic demand but lead on the whole to shrinkage of aggregate spending power, since company profits decline and unemployment rises. A further argument against the estimates presented by the Ifo Institute states that the assumed wage elasticity is poorly substantiated empirically. “All relevant estimates in the literature show negative values”, Ragnitz and Thum explain. There can be no doubt that a wage increase is always linked with a decline in employment. “From a scholarly viewpoint it is completely inadmissible to start with a wage elasticity of zero, as some politicians appear to do”, the researchers criticise. The argument is also misleading that the introduction of minimum wages in specific sectors in Germany has had no negative employment effects, and that consequently the labour market model on which the Ifo calculations were made is unsuitable. The study of König and Möller (2007), which examined the introduction of minimum wages in the employee posting law in the construction industry, drew the conclusion that employment among the low-skilled in construction declined significantly in eastern Germany but that no effects (or in one variant only weak effects) were found for western Germany. “This study by no means supplies a counter argument”, Ragnitz and Thum explain. The insignificant increase in employment in the west could be explained by the displacement of eastern German firms as a result of the minimum wage. The CESifo International Spring Conference has returned to Berlin, as requested by numerous participants. To be held this year on March 13 and 14 at the premises of the Representation in Germany of the European Commission, the conference will follow its traditional format of dedicating the first day to economic and financial issues of global or European impact, and the second to specific European industries. As to be expected, the subprime financial crisis in the United States will colour many of the presentations this year. Patrick MacGuire, of the Bank for International Settlements, will speak on market repricing to reflect growth risk, while Jan-Egbert Sturm, of the KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich, will address the European economy in the wake of slower growth. Michele Perétié of Bear Stearns will deal with exchange rates and monetary policy, and Jürgen Kröger, of the European Commission, will look at the challenges to European competitiveness from globalisation and integration. The second day will open with a review of the prospects for aeronautics, a fastgrowing European megaindustry, by Klaus Broichhausen, of Bauhaus Luftfahrt. The steel industry will be addressed by Jeroen Vermeij, of Eurofer, while the chemical industry will be analysed by Moncef Hadhri, of CEFIC. After a short break, Thomas Hueck, from Bosch, will warn decision-makers to watch the trend, not the cycle in the automotive industry, while Michele Schweinöster, of ANIMA, will provide an Italian perspective on the European engineering industries. The high energy prices of course could not be absent. Elisabeth WaelbroeckRocha, of BIPE, will examine their impact on European sectors and member states. Further info at: www.cesifo-group.org/isc bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:15 Page 6 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 STRIVING FOR CONTINUOUS EDUCATION Wolter Continuous education or adult education is high on the agenda of education policy in all industrialised countries. In light of the current demographic changes and ageing workforces, continuous training will get even more attention in the coming years. But the fact that some categories of the adult population – mostly those with already low levels of education and working in low wage sectors – do almost never participate in continuous training is worrying in most countries. Many governments therefore consider stimulating the demand for continuous education with subsidies. A popular but yet not well tested idea is to subsidise adults with training vouchers in order to increase participation rates of adults. Although the idea of vouchers in education is well accepted in economics, most economists are sceptical about the usefulness and effectiveness of vouchers in adult education. Is a voucher sufficient to raise the participation rate of adults with low educational levels and if so, does it create huge windfall gains by just replacing private investments with public funds? Ex post evaluations of the few existing voucher programs have not been able to give convincing answers to these questions so far. This is where Stefan Wolter comes in. In collaboration with the Swiss Federal Office for Professional Training and Technology and the Swiss Federal Statistical Office, the Centre for Research in Economics of Education at the University of Bern – which Prof. Wolter heads – started in 2005 a large-scale field experiment to give answers to the questions raised above. The setting consists of some 2400 people, drawn randomly from the Swiss Labour Force Survey (SLFS) who got vouchers for adult education in 2006 with nominal values ranging from 120 to 900 euros. The control group in the experiment were the remaining persons surveyed in the SLFS. The experimental and control group were surveyed at least once (2005) before the voucher experiment and then surveyed again in 2007, one year after the experiment. This gives the experiment a very rich and broad data base that will help to clear up numerous questions that have remained unanswered so far. While at CES, Professor Wolter will work on the first scholarly articles that describe the results of this field experiment. Stefan Wolter is Director of the Swiss Coordination Centre for Research in Education and head of the Centre for Research in Economics of Education at the University of Bern, where he holds a honorary professorship. Prior to his work in education he was chief economist at the Federal Office for Industry and Labour in Switzerland, member of the National Economic Council and Swiss representative to various international organisations. Today he represents Switzerland at the board of the Centre for Educational Research and Innovation (CERI) of the OECD in Paris. He is also president of the Swiss Federal Institute for Vocational Education and Training and Codirector the Swiss Leading House in Economics of Education, a joint research initiative with the University of Zurich (together with Prof. U. BackesGellner, University of Zurich). He obtained a Master in Economics and Psychology at the University of Bern, where he also received his PhD in Economics in 1995 and his post-doctoral degree (Habilitation) in 2003. Together with Samuel Mühlemann, he authored Regional Effects on Employer Provided Training: Evidence from Apprenticeship Training in Switzerland, which is forthcoming in the Journal for Labour Market Research (ZAF). HANS-MÖLLER SEMINARS Seminar for International Economic Relations Library, Ludwigstr. 