Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Working Papers No. 106/07 Regional Income Dispersion and Market Potential in the Late Nineteenth Century Hapsburg Empire Max Stephan Schulze © Max-Stephan Schulze London School of Economics November 2007 Department of Economic History London School of Economics Houghton Street London, WC2A 2AE Tel: Fax: +44 (0) 20 7955 7860 +44 (0) 20 7955 7730 Regional Income Dispersion and Market Potential in the Late Nineteenth Century Habsburg Empire∗ Max-Stephan Schulze Abstract This paper presents new regional GDP estimates for the Habsburg Monarchy and constructs measures of market potential for its 22 major regions. The paper argues that regional income differentials were significantly larger, that intra-empire catching-up of poor with rich regions was far more limited and that the empire’s Eastern regions were much further behind Western Europe than suggested in the historiography. The measurement of regional market potential proves strongly sensitive to the composition of foreign economies considered in the computations and the choice of regional ‘nodes’. Further, though being ‘remote’ imposed some penalty, there was no uniform relationship between changes in regions’ relative GDP position and their market potential. 1. Introduction The profound regional differences in geography, resource endowments and income across Austria-Hungary and issues of regional division of labour are recurrent themes in the Habsburg historiography (Good 1984; Gross 1973; Freudenberger, 2003; Komlos 1983). In the 1990s, David Good made a persistent effort to quantify regional product in the Habsburg domains as a means to assess the economic lag of EastCentral Europe (Good 1991, 1994, 1997; Good and Ma 1998). According to the 1998 estimates, the poorest region in Austria-Hungary enjoyed per capita incomes that on the eve of the First World War, and after a long process of industrialization in the western regions stretching back to the late ∗ I would like to thank the Economic and Social Research Council for financial support (grant RES-000-22-1598), Felipe Tamega Fernandes for research assistance and Dudley Baines for helpful comments. 18th century (good 1984; Komlos 1983, 1989), were about 60 per cent below that of the richest region and about 30 per cent below the mean of the empire. In the Habsburg case, as elsewhere in Europe, the timing, direction and pace of economic change and industrialization were shaped by regional conditions (Pollard 1986). Yet a theoretically explicit and quantitative analysis of how these factors mattered for the development of the Habsburg economy, and more broadly, Europe’s Eastern and South-Eastern periphery, is still missing. This paper aims at providing some empirical input as a first step towards such an analysis. In terms of GDP per capita, the pre-1913 Austrian economy ranked near the bottom of the European growth league: income rose by less than 1 per cent per annum. By contrast, in Hungary – Austria’s partner in the Habsburg customs union – per capita product increased by about 1.3 per cent during 1870-1913, (Schulze 2000, 2007). The following sections present new (Austria) and revised (Hungary) GDP estimates for the 22 major Habsburg regions as a means of gauging the extent to which empire-wide aggregate product measures mask significant regional variations in levels of economic activity. Further, they provide an input for the analysis of regional differences as a potential source of Austria’s poor comparative growth performance. Finally, the regional product estimates are a key ingredient in the computation of regional market potential as an indicator of a region’s centrality. The guiding idea from location theory is that producers are likely to settle in those locations that offer the best (least costly) access to input (supply) and output (demand) markets (Midelfart-Knarvik et al. 2000). In an essentially descriptive exercise, the estimates for GDP and market potential are used to address three issues. First, what was the extent of regional income differentials across the 22 major regions of the Habsburg Empire and how did these differentials change over time? Second, what do 2 computations of economic potential reveal about the centrality or ‘peripherality’ of the Habsburg regions? Third, to what extent did differences in regional economic performance reflect differences in regional economic potential? 2. Methods and Data 2.1 Estimating Regional GDP Austrian regional GDP levels at constant 1913 prices and for 1870 to 1910 (at 10 year census intervals) have been built up from sector level estimates, mirroring the procedure used in the construction of state-wide aggregates (Schulze 2000). The fourteen regions include: Lower Austria, Upper Austria, Salzburg, Styria, Carinthia, Carniola, Littoral, Tyrol/Vorarlberg, Bohemia, Moravia, Silesia, Galicia, Bukovina and Dalmatia. For Hungary, the paper relies on regional shares in total GDP derived from Good and Ma (1998), applying them to Hungarian total product (Schulze 2000, 2007). The estimates for Hungary cover eight regions: Left Bank Danube, Right Bank Danube, Danube Tisza Basin, Right Bank Tisza, Left Bank Tisza, Tisza Maros Basin, Transylvania and Croatia-Slavonia. Good and Ma adopt a Crafts-type structural equation approach to estimate regional per capita income levels as a function of several proxy variables such as crude death rates, the share of the agricultural labour force and letters posted (Crafts 1983; Good 1994). The procedure and its application to the Habsburg case have been criticized by Pammer (1997) on theoretical and empirical grounds, leading to significant revisions of the estimates (Good, 1997; Good and Ma 1998). The proxy approach offers a way to estimate regional income levels where standard national income measures cannot be computed for lack of essential data. This, at present, is 3 the case for the Hungarian regions. For Austria, though, the sources allow reconstructing regional GDP within a national income accounting framework and from the output side. The key advantage compared to the earlier proxy approach to derive regional GDP estimates is the use of variables and measures that are theoretically linked to GDP. Section 3 below shows that the choice of procedure makes for large differences in outcomes. Crafts (2004, 2007) relies on a modified version of Geary and Stark (2002) to estimate British regional GDP as a function of sectoral wages and sectoral employment, augmented by the evidence from income tax returns to account for the non-wage income component of GDP. Here a different route was adopted. Regional GDPs were estimated for each sector separately, reflecting the differences in data availability for each sector, by estimating regional shares in sectoral output at the national level and then aggregating across sectors (or industry branches) for each region. The national level ‘frame’ of sectoral gross value-added is provided in Schulze (2000, 2007). For crop production this is straightforward as quantities of output for more than twenty major products, valued at 1913 prices, are available from Sandgruber (1978). The same source is used for estimating regional shares in livestock output, using the detailed material that underlies the nationallevel aggregates (Schulze 2000). Mining: regional quantities of the full range of mining products and 1913 prices are readily available from the official statistics (Bergbaustatistik). Regional shares in iron and steel production have been approximated on the basis of regional output of pig iron and cast iron (Huettenwesen). No data are available on the regional distribution of wrought iron and steel output. However, the labour force statistics would indicate that this introduces no undue bias as refining was concentrated in the same regions as smelting (Austria – Census). 4 For manufacturing and construction the regional estimates build on wage and employment data extracted from the statistics of the workers’ accident insurance system (Unfallstatistik). The data differentiate between twelve major industry branches and about 38 sub-branches. For each benchmark year and each industry branch, regional wage sums have been converted into gross value added drawing on industry-specific wage sum/output ratios and value-added proportions from Fellner (1916). In the next step, gross value-added per worker was computed for each industry branch in each region. Finally, and cognizant of the less than full coverage of the accident insurance system, a region’s share in total output of a given industry was computed by multiplying regional gross value-added per worker by regional employment in that industry. The relevant regional industry-level employment data have been taken from the censuses (Austria – Census).1 In the tertiary sector, regional shares in total gross value-added were computed for trade, finance and communications and government, professional and personal services on the basis of labour force statistics as no other data are available (Austria – Census). In the case of the latter, though, this corresponds fully with Kausel’s (1979) series, incorporated in Schulze (2000), which provides the relevant ‘frame’ within which the regional estimates slot. Finally, regional shares in total rental income from housing have been estimated drawing on regional population and differences in regional output per capita (with regional GDP per capita excluding rental income as a proxy for average regional income). 1 For 1870 and 1880, regional shares in industrial output were computed on the basis of weighted 1890 regional output per worker relatives, 1870 (1880) overall industrial output per worker and 1870 (1880) regional industrial employment levels. The regional shares so derived were cross-checked against the material in NIHV and found consistent. 5 The new estimates are documented in Tables 4 to 6 below, contrasting them with the results of Good and Ma’s (1998) earlier proxy approach. 2.2 Estimating Market Potential The market potential of a region depends on economic activity in that region and in other adjacent or distant regions (or countries) adjusted for their proximity. Proximity, in turn, depends on distance between localities over land and sea. Distances over land and sea are converted into equivalent measures using corresponding transport costs. Hence changes over time in a region’s relative market potential can result from either shifts in the spatial distribution of economic activity, changes in relative transport cost or a combination thereof. Market potential can serve as a measure of a region’s economic ‘centrality’ or ‘peripherality’. In the market access literature (Midelfart-Knarvik et al. 2000), the degree of regions’ centrality is expected to impact on firms’ location decisions – all else being equal, producers are likely to locate where they find least costly access to markets for their inputs and outputs. Going back to Harris (1954), the market potential of region i (MPi) can be calculated as increasing in purchasing power or GDP of all regions j (GDPj) and decreasing in distance or transport cost between regions i and j (Dij). This can be formulated as MPi = Σj GDPj*Dγij where γ is a distance weighting parameter set at –1. The regional market potential calculations are augmented by an ‘own’ distance measure Dii. (which is commonly approximated as a function of area size: Dii = 6 0.333√(areai/π))2 and the GDPs of the empire’s main trading partners with the associated distance (or transport cost) measures. Estimating market potential requires data on the GDP of domestic regions and foreign countries, measures of transport costs and other trade costs such as tariffs. New GDP estimates for the Habsburg regions are documented in Table 4. GDP data for the empire’s main foreign trading partners are taken from Maddison (2003), measured in purchasing power parity adjusted international dollars.3 Fifteen foreign economies are included: Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, India, Italy, Netherlands, Portugal, Russia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States. However, almost three quarters of the empire’s foreign trade was geared towards Continental Europe and more than half of that was with Germany alone (ÖSH ). With motorized road freight developing only after the First World War, both the internal and external goods traffic of the Habsburg Empire was heavily dominated by the railways. Coastal shipping played no significant role in internal transport. In 1913, the volume of freight transported between the empire’s Mediterranean ports accounted for half a per cent of freight moved on the Austro-Hungarian railways (ÖSH, MSE). Likewise, waterborne transport on the rivers Danube, Elbe and Vlatava, the only major inland waterways, was equivalent to just one per cent of the railways’ ton2 The formula yields a distance value of 1/3 of the radius of a circle of the same area as region i. 3 In principle, the use current price GDP seems preferable to constant price-PPP adjusted GDP as in terms of location decisions that is what mattered to economic agents at the time. However, GDP deflators that would allow reflating the constant price estimates of Habsburg GDP are as yet not available (or rather, only very crude approximations would be possible at this stage). Further, the question of what determines the location of industry is not the primary issue under enquiry in this paper. Here the interest lies mainly in the expost comparison of inter-temporal changes in absolute and relative regional income and regional market potential. 