Download IPE16

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts
no text concepts found
Transcript
Chapter 16
Tax Evasion
Reading
• Essential reading
– Hindriks, J and G.D. Myles Intermediate Public Economics.
(Cambridge: MIT Press, 2005) Chapter 16.
• Further reading
– Allingham M. and A. Sandmo (1972) ‘Income tax evasion: a
theoretical analysis’, Journal of Public Economics, 1, 323—338.
– Baldry, J.C. (1986) ‘Tax evasion is not a gamble’, Economics
Letters, 22, 333—335.
– Becker, G. (1968) ‘Crime and punishment: an economic
approach’, Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169—217.
– Cowell, F.A. Cheating the Government (Cambridge: MIT Press,
1990) [ISBN 0262532484 pbk].
Reading
– Glaeser, E.L., B. Sacerdote and J.A. Scheinkman (1996) ‘Crime
and social interaction’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111,
506—548.
– Schneider F. and D.H. Enste D.H. (2000) ‘Shadow economies:
Size, causes, and consequences’, Journal of Economic
Literature, 38, 77—114.
– Mork, K.A. (1975) ‘Income tax evasion: some empirical
evidence’, Public Finance, 30, 70—76.
– Spicer, M.W. and S.B. Lundstedt (1976) ‘Understanding tax
evasion’, Public Finance, 31, 295—305
• Challenging reading
– Bordignon, M. (1993) ‘A fairness approach to income tax
evasion’, Journal of Public Economics, 52, 345—362.
– Cowell, F.A. and J.P.F. Gordon (1988) ‘Unwillingness to pay’,
Journal of Public Economics, 36, 305—321.
Reading
– Graetz, M., J. Reinganum and L. Wilde (1986) ‘The tax
compliance game: towards an interactive theory of law
enforcement’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 2,
1—32.
– Hindriks, J., M. Keen and A. Muthoo (1999) ‘Corruption, extortion
and evasion’, Journal of Public Economics, 74, 395—430.
– Myles, G.D. and R.A. Naylor (1996) ‘A model of tax evasion with
group conformity and social customs’, European Journal of
Political Economy, 12, 49—66.
– Reinganum, J. and L. Wilde (1986) ‘Equilibrium verification and
reporting policies in a model of tax compliance’, International
Economics Review, 27, 739—760.
– Scotchmer, S. (1987) Audit classes and tax enforcement policy,
American Economic Review, 77, 229—233.
Introduction
• Tax evasion is the illegal failure to pay tax
• Tax avoidance is the reorganization of economic
activity to lower tax payment
– Tax avoidance is legal but tax evasion is not
– The borderline between avoidance and evasion is
unclear
• Estimates show evasion to be a significant
fraction of measured economic activity
• It is an important consideration for tax policy
The Extent of Evasion
• The names black, shadow or hidden economy
are used to described economic activity for
which payment is received but is not officially
declared
• Included in the hidden economy are:
– Illegal activities
– Unmeasured legal activity such as output of
smallholders
– Legal but undeclared activity
• The unmeasured economy is the shadow
economy plus activities which are economically
valuable but do not involve any transaction
The Extent of Evasion
• There are many methods for measuring the
hidden economy
• The difference between the income and
expenditure measures of national income
• Survey data directly or indirectly as an input into
an estimation procedure
• The demand for cash on the basis hidden
activity is financed by cash (monetary approach)
• The use of a basic input that is measured to
estimate true output (input approach)
The Extent of Evasion
• Table 16.1 presents
estimates of the
size of the hidden
economy
• These estimates are
subject to error
• There is a degree of
consistency
• Undeclared
economic activity is
substantial
Developing
Transition
OECD
Egypt 68-76%
Thailand 70%
Georgia 28-43%
Ukraine 28-43%
Italy 24-30%
Spain 24-30%
Mexico 40-60%
Malaysia 38-50%
Tunisia 39-45%
Hungary 20-28%
Russia 20-27%
Latvia 20-27%
Denmark 13-23%
France 13-23%
Japan 8-10%
Singapore 13%
Slovakia 9-16%
Austria 8-10%
Table 16.1: Hidden Economy as % of GDP,
Average Over 1990-93
Source: Schneider and Enste (2000)
The Evasion Decision
• The simplest model of the evasion decision
considers it to be a gamble
• If a taxpayer declares less than their true income
(or overstates deductions)
–
–
–
–
They may do so without being detected
There is also a chance that they may be caught
When they are a punishment is inflicted
Usually a fine but sometimes imprisonment
• A taxpayer has to balance these gains and
losses taking account of the chance of being
caught and the level of the punishment
The Evasion Decision
• The taxpayer has a fixed income level Y
– This income level is known to the taxpayer
– The level of income is not known to the tax collector
• The taxpayer declares a level of income X where
X≤Y
• Income is taxed at a constant rate t
• The amount of unreported income is Y – X ≥ 0
• The unpaid tax is t[Y - X]
The Evasion Decision
• If the taxpayer evades without being caught their
income is given by
Ync = Y - tX
• When the taxpayer is caught evading all income
is taxed and a fine at rate F is levied on the tax
that has been evaded.