28/II, Tuesdays, 4:30 - 6:00 pm 8 January 2008 Christoph Buchheim University of Mannheim The Economic Development of Germany in the Third Reich: A Comparison with the Post-WW II Period 15 January 2008* Bob Allen Oxford University 22 January 2008* Arthur van Soest Tilburg University 29 January 2008* Jaume Ventura University Pompeu Fabra 5 February 2008* Ronnie Schöb FU Berlin * The subject for these seminars can be seen at www.hans-moeller-seminar.vwl.uni-muenchen.de/index.html RESEARCH SEMINARS Winter Semester 2007/08 Monday 3:15 p.m. CES, Schackstr. 4, Munich 7 January 2008 Adam Szeidl University of California at Berkeley Imports and Productivity 14 January 2008* Anna Stangl University of Munich 14 January 2008* Julia Bersch University of Munich 21 January 2008* Lars Siemers RWI Essen 28 January 2008* Stefan Behringer University of Frankfurt 4 February 2008* Reto Foellmi University of Bern * The topic for this seminars is listed at www.lrz-muenchen.de/~u5231ae/webserver/webdata/seminar.html bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:15 Page 7 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 PERSISTENT EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION Bruegemann Most countries have adopted regulations making it costly for firms to dismiss workers. The stringency of employment protection (EP), however, differs greatly across countries. Furthermore, these differences have been very persistent, despite longstanding calls for deregulation. Björn Bruegemann’s research has focused on understanding the mechanisms underlying this persistence. A simple story goes as follows: strict EP keeps workers in unproductive jobs; if regulation were removed, these workers would become unemployed; hence they oppose deregulation. According to this story, once EP has been introduced, it creates its own constituency and becomes very difficult to deregulate. Mr Bruegemann analyses under which circumstances this story holds true. He shows that the answer depends on what EP does for workers. One possibility is that it strengthens the workers’ bargaining position, enabling them to obtain higher wages. Another is that dismissal is sometimes involuntary to workers, and that EP prevents involuntary dismissal. He demonstrates that if EP uniformly increases wages of all workers while dismissal is voluntary, then the simple story outlined above does not hold true any longer. This result suggests that involuntary dismissal is key to understanding the persistence of dismissal regulations. In a quantitative analysis he shows that involuntary dismissal is indeed a potent source of persistence. In related work, he argues that not only is EP difficult to deregulate, it is also difficult to introduce: those workers who would gain most from introducing job protection may never see those benefits, because firms would dismiss them before EP actually takes effect. Anticipating this, workers in this position are unlikely to support proposals to introduce protection. Continuing this research agenda while at CES, Mr Bruegemann plans to investi- gate the prevalence of involuntary dismissal empirically. Björn Bruegemann is an assistant professor at Yale University. He received his PhD from MIT and his MSc from the University of Bonn. CHANGE OF EDITORSHIP AT DICE REPORT The CESifo DICE Mr Osterkamp took Report has been a leave of absence from the Ifo Instipublished since tute to take on a 2003. From the new task in Namibbeginning, Rigmar ia. His position as Osterkamp was Editor of the CESione of the two edifo DICE Report has tors (the other one been taken over by is Wolfgang Ochel). Marko KoethenIt is largely due to Rigmar Osterkamp (left) and buerger. Mr Osterkamp’s Marko Koethenbuerger (right) efforts that DICE Mr Koethenbuerger Report has become a respected journal in holds a PhD from the University of Paderinternational institutional comparisons. born, is a Research Director at CESifo, It is read not only by economists but also and was an assistant professor at the Cenby policy-makers and journalists ter for Economic Studies of the Ludwig throughout the world. Maximilian University of Munich. CESIFO ECONOMIC STUDIES: FEDERALISM REVISITED The latest issue of CESifo Economic Studies, published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the CESifo Group, takes a fresh view at federalism, based on the proceedings of a special conference held a few months ago in Lexington, Kentucky. Co-sponsored by the Institute for Federalism and Intergovernmental Relations at the University of Kentucky and by CESifo, the conference aknowledged that global changes in institutional structures and economic conditions within and among countries, including fiscal, economic and political reforms, have highlighted the importance of the division of fiscal and political responsibilities among governments. Better understanding of the fiscal policies and interactions of governments, and of their institutional and political underpinnings, presents deep intellectual challenges as well as opportunities for useful policy applications. Five keynote addresses presented at that conference were selected for this issue of CESifo Economic Studies. In one of them, George Zodrow reviews the property tax incidence debate and the mix of state and local finance of local public expenditures. Robert Inman examines empirically how and to what degree federalism contributes to improved economic performance, highlighting in particular its role in securing property rights and its dependence upon democratic governance. Jens Brøchner and his colleagues delve into the dilemmas of tax co-ordination