Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
RURAL CHANGE The Challenge for Agricultural Economists PROCEEDINGS SEVENTEENTH INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMISTS Held at Banff, Canada 3rd-12th SEPTEMBER 1979 Edited by Glenn Johnson, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, USA and Allen Maunder, Institute of Agricultural Economics University of Oxford, England INTERNATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMISTS INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS OXFORD 1981 Gower CSABA CSAKI National Agricultural Sector Models for Centrally Planned Economies Because food production is one of the most decentralized activities of mankind and nations are the largest units in which agricultural problems appear in their full complexity, the study of national food and agricultural systems has always been under focus of research in food and agriculture. At IIASN to study the world's food and agricultural problems, consistent national agricultural policy models are going to be constructed and linked. In this paper the first results of IIASA's modelling work on centrally planned food and agriculture systems are summarized. 1 OBJECTIVES AND MAJOR ASSUMPTIONS IN THE MODELLING OF CENTRALLY PLANNED FOOD AND AGRICULTURE SYSTEMS In the CMEA 2 member countries, agricultural policy and policy goals are determined according to the central plans of the countries. The basic figures of production and consumption are fixed by the national plan and realized by a co-ordinated system of sectoral (industry, agriculture, etc.), regional, local (country, city, etc.) and enterprise plans. Therefore, the major policy goals in agriculture are to ensure a level of consumption to satisfy industrial needs in agricultural products as determined by the national plan. Thus the government's agricultural aims are the following: the satisfactory growth of food production by increased efficiency and productivity in agriculture; a certain degree of self-sufficiency of the country in agricultural products; optimization of foreign exchange earnings from agriculture; the improvement of living and working conditions of the population. From the above mentioned policy objectives in each country in a given period of time only few and not by any means all are emphasized. The methods for realization of these policy objectives often differ. Though agricultural policies of the individual countries are not unified, we intend 312 National agricultural sector models 313 to model the European centrally planned economies on the basis of a common model structure. We believe that the similarity of major agricultural policy objectives, and the fact that the food and agricultural sector is an integral part of the centrally planned national economy, fully justifies our approach. Using the experiences gained from former agricultural modelling work in socialist countries and the results of methodological research on the general structure and linkage of national sector models, 3 we aimed at the development of a relatively new model structure for centrally planned food and agriculture systems. This structure should incorporate the basic features of the CMEA member countries' economy, should be suitable to incorporate the specific features of the individual CMEA countries, should be consistent and comparable with other parts of liAS A's Food and Agricultural model system should be detailed enough to be used as an experimental tool for investigations connected with the development of food and agriculture, and would hopefully contribute to the further development of techniques applicable in the planning and management offood and agriculture. 2 THE GENERAL MODEL STRUCTURE The basic characteristics of the IIASA model for centrally planned food and agriculture systems is determined by the main objective of this modelling effort. Our main goal is not straightforward optimization, but to make a tool that offers opportunities for a better understanding of the dynamic behaviour of the centrally planned agricultural systems and the interactions of their elements, so that the model can also be used for midand long-range projections. Unlike the normative agricultural models that have been developed, this model has a descriptive character. It reflects the present operation of the centrally planned food production systems and, therefore, the present decision-making practices and economic management of the government are described. At the same time, various normative elements, such as government decisions and published plan targets influencing the projected operation of the system, are also considered. In the model we try to endogenize a large part of the economic environment and the most important factors of food production. Food and agriculture is modelled as a disaggregated part of an economic system closed at the national as well as at the international level. Therefore our model has the following features: the food consumption sphere is incorporated; the non-food production sectors of the economy are represented by Adjustment of objectives _j n .0 , L_;r~ =-w=-e=-a·:/'.l,:lt...e:-r:-:~1-------E~L~::::.J---.Jit'Lr= ~====~---1~~-t~--~--~~::::::r--:E~x~c~h~a~ng;e~"l~ = module ~ Producer's 1._.,.