7 kilometres. Accordingly, railways are chosen as the transport mode for distances between the regions of the empire. Further, almost three quarters of the empire’s foreign trade was geared towards Continental Europe and more than half of that was with Germany alone (ÖSH) . For distances between Habsburg regions and foreign countries, the transport mode chosen was the cheaper of rail or rail and ship, based on new estimates of time-varying railway freight rates for Austria-Hungary and several European countries (see below) and Kaukiainen’s (2003) estimate of ocean shipping rates. For both railway and sea transport cost approximations, coal and grain were taken as representative cargoes (cf. Crafts 2007). Further, both sets of freight rates build on estimates of terminal charges and cost per ton-mile. Distances. For the measurement of railway distances between Habsburg regions and between these regions and foreign countries, provincial and country capitals, respectively, have been chosen as the relevant ‘nodes’. Both the domestic and the international railway connections are measured such that they take full account of changes over time in route length. Railway distance measures between the twenty-two Habsburg internal ‘nodes’ have been extracted from the numerous sources listed under Railway Distances. For connections from Habsburg to foreign ‘nodes’ (and to/from port cities such as Hamburg, for example) the initial source is Bradshaw’s 1914 Continental Guide. The distances reported there were checked against (and augmented by additional distance measures from) contemporary railway maps, held at the British Library, for all relevant years prior to 1914. Whenever the 1914 connection was not in place before, the shortest alternative route was extracted from this material. Ocean shipping. The length of sea journeys has been estimated using the material in www.dataloy.com/newwebsite/index.php; as mentioned 8 above, estimates of costs of ocean transport have been taken from Kaukiainen (2003) and are reported in Table 1. Note, though, that only a relatively small proportion (c. 12 per cent) of Austria-Hungary’s total foreign trade was conducted through her Mediterranean ports and, likewise, the port of Hamburg. Railway freight cost. Estimates of railway transport cost are based on material from a diverse set of sources. The (US) Bureau of Railway Economics (1915) provides comparative 1914 freight rate data for a large number of different-length railway routes in different countries and for a variety of products. Again, as for sea transport, coal and grain were chosen as representative cargoes. For both products transport costs were decomposed into terminal and variable charges, providing a set of 1914 baseline estimates for Austria-Hungary and several other European countries. Noyes (1905) and Cain (1980) provide estimates of average railway freight rates per ton-mile for Austria-Hungary, France, Germany, Italy, European Russia and Britain, respectively. These data have been converted into indices and used to extrapolate back to 1870 both the terminal and variable components in the 1914 equations. The estimates are shown in Table 2. For rail connections within the Habsburg Empire the rates reported under ‘Austria’ have been used, deflated by the ‘Generalindex’ of Mühlpeck et al. (1979). For rail connections between the Habsburg regions and foreign countries the arithmetic average of the Austrian and appropriate foreign rates given in Table 2 has been used, again deflated. Where no foreign country-specific freight rates are available for foreign countries, the estimate for ‘Europe’ has been used instead. The comparison of real cost of transport in Table 3 shows that ocean freight rates fell more quickly over the course of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries than railway freight rates. The implication here is, all else 9 being equal, that market potential increased relatively faster in those regions of the empire that had ready access to the sea, like the Littoral (Trieste) and Dalmatia, compared with landlocked regions like the Bukovina and Silesia. Tariffs. The last building block for the estimation of market potential involves accounting for the effects of trade costs such as tariffs. Here, the procedure of Crafts and Mulatu (2006) was followed to convert tariffs into distance equivalents drawing on Estevadeordal et al. (2003). They estimated a gravity model for trade which has a distance elasticity of -0.8 and a tariff elasticity of -1.0 (where the tariff is measured as (1+t)). These elasticities have been used to convert ad valorem tariffs between any two given countries into a distance equivalent measure which was then added to the intercept of the equations for sea and rail freight rates reported in Tables 1 and 2. All tariff figures were computed as the ratio of customs revenue over value of imports and Mitchell (2003) was the main source.4 Drawing on these elements (regional GDP, transport costs, tariffs), market potential estimates for all 22 Habsburg regions are presented in Tables 8 to 10, showing the evidence for three different country samples. 3. Growth and Dispersion in Regional Product The new regional GDP estimates for the Habsburg regions are documented in Tables 4 and 5. They show major level differences compared with the results of Good and Ma (1998), ranging between a minimum of +/- 1 per cent (Salzburg) and +/- 39 per cent (Dalmatia) for 1910. For the Austrian 4 Other sources are Mitchell and Deane for the UK; Prados de la Escosura (2003) for Spanish imports; Johanson (1984) for Denmark; Lains (2006) for Portuguese imports and Capie (1994) for an approximation of the German tariff rate for 1870. 