* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download SNA production boundary
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
There are many human activities that can be seen as economic in some sense. For example growing your own potatoes can be seen as an economic activity even though there is no cash transaction involved. Or again, travelling to work can be seen as an economic activity since it is a necessary prelude to earning one’s living. The so-called « production boundary » defines which of these and other economic-type activities are to be included in the GDP. As it happens, the first of the two examples above is inside the production boundaqry while the second is outside it. The first part of this lesson gives more detail about the SNA production boundary. The second part of this lesson then considers how the outputs of the various activities included within the production boundeary are defined. Output was the first column of the SUT we looked at in lesson 1. In many cases it is clear what the output of an economic activity consists of: coal is the output of a coal-mine and sausages are the output of a sausage factory. But there are several activities included in the production boundary where the nature of the output is not so clear. The SNA Production Boundary covers five kinds of activities: 1.The first of these is by far the most important. It covers the production of goods and services for sale – crops, livestock, minerals, manufactured goods, business services for example. Note that it also includes government services. Some of the services produced by government are collective services provided to the community at large, such as law and order, national defense and statistics. Others are provided to individual households such as education and health services. 2.The second of these is particularly important in countries with a large agricultural sector. Farmers usually produce for the market but also keep back enough of what they grow to feed the family. All this produce is included as agricultural output, whether sold or not. Building your own house or a storage shed also counts as production. 3.Authors, film producers and musicians are also producers. The SNA treats their output as a kind of capital asset. The original manuscript or piece of music will go on producing an income for the producer over several years. 4.When you live in a flat or house that you own, the SNA considers that you are an entrepreneur selling housing services to yourself. 5.Finally, households can produce domestic services which they “sell” to themselves by employing cooks, butlers, gardeners and body-guards. 2 Output is not always the same as sales. For services, output and sales are always the same. A restaurant's output is what it gets from its customers for the meals it serves: the output of an airline is the tickets it sells. But for goods, some of what is produced may not be sold immediately. It goes into stocks. This means that goods output may be smaller or greater than its sales. It will be smaller if it is running down its stocks of finished goods and larger if it is accumulating more stocks of goods for sale at a later date. Output can be calculated as sales plus the increase in stocks of finished goods, where the increase can be either positive or negative. 3 For certain producers, the national accounts have adopted special rules for defining output. Here we will look at the most important cases. A special word about Non-Profit Institutions Serving Households- NPISH or “enpish”. To keep it simple, we ignored enpish in the SUT, but they are both producers supplying some of the services that make up the total supply of goods and services and they are also treated as consumers of the services they produce. They should have had a column to themselves in the Uses side of the SUT. The reason we ignored them is that they are relatively insignificant in many countries, but this is not always the case. We give more details about enpish in a later slide. 4 We value the output of “market” producers using the prices at which their goods and services are sold. As governments sell very few of their services we have to value their output as the “costs of production”: • Compensation of employees is the biggest item. It consists of wages and salaries and allowances in cash and the value of any income in kind – free or subsidized housing, food and meals, transport to and from work. An important point to notice here is that wages and salaries include employer’s contributions for social security – health care, unemployment insurance and pensions for example. Mostly governments provide these social benefits without making actual contributions to a social security fund. In this case the national accountant has to estimate what the government should have paid into a fund in order to finance the benefits that employees actually receive. This amount is then added to wages and salaries to obtain compensation of employees. • Intermediate consumption includes office stationery, electricity, rent and other current cost of running government offices, hospitals, schools, police forces and armies. • Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) is the decline in the value of government fixed assets through wear and tear and obsolescence. Government computers, vehicles and office buildings, hospital and school equipment and so on are being used up in the process of producing government services. The national accountant must include this “using up of capital” in the cost of producing government services even if governments themselves do not always show it in their accounts. • Operating surplus is usually zero or negligible. It may include the operating surplus of restaurants or bookshops in museums. •Taxes and subsidies on production are also usually zero. Governments do not tax themselves! 