• The income level when caught is
Yc = [1 - t]Y - Ft[Y - X]
• If income is understated the probability of being
caught is p
The Evasion Decision
• Assume that the taxpayer derives utility U(Y)
from an income Y
• After making declaration X the taxpayer obtains
– Income level Yc with probability p
– Income level Ync with probability 1 – p
• The taxpayer chooses X to maximize expected
utility
• The declaration X solves
max{X} E[U(X)] = [1 – p]U(Ync) + pU(Yc)
The Evasion Decision
• Observe that there are two states of the world.
– In one state of the world the taxpayer is not caught
evading and income is Ync
– In the other state of the world they are caught and
income is Yc
• The expected utility function describes
preferences over income levels in the two states
• The choice of X determines income in each state
• Varying X trades-off income between the states
– High X provides relatively more income in the “caught
evading” state
– Low X provides relatively more in the “not caught”
The Evasion Decision
• When X = Y the income after tax is [1 - t]Y in both
states
• When X = 0 income is [1 - t(1 + F)]Y if caught and
Y if not caught
• The options facing the taxpayer lie on the line
joining the points for X = 0 and X = Y
– This is the opportunity set of income allocations
between the two states
• The utility function provides a set of indifference
curves
– Along an indifference curve are income levels in the
two states giving equal expected utility
The Evasion Decision
• The choice problem is
Yc
shown in Fig. 16.1
• The optimal declaration
achieves the highest
indifference curve
1  t Y
• The taxpayer chooses to
locate at the point with
declaration X*
1  t 1  F Y
• This is an interior point
with 0 < X* < Y
• Some tax is evaded but
some income is declared
X Y
X*
X 0
1  t Y
Y
Figure 16.1: Interior choice:
0 < X* < Y
Y nc
The Evasion Decision
Yc
Yc
1  t Y
1  t Y
X* Y
1  t 1  F Y
1  t 1  F Y
1  t Y
a: X* Y
Y
Y nc
X* 0
1  t Y
b: X* 0
Figure 16.2: Corner solutions
• Corner solutions can also arise
• In Fig. 16.2a X* = Y so all income is declared
• In Fig. 16.2b X* = 0 so no income is declared
Y
Y nc
The Evasion Decision
• Evasion occurs when indifference curves are
steeper than the budget constraint on the 45o
line
• The indifference curves have slope
dYc/dYnc = – [1 – p]U′(Ync)/pU′(Yc)
• On the 45o line Yc = Ync so U′(Ync) = U′(Yc) implying
dYc/dYnc = – [1 – p]/p
• The slope of the budget constraint is – F
• The indifference curve is steeper than the
budget constraint on the 45o line
p < 1/[1 + F]
The Evasion Decision
• Evasion occurs if the p is small relative to F
• The condition applies to all taxpayers
• In practice F is between 0.5 and 1 so 1/(1 + F) ≥
1/2
• Information on p hard to obtain
• In the US
– The proportion of individual tax returns audited was
1.7 per cent in 1997
– The Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program
revealed that 40 percent of US taxpayers underpaid
their taxes
– This is large but less than the model predicts
The Evasion Decision
• An increase in detection
probability is shown in
Yc
Fig. 16.3
• An increase in p reduces
the gradient of the
indifference curves on
1  t Y
the 45o line
• The optimal choice
moves closer to X = Y
1  t 1  F Y
• The income declared
rises so an increase in
the detection probability
reduces evasion
new
old
1  t Y
Y
Figure 16.3: Increase in
detection probability
Y nc
The Evasion Decision
• A change in the fine rate
affects income when
Yc
caught evading
• An increase in F pivots
the budget constraint
around the point where X
1  t Y
=Y
• The optimal choice
moves closer to honest
1  t 1  F Y
declaration
• This is shown in Fig. 16.4 1  t 1  Fˆ Y
by the move from Xold to
