Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Real Business Cycles Route Map • Stochastic Solow-Swan Growth Model • The Crusoe economy – the simple intuition of RBC • The formal model • Assessment New Classical Principles • Real variables affected by other real variables • No profitable opportunities unexploited - market equilibrium • Rational Expectations Real Business Cycles Price Misperceptions Model • Follows these principles • Empirically weak: • Anticipated money matters (Mishkin, Gordon) • King & Plosser AER 1984 introduced money to RBC model in its transactions function • Profit-seeking banks raise money supply in periods of expansion. • High correlation of output with inside money rather than outside money • ‘Reverse’ causation Real Business Cycles Price Misperceptions Model • Empirically weak: • RBC theorists challenged the informational basis for misperceptions model • Barro (Modern Business Cycle Theory 1989) ‘people could expend relatively few resources to find out quickly about money and prices’ (p.2) Real Business Cycles Model-based Trend Output st m xt W N where st log t t and m is the log of the desired mark- • Model-based output gap: t t PY up of price over nominal marginal costs • This is based on a simple production function Y = AN • Interesting to compute z = y – x using the model-based measure of x and compare the time series behaviour of z and y. Real Business Cycles 1979-80 Recession 11.95 11.94 11.93 y UK Fullz Capacity Output using Model-generated Gap 11.92 11.91 11.9 12.6 11.89 11.88 11.87 11.86 12.4 11.85 z 11.84 1978.5 1979 12.2 1979.5 1980 1980.5 y 1981 1981.5 1982 12 1990-91 Recession 11.8 12.155 12.15 12.145 11.6 z y 12.14 12.135 12.13 11.4 12.125 12.12 12.115 11.2 1960 12.11 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 12.105 1989.5 1990 1990 1995 1990.5 1991 2000 1991.5 1992 2005 1992.5 1993 Real Business Cycles Stochastic Solow-Swan Growth Model • Aggregate production function: Y K L1 0 1 L AN Y K L1 K y k f (k ) L L L • A is grows at rate l each year • l is rate of labour-augmenting technical progress • N grows at rate n per year • L grows at rate l + n per year Real Business Cycles Stochastic Solow-Swan Growth Model • With constant savings rate (s): K I K s F (K, L) K • Divide both sides by L: K s f (k ) k L • Evolution of k: k K L K n l k K L K k K K K n l k n l k K L L k s f (k ) k (n l ) k s f (k ) (n l ) k Real Business Cycles Stochastic Solow-Swan Growth Model • With constant savings rate, the evolution of k is given by: k s f (k ) (n l ) k k will be positive if s f (k ) (n l )k k will be negative if s f ( k ) (n l )k k will be zero if s f (k ) (n l )k Real Business Cycles Steady-State Equilibrium k s f (k ) (n l ) k . (n+l+) k k 0 y since s f (k ) (n l )k f(k) y* s f(k) k 0 since s f (k ) (n l )k k(0) k* k Steady-state equilibrium (k*) is where the addition to the capital stock (through saving) is just enough to keep the capitallabour ratio constant. In equilibrium, Y is growing at l + n since y* is constant. Real Business Cycles ‘Vibrating’ Production Function • Imagine that the production function is stochastic: Y zt K L1 zt F (K , L) where zt is total factor productivity zt K L1 y zt k zt f (k ) L 'Good times': zt >1 'Bad times' : zt <1 'Normal' : zt =1 Fluctuations in total factor productivity lead to business cycles Real Business Cycles ‘Vibrating’ Production Function (n+l+) k y • Imagine that z takes on two values - 1.5 and 0.5 • Start at k = k1 and z = 0.5 (in equilibrium). y is constant so Y is growing at l + n • z rises to 1.5 and k starts to rise to k2 – the new equilibrium s 1.5 f(k) s 0.5 f(k) k1 k2 k Real Business Cycles ‘Vibrating’ Production Function (n+l+) k y • Y now grows faster than l + n to approach higher steady state. • Before k2 is reached, let z fall back to 0.5 • k now falls back towards k1 and output growth falls below l + n s 1.5 f(k) s 0.5 f(k) k1 k2 k Real Business Cycles ‘Vibrating’ Production Function log(Y) Steady State Path for z = 1.5 Slope = n +l Transitional paths Steady State Path for z = 0.5 Slope = n +l t0 t1 t2 Time Real Business Cycles Stochastic Solow-Swan v RBC model • The full RBC models differ from the stochastic Solow-Swan model in a number of ways: • the intertemporal substitution effect • labour supply does not grow simply at rate n • more effort supplied when productivity (wages) high • output rises both because productivity is high and because workers offer more effort • endogenous savings rather than a fixed savings rate • start with utility function and solve for consumption