* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Krugman`s Chapter 11 PPT
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 11 >> Consumer Preferences and Consumer Choice Krugman/Wells ©2009 Worth Publishers 1 of 47 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER Why economists use indifference curves to illustrate a person’s preferences The importance of the marginal rate of substitution, the rate at which a consumer is just willing to substitute one good for another An alternative way of finding a consumer’s optimal consumption bundle using indifference curves and the budget line How the shape of indifference curves helps determine whether goods are substitutes or complements An in-depth understanding of income and substitution effects 2 of 47 Mapping the Utility Function A utility function determines a consumer’s total utility given his or her consumption bundle. Using indifference curves, which represent a consumer’s utility function, we will deepen our understanding of the trade-off involved when choosing the optimal consumption bundle and of how the optimal consumption bundle itself changes in response to changes in the prices of goods. 3 of 47 Ingrid’s Utility Function 1,050 utils All combinations of rooms and restaurant meals along this contour line yield 450 utils. 900 utils 750 utils 600 utils 450 utils B A 300 utils 90 80 150 utils 70 Quantity of restaurants 60 0 utils 50 40 30 20 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity of rooms 4 of 47 Ingrid’s Utility Function Ingrid is indifferent between A and B: because A and B yield the same total utility level, Ingrid is equally well off with either bundle. Hence, a contour line that maps consumption bundles yielding the same amount of total utility is known as an indifference curve. 5 of 47 An Indifference Curve Quantity of restaurant meals 90 An indifference curve is a contour line that shows all the consumption bundles that yield the same amount of total utility for an individual. 80 450 utils 70 60 50 40 A 30 B 15 0 Indifference curve, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity of rooms 6 of 47 An Indifference Curve Map Quantity of restaurant meals Consumption bundle Quantity of rooms Quantity of meals Total utility (utils) 90 A 3 30 450 80 B 6 15 450 C 5 10 391 D 4 45 519 70 391 utils 60 D 45 A 30 519 utils B 15 10 0 450 utils C 1 2 3 4 5 6 I3 I2 I1 7 8 9 10 Quantity of rooms The entire utility function of an individual can be represented by an indifference curve map, a collection of indifference curves in which each curve corresponds to a different total utility level. 7 of 47 FOR INQUIRING MINDS Are Utils Useful? The indifference curve map tells us all we need to know in order to find a consumer’s optimal consumption bundle. Economists say that bundle X is better than bundle Y. The theory does not, however, require “cardinal” utility, which actually assigns a specific number to the total utility yielded by each bundle. So why introduce the concept of utils at all? The answer is that it is much easier to understand the basis of rational choice by using the concept of measurable utility. 8 of 47 Properties of Indifference Curves All indifference curve maps share two general properties: indifference curves never cross the farther out an indifference curve is from the origin, the higher the level of total utility it indicates In addition, indifference curves for most goods, called ordinary goods, have two more properties: they are downward sloping are convex (bowed-in toward the origin) as a result of diminishing marginal utility 9 of 47 Properties of Indifference Curves (a)Properties of All Indifference Curves Quantity of restauran t meals Quantity of restauran t meals 200 utils 200 utils B 100 utils A A I2 I2 100 utils I1 I1 Quantity of rooms Quantity of rooms (b)Additional Properties of Indifference Curves for Ordinary Goods Quantity of restauran t meals Quantity of restauran t meals W A X Y Steeper slope Z I Quantity of rooms B I Flatter slope Quantity of rooms 10 of 47 Indifference Curves and Consumer Choice We will use indifference curve maps to find the utility-maximizing consumption bundle of a consumer given his/her budget constraint. The optimal consumption bundle lies on the budget line, and the marginal utility per dollar is the same for every good in the bundle. The first component of our approach is a new concept, the marginal rate of substitution. 