___~ Resources r--L I decision IEnvironment Initial Stage FIG. 1 ~ I Resources 111-------------- ,-----1 ..... J Environment World market net prices ~.,_ ____________,. I General structure of the model. The detailed mathematical structure of the model is described in'. Next Period National agricultural sector models 315 assuming that they produce only one aggregated commodity; the economic, technical, biological, and human aspects of food production are covered; both the production of agricultural raw materials and food processing are modelled; under "other" agricultural production and food processing, all products not individually represented are aggregated; and financial equilibrium is maintained. The structure of the model is outlined in Figure 1. The overall methodology used by the model is a simulation technique. For the description of subsystems, suitable techniques, e.g. linear and nonlinear programming, econometric methods, are employed. The model is dynamic, with a one-year time increment. Subperiods within the year are not considered. The time horizon of the analysis is 15-20 years. Random effects of weather and animal disease conditions can also be considered. Long-range government objectives such as the growth of the whole economy, the growth rate of food production and consumption, a given relation of consumption to accumulation, and a given positive balance of payments in food and agriculture are considered exogenously as they are determined by the long-range development plan of the national economy. The model is focused on the development of food and agriculture (production structure, investments) and its interaction with the rest of the economy. The major steps of the solution can be described as follows: 1 As a first step the overall growth targets are settled for a given year based on long-range objectives and results of the previous period. After setting targets for gross and net production the planned consumption and accumulation funds are calculated, determining the targets for consumption of individual commodities and investment funds in food and agriculture as well as in the rest of the economy. 2 Next a detailed plan for food and agriculture is determined considering available resources and minimum required production of certain commodities. 3 As a third step the behaviour of producers (state and co-operative farms, private producers) is described and the random effects on the final output of food and agriculture as well as the rest of the economy are calculated. In the model both direct and indirect instruments of government can be handled to realize the production targets of the central planners. According to the government's economic management system (more or less decentralization) in a given country the producer's decision model and relations between government and producers might be modelled in various ways. 4 The Exchange Module compares supply and demand. Here export and import figures, final private consumption and investments are calculated satisfying the balance of trade equilibrium constraint. The model can be linked with other IIASA national models through this model part. To express the reaction of a centrally planned economy to changing world 316 Csaba Csaki market conditions a special equilibrium type of model has been developed. 5 As the final results for a given year are obtained, overall government objectives and policy instruments (prices, tax rates, etc.) are adjusted based on the analysis of the performance of the whole system. The available resources and some of the model parameters are also updated. 3 A PROTOTYPE MODEL: HUNGARIAN AGRICULTURAL MODEL(HAM) As a first step in the realization of IIASA's objectives in the modelling of centrally planned agricultural systems, the Hungarian Agricultural Model has been developed as a prototype for the modelling of CMEA countries. This work is a joint undertaking of IIASA and three institutions in Hungary. 4 HAM structure has been developed according to the general principles summarized above. Figure 2 shows the structure of the final version of the model. HAM is in fact a system of interconnected models. Two spheres are differentiated within the system. The economic management and planning submodel describes the decision-making and control activities of the government. The submodel of real sphere covers the whole national economy, including the disaggregated food production sector. The major blocks of the latter submodel are related to production, consumption and trade as well as updating available resource and model parameters. In Hungary the overall targets of food and agriculture are realized mostly using indirect economic means (price, tax, subsidies), therefore HAM represents a decentralized version of our general model structure, where producer's decisions play quite an important role. HAM-I HAM is the first system simulation model to describe the Hungarian food and agriculture sector. The former modelling works offered many useful experiences but in several cases HAM applies entirely new approaches and the development of HAM requires the analysis of several possible alternative methodological solutions. Therefore, to avoid the difficulties of immediately working with a large scale system, we have decided to develop first a more aggregated, relatively simplified model version (HAM-1). 