and savings Real Business Cycles Crusoe Economy • RBC models usually use representative agent assumption • Use Robinson Crusoe economy for intuition • Decision: how many coconuts to (a) eat and (b) invest (plant) • Given preferences and technology (yield on each tree) and without shocks, Crusoe will choose an optimal balance: • enough planted to maintain stock of trees • enough consumed to satisfy inter-temporal optimality • Shocks of two types: transitory and permanent Real Business Cycles Crusoe Economy: Transitory Shocks • Effects of unusually good weather • Crusoe may work harder – amplifies the effect of good weather • Smooth out the benefits of his good luck by planting more trees – investing much of the extra harvest • The island economy will have increased output most of which will be invested but some of it will be consumed. • Implications: • work & output correlated given intertemporal substitution • consumption smoother than investment • although shocks (weather) are serially uncorrelated, they lead to serially correlated changes in output. Real Business Cycles Crusoe Economy: Permanent Shocks • Effects of ‘anti-monkey’ technology • No intertemporal substitution • Less need to smooth out consumption through investment • The island economy will have increased output most of which will be consumed but some of it will be invested. • Combination of transitory and permanent shocks could be used to explain movements in work, output, consumption and investment. Real Business Cycles Formal RBC Model [Taken from McCallum 1989] • Economy consists of large number of identical agents – explain aggregate behaviour using the ‘representative-agent’ model • The agent maximizes the following utility function: U u(Ct , Lt ) u(Ct 1, Lt 1) u(Ct 2 , Lt 2 ) u(Ct 3 , Lt 3 ) ... j u Ct j , Lt j 2 3 j 0 • Subject to budget and technology constraints: Yt Ct It Nt Lt 1 Zt f (Nt , K t ) Ct K t 1 K t K t since Kt 1 Kt Kt It It Kt 1 Kt Kt Real Business Cycles Formal RBC Model [Taken from McCallum 1989] • To derive analytical solution, McCallum assumes: u(Ct ,1 Nt ) logCt (1 )log(1 Nt ) Zt f (Nt , Kt ) Zt Nt Kt1 1 Ct 1 (1 ) N Zt Kt1 Kt 1 (1 ) N Zt K t1 Nt N • Because of utility function, income and substitution effects cancel so there is no intertemporal substitution effect • Given these assumptions analytical solutions for consumption and investment can be derived (handout has details) Real Business Cycles Formal RBC Model [Taken from McCallum 1989] Ct 1 (1 ) N Zt Kt1 Kt 1 (1 ) N Zt Kt1 Nt N • Taking logs and solving for K and Y: log(Kt 1) 1 log(N ) (1 )log(Kt ) log( Zt ) which implies log(Yt ) 2 log(N ) (1 )log(Yt 1) log( Zt ) • Although the shocks are serially independent, their effects on output are serially correlated. Real Business Cycles Formal RBC Models • More general assumptions (e.g. about preferences and depreciation rates) means models: • cannot be solved analytically • require numerical solution methods. • Two approaches: • set the variance of the technology shocks (Z) to replicate exactly the variance of output • use the ‘Solow Residual’ as the measure of the technology shocks Real Business Cycles Testing Methodology • Compare variables’ variance and covariance in the model with those in the data – ‘eye-ball’ testing. • Data for actual US Economy: detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott trend. • The Basic Model: the McCallum model model described earlier in the previous section, but allowing depreciation to be incomplete. • Kydland-Prescott Model: • ‘Time to build’ model: it takes four quarters to build productive capital; • ‘Fatigue effect’: the harder workers have worked in the past, the more they value leisure today; • the technology shock has both permanent and transitory components, which agents cannot distinguish. • Hansen Model: Similar to Basic Model, but workers cannot choose the hours they work - they either work fixed hours or do not work any. Real Business Cycles Standard Deviations of Percentage Departures from Trend Variable Output Consumption Investment Capital Stock Hours Productivity US Economy 1.76 1.29 8.6 0.63 1.66 1.18 Basic Model Model 1.76 0.55 5.53 0.47 0.91 0.89 Kydland-Prescott Model 1.76 0.44 5.4 0.46 1.21 0.7 Hansen Model Model 1.76 0.51 5.71 0.47 1.35 0.5 Contemporaneous Correlations with Output Departures from Trend Variable Consumption Investment Capital Stock Hours Productivity US Economy 0.85 0.92 0.04 0.76 0.42 Hours of work and productivity less correlated with output than models’ predict Basic Model 0.89 0.99 0.06 0.98 0.98 Kydland-Prescott Model 0.85 0.88 0.02 0.95 0.86 Hansen Model 0.97 0.99 0.05 0.98 0.87 Consumption smoother than investment But consumption too smooth and investment insufficiently volatile Constructed to be identical Real Business Cycles Solow-Residual (SR) Method • • Charles Plosser, ‘Understanding real business cycles’, Journal of Economic Perspectives (1989). 