11 of 47 The Changing Slope of an Indifference Curve Quantity of restaurant meals Quantity of rooms Quantity of restaurant meals V 2 30 W 3 20 X 4 15 Y 5 12 Z 6 10 Ingrid trades 10 restaurant meals V 30 Consumption bundle . . . for 1 room. –10 Ingrid trades 2 restaurant meals W 20 +1 X 15 Y 12 10 0 . . . for 1 room. Z –2 I +1 2 3 4 5 6 Quantity of rooms The terms of the trade-off between the reduced consumption of restaurant meals for increased consumption of housing changes as the consumer moves from V to W. Why? 12 of 47 Two Opposing Effects on Total Utility Moving down the indifference curve—reducing restaurant meal consumption and increasing housing consumption—will produce two opposing effects on Ingrid’s total utility: Lower restaurant meal consumption will reduce her total utility, but higher housing consumption will raise her total utility. And since we are moving down the indifference curve, these two effects must exactly cancel out. 13 of 47 Two Opposing Effects on Total Utility Hence, we can calculate the change in total utility generated by a change in the consumption bundle using the following equations: Change in total utility arising from a change in consumption of restaurant meals = MUM × ∆QM Change in total utility arising from a change in consumption of rooms = MUR × ∆QR Along the indifference curve: −MUM × ∆QM = MUR × ∆QR 14 of 47 Marginal Rate of Substitution The following equation would also hold along the indifference curve: −MUR / MUM = ∆QM /∆QR Economists have a special name for the ratio of the marginal utilities in the LHS of this equation and it is called the marginal rate of substitution, MRS. 15 of 47 Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution The flattening of indifference curves as you slide down them to the right—which reflects the same logic as the principle of diminishing marginal utility— is known as the principle of diminishing marginal rate of substitution. It says that an individual who consumes only a little bit of good A and a lot of good B will be willing to trade off a lot of B in return for one more unit of A; an individual who already consumes a lot of A and not much B will be less willing to make that tradeoff. 16 of 47 Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution The principle of diminishing marginal rate of substitution states that the more of good R a person consumes in proportion to good M, the less M he or she is willing to substitute for another unit of R. Two goods, R and M, are ordinary goods in a consumer’s utility function when (1) the consumer requires additional units of R to compensate for less M, and vice versa: and (2) the consumer experiences a diminishing marginal rate of substitution when substituting one good in place of another. 17 of 47 The Optimal Consumption Bundle Quantity of restaurant meals Optimal consumption bundle 80 B 70 60 50 I A 40 30 3 I 2 20 C I 1 10 BL 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Quantity of rooms The tangency condition between the indifference curve and the budget line holds when the indifference curve and the budget line just touch. This condition determines the optimal consumption bundle when the indifference curves have the typical convex shape. 18 of 47 The Slope of the Budget Line The relative price of good R in terms of good M is equal to PR /PM, the rate at which R trades for M in the market. The relative price rule says that at the optimal consumption bundle, the marginal rate of substitution between two goods is equal to their relative price. 19 of 47 Prices and the Marginal Rate of Substitution At the optimal consumption point, the slope of the indifference curve is just equal to the slope of the budget line: Slope of indifference curve = −MUR /MUM Slope of budget line = − (N/PM)/(N/PR) = − PR /PM Putting these two equations together, we arrive at the relative price rule. At the optimal consumption bundle: −MUR /MUM = − PR /PM Optimal consumption rule: MUR / PR= MUM /PM 20 of 47 Understanding the Relative Price Rule At the optimal consumption bundle: Quantity of restaurant meals −MUR /MUM = − PR /PM 80 B 70 At the optimal consumption bundle, MRS is equal to the relative price. 60 50 A 40 30 I 2 20 C 10 I 1 BL 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Quantity of rooms 21 of 47 Preferences and Choices When we say that two consumers have different preferences, we mean that they have different utility functions. This, in turn, means that they will have indifference curve maps with different shapes. And those different maps will translate into different consumption choices, even among consumers with the same income who face the same prices. 