Xnew
• An increase in F reduces
evasion
X new
1  t Y
X old
Y
Figure 16.4: Increase in
the fine rate
Y nc
The Evasion Decision
• An income increase
moves the budget
Yc
constraint outward
• The optimal choice
moves from Xold to Xnew in
1 t Yˆ
Fig. 16.5
1  t Y
• The effect depends on
new
absolute risk aversion
old X
X
RA(Y) = - U′′(Y)/U′(Y)
1  t 1  F Yˆ
• If RA(Y) is constant the
1  t 1  F Y
optimal choices lie on a
locus parallel to the 45o
1  t Y 1 t Yˆ Y Yˆ Y nc
line
• If RA(Y) decreases with
Figure 16.5: Income increase
income the choice locus
bends downward
The Evasion Decision
• An increase in the tax
Yc
rate moves the budget
constraint inward as
inFig. 16.6
• The outcome is not clear1  t Y
cut
1 tˆY
• If RA(Y) is decreasing a
X old
tax increase reduces tax 1  t 1  F Y
X new
evasion
• This is because the fine 1  tˆ1  F Y
is Ft so an increase in
the t raises the penalty
1 tˆY 1  t Y Y
• This reduces income in
the state in which income
Figure 16.6: Tax rate increase
is lowest
Y nc
Auditing and Punishment
• The analysis of the evasion decision assumed
that the p and F were fixed
• This is satisfactory from the perspective of the
individual taxpayer
• From the government's perspective these are
choice variables that can be chosen
– The probability of detection can be raised by the
employment of additional tax inspectors
– The fine can be legislated or set by the courts
• The issues involved in the government's
decision can be analyzed
Auditing and Punishment
• An increase in either p or F will reduce the
amount of undeclared income
• Assume the government wishes to maximize
revenue
• Revenue is defined as taxes paid plus the
money received from fines
• From a taxpayer with income Y the expected
value of the revenue collected is
R = tX + p(1 + F)t[Y – X]
Auditing and Punishment
• Differentiating with respect to p
R
X
 1  F t Y  X   t 1  p  pF 
0
p
p
• Differentiating with respect to F
R
X
 ptY  X   t 1  p  pF 
0
F
F
• If pF <1 – p an increase in p or F will increase the
revenue the government receives
• p is costly, F is free
• Optimal policy is low p very high F
Auditing and Punishment
• This policy maximizes revenue not welfare
• The government may be constrained by political
factors
• The government may not be a single entity that
chooses all policy instruments
• A more convincing model would have:
– The tax rate set by central government
– The probability of detection controlled by a revenue
service
– The punishment set by the judiciary.
Auditing and Punishment
• The economics of crime views tax evasion as
just another crime
• The punishment should fit with the general
scheme of punishments
• Levels of punishment should provide incentives
that lessen the overall level of crime
– Lower punishments for less harmful rather crimes
• Tax evasion has a low punishment if viewed as
having limited harm
Evidence on Evasion
Income interval
17-20
20-25
25-30
30-35 35-40
Midpoint
18.5
22.5
27.5
32.5
37.5
Assessed income
17.5
20.6
24.2
28.7
31.7
Percentage
94.6
91.5
88.0
88.3
84.5
Table 16.2: Declaration and Income
Source: Mork (1975)
• Compares income level from interviews to income on tax
return
• Interviewees placed in income intervals based on
interview
• The percentage found by dividing the assessed income
by the midpoint of the income interval
• Declared income declines as a proportion of reported
income occurs as income rises
Evidence on Evasion
• The propensity to evade is
reduced by an increase in
the probability of detection,
age, income but increased
by an increase in perceived
inequity and number of tax
evaders known
• Extent of tax evasion
increased by inequity,
number of evaders known
and experience of previous
tax audits.