1 Assume an aggregate production function: Yt Zt XN t Kt • where X is labour-augmenting technical progress and Z is the technology shock that affects total factor productivity • Taking logs: logYt log Zt log X t log Nt (1 )log Kt • SR is the combined contribution of X and Z: • Calculate SR as residual given knowledge of Y, N, K and log SRt log Zt log X t logYt log Nt (1 )log Kt Real Business Cycles Solow-Residual (SR) Method • • • King and Rebelo assume that log(X) has a deterministic trend and log(Z) is an AR(1) process: From definition of log(SRt-1), we can write log(Zt-1) as: Substituting we derive: log SRt log Zt log X t log X t log X o t log Zt log Zt 1 t so log SRt log X o t log Zt 1 t log Zt 1 log SRt 1 log X t 1 log SRt 1 log X 0 (t 1) log SRt log X o t (log SRt 1 log X o (t 1)) t log SRt 1 log X o 1 t log SRt 1 t Real Business Cycles Solow-Residual (SR) Method log SRt logYt log Nt (1 )log Kt log SRt 1 log Xo 1 t log SRt 1 t • King and Rebelo use US data to calculate logSR • and then regress logSR on a time trend and lagged logSR • They estimate to be 0.979 – a very high degree of persistence. • They combine the Solow Residual with an RBC model to derive predicted variances and co-variances of the key variables. Real Business Cycles King & Rebelo Model Actual and Simulated Standard Deviations Variable US Economy King & Rebelo Model Output 1.81 1.39 Consumption 1.35 0.61 Investment 5.3 4.09 Hours 1.79 0.67 Productivity 1.02 0.75 • RBC models ‘explain’ about 78% (1.39/1.81) of the business cycle – perhaps not surprising since SR is based on actual output data. • Simulated consumption still too smooth • Simulated Hours & Productivity also too smooth Real Business Cycles Assessment • To explain the actual business cycle we required unreasonably large and persistent technology shocks. • Insufficiently strong internal propagation mechanisms to generate the persistence in output - models only succeed if the shocks themselves are serially correlated • Simulated hours more highly correlated with output than in the data - the models over-emphasize the importance of intertemporal substitution. • Microeconomic evidence suggest that the intertemporal substitution effect is in fact very weak (an example is Joseph Altonji’s (Journal of Political Economy, 1986) study of US household panel data). • Actual correlation of hours and output due to a mechanism not included in the RBC models. • Keynesians suggest it is due to disequilibrium in the labour market (unemployment falls when output rises) Real Business Cycles Assessment • The ‘productivity puzzle’ • RBC models predict high correlation between productivity and employment (typically 0.9) • Data suggests it is far lower – possibly negative • Galí (AER 1999): • price stickiness – so output is demand-determined • favourable technology shock requires less labour to produce required output • hence employment (hours) and productivity negatively correlated. • RBC models are promising once embedded in a new-Keynesian (sticky-price) framework Real Business Cycles Assessment • Weak testing methodology – comparing simulated with actual ‘second moments’. • Hartley, Salyer and Sheffrin (1997) simulated a Keynesian economy (using Ray Fair’s (1990) model), and then compared the simulated economy with the RBC model. • The RBC model did quite well in mimicking the variances and correlations of the simulated data. • RBC models have difficulty in explaining recessions – falling output. • Alan Kirman (1992) questioned the representative agent assumption. Adding a small measure of heterogeneity can have destructive consequences for what we observe in the aggregate Real Business Cycles McCallum’s Conclusion: • It would seem to be virtually indisputable that the RBC literature has provided a substantial number of innovative and constructive technical developments that will be of lasting benefit in macroeconomic analysis. ... the RBC studies have provided a healthy reminder that a sizeable portion of the output and employment variability that is observed in actual economies is probably the consequence of unavoidable shock, that is, disturbances not generated by erratic monetary or fiscal policy makers.