22 of 47 Differences in Preferences (a) Ingrid’s Preference and Her Optimal Consumption Bundle Quantity of restaurant meals Ingrid’s Ingrid and Lars have different 80 optimal 70 preferences. They choose consumption 60 bundle different consumption 50 I3 40 bundles. 30 I2 Both of them have an income 20 I1 10 BL of $2,400 and face prices of 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Quantity of rooms $30 per meal and $150 per (b) Lars’s Preference and His Optimal Consumption Bundleroom. Quantity of While Ingrid’s consumption Lars’s restaurant optimal meals choice is 8 rooms and 40 80 consumption bundle 70 restaurant meals, Lars 60 I3 consumes fewer rooms and 50 40 I2 more restaurant meals even 30 I1 though he has the same 20 10 budget line. BL 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Quantity of rooms 23 of 47 ►ECONOMICS IN ACTION Rats and Rational Choice The theory of consumer choice does not bear much resemblance to the way most of us think about our consumption decisions. The purpose of the theory to help economists think systematically about how a rational consumer would behave. The practical consumers actually behave rationally. Economists have conducted experiments in which rats are presented with a “budget constraint”—a limited number of times per hour they can push either of two levers. One of the levers yields small cups of water; the other yields pellets of food. After the rats’ choices have been observed, the budget constraint is changed by varying the number of lever pushes required to get each good. Sure enough, the rats satisfy the rule for rational choice. If rats are rational, can people be far behind? 24 of 47 A Test for Rationality Quantity of Y B A C BL 1 BL 2 Quantity of X A consumer has the budget line BL1 and chooses the bundle A. If that consumer is now given a new budget line—BL2, it would be irrational to choose a bundle such as B; the consumer could have afforded that bundle before but chose A instead. A rational consumer would always at least stay at A or choose a new bundle that was not affordable before, such as C. It’s difficult to test people in this way—but it works for rats! 25 of 47 Using Indifference Curves: Substitutes and Complements What determines whether two goods are substitutes or complements? It depends on the shape of a consumer’s indifference curves. This relationship can be illustrated with two extreme cases: the cases of perfect substitutes and perfect complements. 26 of 47 Perfect Substitutes Quantity of peanut butter cookies 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 I1 I2 4 6 8 10 12 Quantity of chocolate chip cookies Two goods are perfect substitutes if the marginal rate of substitution of one good in place of the other good is constant, regardless of how much of each an individual consumes. 27 of 47 Consumer Choice Between Perfect Substitutes (a) Cokie Buys Only Peanut Butter Cookies Quantity of peanut butter cookies 12 (b) Cokie Buys Only Chocolate Chip Cookies Quantity of peanut butter cookies 12 I 2 A 10 I 1 10 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 0 BL 2 4 6 I1 I2 8 10 12 Quantity of chocolate chip cookies BL 2 0 2 4 6 B 8 10 12 Quantity of chocolate chip cookies When two goods are perfect substitutes, small price changes can lead to large changes in the consumption bundle. 28 of 47 Perfect Complements Quantity of milk (glasses) A 5 B C I 4 I 3 I 2 3 2 I 1 BL 1 0 4 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity of cookies Two goods are perfect complements when a consumer wants to consume the goods in the same ratio regardless of their relative price. 29 of 47 ►ECONOMICS IN ACTION Publicity or Piracy? When the practice of audio file-sharing took off in the late 1990s, a controversy erupted at the same time. Musicians argued that the widespread sharing of audio files was a modern version of theft. On the other hand, there were those who argued that instead of serving as a substitute for buying the CD, file-sharing actually acted as a compliment. After hearing one or two tracks from a CD via file sharing, a listener was more likely to go out and buy the CD. They argued that file-sharing acted like free publicity. However, the music industry was right because once most people had downloaded the songs they wanted, they did not purchase the CD. So file sharing and CD purchases are substitutes not compliments. 