Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
2nd Ifo BrIEF Ifo Brussels International Economic Forum Desperate Remedies: Lessons from the Crisis 11 November 2008 Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich © Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Publisher: Ifo Institute Editors: Paul Kremmel Jutta Albrecht Photography: Romy Bonitz Layout and design: Jasmin Tschauth, Elisabeth Will and Kinga Bien Printing: Majer & Finckh, Stockdorf Conference venue: Committee of the Regions Bâtiment Jacques Delors Room: JDE 51 Rue Belliard 99–101 1040 Brussels Belgium Contacts: Executive committee: Jutta Albrecht Ifo Institute for Economic Research Tel. 00 49/(0)89-92 24-13 32 Mail: [email protected] Annette Hagemann Committee of the Regions Tel. 00 32/22 82-20 09 Mail: [email protected] 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 Contents 3 Desperate Remedies: Lessons from the Crisis 4 Welcome Addresses 6 I n tro d u c t io n The European Response to the Financial Crisis World Economy in Crisis: Causes and Consequences 13 P a ne l 1 Stagflation Ahead? Output Slump and Excess Inflation in Europe 17 P a ne l 2 European Tax Policy – Taxation of Multinationals 22 Appendix 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 3 D espera te Re med ies: Lessons fro m the Crisis The Committee of the Regions and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich jointly hosted a conference in Brussels on 11 November 2008. This Ifo BrIEF (Brussels International Economic Forum) delved into some of the issues that pose major policy challenges in the years ahead: the fi nancial crisis and its effects upon the real economy, inflation/deflation, and a capitalisation- and investment-friendly tax regime for multinational corporations. The event was the second in an annual conference series, which seeks to strengthen input from economic experts in European policy-making. Hosted by Ifo President Hans-Werner Sinn and Committee of the Regions SecretaryGeneral Gerhard Stahl, the conference opened with a debate featuring Joaquín Almunia, Economic and Monetary Affairs Commissioner, and Ifo President HansWerner Sinn. It addressed the causes of the fi nancial crisis and its consequences on the real economy. A fi rst panel then explored policy options available in the current recession, with contributions by Pervenche Berès, President of the European Parliament’s Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs, and Kai Carstensen, Head of the Business Cycle Analyses and Surveys Department of the Ifo Institute. A second panel examined European tax policy and the taxation of multinationals, with presentations by Robert Verrue, Director General for Taxation and Customs Union, and Thiess Buettner, Head of the Public Finance Department of the Ifo Institute. 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 4 Welcome Add r es s es I Gerhard Stahl Secretary-General, Committee of the Regions, Brussels t is a great pleasure for me to welcome you to the 2nd Ifo Brussels International Economic Forum. The Forum, jointly organised by the Committee of the Regions and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research, has the goal of strengthening the contribution of economic expertise to European economic policy-making and providing a platform for European decision-makers to meet with economists to discuss key issues pertaining to Europe’s future. Last year, in the 1st Ifo BrIEF, we discussed how to reach the goals of the Lisbon Agenda, addressing the dramatic changes in the division of labour brought about by globalisation and Europe’s answer to these challenges. Already last year we had the privilege of a keynote speech by Commissioner Almunia and I welcome very much his presence again here today. I am sure that the expectations for today’s conference are even higher. In a world of financial and economic changes political leadership is needed and new economic answers are expected. Who would be a better partner to discuss this than Professor Sinn and the Ifo Institute with its economic expertise? Today’s programme is entitled “Desperate Remedies: Lessons from the Crisis”. The programme today starts with the keynote speech of Commissioner Almunia followed by an examination of the financial crisis by Professor Sinn. In the afternoon there will be the chance to discuss with Pervenche Berès, the Chairwoman of the Committee on Economic Affairs, and we will also have the Director General of Taxation and Customs Union of the European Union to discuss tax policy. Their comments will be supplemented by the analysis of Ifo economic experts. Hans-Werner Sinn President, Ifo Institute, Munich I look forward to a lively debate on the topics presented. I too am pleased to open this second 2nd Ifo Brussels International Economic Forum (Ifo BrIEF), jointly organised by the Ifo Institute and the EU Committee of the Regions. I welcome all of you, especially Commissioner Almunia, to what has now become an annual event. We had planned to speak about the real climate and how it is changing, but now we are speaking about the real economic climate and what may lie in store for us. We changed the title because of the most recent events. I think this is quite appropriate, given the risks that the world economy is facing from both financial and the real side. Our presentations this morning will discuss the financial and economic crisis. In the afternoon we will examine whether this will be a crisis with inflation. With all the money that governments have pumped into rescue plans and which central banks have provided for liquidity, is there an additional inflation risk that we are facing? This will be discussed in the first panel this afternoon by Pervenche Berès of the European Parliament and by Kai Carstensen of the Ifo Institute. In the second panel we will discuss European tax policy, in particular the taxation of multinational corporations. Due to the increased possibilities to shift taxable profits from one country to another, one obviously needs a harmonised approach here. You will hear what Robert Verrue of the European Commission and Thiess Büttner of the Ifo Institute have to say about this issue. I would like to thank you for attending the 2nd Ifo BrIEF. We have very many important policymakers in attendance today, which will ensure a lively discussion and new insights. It is now my privilege to ask Commissioner Almunia to open the introductory debate on the causes and consequences of the current financial and economic crisis. Gerhard Stahl Hans-Werner Sinn 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 In t ro d u c t i o n 6 A Recipe for R e c o v e r y : T h e E u r o p e a n Response to t h e F i n a n c i a l C r i s i s Jo a q u ín A l mun i a C ommi ssi o n e r for Econom ic and M onetar y Policy, E u rop e a n C ommission, Br ussels Joaquín Almunia Commissioner for Economic and Monetary Policy, European Commission, Brussels A fter a period of excess and risk accumulation in the financial sector, we are now living through a painful market correction. The financial system is enduring a phase of severe deleveraging, characterised by dysfunctional credit markets, unprecedented write-downs in asset valuations, generalised risk aversion and threats to the stability of the banking sector. Although the banking sector has been at the centre of the crisis since the beginning, problems have spilled into other parts of the financial system – to the enormous credit default swaps market, insurance companies and hedge funds. everything in our power to return markets to normal functioning so that they can continue their job of financing households and businesses and supporting growth. The Commission has called for rescue packages to be put in place rapidly and consistently to help restore confidence. We are monitoring their implementation closely. We are also prepared to use competition rules to ensure that a level playing field is maintained between beneficiaries and non-beneficiaries of state