Download Slide 1

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Embedded liberalism wikipedia , lookup

State (polity) wikipedia , lookup

Social liberalism wikipedia , lookup

Third Way wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
International Conference on China’s Social Policy Reform:
Challenges and Direction,
Jointly organised by East Asian Institute, National University of
Singapore & Research Department of Social Development,
Development Research Centre of the State Council, China
Title: The Evolving East Asian
Welfare Regimes: The Case of China
Wong, Chack Kie PhD
Professor, Social Work Department,
Associate Director, Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific
Studies,
The Chinese University of Hong Kong
Introduction



The paper uses a tripartite framework to study the change of
the welfare regime in China.
It suggests that the prevalent Western welfare theories are
inadequate in explaining the development of China’s welfare
regime because it has different institutional logic.
It also incorporates the developmental state theory and the
experiences of welfare developmentalism in some East Asian
welfare regimes in the analysis of the institutional dynamic in
China’s welfare development.
2
Western welfare state theories and
concepts

The welfare state is located at the interface of two
sets of rights, or “rules of the game” (Gintis and
Bowles, 1982, pp. 341-345)



citizen rights underlying the democratic institutions of
society, and property rights underlying the capitalist
market system.
They are in constant and persistent contradictions
According to the neo-Marxist theorists, the
contradictions underlying the welfare state are
functional to the very existence of capitalism
because they legitimize the accumulation function of
capital (O’Connors, 1973; Gough, 1979; Offe, 1984).
3

The welfare systems in East Asian societies where
the underlying institutional arrangements are
different from Western welfare states


The democratic institution and the capitalist economy
were or are absent
Some of them may have different “rules of the game” or
their institutional logic may take time to mature,



such as the market economy in reform China and political
democracy in Maoist and reform China,
or rudimentary democracy in many East Asian societies.
In other words, from the standard set by Western
welfare capitalism, East Asian welfare systems can
be described as “evolving” or immature (Kim, 2001;
Tang, 2000).
4
The concept of regime


The concept of regime in a welfare regime denotes the
complex socio-political, legal and organizational features
that are systematically interwoven in the relationship
between the state and the economy as well as between the
state and society (Esping-Andersen, 1990, p. 2; Walker and
Wong, 2005, p. 6); and class coalitions of power resources
account for the regime types in the form of social
settlements among capital, labour and state actors (EspingAndersen, 1990).
In this light, the concept of the welfare regime looks more
powerful and explains the outcome of social settlements,
i.e., welfare arrangements as major components between
regime types.

5
The concept of globalisation



According to Mishra (1999:3-4)
Globalisation refers to a process through which
national economies are becoming more open
and thus more subject to supranational
economic influences and less amenable to
national control
Internationalisation – the principal economic
units remain national although international
aspects of the economy, e.g., trade, foreign
direct investment and multinational enterprises
assume increasing importance.
6


It is assumed that globalisation exerts a downward
pressure on social protection and weakens
national government’s choice due to fiscal
constraints – increase in taxation will reduce
competitiveness in attracting foreign investment
It is also suggested that globalisation has come to
conflict with democratic politics - constraints of
national government to use expansionary policies
to enhance welfare
7
A brief review of welfare theories and concepts in
the study of East Asian welfare systems

Inform us:



First, East Asian welfare systems have and/or prefer a
greater use of society in the distribution of welfare and
social costs.
Second, they may have different institutional logics
underlying their economic and political systems.
Third, class coalitions of power resources, primarily a
society-led theory, explain the welfare regime types in
the form of social settlements among capital, labour and
state may not be able to explain welfare development in
East Asian welfare regimes.
8




In fact, neither capitalism nor democracy is necessary for
constituting a welfare state or explaining its development
(Walker and Wong, 1996, 2004).
Former Soviet bloc countries and Maoist China had many
essential welfare services and provisions on par with those
in Western welfare capitalism.
In other words, welfare development is driven not only by
the institutional logics of capitalism and democracy
The driving force of welfare development in non-capitalist
and non-democratic societies is often motivated by the
need for political legitimacy of the authoritarian rule over
society (Walker and Wong, 2005, p. 5).
9
The tripartite framework


