Download Demand for Labor

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Minimum wage wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Middle-class squeeze wikipedia , lookup

Family economics wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Demand for Labor
Profit Maximization and the Marginal
Productivity Theory
• The assumption is that firms attempt to maximize
profit by hiring inputs to produce output. Three
possibilities for employing any given input, like
labor:
– If the revenue from employing another unit is greater
than the cost of employing it. Hire more of the input.
– If the revenue from employing another unit is less than
the cost of employing it. Hire less of the input.
– If the revenue from employing another unit is equal to
the cost of employing it. Stop. The profit-maximizing
level of the input has been reached.
Revenue from Labor
• Marginal Product of Labor - Change in output from hiring
another unit of labor, ceteris paribus (holding capital
constant0 .
– MPL = (ΔQ/ΔL) |K constant
• Marginal Revenue Product of Labor - Change in total
revenue from hiring another unit of labor.
– MRPL= ΔTR/ΔL
– MRPL = MR x MPL
– MRPL = (ΔTR/ΔQ) x (ΔQ/ΔL)
• Example:
– MR = $5/1Q or $5 and MPL=10Q/1L or 10
– MRPL = ($5/1Q) x (10Q/1L) = $50/1L or $50
– Hiring one worker results in 10 units of output and if each
additional output sells for $5, the revenue produced by one worker
is $50.
• In competitive output markets, marginal
revenue is equal to price so MR = P and
– MRPL = MVPL = P x MPL
Cost of Hiring Labor
• Marginal expense of an input = change in total
cost of hiring another unit of the input
– MEL = ΔTC/ΔL
• In competitive labor markets,
– MEL = Wage rate or W
• In monopsonistic or oligopsonistic labor markets,
– MEL > W
– This occurs because to hire another unit of labor the
employer must pay a higher wage to all workers
– Say the current wage for 10 workers is $10, to hire
another worker the wage rises to $11, the MEL equals
$11 for the extra worker plus $10 ($1 increase in wages
for 10 workers) or $21.
Labor Demand in Competitive Output and
Labor Markets
• Competitive output markets imply:
– MRPL = P x MPL
• Competitive labor markets imply:
– MEL = W
• Profit Maximization implies:
– MRPL = MEL , or
– P x MPL = W, or
– MPL = W/P
Diminishing Marginal Product of Labor
• The law of diminishing marginal returns –
as the increasing amounts of a variable
input are applied to a fixed factor(s) the
marginal product of the variable input will
diminish.
• Intuitive proof: if the LDMR did not apply,
you could grow the world’s food supply in a
small flower pot.
The Demand Curve for Labor with Real
Wages vs. Nominal Wages
• Real Wages – real wages are nothing more than
valuing cost in terms of how mush output must be
paid to the worker.
• For example, if an MP3 player sells for $100, and
the wages of a worker is $20/hour. The real wage
of the worker is .2 MP3 players/hour.
• Remember profit maximization:
– Hire an additional worker if they produce revenue more
than they cost
– Layoff an additional worker if they produce revenue
less than they cost
• If the worker’s,
– MPL > .2 MP3 player, hire
– MPL < .2 MP3 player, layoff
– MPL = .2 MP3 player, optimal
• When real wages are placed on the vertical axis, the
demand curve is just the MP curve, which is downwardsloping demand curve because of the LDMR.
• The demand curve quickly points out the rule above and
firms will maximize profits by hiring until the MPL= W/P.
• Economic profit and economic rent.
– Profit on labor is the difference between what firms were willing to
pay and the real wage rate
– Economic rent is the difference between what labor was willing to
supply labor for and the real wage rate.
Demand for Labor and Nominal Wages
• Profit Maximization occurs when the firm hires labor up to
the point where the
– MRPL = W
• In competitive output markets,
– P x MPL = W
– The LDMR ensures that the MRPL curve is downward-sloping.
– In this case, the firm looks at the revenue produced by an
additional labor and compares it to the nominal wage = cost of
hiring an additional labor.
• The difference in using nominal wages is that changes in
product price or demand will shift the MRPL curve. Using
real wages, a change in the product price will cause a
movement along the demand curve.
Labor Demand and Changes in other Inputs
• Changes in capital are usually associated with a time
period long enough for the firm to make investment or
plant-size decisions.
• Remember, the difference between the short- and long-run.
– Short-run: at least one input is fixed, usually capital (plant-size
fixed).
– Long-run: all inputs are variable (plant-size is variable).
• Modified profit maximizing rule:
– Remember cost minimization is a necessary condition for profit
maximization but is not a sufficient condition
– With two inputs, the firm must simultaneously satisfy the
following two conditions:
• MRPL = W
• MRPK = C
• To show that profit maximization implies cost
minimization, we recognize that in competitive markets
MRP = P x MP;
– P x MPL = W or P = W/ MPL
– P x MPK = C or P = C/ MPK, this leads to
– W/ MPL = C/ MPK
• To get an intuitive idea why this is cost minimizing
↓
– W/ MPL = W/(ΔQ/ΔL) or (W x ΔL)/ΔQ or ΔTCL/ΔQ or finally
MCQ|using more L
– C/ MPK = C/(ΔQ/ΔK) or (C x ΔK)/ΔQ or ΔTCK/ΔQ or finally
MCQ|using more K
• Numerical example: If W = $5/hr and C=$100/hr (rental or
imputed rent) and MPL = 10Q/1L and MPK=100Q/1K,
what should the firm do? Use a more labor intensive or a
more capital intensive approach?