aid and to prevent distortions in the internal market. For those member states experiencing balance of payment pressures or serious financial sta- “From the outset, Europe has taken decisive action to manage this crisis” From the outset, Europe has taken decisive action to manage this crisis. Governments, the Commission and the European Central Bank (ECB) have been working closely together to contain the turmoil, protect savings and maintain a credit flow for businesses and households. The ECB has injected huge amounts of liquidity into markets to prevent a severe credit crunch by cutting interest rates. And the October agreement by member states on an EU rescue package for banks was an unprecedented act of coordination, allowing us to synchronise national responses within a common European framework. Initial market reactions to these rescue packages have been positive. There has been a modest improvement in the functioning of interbank markets. Yet conditions remain precarious. It’s clear that we must do 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 bility risks, the EU stands ready to provide financial assistance. Even as we deal with the immediate crisis, we have to think further ahead. The last months have exposed the weaknesses in our financial systems. We must act to ensure sure that a crisis of this scale does not and cannot happen again. With this in mind, the Commission has accelerated work on a package of precise mea- Introduction 7 geopolitical realities of the 21st century. sures that tackle shortcomings in our financial sector. We have already proposed reforms to capital requirements, deposit guarantees and accountancy rules. We have put forward measures to tighten up the regulation of credit rating agencies, followed by an initiative on executive pay. We are also working on regulating derivatives, hedge funds and private equity. And a high level group chaired by Jacques de Larosière has been set up to assess cross-border supervision in Europe. It will present its first results to the European Council in the spring. This is part of a major effort to reform the supervisory and regulatory model on which our financial markets are based. But clearly, given the international nature of financial markets, this cannot be a purely European exercise. It should be a global one. Hence the international summit in Washington in mid-November – the first of a series – was crucial: first to establish consen- The financial turmoil has also had considerable fallout for the real economy. The crisis has caused confidence to fall significantly. It is aggravating the housing market corrections in some advanced economies. With the US and some European countries in recession, and the outlook darkening for emerging economies too, the global economy is slowing and external demand is falling rapidly. While all member states will experience a downturn, it will be more pronounced and protracted in those countries with greater exposure to shocks. But there is one piece of good news – the downturn is helping to ease inflation as oil prices fall. The outlook is not only bleak, it is also highly uncertain. There is a real risk that if the financial stress intensifies or lasts longer, it may have a greater effect on the economy and could fuel the negative feedback loop between the economy and the financial sector. In fact, the International Monetary Fund has now updated its own forecasts with even gloomier figures. Faced with the most difficult economic situation in decades, we need to mobilise a concerted and co-ordinated policy response as we have done in the financial sector. This means using all the “We can mitigate the impact on the real economy if we fast-track certain structural reforms.” sus among the key international partners on what needs to be done to prevent a repeat of the current situation, and then to pave the way for effective, concrete reforms. The scope of these discussions should be wide. We need to tackle not just the lax financial regulation but also strengthen international crisis management capacities and address the global current account imbalances that lie at the root of today’s crisis. policy instruments we have available to limit the slowdown, protect jobs and lay the ground for a sound recovery. We are realistic. We know that success will not come easily or quickly. The current framework for global governance makes it particularly difficult to generate the ownership and legitimacy for real change. This is why we must grasp this opportunity to drive forward a restructuring of global governance – including the Bretton Woods institutions – so that they reflect the Second, within the rules of the Stability and Growth Pact there is scope for budgetary policy to cushion the slowdown. We do not underestimate the challenges ahead for fiscal policy. The slowdown will inevitably take its toll on budgetary positions. And emergency measures to support the banking sector are already having an effect on government debts. The first tool is monetary policy. The recent fall in inflation has opened the way to interest rate reductions to help sustain consumption and investment. The European Central Bank has already demonstrated its readiness to act by cutting interest rates. 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 8 Introduction But the revised pact is designed to handle such crisis situations. Since 2005 it has the inbuilt flexibility to manage the deterioration in public finances. We invite member states to draw fully on the flexibility of the pact. However, this cannot be a license to increase the burden for future generations. Fiscal policy should remain on a sustainable course. It should take into account the different situations in different member states. The recent sharp increase in spreads on sovereign debt in a number of member states is a reminder that the scope to use fiscal policy to support the economy varies across countries. The pact provides for specific treatment when “exceptional circumstances” exist. A deviation above the 3 percent ceiling, if it is temporary and the deficit remains close to the reference value, does not trigger the opening of an Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP). If the EDP is open, but the economic situation is what the pact defines as “special circumstances”, the deadlines for the correction of an excessive deficit can deviate from the general rule and be extended to more than one year. And if this situation continues at the end of that period, new recommendations can be issued without advancing to the next steps in the procedure. the bank can continue to support businesses as well as accelerate financing of climate change, energy security and infrastructure projects. I have outlined just a few key measures. However, as with policies in the financial sector, success of our European strategy will depend on whether we can co-ordinate our action at the European level, and, building on a common European approach, if we can generate an international response to the slowdown. The downturn has a global nature, and international partners need to take co-ordinated measures to boost world demand, particularly those countries or regions with large current account surpluses. This would both help support global growth and facilitate the unwinding of large global imbalances. We also need to work together to prevent protectionism from taking hold. In developed and developing countries alike, economic nationalism is on the rise and the benefits of globalisation are being questioned following the crisis. This is understandable. But history tells us that it is a dangerous tendency, one that can turn a downturn into a protracted and more severe problem. It is vital that we in Europe reaffirm our commitment to the principle of openness and lead “We also need to work together to prevent protectionism from taking hold.” We can mitigate the impact on the real economy if we fast-track certain structural reforms, especially those which boost demand