Walker and Wong (2009) use a tripartite framework to
analyze the relationship between economic policy and
social policy in a comparative analysis of social policy
as a public burden in the West and China
The three dimensions are
1. Institutional, e.g., the neo-Marxist macro-institutional logic
underlying welfare capitalism – capitalist welfare state; the
set of citizen rights as rule of the game underlying the
democratic institution of society
2. Ideological, e.g., values and traditional beliefs about welfare
3. Developmental, e.g. national wealth and fiscal resources for
welfare development (i.e., modernisation theory for welfare
development)
10
Developmental state and East Asian
welfare regimes

Developmental state theory



In order to catch up with advanced nations,
developing countries need to use their state
capacity to direct the economy and the society to
accomplish national economic development
(Leftwich, 1995, p. 401).
According to Johnson (1982), a developmental state
is a coalition consisting of government ministers
and state bureaucrats that prioritizes economic
growth over all else.
In essence, it is a combination of political power and
economic expertise that give the developmental
state much transformative power (Weiss, 2000).
11

Ironically, the success of the developmental state may pave the
way for its own demise,


Pang (2000) talks about the end of the East Asian developmental
states due to two major factors—




As these countries achieve their economic growth, a clientelistic
state evolves into a citizen-led state over time and the
developmental elite has to make room for new autonomous
institutions as well as popular interests (Barro, 1997; Lijphart,
1999).
democracy – self-confident civil society confronts the authoritarian
developmental elite
financial globalization – the domestic capitalists no longer need the
financial subsidies from the state to grow
According, the developmental states in East Asia, Taiwan, South
Korea, and Japan ultimately lose their power over the economy
and society, except Singapore
Globalisation is also context-bounded, i.e., affected by regime
type – class coalition, e.g. Singapore is still state-led
12

The exception of Singapore due to two reasons

First, Singapore’s government does not collaborate
with domestic capitalists, but transnational ones.


Second, because of a weak and subordinated civil
society largely due to effective governance


Therefore, the domestic capitalist class has not developed
into an autonomous and powerful social agent with the
capacity to challenge the authority of the developmental
elite.
Singapore’s working class enjoys the fruit of the
developmental state and its trade unions are tightly
controlled by the state.
Political democracy and a global economy
explain the recent divergent national
development of East Asian societies.
13

The application of developmental state in
welfare development in East Asian welfare
regimes

Welfare developmentalism and productivism are
similar concepts, that suggests that the state
subordinates welfare development to economic
growth.

Government intervention and policies are used
extensively to promote industrialization by investing
heavily in the education and health of the workforce
to enhance the legitimacy of the government and to
pacify labour (Aspalter, 2006; Kwon, 2002; Tang,
2000).
14

So, how could welfare developmentalism become
inclusive welfare or universal welfare such as the
extension of the decommodified welfare programme?

Political democracy seems to be the answer in view of
the recent experiences in South Korea and Taiwan (Ahn
& Lee, 2005; Croissant, 2004; Back, 2005; Hill & Hwang,
2005; Hort & Kuhnle, 2000; Kwon, 2002; Yasuhiro,
2005).


In the case of Korea’s change to inclusive coverage, according
to Kwon’s account (2002, pp. 30-32), the development of
universal health insurance was a long process fuelled by
democratization.
In the case of Taiwan’s expansion of its decommodified welfare
programme, both Kuomintang and the Democratic Progressive
Party applied a strategy of promising social welfare policies in
highly competitive elections during the process of
democratization (Aspalter, 2002, 2006; Ku, 2002; Wong, 2005).
15