• Social variables are clearly
important
Variable
Propensity
to evade
Extent of
evasion
Inequity
0.34
0.24
Number of evaders
known
0.16
0.18
Probability of
detection
-0.17
Age
-0.29
Experience of
audits
0.22
Income level
-0.27
Income from wages
and salaries
0.20
0.29
Table 16.3: Explanatory Factors
Source: Spicer and Lundstedt (1976)
Evidence on Evasion
• Data from the US Internal Revenue Services
Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program
survey of 1969
– Evasion increases as the marginal tax rates increases
but decreases when wages are a significant
proportion of income
• The difference between income and expenditure
figures in National Accounts support this result
• Belgian data found the converse: tax increases
lead to lower evasion
• There remains ambiguity about the tax effect
Evidence on Evasion
• Tax evasion games can be used to test evasion
behavior
• These games have shown that evasion
increases with the tax rate
• Evasion falls as the fine is increased or the
detection probability increases
• Women evade more often than men but evade
lower amounts
• Purchasers of lottery tickets were
– No more likely to evade than non-purchasers
– Evaded greater amounts when they did evade
Evidence on Evasion
• The nature of the tax evasion decision has been
tested by running two parallel experiments
– One framed as a tax evasion decision and
– The other as a simple gamble
• These experiments have the same risks and
payoffs
• For the tax evasion experiment some taxpayers
chose not to evade even when they would under
the same conditions with the gambling
experiment
• This suggests that tax evasion is more than just
a gamble
Evidence on Evasion
• There are several important lessons to be drawn
from the evidence
• The theoretical predictions are generally
supported except for the effect of the tax rate
• Tax evasion is more than the simple gamble
portrayed in the basic model
• There are attitudinal and social aspects to the
evasion decision in addition to the basic element
of risk
Effect of Honesty
• The act of tax evasion can have psychological
effects
• Taxpayers submitting incorrect returns feel
varying degrees of anxiety and regret
• The innate honesty of some taxpayers is not
captured by representing tax evasion as just a
gamble
• Non-monetary costs of detection and
punishment are not captured by preferences
defined on income alone
Effect of Honesty
• Honesty can introduced by assuming the utility
function has the form
U = U(Y) - cE
• The level of evasion is E = Y- X and c is a
measure of honesty
• The value of cE the psychological cost of
evasion
• Assume taxpayers differ in their value of c but
are identical in all other respects
• Those with high c will have a greater utility
reduction for any given level of evasion
Effect of Honesty
• Evasion occurs only if the utility gain from
evasion must exceed the utility reduction
• Let E* be the optimal level of evasion
~
~
*
• Evasion is chosen if EU( Y ) – cE > U(Y) where Y
is the random income after optimal evasion
• The population is separated into taxpayers who
do not evade (high values of c) and others who
evade (low c)
• Those who do not evade are “honest” but will
evade if the benefit is sufficiently great
Effect of Honesty
• Empirical evidence shows a positive connection
between number of tax evaders known and the
level evasion
• The evasion decision is not made in isolation but
with reference to the norms and behavior of
society
• Social norms can be incorporated as an
additional utility cost of evasion.
• This cost can be assumed an increasing function
of the proportion of taxpayers who do not evade.