30 of 47 Prices, Income, and Demand How would our consumption choice change if either the prices of goods or our income change? First, let’s see the effects of a price increase illustrated in the following figure. Then, we will consider the impact of a change in income. 31 of 47 PITFALLS “Other Things Equal,” Revisited One of the biggest sources of confusion and error in economics—both in the classroom and in the real world—is failure to keep in mind the principle that all economic relationships are defined “other things equal.” The law of demand, which says that increasing the price of a good reduces the quantity demanded, is only an “other things equal” proposition; a higher price results in a lower quantity demanded, holding other prices and income constant. 32 of 47 Effects of a Price Increase on the Budget Line Quantity of restaurant meals 80 New BL: price of rooms = $600 An increase in the relative price of rooms rotates the budget line inward. 70 60 Original BL: price of rooms = $150 50 40 30 20 10 BL 0 2 4 BL 2 6 8 10 12 14 1 16 Quantity of rooms An increase in the price of rooms, holding the price of restaurant meals constant, increases the relative price of rooms in terms of restaurant meals. As a result, Ingrid’s original budget line, BL1, rotates inward to BL2. Her maximum possible purchase of restaurant meals is unchanged, but her maximum possible purchase of rooms is reduced. 33 of 47 Responding to a Price Increase Quantity of restaurant meals New optimal consumption bundle 80 70 3. … and increases restaurant meal consumption. 60 Original optimal consumption bundle C 50 A 40 I 2 30 Ingrid responds to the higher relative price of rooms by choosing a new consumption bundle with fewer rooms and more restaurant meals. Her new bundle, C, contains 1 room instead of 8 and 60 restaurant meals instead of 40. 20 10 0 1 2 BL 2 4 6 I 1 8 10 12 14 BL 1 16 Quantity of rooms 2. … reduces housing consumption … 1.An increase in the relative price of rooms rotates the budget line… 34 of 47 Effect of a Change in Income on the Budget Line Quantity of restaurant meals 100 80 A fall in income results in a parallel inward shift of the budget line. A rise in income results in a parallel outward shift of the budget line. 40 BL BL 0 8 2 BL 3 1 16 20 Quantity of rooms 35 of 47 Income and Consumption: Normal Goods Quantity of restaurant meals At a monthly income of $1,200, $2,400, Ingrid she chooses chooses bundle bundle B,A, consisting of 4 8 rooms and 20 40 restaurant meals. Since When relative consumption Ingrid’s price remainsof both unchanged,meals restaurant a fall and in income rooms shiftswhen falls her budget her income line inward falls, to BL2. goods are normal goods. both Optimal consumption bundle income at of $1,200 80 Optimal consumption bundle at income of $2,400 70 60 50 3. … and a fall in consumption of restaurant meals A 40 I 2 30 B 20 10 0 2 4 6 BL 2 8 10 2. … resulting in a fall in consumption of rooms… 12 I 1 BL 1 14 16 Quantity of rooms 1. A fall in income shifts the budget line inward, … 36 of 47 Income and Consumption: An Inferior Good Quantity of restaurant meals Optimal consumption bundle at income of $2,400 D Optimal consumption bundle at income of $1,200 I 2 3...and a fall in consumption of restaurant meals E BL 2 I 1 BL 1 When Ingrid’s income falls from $2,400 to $1,200, her optimal consumption bundle changes from D to E. Her consumption of second-hand furniture increases, implying that second-hand furniture is an inferior good. In contrast, her consumption of restaurant meals falls, implying that restaurant meals are a normal good. Quantity of second-hand furniture 2. … resulting in a rise in consumption of second-hand furniture 1. A fall in income shifts the budget line inward, … 37 of 47 Income and Substitution Effects The change in a consumer’s optimal consumption bundle caused by a change in price can be decomposed into two effects: the substitution effect, due to the change in relative price, and the income effect, due to the change in purchasing power. The substitution effect refers to the substitution of the good that is now relatively cheaper for the good that is now relatively more expensive, holding the utility level constant. It is represented by movement along the original indifference curve. 