5 Hungarian food and agriculture is described in HAM-1 on a relatively high level of aggregation. The Hungarian food and agriculture is represented by 5 agricultural and 4 processed food commodities, the 1Oth commodity is related to the rest of the economy. Practically all the model commodities represent a relatively wide range of products. On the whole, approximately the whole Hungarian food and agriculture and the national economy as well are covered. Therefore the computed results of I l I I I I UD: Updating Parameters UD-1 Demographic changes UD--2 Land and physical resources - -- UD 3 Updating Block GM p parameters UD 4 Updating Block P parameters I I I I J I I I CM-P: Government Economic Planning CM-A: I Economic Analysis of Government I CM p 1 Calculation of major economic goals CM p ~ GM A 1 Fixing consumption targets CM p 3 Government plan for food production GM p 4 Government investments ,. t-- Revision of policy variables intluencing the system I Revision of prices UD: ! Updating Parameters r P: Production 1'- P--1 Household & private agriculture ~ P-2 Socialist agriculture P--3 Final output of agriculture P-4 Food processing P---5 Rest of the economy P--6 GM A 2 I Investment of farms CT: Consumption & Trade CT I Committed expenditures UD I Demographic changes UD r--- CT 2 Consumer demand CT-3 Exchange module CT Financial accounts 4 I Previous period FIG. 2 Schematic structure of the second version of the Hungarian Agricultural Model r- ~ Land and physical resources UD 3 Updating Block GM--1' parameters UD 4 Updating Block P parameters I I I I I I ~ I lz;: r. n. I"" 318 Csaba Csaki HAM-1 can be compared with the actual indicators of Hungarian food and agriculture and the national economy. HAM-1 is based on official Hungarian statistics. The methodological character of the HAM-1 experiment allowed us to be less exacting and sophisticated in data preparation. Most of the model parameters have been calculated using the data of the Hungarian National Statistical Bureau and the Ministry of Food and Agriculture. The consumers' demand system has been estimated at IIASA based on time series. HAM-1 is structured according to our general model outline and has all of the features described above. Besides the commodity coverage, the simplified features of HAM-1 mean the following: different sectors of agricultural production (state farms, co-operative farms, household plots) are not considered, only the so-called socialist agricultural production (state and co-operative farms together) is modelled, weather random effects on agricultural production are not directly included, in some cases (e.g. savings function) less sophisticated mathematical formulation is applied, the description of the government's policy instrument revising activities (e.g. pricing) can be considered as the first preliminary approach, no separate CMEA market is considered. During 1978 numerous runs of HAM-1 have been executed. The results of these investigations supported the appropriateness of our approach and proved that the IIASA's model structure really can contribute to the further development of planning techniques and is suitable for various investigations connected with the development of the centrally planned food and agriculture systems. (Figure 3 shows the impacts of various government policies on the development of the Hungarian food and agriculture as forecasted by HAM-1.) HAM-1 also led us to several methodological conclusions that are very important for the further refinement of the model. HAM-2 The second version of HAM has been completed recently. The Hungarian food and agriculture as well as economic management system are modelled in HAM-2 in a rather disaggregated way. There are 45 food and agriculture commodities considered in the model. The detailed structure ofHAM-2 can be seen in Figure 2. As far as the methodology of the model is concerned, first of all our attempts to describe the agricultural policy-making and planning activities of the government have to be pointed out. In HAM-2 the implementation of given policy objectives is fully endogenized. Government plan targets on food and agriculture are determined by a linear programming model assuming that central planners want to maximize National agricultural sector models 319 ]" 600 s l!l c ·;:: ................... .s c ·-·-·-·-·- "' ·;:: ~ ::r: ---Base' -·-V04) 2 ----VI4) 3 12 0 13 14 IS 16 Years FIG. 3 GNP in food and agriculture as projected by HAM -1 ' Basic Variant expresses the present operation of Hungarian food and agriculture. • Variant 4: world market prices are used as domestic producer prices using 1 US$ = 30 Hung. Ft. exchange rate. • Variant 14: instead of 100% only 70% is the required level of self-sufficiency from food and agricultural commodities. Csaba Csaki 320 foreign exchange earnings from food and agriculture beside a given level of self-sufficiency. The adjustment of overall objectives and policy instruments is modelled by heuristic routines. This is one of the first attempts at a mathematical description of the pricing mechanism in a centrally planned economy. The food and agricultural production is modelled according to producing sectors. The socialist agriculture (state and co-operative forms) is modelled by a linear programming model, the behaviour of private and household farms is described by supply functions and a separated model block is related to the food processing. A simulation type of model is constructed to describe the investment decisions of producing firms. The output of the non-food producing part of the economy is calculated by a Cobb-Douglas type function. The Exchange Module is a crucial part of the whole system. As was already mentioned, an equilibrium type of model has been constructed to reach the balance of trade equilibrium and adjust to changing international market conditions. In this model, stock adjustment, adjustment of government and other investment as well as private consumption are considered. A special version of extended linear expenditure systems has been estimated to describe consumers' behaviour. The parameters of the two linear programming models are updated based on production functions. HAM-2 can obviously be considered as an element of the IIASA agricultural model system being developed and as such it will be linked with other national models, and used for global investigations. Furthermore HAM-2 is used in the elaboration of the next five year plan of Hungarian food and agriculture. Up until now several runs have been executed to analyse the impacts of various alternatives for agricultural pricing mechanisms. In the very near future the model is intended to be used to investigate the reality of major policy goals, the desired level of self-sufficiency and specialization, the possible strategies of the reaction of the domestic to the world market and changes in export and import structure. 