10 part of the empire, these differences add up to 10 per cent and to about 13 per cent for the Hungarian half, also for 1910 (Table 6).5 Overall, regional product levels followed a far more pronounced profile of variations than the earlier historiography suggests. In 1870, the richest region (Lower Austria) enjoyed per capita incomes that were about 108 per cent above the Habsburg average and about 240 per cent above the level of the poorest region (Dalmatia). By 1910, this had changed to 74 and 258 per cent, respectively. The coefficients of variation for all years show a significantly higher degree of regional income dispersion for both Austria and the Habsburg Empire as a whole than indicated by the results of the proxyapproach (Table 5). All this suggest that the use of proxy variable within a structural-equations framework masks the extent and persistence of regional income differentials. The material in Table 7 illustrates the extent of regional growth variations and contrasts the new evidence with the findings of Good and Ma. The key messages here is that growth in GDP per capita was persistently slower across the regions and, at the same time, characterized by stark inter-regional differences. Whereas the Good and Ma estimates for Austria point to a fairly narrow range of regional growth between 1.12 (Upper Austria) and 1.47 per cent per annum (Tyrol & Vorarlberg), the new estimates suggest a far wider band between 0.52 (Dalmatia) and 1.32 per cent (Silesia). Thus reconstructing regional GDP on the basis of regional output and employment data yields estimates that seem far more responsive to regional conditions and endowments. 5 Note that the regional GDP estimates for Hungary are based Good and Ma’s (1998) regional shares in total Hungarian GDP in each benchmark year that were applied to total state-level GDP as estimated in Schulze (2000, 2007) – the effect is an identical percentage point difference between the new and the Good and Ma estimates across all Hungarian regions in any given year. These differences, of course, change over time. 11 In Austria, the initially poorest regions in terms of GDP per capita in the East and South-East (Galicia, Bukovina, Dalmatia) were expanding at as low rates as the three richest regions in the West (Lower Austria, Upper Austria, Salzburg). This ties in well with the slow decline in income dispersion reported in Table 7. Apart from the generally faster growth of the Hungarian regions compared with those in Austria, there is only very limited evidence for intra-empire catching-up. Within the Austrian half of the monarchy, it was the initially mid-income regions such as Bohemia and Silesia whose relative position improved over 1870 to 1910. 4. Regional Market Potential in Austria-Hungary Three alternative estimates of regional market potential have been prepared. These show that the composition of the sample of foreign countries included has a powerful influence on the Habsburg regions’ relative market potential (Tables 8-10). According to the evidence in Table 8, the relative position of two regions – the Littoral and Dalmatia – is particularly noteworthy. Their market potential was the highest in 1870 and continued to rise the fastest up to 1910. In close proximity to sea routes they were well located to benefit from lower and relatively fast declining shipping rates, offering ready access to overseas markets. The effect, though, is somewhat exaggerated as the two port cities of Trieste and Zara are the designated nodes. The only other regions that saw significant change in their relative market potential were Carniola adjacent to the Littoral, and Croatia-Slavonia – again, a region that is bordering on the sea. For all other, landlocked, regions the relative market potential remained practically unchanged over the period 1870 to 1910. In 12 other words, changes in railway route length and shifts in relative transport costs (shipping vs. rail) had little effect. Rather low and declining transport cost to India, the USA and Turkey means that their GDPs feature strongly in the market potential measures, particularly in coastal regions. However, the use of a foreign country sample restricted to Europe reduces estimated relative market potential of the regions. For landlocked regions far removed from ports such as the Bukovina, Galicia and Transylvania, the inclusion or exclusion of these economies makes no difference (Table 9). Bohemia’s profile is raised, though. This is an outcome of her proximity to large economies such as Germany and the UK (via the port of Hamburg) whose GDP now gains more weight in the market potential calculations. This finding is consistent with the foreign trade data: more than half of the empire’s foreign just before the First World War was conducted with these two economies. If the analysis is further restricted to consider only the GDP of the Habsburg regions, the emerging picture is one of stasis (Table 10). In effect, the procedure maximizes the impact of a region’s own potential and that of its adjacent regions. There are no differential changes in transport costs over time as railway freight rates are assumed to change at the same rate across the entire network of the empire. Dalmatia, the region with the largest market potential if the full sample were considered, turns into the region with the lowest potential in the Habsburg-only setting. This is no coincidence. In fact, Dalmatia was not only the poorest and least rapidly growing region of the empire – it was also the only region with no direct railway connection to the rest of the empire. 