38 of 47 Income and Substitution Effects When a price change alters a consumer’s purchasing power, the resulting change in consumption is the income effect. It is represented by a movement to a new indifference curve, keeping the relative price unchanged. For normal goods, the income and substitution effects work in the same direction; so their demand curves always slope downward. Although these effects work in opposite directions for inferior goods, their demand curves usually slope downward as well because the substitution effect is typically stronger than the income effect. The exception is the case of a Giffen good. 39 of 47 Income and Substitution Effects Quantity of restaurant meals Hypothetical optimal consumption bundle 180 160 140 B 120 New optimal consumption bundle 100 Original optimal consumption bundle 80 60 A C 40 I BL 20 BL 0 1 2 4 S I 2 6 2 8 1 10 BL 12 14 1 16 Quantity of rooms Income effect Substitution effect 40 of 47 ►ECONOMICS IN ACTION How Much Housing? To illustrate the substitution effect, an example was given where an individual moves form Cincinnati to San Jose, gaining higher income but facing a higher price of housing. Also, the cost of living in San Jose is about twice that in Cincinnati. So, on average, families live about as well in the two metropolitan areas. But they don’t live the same way because the relative prices are different. Houses are typically smaller in San Jose, with fewer rooms and fewer square feet. Most noticeably, the great majority of new homes in the Cincinnati area are single-family houses on big lots; in San Jose, people are much more likely to live in townhouses or apartments. 41 of 47 SUMMARY 1. Preferences can be represented by an indifference curve map, a series of indifference curves. Each curve shows all the consumption bundles that yield a given level of total utility. Indifference curves never cross, and greater distance from the origin indicates higher total utility levels. The indifference curves of ordinary goods slope downward and are convex in shape. 42 of 47 SUMMARY 2. The marginal rate of substitution, or MRS, of R in place of M—the rate at which a consumer is willing to substitute more R for less M—is equal to MUR/MUM and is also equal to minus the slope of the indifference curve when R is on the horizontal axis and M is on the vertical axis. Convex indifference curves get flatter as you move to the right along the horizontal axis and steeper as you move upward along the vertical axis because of diminishing marginal utility: a consumer requires more and more units of R to substitute for a forgone unit of M as the amount of R consumed rises relative to the amount of M consumed. 3. Most goods are ordinary goods, goods for which a consumer requires additional units of some other good as compensation for giving up some of the good and for which there is diminishing marginal rate of substitution. 43 of 47 SUMMARY 4. A consumer maximizes utility by moving to the highest indifference curve his or her budget constraint allows. Using the tangency condition, the consumer chooses the bundle at which the indifference curve just touches the budget line. At this point, the relative price of R in terms of M, PR/PM (which is equal to minus the slope of the budget line when R is on the horizontal axis and M is on the vertical axis) is equal to the marginal rate of substitution of R in place of M, MUR/MUM (which is equal to minus the slope of the indifference curve). This gives us the relative price rule: at the optimal consumption bundle, the relative price is equal to the marginal rate of substitution. 44 of 47 SUMMARY 5. When the marginal rate of substitution is constant, two goods are perfect substitutes and indifference curves are straight lines: there is only one relative price at which the consumer is willing to purchase both goods. When a consumer wants to consume the two goods in the same ratio, regardless of the relative price, the goods are perfect complements. In this case, the indifference curves form right angles and the marginal rate of substitution is undefined. 45 of 47 SUMMARY 6. The effect of a change in price on consumer choice can be decomposed into the substitution effect and the income effect. The substitution effect is shown by a movement along the original indifference curve in response to the change in relative price, as the consumer substitutes more of the relatively cheaper good in place of the relatively more expensive good. The income effect is shown by a change to a new indifference curve, reflecting the fact that a change in a good’s price alters the purchasing power of a given level of income. 7. The income and substitution effects work in the same direction for normal goods, ensuring that demand curves slope downward. 46 of 47 The End of Chapter 11 Coming attraction: Chapter 12: Behind the Supply Curve: Inputs and Costs 47 of 47