Two models as concluded on the
experiences of a few East Asian welfare
regimes


The first model, seen in Korea and Taiwan, is the
shift from state-led welfare development to
society-led after the democratic institution of
society dominates.
In the second model, seen in Singapore, the
developmental elite hold its power even in
economic affluence due to its deliberate polices
and exercise political control over trade unions.
16
The case of China as an evolving
Welfare Regime

The application of the tripartite framework

Institutional – China lacks a democratic institution
of society but it adopts market mechanism and
principles in economic reform




The need to address the structural contradiction imposed
from the logic of capital accumulation (state-led factors)
Also the constraint imposed by globalisation
(internationalisation?)
Ideological – to look at trait of ideological shift
relevant to welfare development.
Developmental – to see whether the new social
resources from economic growth are turned into
fiscal support for welfare development
17

Four types of statistical data are presented as
empirical evidence for our tripartite analysis of
China’s evolving welfare regime; they are
1. the share of social expenditure as a percentage of GDP
- to indicate the commitment of the state to citizen rights
2. the share of SOE employment as a percentage of total
urban employment
- to indicate the extent of the need for redistribution by the welfare state
3. health care expenses
- to see whether welfare development as depicted by macro-level data of
social spending matches that of the micro–level specific policy area
4. the division of expenditure and revenue of central
government and local governments.
- to see whether China has commanded the required social resources for
redistribution.
18
The institutional dimension


Table 1 reveals the social expenditure patterns of China during
economic reform and its different institutional arrangements of
welfare.
In the pre-reform period, China spent very little of its national
wealth for social expenditure (a broader definition to include
education and even cultural activities due to inseparable official
statistics)



3.61 percent of GDP in 1978, when Deng Xiao-ping started the reform
process. That share increased to 9.48 percent in 1985 because we
include 5.62 percent of GDP as subsidies to loss-making enterprises in
the social expenditure budget.
Up to 3.84% of GDP in 2002 during the last year of Jiang Zemin, and
before Hu Jintao became the party chief secretary
This reveals the low level of social expenditure


E.g., OECD countries spend on average 20% of GDP in social protection;
This is why China’s welfare regime is immature
19
20


Table 2 is the share of employment of SOEs as a
percentage of total urban employment. In 1978 when Deng
Xiao-ping initiated economic reform, SOEs had 78.3 percent
of total urban employment, but that figure declined to 35
percent in 2000, one year before China was admitted into
the World Trade Organization.
The share of SOE employment declined to 21.3 percent in
2008.
21
22

This gradual decline of employment of SOEs as a
percentage of total urban employment had an
important implication to the welfare regime of
China, a need for the state to intervene to alleviate
the capital accumulation function due to the
following reasons
1. Foreign direct investment comes to China to lower
cost of production
2. Private-sectors do not enjoy financial subsidies from
the state
3. Disquiet organized labour and subordinated civil
society are not in favour of labour
23



Therefore, despite the introduction of a capitalist market system, the
protection of labour is at the mercy of the developmental elite
because of inadequate citizen rights.
If structural factors do not favour non-state sector employees in
primary distribution, it is necessary to look at secondary distribution;
that is, redistribution by the state in China’s welfare regime.
Table 1 also reveals substantial increases recently



Social expenditure as a share of GDP rose from 3.83 percent in 2005 to
4.04 percent in 2006, 6.19 percent in 2007, and 6.66 percent in 2008,
substantial increases in a short time.
In absolute terms, spending on culture, education and health care jumped
from 610 billion¥in 2005 to 1,286 billion¥in 2008, an increase of 210
percent over four years.
The corresponding rise in social expenditure on pension and social welfare
was even more impressive, from 71.6 billion¥in 2005 to 680.4 billion¥in
2008, a jump of 950 percent in four years.