13 5. Some Preliminary Conclusions This paper has presented new estimates of regional GDP and regional market potential in the Habsburg Empire. There are several conclusions. First, regional differentials in terms of both levels and growth of per capita GDP were significantly larger than earlier estimates based on the proxy-approach suggest. Further, the Eastern parts of the empire were economically much further behind Western Europe than the recent historiography acknowledges. Second, intra-empire catching-up of poor with rich regions was very limited just as much as the Habsburg Empire, and especially Austria, failed to catch-up with the leaders in the European income league. . Third, the measurement of market potential is highly sensitive to the composition of the group of foreign economies considered in the calculations and the choice of ‘nodes’. Improvements in this area will involve the generation of new regional income estimates for Germany as the empire’s main trading partner, building on Frank (1994), to replace the German aggregate. Further, drawing on overseas port cities as nodes (e.g. New York, Bombay etc.) appears to bias the result by, effectively, lowering relative transport cost. Hence the use of alternative, more ‘representative’ nodes needs to be explored. Likewise, the unique position of Dalmatia and Zara as a node needs to be accounted for by, for instance, allowing for highcost road transport in the absence of direct rail communications. Fourth, comparatively low and falling relative shipping cost meant that regions close to the sea further improved their market potential relative to landlocked regions during 1870 to 1910. Fifth, some Habsburg regions commonly described in the literature as ‘remote’, ‘economically backward’ or ‘peripheral’ (e.g. the Bukovina and Galicia) display low levels of market potential on all alternative measures. 14 Finally, there is no clear-cut relationship between changes in regions’ relative GDP (or GDP per capita) position and market potential. However, some regions such as, for example, Silesia appear to have been far more successful in tapping into their economic potential than others. 15 References A. Official Publications, Maps, Reports, Statistics Census 1869: K.k. Statistische Central-Commission, Bevölkerung und Viehstand der im Reichsrathe vertretenen Königreiche und Länder, dann der Militärgränze. Nach der Zählung vom 31. December 1869. Heft II: Anwesende Bevölkerung nach Beruf und Beschäftigung (Vienna, 1871). Census 1880: K.k. Statistische Central-Commission, ‘Die Bevölkerung der im Reichsrathe vertretenen Königreiche und Länder nach Beruf und Erwerb’, Österreichische Statistik I (1882) 3. Heft. Census 1890: K.k. Statistische Central-Commission, ‘Berufsstatistik nach den Ergebnissen der Volkszählung vom 31. December 1890’, Österreichische Statistik XXXIII (1894) 1. Heft ff.. Census 1910: K.k. Statistische Central-Commission ‘Berufsstatistik nach den Ergebnissen der Volkszählung vom 31. Dezember 1910’, Österreichische Statistik, N.F., III (1916) 1. Heft ff. MSE: Magyar Kir. Központi Statisztikai Hivatal, Magyar Statisztikai Évkönyv, 1872-1915 (Budapest). NIHV: Nachrichten über Industrie, Handel und Verkehr 1870, 1880 (Vienna: 1873, 1886). ÖSH: k.k. Statistische Central-Commission, Österreichisches Statistisches Handbuch, 1883-1915 (Vienna). Railway Distances: (a) Neueste Eisenbahnkarte der österreichischen Monarchie, C. Lehmann (Vienna: 1870); 16 (b) Eisenbahn-Karte von Oesterreich-Ungarn, bearb. von T. Bomsdorff, einschl. Kilometer-Zeiger fuer die Eisenbahnen Oesterreich-Ungarns (Vienna: 1878); (c) Oesterreich-Ungarn. Eisenbahn-Karte, gezeichnet und bearbeitet von T. v. Bomsdorff (Vienna: 1883); (d) Artaria’s Eisenbahn-, Post- und Communicationskarte von OesterreichUngarn (Vienna: 1888, 1891, 93, 1900). (e) Eisenbahn- und Strassenkarte der oesterreichisch-ungarischen Monarchie (Vienna: 1904). (f) Uebersichtskarte der Eisenbahnen der oesterreichisch-ungarischen Monarchie (Vienna: 1913). (g) Artaria’s Eisenbahnkarte von Oesterreich-Ungarn, 3. Aufl., einschl. Stations-verzeichnis, etc. (Vienna: 1913). (h) A. Bechtel, Kilometerzeiger zu den allgemeinen und Militaer-Tarifen der oesterreichisch-ungarischen Eisenbahnen (Vienna: 1882-91). (i) F. Smolik, Offizieller Kilometerzeiger der saemtlichen oesterreichischungarischen und bosnisch-hercegovinischen Eisenbahnen (Vienna: 1912). SJB: (1870-1882): k.k. Statistische Central-Commission, Statistisches Jahrbuch der österreichischen Monarchie, 1870-1882 (Vienna). Unfallstatistik: (a) K.k. Ministerium des Innern, Die Gebarung und die Ergbenisse der Unfallstatistik 1889-1896 (Vienna, 1891-1898). (b) K.k. Ministerium des Innern, Ergebnisse der Unfallstatistik der fünfjährigen Beobachtungsperiode 1897-1901, 1902-1907, 1907-1911 (Vienna, 1904-1914). (US) Bureau of Railway Economics (1915), Comparison of Railway Freight Rates in the United States (and) The Principal Countries of Europe, South Australia, and South Africa (Washington, D.C.). 17 B. Books, Articles Abramovitz, M. (1986), ‘Catching up, forging ahead and falling behind’, Journal of Economic History 46, No.2, pp.385-406. Bradshaw’s August 1914 Continental Guide (repr. Newton Abbot, 1972) Cain, P.J. (1980), ‘Private enterprise or public utility? Output, pricing and investment on English and Welsh railways, 1870-1914’, Journal of Transport History 1, No.1, pp.9-28. Capie, F. (1994), Tariffs and Growth (Manchester 1994). Crafts, N.F.R. (2005), ‘Regional GDP in Britain, 1871-1911: Some estimates’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 52, No.1, pp.54-64. Crafts, N.F.R. and A. Mulatu (2006), ‘How did the location of industry respond to falling transport costs in Britain before World War I?’, Journal of Economic History 66, No.3, pp.575-607. Estevadeordal, A., Frantz, B. and A. Taylor (2003), ‘The rise and fall of world trade, 1870-1939’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, No.2, pp.359407. Fellner, F. (1915), ‘Das Volksvermögen Österreichs und Ungarns’, Bulletin de l’Institut International de Statistique, Tome XX – 2e Livraison (Vienna), pp.503-573. Frank, H. (1994), Regionale Entwicklungsdisparitäten im deutschen Industrialisierungs-prozeß (Münster). Freudenberger , H. (2003), Lost Momentum. Austrian Economic Development 1750s-1830s (Vienna). Gerschenkron, A. (1962), Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, MA) Estevadeordal, A., Frantz, B. and A. Taylor (2002), ‘The rise and fall of world trade, 1870-1939’, NBER Working Paper No. 9318. 