5 There are several kinds of non-profit institutions. Chambers of commerce and business associations are often “non-profit” organizations. In some countries government hospitals and schools are operated as “non-profit” institutions. In deciding where to classify them, we ask the question “Who finances their operations?” If they are financed by enterprises, they are treated like enterprises and are not shown separately. If they are financed by government they are included together with other unit-s of general government. If they are financed by households they are Non-Profit Institutions Serving Households - or “Enpish” - and they are shown as a separate kind of producer. Religious organizations may run hospitals, clinic and schools in addition to mosques and churches. Their output must be included in the national accounts. In many low income countries the last of kind of enpish listed here – Unicef, Red Crescent etc – may be quite important. They employ both expatriate and locally-recruited staff and provide a range of services from health care, reproductive advice for women, mineclearance, disaster relief and so on. The output of NPISH is not sold and so we have to value their output in the same way as for government. That is we add up the costs of producing their services – intermediate consumption, compensation of employees, consumption of fixed capital and other taxes on production. 6 Trade output is the margin. This measures the value of the service that the retailer or wholesaler adds to the value of the goods sold by storing them, keeping them in good condition, displaying them in an attractive fashion and providing advice to customers. Some examples of how we calculate gross output of trade: • A trader buys goods for resale for 50 and has sales of 75. Assuming there is no change in stocks of goods for resale, the gross output will be 75 minus 50 = 25. Twenty five is the margin on the goods sold. • A trader does not buy any goods for resale but sells 100 this year. Those sales must have come out of the stock purchased in an earlier year. In this case the increase in stocks for resale will be a minus figure - minus 60 for example. The gross output is then 100 + (minus 60) = 40. Forty is the margin on the goods bought for resale that were actually sold. • A trader buys goods for resale for 70 and over the year the stock of goods for resale increases by 10. If sales are 80, gross output equals 80 minus 70 plus 10 = 20. Twenty is the margin on the goods bought for resale that were actually sold. 7 Bank output is the value of services sold (usually quite small) plus the difference between the interest paid to depositors and the property income earned by banks (usually very big). The difference between interest and other property income received and interest paid to depositors is now called FISIM – financial intermediation services indirectly measured. In the older versions of the SNA it was called “Imputed Bank Service Charges” and was calculated in the same way as FISIM. FISIM is not new. It is just a new name. However, the 1993 SNA made an important change to the way in which FISIM is treated in the accounts. In the 1968 SNA all FISIM – or imputed bank service charges were treated as the intermediate consumption of an imaginary financial institution. The 1993 SNA went back to the original idea of the first(1952) SNA and said that FISIM should be treated as consumption of the unit that actually consumes it. The consuming units may consist of enterprises, government, NPISH, households and non-residents. The 1993 SNA suggests that the best way to allocate FISIM among consuming units is to use a “reference” rate of interest. This has proved difficult for many countries but the SNA also suggests that FISIM could be allocated according to the shares of each sector’s bank deposits, bank loans or the sum of deposits and loans. The 1993 SNA recognizes that even this may not be possible for some countries and in this case they may continue to follow the 1968 SNA and treat all FISIM as the intermediate consumption of a financial institution. Note that if FISIM is allocated to consuming units, that part which is not consumed by 8 Note that there are two kinds of life insurance. The commonest kind is where you invest a fixed amount each month in return for a pension in later life. The other kind is an accident insurance. The client makes a bet with the insurance company that he will die before a certain age – 60 years old for example. If he dies before that he wins and the insurance company pays out to his widow or other beneficiary. If he lives beyond 60 the client loses and the insurance company pays out nothing. This is often called “term insurance”. Here we are only talking about accident insurance. This includes term insurance but also, more important, insurance against road accidents, unemployment, ill health, death while abroad, and any of the other misadventures that may befall you. In the 1968 SNA the output of insurance was only the difference between premiums and claims. The SNA 1993 added “premium supplements” which are equal to the interest earned on the contingency funds which are held by insurance company and from which claims are paid. The reasoning behind “premium supplements” is that the contingency funds really belong to the customers and not to the insurance companies. It is as though the customers earn interest and other property income from investing those funds and then pay it to the insurance companies as an additional, or “supplementary”, premium. 9 If business registers are not kept up to date many enterprises will slip below the radar. The statistical office has no record of them and they are omitted from GDP. In other cases, businesses may hide what they are doing or only declare part of their income to avoid paying taxes. Whether they are hidden by accident or by design these activites are included in the production boundary . Most often hidden activites will involve thingts like: •Repair services (vehicles and household equipment). •Trade (street traders and small shops). •Selling food and drinks (especially on the street). •Personal services (haircutting and beauty salons). •Transport (taxis and minibuses) 10 An OECD/Eurostat/EFTA study in the Balkans showed that the hidden economy can be quite large. Special studies were made to fill the hidden gaps in the GDP for the countries in this slide. These ranged from about 5% in Montenegro to nearly 30% in Albania. A few years ago the European Union asked all member states to examine their GDP estimates to make sure that hidden, underground, informal activities were all properly covered. This resulted in quite large increases in GDP for several countries including an increase of 16% for Italy. In a later lesson we will examine the methods used by the European Union countries as they can also be used by countries in other regions. 