* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Labour Economics and Socio
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Vladimir Dahl East-Ukrainian National University © Filippova I.H. Demos of the discipline ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Emigration Labor Migration Immigration © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS According Organization to for the International Migration's World Migration Report 2010, the number of international migrants was estimated at 214 million in 2010. If this number continues to grow at the same pace as during the last 20 years, it could reach World Population: 6,853,328,460 Migrants in the world: 215,738,321 Almost 3.15% of the world population live outside their countries 2 Migration 405 million by 2050. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. International migration will play an increasing role in the demographic future of nations if fertility continues to decline in most countries. Net immigration already accounts for roughly 40% of population growth in the United States of America and about 90% in the EU-15 countries 3 International migration ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. International labour migration is defined as the movement of people from one country to another for the purpose of employment. Labour mobility has become a key feature of globalization global and economy the with migrant workers earning US$ 440 billion in 2011, and the estimating World Bank that more than $350 billion of that total was transferred to developing countries in the form of remittances. 4 International Labour Migration ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Recently, Ukraine has become one of the major labor exporting countries in Europe. Rough estimations of the workforce that has at some time worked abroad about 7 million people, which is a lot in any case for Ukraine with its work-capable population of about 28 million. 5 Migration from Ukraine © Filippova I.H. © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS INDIA 5436012 AUSTRALIA 5522408 Top migrant destination FRANCE 6684842 SPAIN 6900547 UNITED KINGDOM 6955738 CANADA 7202340 SAUDI ARABIA 7288900 GERMANY 10758061 RUSSIAN FED 12270388 42788029 USA 0 6 7000000 14000000 21000000 Top migrant destination 28000000 35000000 42000000 49000000 © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS TURKEY 4261786 PHILIPPINES 4275612 UNITED KINGDOM 4666172 PAKISTAN 4678730 Top emigration countries 5384875 BANGLADESH UKRAINE 6525145 CHINA 8344726 RUSSIAN FED 11034681 INDIA 11360823 11859236 MEXICO 0 7 2000000 4000000 6000000 Top emigration countries 8000000 10000000 12000000 14000000 © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS •CHINA-USA 1736314 Top migration •INDIA-UNITED ARAB EMIRATES 2185919 •CHINA-HONG KONG 2224503 •RUSSIAN FED.KAZAKHSTAN 2226706 corridors •KAZAKHSTAN-RUSSIAN FED. 2648315 •TURKEY-GERMANY 2733109 •BANGLADESH-INDIA 3299268 •UKRAINE-RUSSIAN FED. 3647234 •RUSSIAN FED.-UKRAINE 3684217 •MEXICO-USA 11635995 0 8 2000000 4000000 6000000 Top migration corridors 8000000 10000000 12000000 14000000 © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS In countries, which do not share a long and porous border with the destination country and do not have extensive networks leading to low-skilled jobs there, international migration is more costly and risky. This precludes much emigration from the low end of the skill distribution, leaving a predominance of brain-drain migrants at the top. 9 Migration's costs & risks © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Theories of migration try to explain what drives population flows. Given the complex nature of the decision process individuals face, there is a large variety of theoretical models available to explain the actual migration outcome. While micro behavioural models focus on dominant factors at the individual level (such as These models may either be the human capital model), macroeconomic models classifed especially focus on the labour market dimension of as micro- macroeconomic in nature. 10 or migratory flows. Theories of migration © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS The neoclassical migration theory starts from The human capital model of migration in expected maximization approach. fact views the process of migration as an investment where the returns to migration (in terms of higher wages associated with a new job) exceed the costs involved in moving. From this follows that the humans compare the expected income they would obtain for the case they stay in their home region (X) with the expected income they would obtain in the alternative region (Y) and further accounts for 'transportation costs' of moving from region X to Y. 11 an Neoclassical migration theory income (utility) ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. Thus, neoclassical economic theories of labor migration posit that individuals situate themselves in the labor market and jobs where their expected earnings (net of migration costs) are highest. Earnings are the product of wages and time worked, both of which depend on education and other “human capital” characteristics of individuals. Other considerations affecting individuals’ satisfaction or “utility” at different locales (e.g., proximity to family members, relative deprivation, family income risk) also affect migration propensities in neoclassical models. The association between characteristics of individuals and their likelihood of migrating frequently to referred as is the “selectivity” of migration. 