18 Geary, F. and T. Stark (2002), ‘Examining Ireland’s post-famine economic growth performance’, Economic Journal 112, pp.919-35. Good, D.F. (1984). The Economic Rise of the Habsburg Empire, 1750-1914 (Berkeley). Good, D.F. (1994). ‘The economic lag of central and eastern Europe: income estimates for the Habsburg successor states, 1870-1910’, Journal of Economic History 54, No.4, pp.869-91. Good, D.F. (1997). ‘ Proxy data and income estimates: reply to Pammer’, Journal of Economic History 57, No.3, pp.456-63. Good, D.F and Ma, T. (1998). ‘New estimates of income levels in central and eastern Europe, 1870-1910’, in F. Baltzarek, F. Butschek and G. Tichy (eds), Von der Theorie zur Wirtschaftspolitik - ein österreichischer Weg (Stuttgart). Harris, C. (1954), ‘The market as a factor in the localization of industry in the United States’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers 64, pp.315-348. Johansen, H.C. (1980), Dansk historisk statistik (Copenhagen). Kaukiainen, Y. (2003), ‘How the price of distance declined: Ocean freights for grain and coal from the 1870s to 2000’, mimeo, University of Helsinki. Kausel, A. (1979), ‘Österreichs Volkseinkommen 1830 bis 1913’, in Österreichisches Statistisches Zentralamt (ed.), Geschichte und Ergebnisse der zentralen amtlichen Statistik in Österreich, 1829-1979 (Vienna), pp. 689-720. Komlos, J. (1983). The Habsburg Monarchy as a Customs Union. Economic Development in Austria-Hungary in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton). 19 Komlos, J. (1989). Stature, Nutrition, and Economic Development in the Eighteenth Century Habsburg Monarchy: The `Austrian' Model of the Industrial Revolution. (Princeton). Lains, P. (2006), ‘Growth in a protected environment: Portugal, 1850-1950’, Research in Economic History 24, pp.121-163. Maddison, A. (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics (Paris). Midelfart-Knarvik, K.H., H.G. Overman, S.J. Redding and A.J. Venables (2000), ‘The location of European industry’, Economic Papers 142. DG Economic and Financial Affairs, European Commission (Brussels). Mitchell B.R. (2003), International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750-2000 (Basingstoke). Mirchell, B.R., Deane, P. (1962), Abstract of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge). Pammer, M. (1997). ‘Proxy data and income estimates: The economic lag of central and eastern Europe’. Journal of Economic History 57, No.2, pp.448-455. Noyes, W.G. (1905), American Railroad Rates (Boston). Pollard, S. (1986), Peaceful Conquest (reprint, Oxford). Prados de la Escosura, L. (2000), ‘International comparisons of real product, 1820-1990: An alternative data set’, Explorations in Economic History 37, pp.1-41. Prados de la Escosura, L.(2003), El progreso económico de España (Madrid). Sandgruber, R. (1978), Österreichische Agrarstatistik 1750-1918 (Munich). Schulze, M.S. (2000), ‘Patterns of growth and stagnation in the late nineteenth century Habsburg economy’, European Review of Economic History 4, pp.311-340. 20 Schulze, M.S. (2007), ‘Origins of catch-up failure: comparative productivity growth in the Habsburg Empire, 1870-1910’, European Review of Economic History 11, pp.189-218. 21 Table 1: Shipping Rates Per Ton (current price in old pence) 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 Terminal Component 159 132 104 79 70 Cost per mile 0.046 0.030 0.020 0.018 0.020 Source: Kaukiainen (2003) . Years refer to 1872-1874, 18791880, 1888-1889, 1898-1899 and 1911-1913. Table 2: Railway Freight Rates Per Ton (current price in old pence) 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1914 Austria Terminal Variable 44 1.085 39 0.958 29 0.730 26 0.648 25 0.620 24 0.593 France Terminal Variable 62 0.252 78 0.317 71 0.289 61 0.246 55 0.224 52 0.209 Germany Terminal Variable 53 0.435 60 0.488 58 0.473 52 0.429 47 0.387 44 0.362 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1914 Russia terminal variable 281 0.638 238 0.542 175 0.397 128 0.291 96 0.219 85 0.193 UK terminal variable 19 0.686 21 0.730 19 0.684 20 0.689 18 0.637 17 0.608 Europe terminal variable 61 0.446 68 0.497 59 0.431 54 0.393 49 0.358 46 0.339 Sources: See text. 22 Table 3: Real Transport Cost 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 Sea 100.0 78.5 66.6 52.3 40.0 Europe Rail 100.0 107.9 102.4 95.3 73.2 Austria Rail 100.0 85.6 71.2 64.7 52.2 Sources: See text. Assumes 500 miles as the distance in all three cases. Deflated using ‘Generalindex’ from Mühlpeck et al. (1979). Table 6: Percentage Difference in GDP - New Estimates vs. Good & Ma Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube Danube Tisza Basin Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza Tisza Maros Basin Transylvania Croatia-Slavonia Austria Hungary Habsburg Empire Sources: See text. 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 7.00% 32.56% 19.23% 4.67% -8.86% -13.34% -8.40% 10.94% 1.57% 1.44% -10.51% -8.78% -11.62% -17.74% -6.44% -6.44% -6.44% -6.44% -6.44% -6.44% -6.44% -6.44% -4.15% 16.46% 4.47% -0.94% -17.87% -29.67% -16.11% -2.97% -4.93% -14.92% -24.92% -15.25% -24.63% -18.80% -13.95% -13.95% -13.95% -13.95% -13.95% -13.95% -13.95% -13.95% -6.96% 14.27% -10.55% 1.42% -16.55% -24.90% -16.16% -14.26% -5.28% -11.21% -16.79% -17.77% -23.20% -30.02% -10.72% -10.72% -10.72% -10.72% -10.72% -10.72% -10.72% -10.72% -12.14% 9.70% -4.11% 7.73% -2.87% -10.48% -20.68% -8.52% -10.70% -5.57% -18.45% -30.40% -30.90% -34.14% -12.92% -12.92% -12.92% -12.92% -12.92% -12.92% -12.92% -12.92% -11.57% 13.62% -1.03% 3.92% -7.30% -13.95% -16.81% -9.53% -4.86% -1.63% -12.20% -22.43% -29.56% -39.04% -13.09% -13.09% -13.09% -13.09% -13.09% -13.09% -13.09% -13.09% 0.85% -8.69% -6.44% -13.95% -1.72% -10.55% -9.76% -10.72% -10.11% -13.74% -12.92% -13.45% -10.12% -13.09% -11.21% Table 7: Growth in GDP Per Capita (Per Cent Per Annum), 1870-1910 New Good & Ma Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube Danube Tisza Basin Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza Tisza Maros Basin Transylvania Croatia-Slavonia 0.65% 0.73% 0.80% 1.17% 1.23% 1.29% 1.02% 0.95% 1.10% 1.07% 1.32% 0.85% 0.67% 0.52% 1.18% 1.39% 1.35% 1.26% 1.24% 1.28% 1.31% 1.36% 1.13% 1.12% 1.27% 1.19% 1.18% 1.30% 1.27% 1.47% 1.27% 1.15% 1.37% 1.26% 1.25% 1.27% 1.36% 1.58% 1.54% 1.44% 1.42% 1.46% 1.49% 1.54% Austria Hungary Habsburg Empire 0.97% 1.34% 1.10% 1.20% 1.50% 1.28% Sources: See text. 24 Table 4: Regional GDP in the Habsburg Empire (million 1990 G-K Intl. $) 1870 Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube Danube Tisza Basin Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza Tisza Maros Basin Transylvania Croatia-Slavonia Austria Hungary Habsburg Empire Sources: See text. 1880 New 5132.48 1371.00 285.27 1622.66 438.36 451.19 849.52 1387.11 8776.23 3069.64 717.20 4672.83 444.46 347.83 1792.32 2280.08 2761.33 1498.90 1697.94 1610.30 1828.04 1443.26 Good & Ma 4796.81 1034.27 239.25 1550.28 480.98 520.62 