4 AGGREGATEDCMEAMODEL Based on IIASA's model structure and experiences gained by the Hungarian Agricultural Model, an aggreated CMEA model has also been constructed at IIASA. The CMEA model first of all is designed to represent the European centrally planned countries within IIASA's aggregated model system. 6 Therefore our main objective is to develop a model which realistically describes the aggregated behaviour of this group of countries on the international market of agricultural commodities. The model is not for the study of problems of the agricultural development of the CMEA countries in detail. But besides its aggregated character it hopefully will be useful for investigations related to the National agricultural sector models 321 overall problems of agricultural development of these countries. Based on the model, first of all: · the realization of major targets on growth of agricultural production and their main alternatives, the key factors and conditions of realization, the interaction of agricultural and industrial development (more or less investment in agriculture), the feasibility of certain overall targets (consumption versus investment) can be investigated. The CMEA model which actually covers the European CMEA member countries (Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, GDR, Poland, Hungary, USSR, Romania) has a structure consistent with other elements of the aggregated model system including the same commodity coverage. Figure 4 shows the general structure of the model. In the model, similarly to the general structure and HAM, we assume that long-range government objectives are taken as exogenous variables. We also assume that central decisions on the production structure of agriculture are transferred directly to producing enterprises. Therefore a producer's decision model is not included and deviation from targets at the national level is not considered. The production plan of the government is modelled using a non-linear optimization model including constraints on available resources and minimum required production of certain commodities. In the objective function either the net national product of food and agriculture or foreign exchange earnings from the food sector are maximized. The parameters of the production model have been estimated based on FAO data. The Exchange Model is solved similarly to the Hungarian Agricultural Model. The development of private consumption is modelled based on past trends and considering overall objectives on changes in the food consumption structure. In the model three types of prices are distinguished: producer prices, consumer prices and international prices. The domestic prices are expressed in roubles. The initial prices have been calculated as weighted average of the individual country prices using the inter-CMEA exchange rates as published in Hungary. The domestic prices are not modified during the simulation run. As further steps in IIASA modelling work on centrally planned food and agriculture systems the Polish and Bulgarian agricultural models will be developed. In the case of Poland the special role of private farms and in the case of Bulgaria the higher level of centralization in the management of agriculture, represent new features and obviously require special solutions. (J.} N N Adjustment or" objectives '------11---+1·I ConsumptionJ · 1 targets Ir II I Domestic pnces 1 I { [targets nvestm~nt ~ J ·I I Production plan I ----t-·+-1----F----L---+-+-*'--=~-----.... --+~ I Resources Exchange moduk ~ f-J [ ~ L-..1 ;;; f Worldmarketl c ·~.,_ ]s~E j Initial stage FIG. 4 General structure of the CMEA model net pnces Stocks Government Investment Consumption I Export import ]------- r-1 Rl'SOllfL'CS ~1---1------- 1 I Next period National agricultural sector models 323 NOTES 1 International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria. • CMEA = Council for Mutual Economic Assistance. 3 Primarily Prof. Ferenc Rabar's and Michie! Keyzer's works.,e,1 and •· 4 Research Institute for National Planning at the National Planning Bureau, Research Institute for Agricultural Economics of the Ministry of Food and Agriculture, and Department of Agricultural Economics at the K. Marx University of Economic Sciences. • The experiences with HAM-I are discussed in detail in•. • First aggregated version of IIASA's food and agriculture model system. The commodity coverage of the study includes: wheat, rice, coarse grain, bovine and ovine meats, dairy products, other animal products, protein feeds, other food, non-food agriculture, nonagriculture. REFERENCES 1 Csaki, C., Jonas, A., Meszaros S., "Modelling of Centrally Planned Food and Agricultural Systems: A Framework for a National Policy Model for the Hungarian Food and Agricultural Sector", IIASA, RM-78-11. • Csaki, C. "First Version of the Hungarian Agricultural Model" (HAM-I), IIASA, RM-78-38. 3 de Haen, H. Schrader, J.V. Tangermann, S. "Modelling the EC Agricultural Sector: Problem assessment, policy scenarios and model outline", IIASA, RM-78-23. 4 Heady, E.O. Srivestana, U.K. (eds): Spatial Sector Programming Models in Agriculture, Iowa State University Press, Ames, 1975. • Keyzer, M.A. "Linking National Models of Food and Agriculture- An Introduction", IIASA, RM-77-2. • Keyzer, M.A." Analysis of a National Model with Domestic Price Policies and Quota on International Trade", IIASA, RM-77-19. 