12 Selectivity of migration © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Social science research the For example, in most cases, average determinants of migration using household schooling levels for immigrants in the level data generally find that human capital U.S. are substantially above those of (e.g., education) is positively related to the their countries of origin. This finding likelihood of out-migration. reflects higher economic returns to The selectivity of migration on individual and schooling in the U.S. compared to household places of origin as well as other characteristics on varies across migrant destinations. It depends critically on potential the returns to these characteristics in urban areas in migrants’ countries of different migrant labor markets. origin). migrant destinations (e.g., It also has implications for development. If migrants take (human) capital with them when they migrate, this may have detrimental effects on the productivity of workers left behind. 13 Human capital as the factor of migration ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. The Lewis dual economy consists of a "capitalist" sector and a "non-capitalist" sector. Although Lewis did not intend this, in practice the capitalist sector has generally become identified with the urban economy and the non-capitalist sector with agriculture or the rural economy. Sir W. Arthur Lewis Though neoclassical two-sector models originally designed to examine the reallocation of labor between rural and urban areas, it is potentially applicable to international migration. 14 Lewis dual economy © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS The capitalist sector hires labor and sells Profit output for a profit, while the non-capitalist (or subsistence) sector does not use reproducible capital and does not hire labor for a profit. Capitalist Initially, labor is concentrated in the non- sector capitalist sector. As the capitalist sector expands, it draws labor from the noncapitalist sector. Labor If the capitalist economy is concentrated in the urban economy, labor transfer implies geographic movement, i.e., rural-to-urban migration. 15 Dual economy Subsistence sector © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS In theory, migration implies an opportunity Opportunity cost for the rural economy cost for the rural economy, which loses the product of the individuals who migrate. However, the centerpiece of the Lewis model (and essence of the classical approach) is the assumption that labor is available to the industrial sector in unlimited In the limiting case, this implies that there quantities at a fixed real wage, measured in is surplus or redundant labor in rural agricultural goods. areas, such that the marginal product of rural labor is zero, and labor thus may be withdrawn from rural areas and employed in the urban sector without sacrificing any loss in agricultural output. That is, the opportunity cost or "shadow price" of rural labor to fill urban jobs is zero. 16 Opportunity cost for the rural economy © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS More generally, the labour supply from In the Lewis model, earnings at the the subsistence sector is unlimited if the prevailing capitalist-sector wage must exceed the labour supply is infinitely elastic at the non-capitalist-sector ruling capitalist-sector wage. earnings of individuals willing to migrate. Any tendency for earnings per head to rise in the non-capitalist sector must be offset by increases in the labor force W LD there (e.g., through population growth, female labor-force participation, or LS immigration). A key hypothesis of the Lewis model is that rural accompanied out-migration by a is decrease not in agricultural production nor by a rise in either rural or urban wages. 17 Key hypothesis of the Lewis model L ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. According to Ranis and Fei’s interpretation of the Lewis model, the perfectly elastic labor supply to the capitalist sector ends once the redundant labor in the rural sector disappears and a relative shortage of agricultural goods emerges. Through migration, the marginal value products of labor are equated between the two sectors. Here the Lewis classical approach ends and the neoclassical analysis starts. The dual economies merge into a single economy in which wages are equalized across space. Assuming full employment of labor in both rural and urban sectors and minimal transactions costs, inter-sectoral wage differentials should be the primary factors driving rural outmigration. 18 Gustav Ranis & John Fei © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Rural-to-urban migration exerts upward pressure on wages and on the marginal value product of labor in rural areas, while putting downward pressure on urban wages. W W LD W1 U 0 W R S LS LD L migration W2R W1U Labor drawn W0R R 1 L R 0 L L U 0 L Rural-to-Urban Migration Rural sector 19 Rural-to-Urban Migration U 1 L Urban sector L © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Internal and international migration are modeled according to this perfect-markets neoclassical specification in virtually all computable general equilibrium models, both national and international. In contrast, most microeconomic models of rural out-migration are grounded on Todaro's seminal work, which incorporates labormarket imperfections, including urban unemployment, into a migration model. Michael P. Todaro 20 Michael P. Todaro © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Todaro proposed a modification of the neoclassical migration model in which each potential rural-to-urban migrant decides whether or not to move to the city based on an expected income maximization objective. Expected urban income at a given locale is the product of the wage (the sole determinant of migration in the neoclassical models), and the probability that a prospective migrant will succeed in obtaining an urban job. Expected rural income is calculated analogously. Individuals are assumed to migrate if their discounted future stream of urban-rural expected income differentials exceeds migration costs; i.e., if T e t pu (t ) yu yr (t )dt c 0 0 pu (t ) is the probability of urban employment at time t, yu denotes urban earnings given employment, yr (t ) represents expected rural earnings at time t, 21 Michael P. Todaro c is migration costs, is the discount rate. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. Among nations, the share of rural population declines sharply as per-capita incomes increase, from 70 to 80% in countries with the lowest per-capita GNPs to less than 15% in the highest-income countries. 22 Share of rural population & GNP pc ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. The share of the national workforce in agriculture plunges even more sharply, from 90% or higher in low-income countries to less than 10 % in high-income countries. 23 The share of the national workforce in agriculture ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS In the United States an estimated 69 % of the 1996 seasonal agricultural service workforce was foreign-born, and in California, the nation's largest agricultural producer, more than 90 % of the seasonal agricultural service workforce was foreign-born. 24 Foreign seasonal agricultural service workforce © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. The world's great migrations out of rural areas are accelerating. The most populous countries also are among the most rural. The greatest migration potential is in China, where 71 % of the population is rural and an estimated one-third of the rural labor force of 450 million is either unemployed or underemployed. 25 World migrations out of rural areas ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. Human capital models of migration represent an effort to provide the migration theories presented above with a micro grounding, permitting tests of a far richer set of migration determinants and impacts. The predictions of Human capital migration theory 26 Human Capital Theory and Migration © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS The predictions of Human capital migration theory First, the young should be more mobile than the old, inasmuch as they stand to get returns from migration over a longer period of time. Second, migration between locales should be negatively related to migration costs. This has been interpreted as implying a negative association between migration flows and distance. However, considerations besides distance (especially access to information) may make distance less of a deterrent for some individuals (e.g., better-educated individuals or those with "migration networks", contacts with family or friends at prospective migrant destinations). 27 The predictions of Human capital migration theory ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. The predictions of Human capital migration theory Third, neutral productivity growth in an economy - e.g., equal rates of growth in the rural and urban sectors - will increase migration from low-income (e.g., rural) to high-income (e.g., urban) sectors or areas. Fourth, specific human capital variables that yield a higher return in region A than in region B should be positively associated with migration from B to A. In addition to these predictions, human capital theory implies that income differentials between rural and urban areas are eliminated by migration over time. 28 The predictions of Human capital migration theory © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Labor Migration W If the countries are closed, there are no migration flows W LS LD D L W1 LS emigration immigration B 0 W A W1 A W0A W1B S 1 L A 0 L D 1 L L Country A 29 B 0 L Country B Equilibrium model of migration B 1 D 1 L L L ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS © Filippova I.H. Migration not only produces lost-labor, and possibly also lost-capital, effects on rural economies. It also represents a potentially important source of income and savings, through migrant remittances. Non-migrants benefit from emigration, even if they do not receive any of the remittances themselves, provided that the magnitude of migrants' remittances exceeds a critical threshold roughly equal to the value of the production they would have produced had they stayed behind. Measuring remittances is difficult because migrants often enter developed countries outside of official channels and repatriate their earnings through informal means. Money may be returned in the form of goods purchased abroad or in the form of cash savings brought back by migrants or visiting family members ("pocket transfers"). 30 Migrant remittances © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Causes of Impacts of migration migrations on sending countries Analysis on receiving countries of migration in migrants and their s families TOWARDS AN ASSESSMENT OF MIGRATION, DEVELOPMENT AND HUMAN RIGHTS LINKS: CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK AND NEW STRATEGIC http://www.un.org/esa/population/meetings/ninthcoord2011/assessmentofmigration.pdf 31 The Modern Approach to analysis of Migration INDICATORS © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS IMPACTS ON Economic impacts of remittances SENDING Impacts of return migration COUNTRIES Social costs of Demographic reproduction impacts (human capital) Demographic Social and cultural impacts impacts Political impacts 32 IMPACTS ON SENDING COUNTRIES © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS Economic asymmetries between sending and Causes of migration receiving countries Relative economic productivity Social inequalities between sending and receiving countries Human development index between sending and receiving countries GINI coefficient Differences in economic growth Wage differentials Labor precariousness in sending and receiving countries Deficit or surplus in labor force Gaps in research and development investments 33 Causes of Migration Gender inequalities © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS IMPACTS ON Economic impacts RECEIVING Impacts on national security COUNTRIES Demographic Social and cultural impacts impacts 34 IMPACTS ON RECEIVING COUNTRIES © Filippova I.H. ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS IMPACTS ON Economic MIGRANTS Impacts on labor impacts AND THEIR conditions FAMILIES Impacts on Social and cultural human rights impacts 35 IMPACTS ON MIGRANTS AND THEIR FAMILIES ECONOMIC OF LABOUR & SOCIO-LABOUR RELATIONS THE END 36 The end © Filippova I.H.