in the enlarged European Union, while Jacques Drèze and his colleagues ask whether federal grants can mitigate social competition. Finally, John D. Wilson pits the welfare state against the common labour market, and asks which should be dismantled. More at www.cesifo.oxfordjournals.org bulletin_0801.qxp 01.07.2008 10:15 Page 8 Vol. 18, No. 1 • January 2008 ON SUBSIDISING EDUCATION HISTORY AND MACROECONOMETRICS Jacobs Woitek Checking the literature on the marginal cost of public funds and the optimal provision of public goods, Bas Jacobs, of Erasmus University Rotterdam, found several problems. The MCF, he says, is mostly studied in optimal tax models without redistributional concerns. Hence, the fundamental reason why the government introduces tax distortions is not explicitly taken into account. This has important and non-trivial consequences for the Samuelson rule. By leaving out the distributional benefits of distorting tax rates, the optimal level of public goods is probably too low. Furthermore, Mr Jacobs shows that standard measures for the MCF are highly sensitive to the normalisation of the tax system, which is an awkward property and makes standard MCF measures useless for practical policy analysis. Finally, the literature cannot adequately relate the marginal excess burden of taxation to the MCF, unless one assumes that public goods are perfect substitutes for cash. That is an extremely unattractive assumption, because it is not clear what is ‘public’ about providing ‘cash’ and why the government would use distortionary income taxes to provide it. In the project Mr Jacobs will pursue while at CES, he will try to resolve all three problems. A further field he is studying is optimal tax and education policies in models with endogenous labour supply and education choices and heterogeneous agents. In earlier joint work with Lans Bovenberg, Mr Jacobs showed that optimal education policies should ensure efficiency in human capital formation if redistributive income taxes distort education choices. Therefore, more redistributive governments should subsidise education more. This second-best argument can explain the widespread use of education subsi- Bulletin dies, whereas standard explanations (external effects, liquidity constraints and so on) are either theoretically or empirically too weak. In recent work, he also shows that these results are sensitive to the particular earnings functions used. Indeed, when education is strongly complementary to work effort, education subsidies can be used to reduce tax distortions on labour supply. However, education subsidies are also regressive if highability individuals benefit most from education subsidies. He demonstrates that non-separabilities in the earnings function are crucial as to whether education should be taxed or subsidised (on a net basis) in an optimal redistributive tax system. Lastly, he is devoting research efforts to the life-cycle interactions between education, labour market performance, and retirement. Education raises the opportunity costs of leisure and retirement. Higher labour supply and later retirement raise the returns on investments in human capital by increasing its utilisation rate and extending the payback period of the investment. Hence, there are important life-cycle feedbacks between education, labour supply and retirement. Taxation not only reduces labour supply, but also reduces the returns on human capital investment and makes early retirement more attractive. Ulrich Woitek, a professor for economic history and economics at the Institute for Empirical Research in Economics at the University of Zurich, is currently at CESifo as a visiting researcher. His main areas of expertise are applied macroeconometrics and quantitative economic history. He is involved in projects on the anthropometric history of Switzerland in the 20th century and on monetary policy issues in the 1930s. Work on the history of primary school education in Switzerland with CESifo researchers Josef Falkinger and Volker Grossmann shows that accounting for a broader range of sociocultural characteristics qualifies the role of religion for educational production well documented in the literature. Currently, he works on estimation techniques for Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models. The aim of this research is to provide econometrically estimated macroeconomic models which are useful for policy analysis, incorporating fiscal and monetary policy into the basic DSGE framework in a variety of ways. Mr Jacobs also shows that stronger interactions over the life-cycle drive up the elasticities of all behavioural margins. Consequently, deadweight losses of taxation are much larger than commonly understood. Indeed, Prescott may well be right in blaming high levels of taxation for poor labour market performance in continental Europe. Recent work with CESifo researchers Jim Malley and Apostolis Philippopoulos examines the quantitative macroeconomic implications of countercyclical fiscal policy for France, Germany and the UK. The model incorporates real-wage rigidity, which is the particular market failure justifying policy intervention. A formal general equilibrium welfare assessment of the volatility implications of alternative instrument/target combinations reveals the welfare gains from active policy, measured as a share of consumption, to be moderate. Bas Jacobs is a professor in economics and public finance at Erasmus University Rotterdam, and an academic advisor to the CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Research. Before joining the University of Zurich in 2005, Mr Woitek worked at the Universities of Glasgow and Munich. He received his doctorate in 1996 from the University of Munich. Munich Society for the Promotion of Economic Research (Münchener Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wirtschaftswissenschaft, CESifo GmbH) is the international platform of Ludwig-Maximilians University and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research. President and CEO: Hans-Werner Sinn Address: CESifo, Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich (Germany) Telephone +49 (0) 89/9224-1410, Fax: +49 (0) 89/9224-1409 Editor: Julio C. Saavedra (JS). Ifo News provided by Annette Marquardt (AM).