and help reduce inflationary pressures, supporting household purchasing power. Immediate priority should be given to measures which enhance productivity. So we must step up investments in research and technology and in innovation. Pressing ahead with measures in low carbon technologies and energy efficiency would both support European competitiveness while tackling climate change. Accelerating implementation of the Services Directive should also be a high priority, given the key role services play in creating jobs and reducing inflationary pressures. As unemployment is set to increase, we will also need measures that ease the hardship of job losses and lay the ground for renewed employment growth. This means strengthening “flexicurity” in our labour markets policies, making sure that income support is available to vulnerable households and investing in education and skills. Finally, we must take immediate steps to improve access to financing for businesses, especially SMEs. Part of this can be done through the European Investment Bank. We will propose reinforcing the capital base of the EIB so that 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 by example. We must uphold the competition rules that underpin the Single Market and come out strongly against trade barriers. Faced with the most daunting economic situation in decades, we have to act on three fronts: to stabilize and reform the financial system; to limit the impact on economic growth and prepare the ground for recovery; and to mobilise a co-ordinated, global response to the macrofinancial risks that threaten the stability of the world economy. The European Commission’s recovery plan aims to drive forward a co-ordinated response to the crisis, one that instils confidence in our economic and financial systems and safeguards prosperity for citizens and businesses. Introduction 9 Wo rld Ec onom y in Cr is i s: C au ses and Cons eque nces H a n s - We r ne r S i n n T o comprehend the deeper economic reasons for the current crisis we need to look beyond the record US current account deficit, the low US savings rate, subprime mortgages and the bursting of the real-estate bubble to the issue of limited liability and how this was misused by American investment banks. What do I mean? Limited liability is a legal privilege that was given to joint stock companies in the 19th century in Western Europe and North America but has deep historical roots in Medieval Italy and the Netherlands. This was a major innovation in corporate law that made modern capitalism possible. You cannot create a joint stock company without the provision of limited liability, and with millions of shareholders you cannot make each individual shareholder liable. The problem is, however, that limited liability was misused by American investment banks. Bankers became involved in risky business transactions and exploited the privilege of limited liability to the maximum extent by running their companies with only tiny amounts of equity capital – around ratios of 4 percent of less. Why did they have so little equity? It’s of business – and generate huge rates of return. If you have a rate of return of 25 percent or more, you double your equity in just a few years, provided you retain it. So there would have been an overflow of equity if they had kept it in the banks. The shareholder value principle meant that equity had to be taken out of the bank to secure it over time. This was the deeper reason for the crisis. There is another aspect as well. Once you have decided to run your bank with excessive leverage, then you might as well take great risks. If you have nothing to lose, you can take excessive risks, which will give you huge profits if you are lucky and huge losses if you are unlucky. Because you only bear the losses to the extent you have equity in the company, which is close to zero, most of the losses are borne by someone else – the creditors of the banks and the governments, which in the end have to bail out the companies. If an investment bank has the choice between a safe investment strategy with a low rate of return and a risky one with a large rate of return but the same average value, it will chose Hans-Werner Sinn President, Ifo Institute, Munich “The problem is, however, that limited liability was misused by American investment banks.” not that the shareholders were unable to provide capital. On the contrary, these banks had huge rates of return – between 25 and 40 percent – so the money was there. They could have left it in the company, but the idea was to take it out as quickly as possible so it would not be lost in turbulent times. They thought it was better to run the bank with excessive leverage – 4 dollars for 100 dollars the riskier one, which increases the expected profit above the rate of return on the safe investment. Thus the riskier your strategy is, the higher your expected profit – this is the microeconomic reason for excessive risk-taking. But not only Wall Street turned into a casino – Main Street also gambled. A similar strategy – excessive risk taking due to limited liability – can be observed on the part of American homeowners. Normal homeowners are not in the subprime market. In the subprime crisis we are talking about a segment of homeowners who have low incomes and are protected by law against claims made by banks for anything beyond what they provided as collateral. In many states if you have a below-average or below median income, you can buy a house with borrowed funds and if you 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 10 Introduction have difficulties repaying the loan, the bank does not have the right to obtain your income from labour. It only has a right to foreclose and sell the house. This limitation of liability has been crucial in encouraging homeowners in the subprime segment to take excessive risks. The question is now why did the banks participate? If they knew that the loans would not be repaid if house prices went down, why did they grant the loans in the first place? Were they so stupid that they didn’t know who their clients were? No, in fact they were very clever, because they securitized these claims against the homeowners. They did not keep them on their books. Instead they created mortgagebacked securities, which they sold to someone else in order to get rid of the risk. This someone else was another bank that bought the mortgage-backed securities, and they bundled them together into a package of good and bad claims, gave the package a name and created new asset-back securities, which were claims on the package that contained the claims against the homeowners. This package was then sold to another bank and so on, creating a cascade of claims on claims. And in the end the banks did not really know what claims they had. the crisis? We can distinguish between short-term and long-term strategies. Short-term strategies can mitigate the crisis and prevent a meltdown. Longterm strategies should provide rules for sound banking business. Unfortunately, there is a conflict – the more you spend now, the lower the incentive for bankers to do sound banking in the future because they will expect the government to bail them out. Some hundreds of billions of euros have been provided by the European Central Bank to improve liquidity. Interest rates have been lowered. But this is not really the solution, because it is not only a liquidity crisis. Rather it is a solvency crisis resulting from the enormous loss of equity and the undercapitalization of the banking system. Short-term credit procurement by the European Central Bank (ECB) – lending between banks has stopped. Whoever has money deposits it at the ECB and whoever wants money takes the money from the ECB. The banks do this even though they have to pay for the interest spread the ECB charges. There are also state guarantees, as in the case of Hypo Real Estate in Germany. Moreover, the government can purchase toxic credit claims, and there is the possibility of