• MCQ|using more L= ($5 x 1L)/10Q = $.50/1Q
• MCQ|using more K= ($100 x 1K)/100Q = $1.00/1Q
• If the W rises, the equality MCQ|using more L= MCQ|using
is disturbed and the firm will change its hiring
decisions and the following will result
more K
– MCQ|using more L will rise causing firms to cut back on labor in the
short-run
– L↓ → MPL↑ →MCQ|using more L↓
– L↓ → MPK↓ →MCQ|using more K↑
– These movements help to restore MCQ|using more L= MCQ|using more K
– The quantity demand of labor will fall for two reasons:
• Scale effect – MC of output ↑ so Q↓ and K and L both↓
• Substitution effect – K is substituted for L because K becomes
relatively cheaper (see above)
– The change in wages will have an ambiguous effect on the firm’s
desired stock of capital. The firm will produce output with a more
capital intensive production method [(K/L) ↑] if the substitution
effect outweighs the scale effect and more labor intensive [(K/L) ↓]
if the scale effect outweighs the substitution effect
Various Inputs
• So far we have discussed K and L, but we could add
natural resources and entreprenuership as well as break
each input class into different qualities or characteristics
(e.g. skilled versus unskilled workers)
• Inputs are gross substitutes when one input can be used in
place of another input. The are perfect substitutes when
they are interchangeable.
• Inputs are gross complements when increases (decreases)
in one input is accompanied by an increase (decrease) in
the other input. They are perfect complements if they need
to be used in fixed proportions.
• Example: US unskilled workers, foreign unskilled workers,
and computers:
– WUS↑→ substitution effect: LUS↓ →LFUS↑ scale effect: LUS↓ and
LFUS↓
– Two possibilities: sub>scale→ LUS↓ →LFUS↑ gross substitutes
sub<scale LUS↓ and LFUS↓ gross complements
– Computers and workers are gross complements, reductions or
increases in L will cause changes in the demand for computers.
Also, changes in the price of computers will affect the DL
Imperfect Competition in Output and Labor Markets
• Monopoly in output markets and monopsony in input
markets. Firms may have market power or the ability to
affect market prices and/or wages.
• Monopoly in output markets:
– Π max. rule is to hire L until MRPL = MRQ x MPL=W
– MRQ<P the monopolist will produce less output and hire fewer workers
that a competitive market.
– Theoretically, if monopolist has no market power in the labor market, they
must pay the going wages.In practice, however, it has been argued that:
• Regulated monopolist are not subject to competitive market forces and
therefore may pay higher wages. The incentive to offer higher wages is
similar to the argument for efficiency wages (less turnover, greater employee
satisfaction)
• Unregulated monopolists may not wish to report high profits and thus the
opportunity costs of offering reservation wages is lower.
• The empirical evidence is inconclusive.
• Monopsony in the labor market:
– Π max. rule is to hire L until MRPL = MRQ x
MPL=MEL
– In monopsony, the firm faces the entire market supply
curve for labor and must raise the wage to obtain an
additional worker. If all workers must be paid the same
wage rate, the MEL>W
– Example: At the wage of $10, 10 workers are
employed, to hire another worker requires raising the
wage to $11. The MEL of labor is the wage of $11 for
the additional worker plus the $1 increase in wages for
the existing 10 workers, which comes to $21.
– Monopsony and competition in the major leagues.
Leroy “Satchel” Paige and free-agency
– Monopsonist does not have a labor demand curve
because they are wage makers (monopolist don’t have a
supply curve because they are price makers).
– However, decreases in labor supply will raise wages,
but reduce employment. The decline in employment
will likely be greater in the long-run than in the shortrun if the substitution effect outweighs the scale effect.
Remember, in the case of two inputs MEL/ MPL = C/
MPK
• Mandated wages, such as a minimum wage, changes
incentives for monopsonists.
– In the short-run, if the wage is set between above the wage
monopsonist would have pay and below the amount that they
would be willing to pay, the minimum wage will lower the MEL
and will increase employment and average wages.
– In the long-run, there are two opposing effects:
• Substitution effect: The reduction in the MEL can cause firms to
substitute labor for capital.
• Scale Effect: The increase in wages (average wages) reduces
profitability. If the firm is a perfect competitor, this will cause exit
from the industry and reduce the demand for labor.
• In summary, in monopsony the effect of mandated wages
can be ambiguous, but decreases in the supply of labor
reduce employment. In competitive markets, both will
reduce employment.
Who Pays the Payroll Tax?
• Taxes drive wedges between the price the buyer pays and
the seller receives. A payroll tax drives a wedge between
the wages a firm pays and the wages that workers receive.
• Payroll taxes include social security retirement, disability,
and medicare taxes; unemployment insurance, and
Washington State L and I.
• The payroll tax maybe levied against the employee and/or
the employer (e.g. social security is paid to the government
by both the employer and the employee).
• The question we are asking is who really pays the tax or
the tax incidence.
• Knowing that a tax will lower the wage to
employees and increase the effective wage paid by
the employee, both the employer and the
employee will modify their behaviors. The
employee will reduce the QLS and the employer
will reduce their QLD.
• The distortion in behaviors will cause both to
share in the burden of the tax and the welfare loss.
• Imposing the payroll taxes on the employer shifts the
demand curve for labor downwards and to the left.
Graphical Demonstration of tax burden
• Imposing the payroll taxes on the employee shifts the
supply curve for labor up and to the left.
• The difference between the old and new curves is the tax
and represents the difference between what employers pay
and employees receive.
• It is important to note that the tax burden borne by the
employee and employer is independent of who the tax is
levied upon.
• The more inelastic the supply (demand) curve the more the
employee (employer) bears the burden of the tax. Studies
indicate in the long-run, most of the payroll tax is shifted
onto employees.