7 Keyzer, M.A. "International Trade Policies in Models of Barter Exchange", IIASA, RM-77-51. • Parikh, K.S. "A Framework for an Agricultural Policy Model for India", IIASA, RM-77-59. • Rabar, F. "Food and Agriculture Programme Annual Report of IIASA, 1977. 10 Rosmiller, G.E. (ed.) Agricultural Sector Planning -A General System Simulation Approach, Michigan State University, 1978. DISCUSSIONOPENING-MOHINDERS.MUDAHAR Introduction This paper describes national agricultural sector models for centrally planned economies in general and the Hungarian agricultural sector model in particular. It is part of a large modelling effort at IIASA to build global models for the food and agricultural sector. The main purpose is to provide insights to the planners about the development process of the agricultural sector and to provide guidelines for them to formulate agricultural policies which are effective and consistent with national goals. Professor Csaki has presented us interesting and very complicated agricultural sector models in a very limited time and space. The paper summarizes four different but closely related agricultural sector models. These are (a) the general model structure for centrally planned 324 Csaba Csaki economies, (b) the aggregated Hungarian agricultural sector model (HAM I), (c) the disaggregated Hungarian agricultural sector model (HAM II), and (d) aggregated CMEA (Council for Mutual Economic Assistance) model. My knowledge of decision-making in centrally planned economies is rather limited, and the information provided in the paper about the specifics of the models is rather scanty. As a result, I have decided in favour of raising some general issues for discussion and asking some important questions for clarification. I have divided my opening comments into three categories, namely, methodology, empirical analysis, and relevance of the results for policymakers. Methodology I commend Professor Csaki on his ability to develop comprehensive agricultural sector models which incorporate three major modelling approaches, namely, system simulation approach, mathematical programming approach, and econometric approach. However, I have not been able to determine which model components use which of these approaches, how these various methodologies used in different model components are made consistent and linked with each other, or the basis for choosing each of these alternative approaches. From the macro point of view, the objective (or set of objectives) and constraints for the models are specified exogenously. It is not very clear, however, what the optimality criterion is to determine the allocation of physical resources to achieve these objectives at the regional and/or national levels. From the micro point of view, one component of these models deals with the "producer or farmer's decision". However, it is not clear how the farmers make the production decisions with respect to various farm activities, allocation of resources, and what their decision criterion is. For example, in "market-oriented" economies farmers may maximize profit and/or minimize cost and/or minimize risk subject to different behavioural and resource constraints. The model is dynamic with a one-period time increment. Sub-periods within a year are not considered. Since agriculture is seasonal in nature, the models do oversimplify the agricultural sector and thus cannot realistically address very interesting policy issues dealing with seasonal allocation of physical resources and scheduling of marketing, storage, and transportation activities for inputs and outputs. Empirical analysis The paper does not deal with the empirical aspects of these models. I wish that Professor Csaki had chosen instead just one model and provided us with more detail on the methodological and empirical aspects of that model. Since the models reported in the paper are not empiricially tested -except a prototype model for Hungary- it is rather difficult to discuss the associated data needs, estimation of these models, and interpretation of the results. To what extent these models would track the real history of National agricultural sector models 325 the agricultural sector in Hungary or for that matter in any other centrally planned country is a question which can only be answered (a) by comparing model results with actual time series of various variables in the agricultural sector and (b) by subjecting the model results to various validation tests. Professor Csaki has indicated that the empirical results obtained from HAM I support the appropriateness of these models for planning purposes. However, these empirical results and the basis for this conclusion are not reported in the paper. Relevance for policy-makers The models do incorporate producer prices, consumer prices, and international prices for inputs and outputs into various model components. However, it is not clear what the roles of these prices and the shadow prices derived from programming models are. Also, what are the flexibility and constraints imposed in the model to determine consumer and producer prices? What are the other policy instruments incorporated in these models and how do they influence the working of the model structure such that they could provide insights with respect to the implications of various policy instruments and thus be relevant to the policy-makers to achieve the stated goals? Finally, in all fairness, I fully sympathize with Professor Csaki in the sense that it is very difficult to present these complex models in a limited space. However, the answers to these questions would, I believe, be quite informative for our professional colleagues from the so-called "marketoriented" developed and developing countries.