partial nationalization. The British developed this plan and I think it is sound. The advantage is that if the government invests its money, it also has claims for future dividends so that the taxpayer is not cheated. “Long-term strategies should provide rules for sound banking business.” You may wonder why the European banks bought these packages. After all there were the rating agencies that assessed the creditworthiness of the claims and the repayment probabilities of those involved. But they did not perform properly. They were much too generous with some of these products and gave them a triple-A rating even though the claims were dubious. This is partly because these rating agencies are private joint stock companies. They make money from giving advice. When they evaluate a bank or its products, they collect huge honoraria. And how can such a rating agency easily downgrade a big client like Lehman Brothers? It’s much easier to correctly assess the true value of a small European bank. If a minor client doesn’t return, it doesn’t matter but you can’t do that with an important client. What we see here is that rating agencies are in principle unable to perform and do their job properly. This is a task for the government and not private institutions. And I believe in fact that these rating agencies will not survive this crisis. What are the policy measures required to handle 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 There is a final problem, which I must admit I do not completely understand. It’s a potential time-bomb for the system – 50 trillion credit default swaps – a magnitude beyond all imagination. Credit default swaps mean that if a bank gives a loan to someone, it can insure itself with a contract with another bank. The first bank pays a regular fee and if the debt on a loan is not repaid, then the second bank pays indemnification. That sounds good but again there is a chain of claims involved. The second bank also insures itself with a third bank that pays if the second bank has to pay the first bank, etc. In this Introduction 11 the ECB, to really control the banking business. market there are insurance contracts where Bank C insures Bank B in case Bank A has a problem, even though neither Bank B nor Bank C has any business connection with Bank A. There are rumours that companies are driven to bankruptcy just by spreading bad information on the market to create an insurance case. No one completely understands this but it is definitely a problem that needs to be investigated, a problem that creates a great risk that we presently do not have under control. So what long-term policy measures are necessary if we want to have a sound banking business? Basel II seemed to be a good start when it was introduced, but we now know that it has been too lax a regulatory system. The banks must be regulated; they cannot control themselves. In particular conduits and other offshore activities need to be included in the balance sheet in a Basel II type system. In general we need higher equity capital requirements. First of all, if banks are required to have more equity capital, they will have a cushion in case of a crisis and won’t go bankrupt. And second, much more impor- I would like to add that the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) accounting rules should also be reconsidered because this market to market, fair value principle means that the turbulence of the markets is immediately translated to the balance sheets, thereby creating a lot of unforeseeable legal consequences. In Germany we had the “lowest value principle”, which meant that typically you had assets in your books at the historic purchasing price. When the price later increased you had silent reserves that were not reported and that you could draw on in turbulent times. This applied to banks and corporations of all sorts and thus they were not vulnerable to economic shocks as they are today with the fair value principle. The true microeconomic, regulatory reason for the crisis was undercapitalization of the banking system, which led to excessive risk taking. In order to prevent this from happening again, higher equityasset ratios must be harmonised. Only with an internationally harmonised system – a joint agreement between countries – will we be able to prevent a competition of laxity in international banking. “The competition of governments, especially of regulators, leads to a competition of laxity.” tantly, they will be more prudent. If large amounts of money are at stake, the shareholder will make sure that the managers chose a prudent and cautious strategy. They will not be looking for 25 percent rates of return on equity. They will be content with less and prefer safer strategies. To achieve this international banking harmonisation is absolutely necessary because otherwise there will be a competition of regulations between countries. The competition of governments does not follow the same rules as those of private companies. The competition of governments, especially of regulators, leads to a competition of laxity. One regulator tries to undercut the rules of the other countries in order to attract banking business. The only possibility is an international agreement, a set of rules controlled by the IMF and then broken down by the central governments in Europe, 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 P a n e ls 13 P anel 1 S tag flat ion Ahe ad? Ou tp u t Slum p a nd Exc ess I nf l at i on i n E u ro pe P e r v e n c h e B erés I would like to start by drawing my conclusion relating to the topic of this panel. I believe that it is much more likely that Europe and the rest of the world are now moving faster and faster towards a deep recession with more unemployment and thus lower inflation, especially as the demand for oil and other commodities decreases. Stagflation – high inflation together with declining growth – is no longer likely. We are much more likely to see a prolonged period of slow or even negative growth. statement, the Bank of England warned that the economy in the UK was set for a “severe contraction” in the coming months. Even with consumer-price inflation running at 5.2 percent, the bank saw a need to react to the sharp downturn in the economy. One can then only wonder why the European Central Bank (ECB) has been slow to react in terms of interest policy to the main challenge of slower or even minus growth next year. I am Pervenche Berés Chairwoman of the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs, European Parliament, Brussels “We are much more likely to see a prolonged period of slow or even negative growth.” But the future economic development also depends on the policy actions to be taken not only by us in Europe, but also in the rest of the world, notably in the US, China and in the oil producing countries. Let me start by explaining the reasons for my conclusion. Last week the International Monetary Fund revised its economic forecast within a month of its biannual world outlook and said that advanced economies were likely to contract in 2009 for the fi rst time since the Second World War. Last week the Bank of England also slashed interest rates to their lowest level since 1955, when the bank’s benchmark interest rate was lowered by 1.5 basis points, to 3 percent. In an extended sure this is an issue which will be debated in the near future. I would also like to make a short comparison to the stagflation era of the 1970s. As in the 1970s inflation was driven higher by commodities, which, led by the US, resulted in subsequent global growth slowing. However, I would argue that there are several differences, making stagflation highly unlikely today. Unlike the 1970s, there is no wage-price spiral in sight today as wages are no longer indexed to inflation. There are also no governmental price controls. Furthermore, on the eve of the crisis commodity prices rose mainly due to positive demand shocks rather than to negative supply shocks. The current fall in