11 People who earn their incomes illegally will spend most of it on goods and services that are quite legal. Since their consumption expenditure will therefore be correctly recorded along with the consumption expenditure of those who earn their livings legally, we need to cover their production as well. Otherwise GDP(P) will not equal GDP(E). Several countries have recently made attempts to estimate the value added of illegal activities such as production and trade in narcotics, prostitution and counterfeit manufactures like fake watches and DVDs. In most cases value added from illegal activities is not more than 1 or 2% of GDP. 12 The average for these ten countries is about 0.9% of GDP. The percentage is higher for Ukraine because it includes a lot of income from producing and selling counterfeit goods including DVD for films, music and computer software. Most countries have concluded that it is not really worth the effort. The estimates are all very weak and it is time consuming to make them. 13 Agriculture may account for 50% or more of GDP in many African countries. These are some of the data source for measuring output: • Most countries try to carry out an agricultural census once every five or ten years. • Some countries have annual surveys with “crop-cutting” to measure output of major crops like rice or maize. • “Farmers marketing boards” are another source of data in many countries. Marketing boards usually offer to buy all of a farmer’s output at a fixed price which is announced before the growing season. • Sometimes ministries of agriculture have extension workers who make forecasts for the major crops grown in their areas. • Household surveys carried out in rural areas may collect information on income from sales of crops and livestock. • Import and export statistics will show if crop output is more or less than enough to feed the population. 14 In most countries a relatively small number of large enterprises account for a large part of total out put. For example: • Companies running plantations (coffee, rubber, coca and tea), • Mining and timber extraction, • Coca cola and soft drinks producers, • Breweries, cold-storage, and food processing, • Electricity generation. These companies are generally covered by regular industry surveys and also publish annual accounts. Income tax record can also be a good data source in countries where legislation allows tax data to be shared with the statistical office. 15 Government budget documents and annual accounts are often detailed but do not always follow economic concepts. For example, they may combine compensation of employees with other current expenditures in a single line. In many countries the IMF provides training for finance ministry officials to help them provide data according to the IMF Government Finance Statistics rules. Talk to the Ministry of Finance. They may have reworked the government accounts into the right format for the national accounts. Foreign-funded NPISH are easy to identify and they can be included in regular surveys. They will also usually keep good accounting records. 16 Now we come to the difficult part. How do we estimate output of small enterprises which are not included in the business register but which may account for a large part of total output? Mostly they will be in trade, transport, catering, repair services and personal care services. Household labor force surveys are carried out in an increasing number of countries. They discover how many people are gainfully employed and what they are working at. These data can be compared with employment estimates from enterprise surveys to find out how many are working in the informal, hidden economy. The United Nations Statistical Office and Regional Commissions including the Economic Commission for Africa are helping countries to go one step further with “1-2 survey”. The labor force survey identifies households that are operating a small enterprise of some kind, and a second survey uses this list as a sample frame to collect data on output, sales, employment, and intermediate consumption. Several Franco-phone African countries have carried out these surveys. The World Bank’s Living Standards Measurement Study – LSMS - provide a great deal of information on sources of income, including earnings from small household enterprises. Area surveys are used to discover the numbers and types of enterprises operating in a given city block or rural area. If the city blocks and rural areas are randomly selected the total numbers of street traders, carpenters, plumbers, shoe-shiners, food sellers, etc. can be calculated. Follow-up surveys can then measure their output and incomes. But national accountants also need to use “innovative” methods. 17 It is certain that the regular statistical sources available to the national accountant will never cover all the economic activities known to be carried out in a country. Be bold in making estimates of the output of people you see each day earning a living from an “informal” activity of some kind. If people regularly selling apples on street corners and you do not try to estimate the total output of the apple-selling business, you are actually making an estimate for it. Your estimate of their output is zero. But that cannot be right. Almost any rough guess you make will be closer to the truth. These and other techniques for ensuring that GDP estimates are “exhaustive” – that is, they cover everything within the production boundary - are discussed in more detail in later lessons. 18 The SNA production boundary is wide. It covers hard-to-measure, «non-observed» activities as well as production by large-scale private and public producers. Regular data sources like enterprise and household surveys will provide much of the information you need, but there will always be gaps that have to be filled by innovative methods. Remember, if you know that an economic activity is taking place and you ignore it, you are actually making an estimate for it. Your estimate of its production and value added is ZERO. That must be wrong. Almost any etimate, however weak, will be better!