Effect of Honesty
• This captures the fact that more utility will be lost
the more out of step the taxpayer is with the
remainder of society
• If evasion is chosen expected utility is
EU – m(n)
• The function m(n) is increasing in the number of
honest taxpayers, n
• This modification reinforces the separation of the
population into evaders and non-evaders
Tax Compliance Game
• A revenue service chooses the probability of
audit to maximize total revenue taking as given
the tax rate and the punishment
– The government is viewed as allocating choices to
separate agencies
• The choice of probability requires an analysis of
the interaction between the revenue service and
the taxpayers
• The revenue service reacts to income
declarations and taxpayers react to the expected
detection probability
Tax Compliance Game
• A strategy for the revenue service is the
probability with which it chooses to audit any
given value of declaration
• A strategy for a taxpayers is a choice of
declaration given the audit strategy of the
revenue service
• At a Nash equilibrium the strategy choices must
be mutually optimal
• In this game predictability in auditing cannot be
an equilibrium strategy
Tax Compliance Game
• Observe
– No auditing at all cannot be optimal because it would
mean maximal tax evasion
– Auditing of all declarations cannot be a solution
because this incurs excessive auditing costs
– A pre-specified limit on the range of declarations that
will be audited since those evading will remain
outside this limit
• To be unpredictable the audit strategy must be
random
Tax Compliance Game
• The probability of an audit should be high for an
income report that is low compared to what one
would expect from someone in that taxpayer's
occupation
• Or it should be high given the information on
previous tax returns for that taxpayer
• In either case a taxpayer should not be able to
predict if they will be audited
Tax Compliance Game
• A version of the strategic interaction is depicted in Fig.
16.7
• A taxpayer with income Y can either evade (reporting
zero income) or not (truthful income report)
• By reporting truthfully the taxpayer pays tax T to the
revenue service (with T < Y)
• The revenue service can either audit the income report
or not audit
• An audit costs C, C < T, for the revenue service to
conduct and is accurate in detecting evasion
• If the taxpayer is caught evading the tax T plus a fine F is
paid (where F > C)
Tax Compliance Game
Revenue Service
Taxpayer
Audit
No Audit
Evasion
Y T  F, T  F  C
Y, 0
No Evasion
Y T, T  C
Y T, T
Figure 16.7: Compliance game
Tax Compliance Game
• There is no pure strategy equilibrium in this tax
compliance game
– If the revenue service does not audit the taxpayer
strictly prefers evading and therefore the revenue
service is better-off auditing as T + F > C
– If the revenue service audits with certainty, the
taxpayer prefers not to evade as T + F > T, which
implies that the revenue service is better-off not
auditing
• The revenue must play a mixed strategy in
equilibrium with the audit strategy being random
• The taxpayer’s evasion strategy must also be
random
Tax Compliance Game
• Let e be the probability that the taxpayer evades, and p
the probability of audit
• In equilibrium the players must be indifferent between
their two pure strategies
• For the revenue service to be indifferent between
auditing and not auditing the cost of auditing C must
equal the expected gain in tax and fine revenue e[T + F]
• For the taxpayer to be indifferent between evading and
not evading the expected gain from evading (1 – p)T
must equal the expected penalty pF
• The equilibrium is
e* = C/(T + F), p* = T/(T + F)
Tax Compliance Game
• The equilibrium payoffs are
u* = Y – T, v* = T – (C/(T+F))T
• The taxpayer is indifferent between evading or
not evading so equilibrium payoff is equal to
truthful payoff Y – T
• This is because
– Unpaid taxes and the fine cancel out in expected
terms
– Increasing the fine does not affect the taxpayer
Tax Compliance Game
• A higher fine increases the payoff of the revenue
service since it reduces the amount of evasion
– increasing the penalty is Pareto-improving
• The equilibrium payoffs also reflect a cost of
evasion
– for any tax T paid by the taxpayer the revenue service
receives T – D
– where D = (C/(T + F))T is the deadweight loss of
evasion
• Evasion involves a deadweight loss that is
increasing with the tax rate
Compliance and Social
Interaction
• Evasion is more likely when others already
evade
• Payoff from non-compliance is increasing with
the number of non-compliers
• Aggregate compliance tendency is toward one
of the extremes
Compliance and Social
Interaction
• This is shown in Fig. 16.8
• Always move away from
the intersection
Compliance
Payoff
Non-compliance
Payoff
0
Non-compliance Rate
1
Figure 16.8: Equilibrium compliance