aggregate demand, with inelastic supply in the short run, together with the global slowdown should therefore result in a reduction, rather than an increase, in inflationary pressures. Finally, the credit crisis and asset deflation in the developed world is spreading and we are experiencing falling inflation. My second point is that we urgently need to act together at the EU and global level to establish a strong and coherent plan for economic policy for the near future. At the EU 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 14 Panel 1 level we need a fiscal stimulus approach in an environment in which monetary policy is not by itself effective enough under current market conditions and consumers are more and more afraid to consume. It has become clear that Keynes is still relevant today. The fiscal stimuli should not only be timely, targeted and temporary, but they should also be large enough and co-ordinated at least at the EU level, if not globally. They must be timely, so that they reach the economy quickly and effectively. They must be targeted so that they do not provide help to sectors that do not need it, leaving an excessive deficit and stock of public debt to be paid off in the future. We need to focus on the sectors that would really have a “demand” increasing effect. I am not sure, for instance, that Europe should copy the US and concentrate support on the car industry, as the demand multiplier is not straightforward. Scarce resources need to be used in the most effective way. The plans must be temporary, so that the idea of anti-cyclicality of fiscal policy is preserved, which is also connected with the sectors chosen. They must also done after a co-ordinated view on the direction to take concerning economic policy has been established. I am therefore happy that the Commission has decided to come forward earlier with its views on a recovery plan in order to give a co-ordinated and coherent approach to the challenges that lie ahead. Finally I would like to comment on the discussions at the global level. As we all know the challenges posed by global imbalances have not disappeared. For example, there has been a massive global redistribution of income from oil importers to oil exporters – a disproportionate number of which are undemocratic states. Economic adjustments of this magnitude have naturally been painful, even more so as the “winners” in this case are less prone to spend, in particular, in the current financial environment. For a long time there has been concern about global imbalances caused mainly by the United States’ huge overseas borrowing. This policy is not sustainable, as we have seen today. And now the president of the US has launched a new comprehensive stimulus package, making the public deficit even larger. Things would obviously have been better if issues relating to global imbalances and regulatory weaknesses could have been addressed at an earlier stage. “It has become clear that Keynes is still relevant today.” be large enough to have a real effect and be credible. Finally these plans must be co-ordinated so that they reinforce each other and increase the impact on the economies. If member states take independent actions to support their export markets, these measures may be ineffective or even counter-productive if they are not co-ordinated with other member states of the same economic area, such as the euro area. The revised Stability and Growth Pact provides room to manoeuvre in the EU, even if the deficits of many members states have resulted in constraints because of too little action in a healthy economic environment. The pact allows the deficit to be temporary and slightly above 3 percent of GDP. Member states need to revise their stability and convergence programmes based on this new economic situation and Commission forecasts. And they should also update and strengthen their national implementation programmes under the Lisbon Strategy for Growth and Jobs. If they do not, we are not serious about economic co-ordination in the EU and in particular in the euro area. This should be 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 In conclusion, I would also like to stress the needs of the developing world, which may be forgotten in the current crisis. When we in the western world are forced to invest trillions to capitalise our financial institutions, we may have difficulties keeping our promises to the developing world. But for them it may be a question of life and death. The reform of global governance has only started and I believe and hope we will make progress in the coming months and years. Panel 1 15 K a i C a r s t e n se n T he title of this panel was set some months ago when inflation was indeed a problem and expected to rise with rising wage costs. With the output slump ahead of us that’s probably not a problem any more. The first part of the crisis concerns the solvency problems in the banking sector. Banks are currently having tremendous problems with refinancing, and the current asset price deflation is adding even more stress on banks and capitalisation. Only with government action have we been able to prevent a system-wide collapse. This has growth engine for Europe and the world economy in 2009 and 2010. Given the structural problems of the US economy – over-consumption over the past years driven by wealth increase, the current account deficit and the crisis in the banking system – the current recession in the US will not be a mild one. Instead we can expect something near a deep recession. This will, of course, have an adverse impact on the world economy and Europe. The Ifo Business Cycle Clock from the World Economic Survey shows Western Europe in a Kai Carstensen Head, Business Cycle Analyses and Surveys Departement, Ifo Institute, Munich “Only with government action have we been able to prevent a system-wide collapse.” had consequences for the business cycle conditions, in particular in the US. But also in Europe we see that the credit supply is not flowing as smoothly as before and it’s becoming more difficult for firms to get new credit. The second part of the crisis is more structural. The current account deficit of the US is probably at the root of the problem. It’s now at roughly 5 percent of GDP, which is really a huge number. And at the same time house and share prices have fallen from their peaks, and there is currently no sign that they will stop falling. What are the consequences of all this? With the structural imbalances in the US, consumption in the US and economy-wide borrowing from abroad will have to come down to a sustainable level. This will require adjustments beyond the very short term. The US will probably go through a sustained period of relatively low growth. This implies that the US will not be the recession scenario, in other words a situation in which economic experts tell us that the present economic situation is bad and will become even worse in the coming six months. Other indicators also confirm that Europe is currently in a recession and that we won’t come out of it very quickly. As I mentioned at the start, inflation is no longer a risk. But what about deflation? Are we heading for a Japanese scenario with very long, sustained low growth rates and general price deflation? If we look at the available figures, deflation seems to be far removed. Current inflation measurements do not indicate this and if we forecast inflation for the coming two years with a baseline scenario for the euro area of a constant dollar/ euro exchange rate at 1.28, a constant (Brent) oil price at 57 dollars and price indices for food and agricultural raw materials constant at their current dollar levels, then inflation in 2009 would decrease to 2.0 percent. The base effect of the decline in oil prices will show in core inflation in 2009. This is a baseline scenario, which of course does not take into account any further negative growth shocks. Using a deflation risk scenario, projected inflation for 2009 would be 1.3 