See Table 1
24


It can be concluded that redistribution in China is at a pretty
low level but there have been impressive increases recently.
Judging from the evidence available, the present level of
social resource redistribution seems unlikely to legitimize
the accumulation function of capital

Empirical evidence of social discontent


E.g. inadequate redistribution resulted in social miseries is
paraphrased in terms of the “Three “Mountains” facing people—
schooling, medical consultation, and housing are not affordable.
E.g., a stability maintenance office was set up in 2006 in different tiers
of the government to oversee social unrest and propose initiatives to
maintain social stability.
25

Look at health care expenses data


Urban health care system is reformed to
facilitate the marketisation of the economy
In 1998, the reform of two traditional health
insurance systems


labour insurance and government insurance into the
basic health insurance system for urban employees,
included private-sector employees
The following data illustrates that it was about a shift
of source of finance to social insurance, whilst
individual self-payment remained at a similar in five
years’ time
26
Source: Wong, Tang & Lo,
2006
27

Inclusion of private-sector employees in
cities did not lessen the affordability issue


Therefore, it does not help in terms of political
legitimization
Affordability of medical consultation is still one
of the “Three Mountains” in public discourse
about their hardship in daily life.

Two examples illustrate the tension due to the
application of market mechanism into the operation
of public hospitals in China:


Public hospital doctors were called “white wolves” by
patients in some reports
Some public hospitals had to ask police to be stationed in
hospitals due to poor relations with patients
29

The underlying factor of the bad relationship between
public hospital doctors and their patients can be
traced back to the early 1980s when the central
government began to freeze its subsidies to public
hospitals (Zheng & Hillier, 1995).

This forced hospitals to rely upon profits from two
sources:



Charges on the use of high-end medical equipment and the sale
of medicine.
This started the decline of the subsidies from
government as a share of the total income of public
hospitals, e.g. only 7-8% from financial subsidies of
governments in comprehensive public hospitals in 2008.
But recent increases in government health expenses as
a percent of total health care expenses was correlated
with the decline of individual health care expenses as a
share of total health care expenses
30
Ideological shift

When Deng Xiao-ping launched economic
reform in 1978, he followed the
developmental state theory by using market
forces to catch up with advanced countries
in national development.

In ideological terms, it is a shift from Mao Ze-dong’s
egalitarianism to market socialism, i.e., an ideology
emphasizing “growth first” development and the
subordination of social welfare and social
development to economic development (Chau & Yu,
1999; Walker & Wong, 2009).
31

Deng Xiao-ping’s goal of building a “xiao-kang
society” was modified to the building of a
“comprehensive xiao-kang society” in 2002 by
the Chinese Communist Party under the
leadership of Jiang Ze-min (2002)


Not only economic development was targeted, but
also higher levels of democracy, culture, science
and education, social harmony, and people’s
standard of living.
However, Jiang’s major ideological advancement
was the “Three Represents,” which includes the
capitalist class as people, and not an ideological
shift with direct implication on welfare development.
32

In late 2002, Hu Jin-tao became the party chief
secretary and the concept of social harmony
was put forward.


Among the six essential components of the concept
of social harmony, the component of “fairness and
justice” implies the reconciliation of the interests
and relations of all parties concerned, under which
people’s internal and other social conflicts are
properly settled and social equity and justice were
implemented (Hu, 2005).
This is also evident in the discourse of the “Five Coordinations” (Hu, 2003)

With seemingly direct implications on welfare development
are: the coordination of rural and urban development,
regional development, economic and social development
33

Both constructing a harmonious society and
the “Five Co-ordinations” indicate a shift
from the trickle-down neo-liberal ideology of
market’s unequal distribution—”a few get
rich first”

to striking a proper balance between economic
growth and social development and an
emphasis on “getting rich both” in either the
market’s primary distribution or the welfare
state’s secondary distribution.
34
Developmental dimension


Development means more resources available for redistribution
In 2009, China’s GDP was equivalent to US$4.985 trillion,
making China the third largest economy in the world after the U.S.
and Japan (Wall Street Journal, July 2, 2010).