927.45 1250.29 8640.74 3026.11 801.45 5122.36 502.88 422.84 1915.76 2437.11 2951.51 1602.13 1814.88 1721.21 1953.94 1542.66 29565.77 14912.18 44477.95 29316.33 15939.20 45255.54 New 5719.20 1412.65 309.91 1832.59 468.01 435.96 920.38 1357.79 9632.27 3146.37 796.42 5217.58 482.07 397.33 1862.20 2572.89 3434.18 1500.69 1738.00 1716.01 1959.50 1769.57 Good & Ma 5966.86 1213.04 296.65 1850.01 569.82 619.84 1097.08 1399.30 10131.26 3698.26 1060.72 6156.15 639.59 489.29 2164.15 2990.08 3991.03 1744.03 2019.82 1994.26 2277.23 2056.51 32128.53 16553.04 48681.58 35187.86 19237.11 54424.96 1890 New 7071.86 1647.49 325.63 2178.95 498.71 533.86 1037.98 1396.48 11501.78 3885.23 1047.52 6716.23 608.38 447.03 2464.49 3476.83 4415.16 1956.00 2330.18 2248.28 2466.87 2296.54 Good & Ma 7600.50 1441.76 364.04 2148.54 597.61 710.82 1237.99 1628.69 12142.53 4375.69 1258.84 8167.92 792.14 638.77 2760.35 3894.22 4945.20 2190.82 2609.92 2518.19 2763.03 2572.24 38897.10 21654.34 60551.44 43105.84 24253.96 67359.80 1900 1910 New 9521.75 1839.53 444.94 2829.50 669.42 695.69 1224.22 1898.09 13985.79 5020.02 1319.33 7389.18 735.72 514.89 2951.86 4133.16 6135.60 2425.24 2938.49 2697.44 2947.47 2722.13 Good & Ma 10837.15 1676.89 464.02 2626.44 689.17 777.11 1543.43 2074.86 15660.89 5316.15 1617.84 10616.89 1064.70 781.78 3389.85 4746.43 7045.99 2785.10 3374.50 3097.68 3384.82 3126.04 New 11807.95 2126.16 550.16 3280.95 837.72 848.42 1900.18 2499.83 17920.94 6118.89 1786.09 9671.98 906.19 602.33 3592.92 5034.58 8258.96 2915.67 3797.90 3250.44 3800.61 3536.75 Good & Ma 13352.38 1871.32 555.89 3157.22 903.65 985.93 2284.19 2763.25 18836.27 6220.29 2034.38 12469.49 1286.40 988.00 4134.26 5793.13 9503.31 3354.96 4370.11 3740.17 4373.24 4069.62 48088.07 26951.38 75039.44 55747.32 30950.42 86697.74 60857.79 34187.83 95045.62 67708.64 39338.80 107047.44 Table 5: Regional GDP Per Capita in the Habsburg Empire (1990 G-K Intl. $) 1870 Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube Danube Tisza Basin Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza Tisza Maros Basin Transylvania Croatia-Slavonia Austria Hungary Habsburg Empire c.v. Austria c.v. Hungary c.v. Habsburg Empire Sources: See text. New 2578.2 1861.4 1862.6 1425.9 1298.1 967.5 1414.6 1566.0 1707.3 1521.7 1397.1 858.2 865.7 758.5 1033.6 940.2 1279.2 999.6 895.1 913.7 843.9 772.1 1449.6 961.3 1238.6 0.342 0.160 0.364 1880 Good & Ma 2409.6 1404.2 1562.1 1362.3 1424.3 1116.4 1544.4 1411.5 1680.9 1500.1 1561.2 940.8 979.5 922 1104.8 1004.9 1367.3 1068.4 956.7 976.6 902 825.3 1447.8 1040.4 1301.2 0.268 0.160 0.289 New 2453.9 1859.7 1894.7 1510.1 1342.1 905.9 1420.5 1487.9 1732.2 1461.1 1408.4 875.6 843.3 834.5 1058.0 996.6 1453.0 1034.5 951.3 991.5 933.9 918.1 1450.8 1051.7 1285.0 0.327 0.166 0.331 1890 Good & Ma 2560.2 1596.9 1813.6 1524.4 1634 1288 1693.2 1533.4 1821.9 1717.4 1875.8 1033.1 1118.8 1027.7 1229.5 1158.2 1688.6 1202.2 1105.6 1152.3 1085.3 1067 1584.4 1239.5 1453.1 0.253 0.166 0.265 26 New 2656.80 2096.49 1876.70 1698.71 1381.44 1069.95 1492.67 1503.58 1968.44 1706.39 1729.58 1016.41 940.90 847.56 1304.6 1254.6 1589.0 1279.0 1122.0 1171.8 1087.7 1028.8 1627.8 1240.0 1464.0 0.320 0.142 0.305 1900 Good & Ma 2855.4 1834.7 2098.1 1675 1655.4 1424.6 1780.3 1753.6 2078.1 1921.8 2078.5 1236.1 1225.1 1211.1 1461.2 1405.2 1779.8 1432.6 1256.7 1312.5 1218.3 1152.3 1801 1398 1651.8 0.249 0.142 0.254 New 3071.0 2270.3 2308.2 2085.9 1822.4 1369.1 1618.3 1933.0 2213.4 2059.3 1939.0 1010.0 1007.6 867.1 1440.2 1413.8 1868.2 1448.6 1257.9 1312.8 1189.9 1108.7 1838.9 1399.7 1652.7 0.332 0.168 0.326 1910 Good & Ma 3495.3 2069.6 2407.2 1936.2 1876.2 1529.3 2040.1 2113 2478.5 2180.8 2377.7 1451.2 1458.1 1316.6 1653.9 1623.6 2145.4 1663.5 1444.5 1507.6 1366.5 1273.2 2116.7 1609.1 1925.5 0.273 0.168 0.277 New 3343.3 2492.5 2562.0 2271.9 2114.4 1613.0 2126.0 2289.2 2647.3 2333.4 2359.6 1205.1 1132.6 932.9 1651.2 1632.3 2190.9 1647.6 1463.6 1517.6 1419.0 1323.8 2130.0 1636.8 1921.7 0.316 0.165 0.311 Good & Ma 3780.6 2193.8 2588.7 2186.2 2280.8 1874.4 2555.6 2530.4 2782.5 2372.1 2687.6 1553.7 1607.8 1530.2 1900 1878.2 2521 1895.8 1684.1 1746.3 1632.8 1523.2 2334.5 1887.7 2164.2 0.256 0.165 0.257 Table 8: Market Potential - Full Sample Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Danube Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube-Tisza Basin Tisza Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza-Maros Basin Transylvaina Croatia-Slavonia 1870 100 91 88 104 106 125 170 99 118 100 87 71 61 168 94 91 88 83 73 74 60 108 Lower Austria = 100 1880 1890 1900 100 100 100 92 91 94 90 89 89 111 112 112 113 113 113 138 142 142 201 209 216 100 99 99 115 112 113 98 94 94 86 83 83 70 68 67 61 58 58 200 209 216 94 94 93 96 97 96 91 92 91 83 80 80 74 74 74 76 76 75 60 60 59 117 118 118 27 1910 100 95 89 112 114 143 215 99 115 96 85 69 60 215 94 97 92 82 74 76 60 119 1870 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 1870 = 100 1880 1890 141 197 142 198 144 199 150 212 150 212 156 224 166 243 143 198 138 187 138 187 139 189 139 188 139 187 168 245 140 196 148 210 145 205 141 190 144 201 145 203 141 196 153 217 1900 282 294 282 303 302 322 357 282 271 266 269 266 268 362 279 298 292 270 285 288 277 310 1910 446 468 449 481 480 510 562 449 438 429 436 432 434 572 443 475 465 440 454 459 443 494 Table 9: Market Potential -Restricted Sample (excl. Russia, Turkey, India, USA) Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Danube Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube-Tisza Basin Tisza Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza-Maros Basin Transylvaina Croatia-Slavonia Lower Austria = 100 1870 1880 1890 100 100 100 88 89 88 87 88 86 96 101 101 96 101 101 107 117 119 143 167 172 98 99 97 126 124 121 101 100 97 85 85 83 69 69 67 58 57 56 136 162 168 94 93 93 83 87 88 84 86 87 79 79 77 69 71 71 69 71 71 57 57 56 94 101 102 1900 100 91 85 101 101 118 176 96 122 97 83 66 56 172 93 87 87 76 70 70 56 101 Sources: See text. 28 1910 100 91 85 101 100 118 176 97 124 98 84 68 57 172 93 87 87 78 70 70 56 101 1870 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 1870 = 100 1880 1890 131 180 132 180 132 179 138 191 138 190 143 200 153 217 132 178 129 173 129 173 130 175 130 175 130 175 156 222 130 179 137 191 134 187 131 176 133 183 134 185 131 179 140 195 1900 258 266 253 272 270 285 318 253 250 248 251 248 251 326 256 270 266 251 260 261 253 277 1910 388 400 381 