percent. So we would still be safely away from deflation, but inflation would come down quickly in the coming year. Overall, the results of this exercise is that core inflation – which is what really matters when 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 16 Panel 1 we think about deflation – will come down next year but it will be safely away from zero and as a consequence the current deflation discussion is probably not the main risk for the European economy. This could of course change if we witness further business cycle shocks, but given the current situation there is not much risk of deflation, defined as a general and sustained decrease in prices in the EU. Let me summarise. There is no inflation problem ahead for the euro area right now. In particular the output slump will relieve the price pressure we have seen in the previous quarters. Still, deflation is not really the scenario we should worry about. But we have bad news on the business cycle. The US recession and the state of the world economy will both be problems for the EU economy. We see this in orders and production and many other indicators for the EU economy. And as a consequence, if we use as a benchmark the economic experts that we survey in Europe, Europe is also currently in recession, not in stagflation. Prices are not the problem, output is the problem. D i scu ssi on In the discussion, Gerhard Stahl observed that Europe has regarded the US as the more dynamic economic model with greater flexibility and productivity. Now with the US entering a period of low growth rates, should Europeans rethink some of the conclusions drawn in the past and revise some of the EU’s economic policies? Pervenche Berès replied that the EU in drafting its Lisbon Agenda tried to tackle the problem of lower productivity in comparison to the US. This was one pillar of the Lisbon Agenda. Another pillar was the emphasis on energy and climate change adopted in 2007 to help reach the goals of the Agenda. “The debate today concerns being coherent with what we have adopted. If the US doesn’t change its model, there’s going to be a drama. You cannot have an economy that only lives on debt. At the time the Lisbon Agenda was conceived it was to help Europe catch up with the US. Today the Lisbon Agenda presents Europe’s solution for a better model for growth.” Kai Carstensen observed that the regulation of financial markets in the US and some other features of the US economy have proven not to be the right way. “But still the US economy is a very innovative, productive and flexible 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 economy. Not everything the US stands for is bad. For Europe too a market economy is the best system and to function it needs a strong government that sets the rules and framework. But we should not make the government a player in the markets; it’s not a very good player. The current government participation in banks will hopefully be just for a limited period of time.” Pervenche Berès responded that the crisis came about not because of a lack of regulation but due to bad regulation. “I fully share the view that governments are not good shareholders. But the challenge today is that all the banking rescue plans have been financed by public budgets. Banks have been rescued so they can fulfil their mandate – to finance the real economy. If the governments are giving the banks money, why shouldn’t they exercise shareholder rights?” She argued that the government as rescuer of the banks must have more say regarding issues such as dividends, executive pay, offshore activities, long-term investments and SME financing. For Hans-Werner Sinn the public debate on this issue is very irritating: “It seems to be saying that we followed the liberal path and it didn’t work, now let’s try the statist approach. If only it were that easy. For economists it’s always a problem of finding the optimum between the extremes. What is the right amount of government and private activity and where is the borderline between these two sectors? The public doesn’t understand that economists are for labour market deregulation, for flexible wages and prices, but also for tough banking regulation. This is not a contradiction. It’s the model on which the German social market economic order is built. We have a tough government that sets the rules but is not itself a player.” 17 P anel 2 E u ro p ean Ta x Policy – Taxat i on of Mu ltin at iona ls R o b e r t Ve r r ue W hat should the Commission’s contribution be to helping the European economy recover? Clearly the main instruments for stimulating demand and employment are in the hands of the member states, in particular as regards short-term developments. But the financial crisis has also shown the need for international co-ordination and international regulation. Since the impact of the credit crisis is being felt by the real economy, the European Commission and European Council are developing a strategy to help limiting the effects on growth and real expansion. That means pressing ahead with the key objectives of the Lisbon strategy and reaffirming the commitment to the development of a strong dynamic single market, which is the key driver for economic expansion in the European Union. The Commission’s initiative in the taxation of multinationals is of great importance. Multinationals – large or medium-sized companies, that operate across several member states in the European Union – still face considerable tax obstacles in the internal market as it exists today. They have to comply with up to 27 different tax codes of which each one is inherently complex and also subject to ongoing changes. The requirement compensation for profit and losses. The current functioning of the corporate tax system in the EU causes not only over- and double taxation but additional compliance costs when it comes to cross-border situations. These obstacles result in considerable loss in economic efficiency. Of course without the internal market with its freedoms, the drive and functioning of multinational companies would be tremendously more difficult. However, today we do not exploit the full potential of the internal market, particularly within the tax domain. And albeit it is up to each individual member state to shape a proper tax environment, i.e., an environment which is conducive to competitiveness, growth and jobs, the EU can play a useful and important supportive role, perhaps a more sophisticated role that one may think. Despite the widespread feeling that Brussels wants to harmonise everything, the Commission does not want to harmonise anything for the sake of harmonisation. It prefers harmonisation only in specific fields where it is supposed to result in a better functioning of the internal market. Regulations and directives do have their place but they are not always the best way to achieve the objectives. Frequently much Robert Verrue Director-General, Taxation and Customs Union Directorate-General, European Commission, Brussels “Today we do not exploit the full potential of the internal market, particularly within the tax domain”. to apply separate entity accounting to integrated corporate groups gives rise to costly transferpricing obligations and the absence of cross-border greater emphasis is put on soft laws, co-ordination and co-operation. If harmonisation and coordination of national policy can be achieved without legislation, so much the better. But in some cases legislation would clearly and will clearly continue to be the best available option. There are several initiatives put forward by European institutions that helped to achieve significant progress in the taxation domain. One is the amended merger directive that made cross-border economic restructuring much easier and con- 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 18 Panel 2 sequently permitted companies to react more quickly to market developments. Another example is reducing or eliminating double taxation in cross-border business. Here