China, with 1.3 billion people, is still a developing lower-medium
income nation at best
Nevertheless, the sustained growth rate of up to 8 percent-10
percent per year over a period of thirty years is phenomenal and
has enabled the country to accumulate sufficient wealth for
redistribution.
This was especially the case after 1994 when the central
government reformed the tax system and allowed the central
government to have a greater share of tax money for
redistribution.
35

In this light, when Hu Jin-tao came to power,
the ratio of central-local government in fiscal
expenses declined from a 30.1/69.9 pattern
in 2003 to a 21.3/78.7 pattern in 2008.


Table 4
This indicates that more social resources are
available from China’s ‘growth’ state for the
use of the local government


The GDP in 2003 was 2,171.53 billion ¥.
In 2008, it jumped to 6,133.04 billion ¥, an
enormous rise of 282 percent (Table 1)
36
37
Conclusion







China’s welfare regime is characterized by the domination of the developmental
elite in the distribution of benefits and costs.
Prevalent Western welfare theories are inadequate to explain welfare
development in China; it has different institutional logic
China is expanding its welfare, e.g., social expenditure despite it increases the
exposure to international capital in terms of foreign direct investment
It seems that internationalisation is more appropriate on China’s exposure to
international economy – its SOEs still not expose to supranational economic
influences and still amendable to national control
‘Globalisation’ seems not a key factor in China’s evolving welfare regime
Its low social expenditure as a share of its national wealth is a clear indicator of
its immaturity.
The increasing share of non-SOE employment suggests that a larger share of
urban employees receive second-class remuneration and welfare packages
compared to their SOE counterparts.


In principle, their poor conditions in primary distribution should be compensated by
secondary distribution in welfare for the sake of the political legitimization of the state.
On the contrary, welfare reform is found to shift the financial cost of state welfare to
society as in the case of the basic health insurance for urban employment
38



The new leadership of Hu Jin-tao, with the new discourse of
constructing social harmony and the “Five Co-ordinations,”
departs from the “growth-first” developmental strategy and
trickle-down neo-liberal ideology.
The ideological shift to a fine balance between economic
development and social development coincided with a slow
but continuous process of a rise in social expenditures in
general and government health care expenses in particular.
The recent increases in social expenditures were
substantial and a greater share of national revenue was
channelled to local governments for redistribution after Hu
Jin-tao took office in 2003. In other words, the
developmental factor, i.e., resources, is also important.
39


To conclude, China’s welfare regime is still
evolving.
As a typical developmental state, welfare
development in China and the well-being of its
citizens depend very much on the ruling
ideology and the transformative power of the
developmental elite


Specifically, whether the political elite, experts and
bureaucrats are able to design social settlements
that are fair to the labour and common people.
In this regard, abandoning the use of marketization
in China’s welfare reform is significant in enhancing
the political legitimization function of the state.
40




At last, if China wants to lessen the social miseries resulted
from capital accumulation and to enhance its political
legitimacy, the Singapore model seems a viable alternative.
Of course, it will be a challenging task to manage rising
expectation of its people fuelled by economic affluence and
the moral driving force of the democratic institution of
society.
In other word, the challenge is not only about material
resources, but also institutional and ideological.
Thank you.
41
Selected key references







Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism.
Cambridge: Polity Press.
Johnson, C. (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle, The Growth of Industrial
Policy, 1925-1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Leftwich, A. (1995) Bringing Politics Back In: Towards a Model of the
Developmental State, The Journal of Developmental Studies, 31(3), 400427
Pang, Eul-Soo (2000) The financial crisis of 1997-98 and the end of the
Asian Development State, Contemporary Southeast Asia, 22 (3) 570-593
Tang, K.L. (2000) Social Welfare Development in East Asia, Hampshire:
Palgrave
Walker, A. and Wong, C.K. (2005) East Welfare Regimes in Transition, From
Confucianism to Globalization, Bristol: Policy Press
Walker, A. and Wong, C.K. (2009) The relationship between social policy
and economic policy: Constructing the public burden of welfare in China
and the West, Development and Society, 38(1) pp.1-26.
42