409 405 428 478 382 384 379 386 380 385 490 386 406 400 383 391 393 381 417 Table 10: Market Potential - Considering Habsburg Regions Only Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Carinthia Carniola Littoral Tyrol & Vorarlberg Bohemia Moravia Silesia Galicia Bukovina Dalmatia Danube Left Bank Danube Right Bank Danube-Tisza Basin Tisza Right Bank Tisza Left Bank Tisza-Maros Basin Transylvaina Croatia-Slavonia 1870 100 71 56 67 53 52 44 48 90 85 62 55 35 31 88 60 72 55 56 53 40 56 Lower Austria = 100 1880 1890 1900 100 100 100 70 69 69 55 54 53 67 67 66 53 52 51 52 51 50 44 43 42 47 45 44 89 87 84 84 83 82 62 62 60 56 57 53 35 36 36 32 34 32 88 88 88 61 65 63 74 78 78 55 56 55 56 58 57 53 55 53 40 40 39 57 57 55 Sources: See text. 29 1910 100 68 53 66 52 51 44 45 85 83 61 54 37 33 88 64 80 55 58 53 39 56 1870 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 1870 = 100 1880 1890 124 204 123 199 123 197 125 202 124 200 124 202 124 200 122 192 124 198 123 199 124 203 125 211 124 212 127 221 124 205 125 219 127 219 123 208 123 211 124 210 123 204 126 208 1900 293 283 278 290 284 285 282 273 276 283 285 281 303 297 292 307 316 291 297 294 283 291 1910 383 369 365 378 373 377 381 362 365 371 378 377 405 402 383 404 421 384 394 387 376 386 Map 1: Regions of the Habsburg Empire 30 LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS ECONOMIC HISTORY DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPERS (from 2003 onwards) For a full list of titles visit our webpage at http://www.lse.ac.uk/ 2003 WP70 The Decline and Fall of the European Film Industry: Sunk Costs, Market Size and Market Structure, 1890-1927 Gerben Bakker WP71 The globalisation of codfish and wool: Spanish-English-North American triangular trade in the early modern period Regina Grafe WP72 Piece rates and learning: understanding work and production in the New England textile industry a century ago Timothy Leunig WP73 Workers and ‘Subalterns’. A comparative study of labour in Africa, Asia and Latin America Colin M. Lewis (editor) WP74 Was the Bundesbank’s credibility undermined during the process of German reunification? Matthias Morys WP75 Steam as a General Purpose Technology: A Growth Accounting Perspective Nicholas F. R. Crafts WP76 Fact or Fiction? Re-examination of Chinese Premodern Population Statistics Kent G. Deng WP77 Autarkic Policy and Efficiency in Spanish Industrial Sector. An Estimation of the Domestic Resource Cost in 1958. Elena Martínez Ruiz WP78 The Post-War Rise of World Trade: Does the Bretton Woods System Deserve Credit? Andrew G. Terborgh WP79 Quantifying the Contribution of Technological Change to Economic Growth in Different Eras: A Review of the Evidence Nicholas F. R. Crafts WP80 Bureau Competition and Economic Policies in Nazi Germany, 1933-39 Oliver Volckart 2004 WP81 At the origins of increased productivity growth in services. Productivity, social savings and the consumer surplus of the film industry, 1900-1938 Gerben Bakker WP82 The Effects of the 1925 Portuguese Bank Note Crisis Henry Wigan WP83 Trade, Convergence and Globalisation: the dynamics of change in the international income distribution, 1950-1998 Philip Epstein, Peter Howlett & Max-Stephan Schulze WP84 Reconstructing the Industrial Revolution: Analyses, Perceptions and Conceptions of Britain’s Precocious Transition to Europe’s First Industrial Society Giorgio Riello & Patrick K. O’Brien WP85 The Canton of Berne as an Investor on the London Capital Market in the 18th Century Stefan Altorfer WP86 News from London: Greek Government Bonds on the London Stock Exchange, 1914-1929 Olga Christodoulaki & Jeremy Penzer WP87 The World Economy in the 1990s: A Long Run Perspective Nicholas F.R. Crafts 2005 WP88 Labour Market Adjustment to Economic Downturns in the Catalan textile industry, 1880-1910. Did Employers Breach Implicit Contracts? Jordi Domenech WP89 Business Culture and Entrepreneurship in the Ionian Islands under British Rule, 1815-1864 Sakis Gekas WP90 Ottoman State Finance: A Study of Fiscal Deficits and Internal Debt in 1859-63 Keiko Kiyotaki WP91 Fiscal and Financial Preconditions for the Rise of British Naval Hegemony 1485-1815 Patrick Karl O’Brien WP92 An Estimate of Imperial Austria’s Gross Domestic Fixed Capital Stock, 1870-1913: Methods, Sources and Results Max-Stephan Schulze 2006 WP93 Harbingers of Dissolution? Grain Prices, Borders and Nationalism in the Hapsburg Economy before the First World War Max-Stephan Schulze and Nikolaus Wolf WP94 Rodney Hilton, Marxism and the Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism S. R. Epstein Forthcoming in C. Dyer, P. Cross, C. Wickham (eds.) Rodney Hilton’s Middle Ages, 400-1600 Cambridge UP 2007 WP95 Mercantilist Institutions for the Pursuit of Power with Profit. The Management of Britain’s National Debt, 1756-1815 Patrick Karl O’Brien WP96 Gresham on Horseback: The Monetary Roots of Spanish American Political Fragmentation in the Nineteenth Century Maria Alejandra Irigoin 2007 WP97 An Historical Analysis of the Expansion of Compulsory Schooling in Europe after the Second World War Martina Viarengo WP98 Universal Banking Failure? An Analysis of the Contrasting Responses of the Amsterdamsche Bank and the Rotterdamsche Bankvereeniging to the Dutch Financial Crisis of the 1920s Christopher Louis Colvin WP99 The Triumph and Denouement of the British Fiscal State: Taxation for the Wars against Revolutionary and Napoleonic France, 17931815. Patrick Karl O’Brien WP100 Origins of Catch-up Failure: Comparative Productivity Growth in the Hapsburg Empire, 1870-1910 Max-Stephan Schulze WP101 Was Dick Whittington Taller Than Those He Left Behind? Anthropometric Measures, Migration and the Quality of life in Early Nineteenth Century London Jane Humphries and Tim Leunig WP102 The Evolution of Entertainment Consumption and the Emergence of Cinema, 1890-1940 Gerben Bakker WP103 Is Social Capital Persistent? Comparative Measurement in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries Marta Felis Rota WP104 Structural Change and the Growth Contribution of Services: How Motion Pictures Industrialized US Spectator Entertainment Gerben Bakker WP105 The Jesuits as Knowledge Brokers Between Europe and China (1582-1773): Shaping European Views of the Middle Kingdom Ashley E. Millar WP106 Regional Income Dispersion and Market Potential in the Late Nineteenth Century Habsburg Empire Max-Stephan Schulze