progress towards this aim has been achieved with our proposal for a code of conduct on the way the arbitration conventions should work. This was based on the work of the EU Joint Transfer Pricing Forum, which brings together transferring pricing experts from the private sector and national fiscal authorities. Thanks to this soft law initiative the member states have agreed to effectively eliminate double taxation within three years and they have committed themselves to ensuring that during the resolution of cross-border disputes, tax collection can be suspended under the same conditions as in domestic appeals and litigation. A third example is simplifying the tax system in order to reduce compliance costs. To simplify compliance with VAT regulations, the Commission has proposed a amendment to the 6th VAT Directive. A onestop shop system would allow traders to fulfil all their obligations for all EU-wide activities in the member states where they are established. Traders would use a single VAT number for all supplies throughout the EU and make their VAT declaration via a single electronic portal. The declaration would then be submitted automatically to the various member countries where the traders supply goods and services. with those of the other member states and with the EC treaty. The aim is not to lay down uniform harmonised tax rules at a community level. What is needed is a co-ordination of tax rules in such a way that member states achieve their national policy objectives in compliance with community law. Co-ordination should ensure that member states eliminate discrimination and international double taxation, both of which have no place in a true single market. It can also eliminate an intentional double taxation and can strengthen tax systems against tax avoidance and evasion. Therefore in 2006 the Commission launched a framework initiative which was followed up by a number of more specific initiatives with the aim to ensure that member states direct tax rules would not only be in compliance with the EC treaty obligations but also with each other. This is a comprehensive tax policy initiative to respond to problems posed by the interaction of 27 national tax systems. ”Co-ordination should ensure that member states eliminate discrimination and international double taxation“. In the longer term the most ambitious and most significant measure would be the introduction of a common consolidated corporate tax base for all EU-wide activities. Here the harmonisation would only cover the tax base, not the tax rates. Setting rates should remain in the competency of member states. A common consolidated tax base would, however, promote transparency, clarity and simplification. It would bring a significant reduction in compliance costs. It would also allow cross-border offsetting of profits and losses, and it would remove most of the tax obstacles to crossborder activities and the restructuring of groups of companies in the internal market. Commission services have completed a considerable amount of work on the Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) proposal and have benefited from the highly valuable input from member state experts and other interested parties in conducting this project. They are now in the process of preparing the final steps of the detailed impact assessment and are drafting a comprehensive proposal for legislation. In the short term the main priority is to help member states make their tax systems compatible 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 Panel 2 19 T h i e s s Bü t tn e r M y presentation this afternoon is aimed at showing you what will happen if there is no European policy on taxation and if no co-ordination is achieved. There is a common perception in Europe that large corporations manage to pay little or no taxes. The Finance Committee of the German Parliament, for example, expressed this view in 2007: “As a consequence of the high tax burden, internationally operating firms arrange their profits in a way that a substantial part is taxed in countries with lower tax rates.” This is an important issue and it involves the “tax planning” that corporations undertake. Larger firms are also perceived as receiving preferential treatment over small firms, which are not in a position to engage in this sort of tax planning. This of course raises equity concerns. A smaller company has to pay higher taxes and at the same time compete with larger firms that are paying less tax. The question confronting tax policy-makers is whether something can be done about tax planning. Are there instruments to restrict tax planning and how should they be used? I would like to use the example of tax legislation in Europe to show that there are some tools for restricting the tax planning of multinationals. But I will also look at the possible adverse implications of these measures for investment. be looking at the emergence of firms that have very little equity, perhaps for tax reasons, and how governments have responded to this with thin capitalisation rules. I will look at empirical evidence to see if these rules are effective in restricting tax planning as well as what effect they have on investment. One important element in multinational corporations’ tax planning is related to the financial structure. While the taxation of corporate profits generally results in an incentive to use debt instead of equity, multinationals can adjust the financial structure not only by means of external debt but also internally by using inter-company loans to and from foreign affiliates. Faced with an increased ability of multinational corporations to use debt finance, governments often respond by imposing thin-capitalisation rules. A general characteristic of theses rules is to limit interest deduction if the debt-to-equity ratio of an affiliate is above a certain threshold. Thiess Büttner Head, Public Finance Department, Ifo Institute, Munich These rules are very much in vogue, but there is not much evidence on the consequences of these rules and whether they are effective. The first question we ask is: If a country applies or tightens these rules, do we see a significant response in the capital structure of the foreign firms that are active in the country. Here our “A smaller company has to pay higher taxes and at the same time compete with larger firms that are paying less tax.” I will look at one specific detail of international tax law that is currently on the agenda in some countries. I will examine thinly capitalised firms, and more specifically at firms in the producing sector and not the financial sector. I will analysis shows that these rules are indeed associated with a significant reduction in firms’ use of internal debt. Our second question: Are these rules really a means to reduce the tax incentive for capital structure choice and can we really remove the tax-planning incentive? The results of our study confirm that thin-capitalization restrictions effectively remove the incentive for tax planning by means of inter-company loans. The third question concerns the impact on investment. We have evidence that investment strongly responds 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 20 Panel 2 to anti-tax-planning measures or thin capitalisation rules. The results are sizable. Investment declines when these rules are in place; if they are removed, the estimate is that foreign investment will increase by five percentage points in the short run and by a higher rate in the long run. Tax policy thus faces the trade-off between limiting multinationals’ tax planning and the negative impact on investment. What can we conclude from these fi ndings? First we must acknowledge that the uncooperative tax policies that we have in Europe force countries to implement thin capitalisation rules. Discussions are in progress in Europe to change this situation, but the current situation forces countries to impose these restrictions. The tax-induced capital structure adjustment that fi rms undertake in response to the current tax situation is quite costly. This means that there is high “collateral damage” of thin capitalisation rules. What we also see is that the continuation of national attempts to protect taxable earnings leads to a rather costly and complex tax system in Europe. The longer it takes for Europe to fi nd a coordinated or at least cooperative approach to taxing “Tax policy thus faces the trade-off between limiting multinationals’ tax planning and the negative impact on investment.” corporations in Europe, the more the phenomenon we are describing will flourish. It is thus very important that we have a discussion on a common, consolidated tax base. The results of our study suggest that this would bring about large efficiency gains. Fortunately, we now have a large body of academic literature on a common, consolidated tax base, which raises the hope that academic research and European policy may be moving in the same direction and that a more effective solution to this problem will be found. 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 example shows that you can have an extensive social model and at the same time be highly competitive. And this is the challenge we now have to face in the European Union. Ap p e nd i x 22 Appendix Pro gra mme D e spe rate R e m ed ies: Lesso n s fro m t h e C r isis 10.15 am Welcome Addresses Hans-Werner Sinn President, Ifo Institute, Munich Gerhard Stahl Secretary-General, Committee of the Regions, Brussels 10.30 am I nt rod uc tor y D eb ate Financial and Economic Crisis: Causes and Consequences Joaquín Almunia Commissioner for Economic and Monetary Policy, European Commission, Brussels Hans-Werner Sinn President, Ifo Institute, Munich Discussion 12.15 pm 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 Lunch Appendix 1.15 pm 23 Pa n el 1 Stagflation Ahead? Output Slump and Excess Inflation in Europe Pervenche Berés Chairwoman, Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs, European Parliament, Brussels Kai Carstensen Head, Business Cycle Analyses and Surveys Department, Ifo Institute, Munich Discussion 2.45 pm Coffee Break 3.00 pm Pa n el 2 European Tax Policy – Taxation of Multinationals Robert Verrue Director General, Taxation and Customs Union Directorate–Gerneral, European Commission, Brussels Thiess Büttner Head, Public Finance Department, Ifo Institute, Munich Discussion 4.00 pm Concluding Remarks Hans-Werner Sinn President, Ifo Institute, Munich 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 24 Appendix BrIEF Org an is er s T Committee of the Regions he Committee of the Regions (CoR) is the political assembly that provides local and regional authorities with a voice at the heart of the European Union. Established in 1994, the CoR was set up to address two main issues. Firstly, about three quarters of EU legislation is implemented at the local or regional level, so it makes sense for local and regional representatives to have a say in the development of new EU laws. Secondly, there were concerns that the public was being left behind as the EU steamed ahead. One way of closing the gap was involving the elected level of government closest to the citizens. The European Treaties oblige the Commission and Council to consult the Committee of the Regions whenever new proposals are made in areas that have repercussions at the regional or local level. The Maastricht Treaty set out five such areas – economic and social cohesion, trans-European infrastructure networks, health, education and culture. The Amsterdam Treaty added another five areas to the list – employment policy, social policy, the environment, vocational training and transport – which now covers much of the scope of the EU’s activity. Outside these areas, the Commission, Council and European Parliament have the option to consult CoR on issues if they see important regional or local implications to a proposal. CoR can also draw up an opinion on its own initiative, which enables it to put issues on the EU agenda. There are three main principles at the heart of the Committee’s work. Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the Universitiy of Munich Subsidiarity. This principle, written into the Treaties at the same time as the creation of CoR, means that decisions within the European Union should be taken at the closest practical level to the citizen. The European Union, therefore, should not take on tasks that are better suited to national, regional or local administrations. Proximity. All levels of government should aim to be close to the citizens, in particular by organising their work in a transparent fashion, so people know who is in charge of what and how to make their views heard. Partnership. Sound European governance means European, national, regional and local government working together – all four are indispensable and should be involved throughout the decision making process. 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 T he Ifo Institute, founded in January 1949, derives its name and purpose from two words: Information and Forschung (research). The Ifo Institute is one of the leading economic research institutes in Germany and the one most often quoted in the media. A co-operative agreement links it closely with the Ludwig Maximilian University (LMU) in Munich, and in 2002 it was officially proclaimed an “Institute at the University of Munich”. The Ifo Institute is a member of the Leibniz Association and its research funding is anchored in the German constitution. Mission and tasks The Ifo Institute is an independent and competent • producer of data and information on the national and international economic situation and its development, which is in great demand in industry, in government and by the public, • a driving force and impetus-giver for the debate on economic policy in Germany and Europe, as well as • an internationally oriented centre of empirical economic research. The tasks of the Ifo Institute are threefold: Services for researchers, business, government and the general public The Ifo Institute dedicates a large part of its capacity to economic-policy services, including the compilation, processing and the provision of economic data and information, the compilation of material for the comparison of international institutions within the framework of DICE – the Database for Institutional Comparisons in Europe – and the collection and processing of other macroeconomic data. Applied economic research The Ifo Institute acts as a mediator between university research and the general public, including the media, by applying theoretical knowledge gained from its compiled economic data to practical economic policy. Policy consulting for the public and private sectors The Ifo Institute uses its database and research competence to participate in the public debate on economic policy and reform concepts. National and international co-operation partners The Institute fosters the exchange of ideas with institutions, universities and researchers throughout the world. Apart from its close ties to LMU, co-operation with its other partners also enriches the work of the Institute. Numerous networks have been created from project co-operations. © Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Publisher: Ifo Institute Editors: Paul Kremmel Jutta Albrecht Photography: Romy Bonitz Layout and design: Jasmin Tschauth, Elisabeth Will and Kinga Bien Printing: Majer & Finckh, Stockdorf Conference venue: Committee of the Regions Bâtiment Jacques Delors Room: JDE 51 Rue Belliard 99–101 1040 Brussels Belgium Contacts: Executive committee: Jutta Albrecht Ifo Institute for Economic Research Tel. 00 49/(0)89-92 24-13 32 Mail: [email protected] Annette Hagemann Committee of the Regions Tel. 00 32/22 82-20 09 Mail: [email protected] 2nd Ifo BrIEF 2008 2nd Ifo BrIEF Ifo Brussels International Economic Forum Desperate Remedies: Lessons from the Crisis 11 November 2008 Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich