Download Corruption, growth and political regimes: Cross country evidence

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
European Journal of Political Economy
Vol. 22 (2006) 82 – 98
www.elsevier.com/locate/ejpe
Corruption, growth and political regimes: Cross
country evidence
Fabio Méndez a,*, Facundo Sepúlveda b
a
Department of Economics, Business Building Room 402, University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR, 72701, USA
Economics Program, RSSS, The Australian National University, Coombs Building # 9, Coombs Close, Acton,
ACT 2601, Australia
b
Received 8 September 2003; received in revised form 13 December 2004; accepted 15 April 2005
Available online 21 July 2005
Abstract
This paper studies the effects of corruption on long-run growth incorporating measures of
political freedom as a key determinant of the relationship. Unlike previous empirical studies, we find
evidence of a non-monotonic relationship between corruption and growth after controlling for
several other economic variables and restricting the sample to those countries considered to be free.
Our results indicate that the growth-maximizing level of corruption is significantly greater than zero,
with corruption beneficial for economic growth at low levels of incidence and detrimental at high
levels of incidence.
D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
JEL classification: D73; H10; 057
Keywords: Corruption; Growth; Political regimes
1. Introduction
The effects of bureaucratic corruption on economic growth have been a topic of debate
over the last 40 years. On the one side, there is a view, exemplified by Myrdal (1989) and
Shleifer and Vishny (1993), that corruption is detrimental for investment and economic
* Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 479 5756231; fax: +1 479 5753241.
E-mail address: [email protected] (F. Méndez).
0176-2680/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2005.04.005
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
83
growth. On the other side, Leff (1964), Lui (1985), and others have found it plausible for
corruption to be beneficial for economic growth at some levels. Up to this point, however,
the empirical evidence has supported the existence of a linear and negative correlation
between the level of corruption and the average rate of per-capita income growth (see
Mauro, 1995; Hall and Jones, 1999).1
Within this debate, a number of theoretical papers have shifted attention towards specific
elements that call into question the results of the typical empirical study. Elrich and Lui
(1999), for example, present a theoretical model in which the effects of corruption on growth
depend upon the political regime that oversees the economy. They consider two types of
political regimes: a bdemocraticQ one where bureaucrats compete over central power and an
bautocraticQ one in which a powerful and rational leadership is capable of imposing its will
on others. In their model, a relationship between corruption and growth is found in
democratic regimes only.
In a separate line of argument, other authors have suggested the possibility of a positive
output-maximizing level of corruption, thus challenging the notion of a linear relationship
between corruption and growth. Acemoglu and Verdier (1998) and Klitgaard (1988), for
example, use theoretical models to show that, if combating corruption is costly, then the level
of corruption that maximizes output might be greater than zero. Friedrich (1972), Nye (1989)
and Huntington (1968) have also suggested the existence of a positive growth-maximizing
level of corruption. Their argument, following Leff (1964) and Lui (1985), is that corruption
can be bbeneficialQ for growth at low levels of incidence by circumventing cumbersome
bureaucratic regulations.
The connection between the scope of government and the effects of corruption, however,
goes beyond the effects of bureaucracies. In particular, empirical studies by Tanzi and
Davoodi (1998), Mauro (1998) and Gupta et al. (2001) have shown that corruption alters the
composition of government expenditure towards less productive activities and, therefore,
that it is detrimental for growth.2 Thus, one cannot tell much about the impact of the
government sector on the relationship between corruption and growth before conducting
any empirical analysis.
This paper seeks to bridge the gap between the empirical evidence and the theoretical
literature by studying the type of nonlinearities discussed above. We focus on three
questions: First, do the effects of corruption on growth depend on the type of political regime
that rules the economy? Second, is there evidence of a positive growth-maximizing level of
corruption? And third, how are the effects of corruption on growth modified by the size of
the government?
In order to answer these questions, we follow Elrich and Lui (1999) and distinguish
between bfreeQ countries and bnot-freeQ countries according to the index of political rights
and civil liberties from Freedom House International. At the same time, we expand the
typical econometric specification by including a quadratic term for corruption that allows a
1
Egger and Winner (in press) however find empirical support for a positive relation between corruption and
foreign investment.
2
On corruption and public expenditures more generally, see Abed and Gupta (2002) and the review by Hillman
(2004).
84
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
test for a positive growth-maximizing level of corruption. We also include a measure of
government expenditures and study its interaction with corruption.
The results obtained show that the distinction made between free and not-free countries
is indeed important. In political regimes labeled bnot-freeQ, corruption does not affect
economic growth in the same fashion as in free countries. After controlling for several
other economic variables, we find evidence of a non-monotonic relationship between
corruption and growth for free countries only. This relationship is not significantly
modified by the size of the government.
These results are compatible with the findings of previous econometric studies that
estimate a linear model. The econometric specification used here, however, improves upon
the simple linear specification by increasing both the statistical fit and the robustness of
the model. Furthermore, the endogeneity problem that has usually been present in
previous cross-sectional studies is addressed by using a fixed-effects regression over 5year periods.
The following section provides a detailed description of the data. Section 3 discusses
the econometric work and the results obtained, and the last section of the paper elaborates
on the conclusions and the possibilities for additional research.
2. Description of the data
The empirical analysis uses data from a large sample of countries during the period
1960–2000. Values of annual population growth (POP), real income per capita (GDP),
annual GDP growth, secondary school enrollment rates (SED), the investment share of
GDP (Investment) and the share of government expenditures in GDP (Government) were
extracted from World Bank’s World Development indicators (2004).
In turn, data regarding the level of corruption was taken from three alternative
measures: the ICRG index, the IMD index and the CPI index. The ICRG index of
corruption comes from Political Risk Services Inc., a private firm that annually publishes
the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG). The ICRG contains a corruption index,
which is intended to assess the degree of corruption prevailing in a certain country and is
based on a survey among foreign investors.
The raw data of the corruption index in the ICRG ranges from 0 (most corrupt) to 6 (least
corrupt). In this paper, however, this index has been rescaled to range from 0 (most corrupt)
to 10 (least corrupt) in order to allow for an easier comparison with the other indices used.
The ICRG reports corruption for up to 130 countries between 1982 and 2001.
The IMD index of corruption is published by the Institute for Management
Development (IMD) in the World Competitiveness Yearbook and is based on a survey
among local managers in up to 50 countries. The index is based on a scale from 0 to 10
with lower values indicating that bimproper practices such as bribing and corruption
exist in public sphereQ (Herzfeld and Weiss, 2003). The index has been published since
1990.
The Corruption Perceptions index of corruption (CPI) is compiled by Transparency
International. This index is scaled from 0 (almost corrupt) to 10 (almost clean). The CPI
represents a bpoll of pollsQ and is compiled from up to 11 different surveys to businessmen,
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
85
Table 1
General descriptive statistics
ICRG
IMD
CPI
GDP growth
POP
SED
Investment
Government
Instability
Mean
Std. Dev
Max
5.43
4.91
4.25
1.6
1.98
56.7
22.31
16.88117
.8934012
2.02
2.57
2.21
3.08
1.18
32.1
7.15
6.468877
.6320366
10
9.34
9.69
6.6
8.44
100
59.5
43.09
2.43
Min
1.49
1.32
1.29
6.08
0.36
4.6
8.54
5.97
0
country experts, and local populations. The index reports perceived corruption for up to
100 countries within the period 1996–2003.
Since these corruption indexes are not available before 1980, for all of the crosssectional regressions we had to make the choice of using the average of these indexes for
the periods they are available as an approximation for the corruption level present during
the entire period (1960–2000). We believe that this is a reasonable assumption.
In order to classify countries as bfreeQ or bnot-freeQ we use the index of freedom from
Freedom House International. Since 1970 they have surveyed several countries, recorded
the state of several elements considered to be essential for freedom, and transformed these
elements into an index. This index is divided into two sub-indices: one of political rights
and another of civil liberties. Each sub-index ranges from 1 to 7, where a lower number
indicates a higher degree of freedom. To give an idea of what those numbers represent,
their report states that bas one moves down the scale below the category of 2, the level of
oppression increases, especially in the areas of censorship, political terror and prevention
of free associationQ.
Freedom House classifies countries as bfreeQ if the sub-indices do not add more than
five, as bpartly freeQ if they add up between five and ten, and as bnot-freeQ if they add up to
11 or more. For the purposes of this study, countries will be categorized as free if the total
index is less than 7.5; however, the results remain mostly unaltered if a value in the range
of 5–9 is used to separate the categories.
The political rights sub-index was also used to create a variable intended to
approximate the degree of political instability within a country (Instability); this variable
was constructed by taking the standard deviation of the political rights index for the period
in question. Although this might not be a perfect measure of political instability, one would
Table 2
Correlation matrix of corruption indexes
IMD
CPI
ICRG
IMD
CPI
ICRG
1
0.9638
0.8239
1
0.9125
1
86
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
certainly expect that the countries that have a more volatile score in political rights are the
ones that are less stable.
Other studies such as Alesina et al. (1996) have used the probability of the opposition
taking over, or the number of changes in power over a certain period in time, as a measure
of political instability. These measures may not be adequate for the case of free countries
since free countries are likely to be governed by democracies and stable democracies in
turn are likely to have frequent changes in power. The alternative proposed here does not
suffer from this inconvenience.3
Appendix A shows the source and the definition of all data variables used in this study.
Additionally, Tables 1 and 2 offer a summary of descriptive statistics for these variables.
Table 2, in specific, shows the correlation matrix for the country averages of the alternative
corruption indices. As shown there, all measures of corruption are highly correlated with
each other.
3. Empirical analysis and results
The typical empirical studies of corruption and growth, like Mauro (1995), Knack and
Keefer (1995), Li et al. (2000) and Rock and Bonnett (2004), generate cross-sectional
regressions for which the average rate of economic growth is the dependent variable and a
standard list of regressors are used as independent variables. This standard list includes the
initial level of income per-capita in 1960, the rate of population growth, the secondary
school enrollment ratio, and in some cases the ratio of investment to GDP. The investment
ratio is often excluded from the estimations as some authors consider it to be a likely
source of endogeneity.
We shall use this typical econometric framework (to which we will refer as brestrictedQ
from now on) as the base of our econometric estimations; but as a robustness check in
some regressions we also include additional variables that are frequently found in growth
accounting exercises. These additional variables include a measure of government
consumption, our measure of political instability, and three dummy variables that identify
Latin-American, African and Scandinavian countries.
Table 3 presents the results obtained in the OLS estimation of the restricted model.
Columns (1)–(3) show the results of the estimations for which the ICRG index is used to
measure corruption; whereas columns (4)–(6) and (7)–(9) show the results of the
estimations for which corruption is measured by the IMD and the CPI indexes,
respectively. As shown in Table 3, the results of the estimation do not seem to depend
on the corruption index chosen.
Besides using alternative corruption indexes, the only difference across columns in
Table 3 is the number of explanatory variables. For the simpler specifications (columns
(1), (4) and (7)), the coefficient on corruption is found to be significantly different from
3
As a robustness check, two other alternative measures of political instability were used: the annual turnover of
government’s key decision makers (taken from the database of political institutions described in Beck et al., 2001)
and the political instability indicator from the World Bank’s governance data (Kaufmann et al., 2003). All results
in the paper remained unaltered when these measures were used.
Table 3
Dependent variable: per capita GDP growth (1960–2000)
Corruption
POP
SED
GDP (1960)
IMD
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
0.002
(2.06)
0.0007
(0.28)
0.0003
(3.79)
2.0E 6
( 3.67)
0.0016
(1.59)
0.0007
( 0.34)
0.0001
(1.50)
1.2E 6
( 2.57)
0.002
(6.36)
0.003
(2.6)
0.01
( 2.85)
0.0002
( 1.61)
1.7E 6
( 3.47)
0.0016
(1.71)
0.007
( 2.60)
0.0001
( 1.23)
1.2E 6
( 3.18)
0.002
(5.10)
0.003
(3.50)
0.0019
( 0.86)
0.00001
( 0.12)
1.7E 6
( 3.73)
0.002
(6.25)
0.034
( 3.58)
84
0.53
0.058
(4.07)
40
0.24
0.0006
( 0.04)
40
0.55
0.0013
(1.35)
0.007
( 2.46)
0.0002
( 1.67)
1.5E 6
( 3.67)
0.0018
(3.75)
0.0001
(0.36)
0.0039
( 1.27)
0.009
( 1.75)
0.004
( 0.65)
0.003
( 0.73)
0.017
(1.0)
40
0.61
0.004
(3.62)
0.0005
(0.20)
0.0002
(1.85)
2.0E 6
( 4.25)
0.011
( 1.06)
85
0.31
0.0018
(1.88)
0.0007
(0.30)
0.0007
(0.8)
1.4E 6
( 2.88)
0.0017
(5.54)
0.00006
(0.17)
0.002
( 0.72)
0.008
( 1.94)
0.013
( 3.19)
0.003
( 0.57)
0.022
( 2.06)
84
0.57
0.005
( 0.57)
77
0.34
0.028
( 3.30)
77
0.57
0.003
(3.29)
0.0002
( 0.09)
0.00002
( 0.21)
1.7E 6
( 3.65)
0.0017
(5.07)
0.00004
( 0.12)
0.0009
( 0.36)
0.0071
( 1.76)
0.01
( 2.65)
0.005
( 0.84)
0.018
( 1.83)
77
0.59
Investment
Government
Instability
LA
AF
SC
Constant
N
Adjusted R 2
CPI
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
ICRG
T-statistics are in parentheses.
87
88
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
zero and the estimated coefficient ranges from 0.002 to 0.004. These results coincide very
closely with the other empirical studies that use this restricted specification. Mauro (1995),
for example, estimated the corruption coefficient to be 0.002.
As the list of explanatory variables expands, the magnitude of the coefficient on
corruption remains roughly the same but, in some cases, the coefficient of corruption
becomes statistically insignificant. Other authors including Mauro (1995), Keefer and
Knack (1997), and Li et al. (2000), have also reported similar concerns regarding the
robustness of their results. In their case, the coefficient on corruption becomes
insignificant after controlling for other important determinants of growth.
It is immediately apparent, however, that the statistical model of Table 3 is not ideal to
test the hypotheses that the effects of corruption on growth are non-linear or that they
depend on the degree of political freedom. Thus, in order to address these questions we
separate the sample between free and not-free countries and we estimate an alternative
bunrestrictedQ model that includes a quadratic term for corruption. Tables 4 and 5 show the
results of the estimation of the unrestricted model for the free and not-free subsamples
respectively. The results of using all three of the alternative corruption indexes are
presented in both tables.
As shown in Table 4, in the case of free countries the results of the estimations suggest
the existence of a positive growth-maximizing level of corruption. For these countries,
the coefficients on corruption and corruption squared are always significant at the 1%
level and the coefficient estimates are robust to the inclusion of all other independent
variables. Moreover, these results do not vary as the specific corruption index used
changes.
The growth maximizing level of corruption implied by the estimations can be easily
calculated. Using the ICRG index, this level is found to be 8.6, 7.2, and 8 for columns (1)–
(3) respectively. Using the IMD index, the level is found to be 6.8, 7.2 and 6.2 for columns
(4)–(6) respectively. And finally, using the CPI index, the level is found to be 8.1, 8.1, and
7.1 for columns (7)–(9), respectively.
Given that a higher corruption index denotes a lower incidence of corruption and that
all indexes vary from 0 to 10, these results imply that economic growth reaches its
maximum level for small but positive amounts of corruption. Noticeably, the estimated
growth-maximizing level of corruption is well beyond the minimum levels of corruption in
our sample. Countries with corruption levels lower than these estimated growthmaximizing levels (for all three indexes) include: Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark,
Finland, Germany, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Luxemburg, Netherlands, New Zealand,
Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, UK and USA.
The results presented in Table 4 contrast with those in Table 5, in which the not-free
countries subsample is studied. Columns (1)–(3) in Table 5 show the results of the
estimations for which the ICRG index is used to measure corruption; whereas columns
(4)–(5) and (6)–(8) show the results of the estimations for which the IMD and the CPI
indexes were used, respectively. For the case of the IMD index, the regressions could not
be estimated when the sample size fell below 10 countries.
As shown in Table 5, the results of the estimations do not allow us to establish any
significant correlation between corruption and economic growth for the subsample of notfree countries. The size of the estimated coefficients of corruption and corruption squared,
Table 4
Dependent variable: per capita GDP growth (1960–2000)
Free countries
Corruption
Corruption2
POP
SED
GDP (1960)
IMD
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
0.019
(3.22)
0.0011
( 2.61)
0.0009
( 0.30)
0.0001
(0.97)
1.1E 6
( 2.18)
0.016
(3.27)
0.0011
( 2.83)
0.0005
(0.23)
0.0001
(0.98)
7.8E 6
( 1.70)
0.0017
(3.93)
0.016
(3.41)
0.0010
( 2.80)
0.0012
( 0.53)
0.0001
(0.23)
8.5E 6
( 2.06)
0.006
(1.43)
0.0003
( 1.08)
0.0003
(0.11)
0.011
( 2.57)
0.032
(3.35)
0.0038
(0.70)
0.036
( 1.66)
45
0.64
0.015
(4.44)
0.0011
( 4.01)
0.008
( 3.00)
0.0002
( 2.23)
1.3E 6
( 4.04)
0.013
(4.40)
0.0009
( 4.00)
0.007
( 2.96)
0.0002
( 2.35)
1.2E 6
( 4.33)
0.0011
(3.02)
0.015
(3.83)
0.0012
( 3.69)
0.005
( 1.99)
0.0002
( 2.60)
1.2E 6
( 4.18)
0.0009
(2.17)
0.0001
( 0.51)
0.002
( 0.70)
0.007
( 1.95)
.
0.018
(4.11)
0.0011
( 3.21)
0.0012
( 0.42)
0.0001
( 0.87)
1.2E 6
( 2.53)
0.013
(3.60)
0.0008
( 2.91)
0.0014
( 0.57)
0.0001
( 1.06)
1.0E 6
( 2.59)
0.0017
(4.30)
0.018
( 1.16)
43
0.38
0.043
( 3.05)
43
0.58
0.012
(2.89)
0.0008
( 2.46)
0.0011
( 0.44)
0.00009
( 0.93)
7.5E 6
( 1.90)
0.0009
(2.09)
0.0001
( 0.62)
0.002
(0.79)
0.009
( 2.17)
0.024
(2.56)
0.003
(0.73)
0.020
( 1.19)
43
0.65
Investment
Government
Instability
LA
AF
SC
Constant
N
Adjusted R 2
CPI
(1)
0.044
( 1.97)
45
0.31
0.07
( 3.62)
45
0.50
0.029
(2.44)
30
0.56
0.029
(2.44)
30
0.67
0.008
(1.72)
0.011
(0.8)
30
0.70
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
ICRG
T-statistics are in parentheses.
89
90
Not-free countries
ICRG
Corruption
Corruption2
POP
SED
GDP (1960)
IMD
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(7)
(8)
(9)
0.012
(1.44)
0.0011
( 1.29)
0.0007
( 0.14)
0.0007
(3.84)
7.0E 6
( 1.13)
0.010
(1.46)
0.0010
( 1.30)
0.002
( 0.61)
0.0003
(1.71)
7.4E 6
( 1.40)
0.002
(3.98)
0.028
( 1.91)
0.0033
(2.42)
0.0035
(0.41)
0.0010
(1.77)
2.3E 4
( 2.64)
0.003
( 0.18)
0.0007
(0.41)
0.0004
(0.06)
0.0006
(1.21)
1.9E 4
( 2.36)
0.002
(1.87)
0.002
( 0.42)
0.0012
(2.13)
0.0011
(0.30)
0.0007
(4.69)
2.0E 4
( 4.72)
0.0030
(0.52)
0.0005
(0.91)
0.0006
( 0.18)
0.0004
(2.14)
2.0E 4
( 4.02)
0.0013
(2.49)
0.032
( 1.54)
40
0.38
0.04
( 2.59)
39
0.55
0.018
(2.89)
0.0018
( 2.73)
0.0018
( 0.38)
0.0002
(1.17)
1.3E 7
(0.03)
0.0011
(2.35)
0.00018
(0.25)
0.004
( 1.04)
0.018
( 2.39)
0.023
( 4.25)
0.03
( 1.71)
39
0.70
0.037
( 0.98)
10
0.43
0.05
( 0.93)
10
0.65
0.003
( 0.26)
37
0.56
0.025
( 1.55)
34
0.68
0.009
(1.54)
0.0001
( 0.21)
0.0037
(0.79)
0.0004
(2.25)
2.0E 4
( 3.36)
0.0010
(1.98)
0.0010
( 1.34)
0.005
( 1.22)
0.004
( 0.67)
0.010
( 1.82)
0.018
( 0.95)
34
0.74
Investment
Government
Instability
LA
AF
Constant
N
Adjusted R 2
CPI
(1)
T-statistics are in parentheses.
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
Table 5
Dependent variable: per capita GDP growth (1960–2000)
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
91
the sign of these coefficients, and the t-statistic values associated with them are all very
sensitive to the number of explanatory variables in the regression and to the specific
corruption index used.
In contrast to the results obtained for the free countries subsample, any relation between
corruption and growth that is found in Table 5 can be shown to vary with small changes to the
econometric specification and the coefficients of corruption are often not significantly
different than zero. Without freedom, the effects of corruption do not work in the same way
as they do with freedom. We return to study this issue in the next sub-section, where we
conduct fixed-effects regressions.
3.1. Addressing endogeneity
The results presented in the previous section are susceptible to two major criticisms. First,
it is possible that corruption and growth respond simultaneously to an omitted factor. Such
factor could be a cultural disposition towards leisure or morality, the legal framework, the
historical evolution of the nation in question, etc. Second, one may think that the incidence of
corruption is directly affected by the rate of economic growth; as for example, it could be the
case that rich, fast-growing countries have more resources to combat and control corruption.
In either case, corruption would be correlated with the error term in the OLS regression and
the estimates would be biased.
Past studies have used instrumental variable techniques in an attempt to correct this
potential bias. The main instrument in the literature has been the Ethno linguistic
Fractionalization (ELF) index. This variable, however, has been shown to be directly (and
indirectly) correlated with economic growth (Easterly and Levine, 1997) and thus, it
cannot be considered as a valid instrument in our regressions.
Alternatively, in this study we attempt to control for endogeneity by conducting a fixedeffects regression where the variables are averaged over three 5-year periods: 1984–1989,
1990–1995 and 1996–2000. The use of 5-year averages reduces short run fluctuations and
allows us to concentrate on the relationships of interest for this study.4
A fixed-effects regression will effectively control for endogeneity due to time invariant
effects, such as the state and quality of socio-political institutions; but it will not address
endogeneity due to the possible interactions between higher growth rates and greater
resources to combat corruption, or other time varying effects. Levin and Satarov (2000) and
Paldam (2002) have presented evidence for the existence of both types of endogeneities.
Unfortunately, only the ICRG index of corruption can be used for this exercise, as it is the
only one with data covering all these years. The ICRG index, however, has been shown to be
highly correlated with the other two indexes, and, in light of the previous results in this study,
we would not expect the results to be sensitive to changes in the corruption index used (at
least for the case of free countries).
Table 6 shows the results of these fixed-effects regressions for the case of free
countries. The econometric specifications of columns (1)–(3) include both a linear and a
4
Many other authors have also worked with 5-year averages for similar purposes. See, for example, Deininger
and Squire (1996), Li et al. (2000), and Paldam (2002).
92
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
Table 6
Dependent variable: per capita GDP growth
Fixed-effects regressions—free countries
Corruption
Corruption2
POP
SED
Initial GDP
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.010
(2.06)
0.0010
( 2.33)
0.009
(1.43)
0.0002
(1.31)
2.8E 6
( 3.06)
0.014
(2.54)
0.0012
( 2.80)
0.008
(1.48)
0.0002
(1.67)
2.6E 6
( 3.24)
0.002
(3.81)
0.013
(2.45)
0.0011
( 2.54)
0.006
(1.23)
0.0003
(1.96)
2.5E 6
( 3.15)
0.0018
(2.89)
0.0027
( 3.31)
0.003
(0.70)
0.0005
( 0.32)
0.0006
( 0.33)
0.0002
(0.14)
0.007
(1.22)
0.0002
(1.56)
2.2E 6
( 2.45)
0.006
(1.14)
0.0003
(1.84)
1.9E 6
( 2.40)
0.002
(4.30)
0.005
(0.92)
0.0003
(2.09)
1.8E 6
( 2.42)
0.002
(3.29)
0.003
( 3.62)
0.003
(0.70)
Investment
Government
Instability
T-statistics are in parentheses.
quadratic term of corruption; while columns (4)–(6) mimic the restricted specification and
do not include the quadratic term. Besides this difference, only the number of explanatory
variables changes from one column to the next.
The results confirm the previous findings regarding the existence of a positive growthmaximizing level of corruption for free countries. As shown in columns (1) to (3) of Table
6, the estimated coefficients of corruption and corruption squared are roughly the same as
those estimated before and shown in Table 4. These coefficients are always significant at
the 1% level and they remain unaltered as the list of explanatory variables expands to
include our measures of investment, government consumption and political instability.
Interestingly, the estimated growth maximizing level of corruption now becomes lower. It
amounts to 5, 5.8 and 5.9 in columns (1) to (3), respectively.
In columns (4) to (6) of Table 6, where the restricted specification was used and the
linear term of corruption was tested alone, the estimated coefficient of corruption was
never significantly different than zero. The coefficients for all other variables, however,
are not affected by the change in the econometric specification.
The regressions shown in Table 6 are reproduced in Table 7 for the not-free
subsample of countries. As before, the results of the estimations do not allow us to
establish a stable or significant correlation between corruption and economic growth. In
column (1), for example, the results show a non-monotonic relationship between
corruption and growth, but as the number of explanatory variables increases, such a
conclusion is no longer supported. In some cases, like those of Columns (2), (3) and (5),
the results suggest a positive correlation between corruption and growth, and in other
cases like columns (4) and (6), the coefficient of corruption was found to be statistically
no different than zero (but with different signs).
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
93
Table 7
Dependent variable: per capita GDP growth
Fixed-effects regressions—not-free countries
Corruption
Corruption2
POP
SED
Initial GDP
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.045
(3.47)
0.005
( 3.46)
0.001
(0.13)
9.1E 5
( 0.16)
1.1E 5
( 2.66)
0.007
(1.17)
0.0013
( 1.81)
0.0011
( 2.69)
0.0003
( 1.24)
6.5E 6
( 2.81)
0.002
(5.44)
0.011
(1.60)
0.0014
( 1.91)
0.008
( 2.04)
0.0003
( 1.27)
6.1E 6
( 2.91)
0.002
(4.95)
0.002
( 3.40)
0.012
( 3.37)
0.002
(0.57)
0.003
( 1.76)
0.0016
( 0.86)
0.0017
( 0.20)
4.3E 5
( 0.07)
7.4E 6
( 1.68)
0.012
( 2.91)
0.0003
( 1.15)
5.1E 6
( 2.32)
0.002
(5.44)
0.008
( 2.01)
0.0003
( 1.18)
4.7E 6
( 2.35)
0.002
(5.00)
0.003
( 3.80)
0.0011
( 3.09)
Investment
Government
Instability
T-statistics are in parentheses.
Thus, by studying Tables 4 5 6 and 7, our analysis suggests that the distinction made
between free and not-free countries is in fact pertinent; that the links between corruption
and growth are different in free countries than what they are in not-free countries.
We may only speculate about the specific mechanisms that produce this result, as there
are several plausible explanations: 1. In a controlled economy, corruption receipts and
economic activities are both endogenous decisions of the policy maker and, thus, they do
not necessarily affect one another. 2. In a controlled economy the difference between
corrupt and legal acts is blurred and the quality of the corruption indexes available might
suffer in these cases. 3. The private agent’s incentive to bribe might be smaller in
controlled economies where returns to private capital are reduced, thus minimizing the link
between corruption and private investment. 4. The ratio of fund-grabbing corruption vs.
speed-money corruption is likely to be higher in less democratic economies and, therefore,
more likely to go unnoticed in the data.
In what follows, we continue our study of the relation between corruption and growth,
but we concentrate our analysis in the case of free countries only.
3.2. The role of the government
So far, in the case of free countries we have shown evidence supporting the existence of
a quadratic relationship between corruption and growth. Thus, holding everything else
constant, the rate of growth of an economy is greatest when there is a low but positive
level of corruption.
At least two potential explanations exist for these findings: On the one hand, as proposed
by Huntington (1968) and De Soto (1989), it is possible that corruption promotes investment
94
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
Table 8
Dependent variable: per capita GDP growth
The role of government
Corruption
Corruption2
Gov * corruption
POP
SED
Initial GDP
Investment
Government
Instability
(1)
(2)
0.012
(2.18)
0.0012
( 2.52)
0.0001
(0.56)
0.006
(1.12)
0.0003
(2.00)
2.5E 6
( 3.15)
0.0018
(2.92)
0.0034
( 2.23)
0.002
(0.60)
0.002
(0.58)
0.0001
( 0.58)
0.005
(1.01)
0.0003
(1.99)
1.9E 6
( 2.47)
0.002
(3.10)
0.002
( 1.51)
0.002
(0.47)
T-statistics are in parentheses.
that is otherwise hindered by government procedures, bureaucratic red tape, and other
regulations. On the other hand, as pointed out by Klitgaard (1988) and Acemoglu and
Verdier (1998), it is possible that the resources necessary to combat bureaucratic corruption
become greater as the level of corruption decreases and thus, that a small but positive level of
corruption is optimal for the economy.5
Which one of these explanations is more accurate is a question of importance, as they
both have different implications regarding the role of the government sector: in the first case,
the greater the scope of the government, the greater the optimal amount of corruption. In the
second case, the amount of the government expenses can have both positive and negative
effects on the marginal cost of combating corruption and it would be difficult to say a priori
which one of those effects dominates the other.6
In order to study the role of the government, an interaction term between corruption and
the share of government expenditure was included as an explanatory variable and the fixed
effects estimations were recalculated. Table 8 shows the results. Column (1) uses the
unrestricted specification while column (2) studies the role of the government within the
restricted model where corruption enters the equation linearly.
5
In an alternative theoretical formulation of corruption and crime, Liew (1992) finds that at high levels of
corruption only a massive injection of resources can reduce corruption, whereas for low levels of corruption any
increase in resources will reduce it.
6
An increase in public sector wages, for example, is likely to make it easier for governments to combat
corruption. An increase in public sector military expenses, in contrast, is more likely to make it harder (see Tanzi
and Davoodi, 1998).
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
95
Authors such as Mauro (1995, 1998) and Tanzi and Davoodi (1998), who have reported a
linear and negative correlation between corruption and growth, have also claimed that this
result is partly due to the interaction between corruption and government expenses. As they
explain, corruption alters the composition of government expenses towards less productive
activities, and thus, the greater the government expenses are, the greater the negative effects
of corruption are as well. Thus, a linear model of corruption is better suited to study these
arguments.
The results shown in Table 8 regarding the role of the government are similar for both
specifications.7 In both columns, the estimated coefficient for the interaction term is
statistically insignificant. In column (1) the coefficient of the government expenses is
negative and significant at the 1% level. In column (2) the coefficient of the government
expenses is also negative but insignificant. Thus, although the level of government
expenses seems to have a negative effect on growth, it does not alter the growth
maximizing level of corruption.
These results are not sufficient to support either one of the arguments made by authors
like Huntington (1968) or Mauro (1998). In one argument, bigger governments will make
corruption more productive or beneficial as bigger governments provide additional
bureaucratic constraints. In the other argument, bigger governments make corruption more
detrimental as corruption reduces the allocation efficiency of the spending. In either case,
there is a direct link between the size of the government and the effects of corruption on
growth. We do not find such a direct link.
In contrast, the results in Table 8 are supportive of the ideas put forward by Acemoglu and
Verdier (1998) and Klitgaard (1988). In their works, it is the marginal cost of combating
corruption and not the size of the government sector that directly determines the growthmaximizing level of corruption. The question regarding the links between the costs of
combating corruption and the amount of government expenses, however, goes beyond the
scope of this paper and is left for future research.
In sum, a definitive judgment about the exact role of the government cannot be made in
this study. Direct measures of the cost of combating corruption, of the cost that bureaucratic
regulations impose on investment and of the misallocation of government expenses due to
corruption would be needed to explore this issue further.
4. Conclusions and future research
The empirical evidence reported here supports the claim that the type of political regime
is an important determinant of the relation between corruption and economic growth. For the
case of free countries we find evidence of a non-linear relationship between corruption and
income growth. This relationship is not modified by the size of government expenditures.
In these countries, controlling for all other characteristics, the level of corruption that
maximizes the rate of growth is greater than zero. This finding remains unchanged under
7
When the interaction term of government and corruption is included at the same time than corruption and
corruption squared, some collinearity is created. The correlation coefficient between either corruption or
corruption squared and the interaction term falls below 0.45.
96
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
several specifications that include a variety of independent variables and fixed-effects
regressions.
The empirical literature that noticed a linear relationship between corruption and growth
failed to differentiate between free and not-free countries. Once this differentiation is made
the alternative specification proposed in this study is preferred to the traditional one in terms
of robustness and goodness of fit. Thus, the incorporation of the Freedom Index proves to
be a key element in the analysis and may be an important avenue of future research.
The fact that the effects of corruption are not independent of other political and
institutional elements is important by itself as it suggests that corruption might not be an
inherent evil of developing economies but the consequence of other government policies, or
socio-political circumstances; and thus, that public policies designed to eliminate corruption
alone might not be optimal for growth.
Conducting more empirical analysis to further clarify the role of government in a corrupt
economy would require a more detailed data set. In this respect, the world development
indicators have included since 2002 two variables that attempt to measure the costs of slow
bureaucracies directly. These variables include the number of days it takes to establish a legal
business, as well as the actual costs. Future studies could benefit from this data.
Acknowledgements
We wish to thank Rowena Pecchenino, Gerhard Glomm, Jeffrey Wooldridge and two
anonymous referees of this journal for their comments. We also thank Thomas Herzfeld
and Jungmin Lee for their assistance. All errors are ours.
Appendix A. Variable definitions
GDP growth Annual growth rate of GDP per-capita. World Development Indicators
(2004)
ICRG International country risk guide corruption index. Political Risk Services Inc.
IMD
Institute for management development corruption index. World Competitiveness
Yearbook
CPI
Corruption perceptions index of corruption. Transparency International.
POP
Average annual population growth. World Development Indicators (2004)
SED
Gross enrollment rate in secondary schooling. World Development Indicators
(2004)
GDP Yearly gross domestic product per-capita, constant 1995 USA dollars. World
Development Indicators (2004)
Investment Yearly gross fixed capital formation (% of GDP). World Development
Indicators (2004)
Government General government final consumption expenditures (% of GDP). World
Development Indicators (2004)
Instability Standard deviation of the political rights sub-index provided by Freedom House
International
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
LA
AF
SC
97
Dummy variable taking the value of 1 for Latin American countries and 0 otherwise
Dummy variable taking the value of 1 for African countries and 0 otherwise
Dummy variable taking the value of 1 for Scandinavian countries and 0 otherwise
References
Abed, G.T., Gupta, S., 2002. Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance. International Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
Acemoglu, D., Verdier, T., 1998. Property rights, corruption and the allocation of talent: a general equilibrium
approach. Economic Journal 108, 1381 – 1403.
Alesina, A., Roubini, N., Ozler, S., Swagel, P., 1996. Political instability and economic growth. Journal of
Economic Growth 1, 189 – 212.
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., Walsh, P., 2001. New tools in comparative political economy: the
database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review 15, 165 – 176.
Deininger, K., Squire, L., 1996. A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank Economic Review 10,
565 – 591.
De Soto, H., 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. Harper and Row, New York.
Easterly, W., Levine, R., 1997. Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 111, 1203 – 1250.
Egger, P., Winner, H., in press. Evidence on corruption as an incentive for foreign direct investment. European
Journal of Political Economy.
Elrich, I., Lui, F., 1999. Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Political Economy
107, s270 – s293.
Friedrich, C.J., 1972. The Pathology of Politics, Violence, Betrayal, Corruption, Secrecy and Propaganda. Harper
and Row, New York.
Gupta, S., de Mello, L., Sharan, R., 2001. Corruption and military spending. European Journal of Political
Economy 17, 749 – 777;
(Reprinted in). Abed, G.T., Gupta, S. (Eds.), 2002. Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance.
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, pp. 300 – 332.
Hall, R.E., Jones, C., 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 83 – 116.
Herzfeld, T., Weiss, C., 2003. Corruption and legal (in)effectiveness: an empirical investigation. European Journal
of Political Economy 19, 621 – 632.
Hillman, A.L., 2004. Corruption and public finance: an IMF perspective. European Journal of Political Economy
20, 1067 – 1077.
Huntington, S.P., 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M., 2003. Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996–2002.
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, vol. 3106. World Bank, Washington DC.
Keefer, P., Knack, S., 1997. Why don’t poor countries catch up? A cross-national test of an institutional
explanation. Economic Inquiry 35, 590 – 602.
Klitgaard, R., 1988. Controlling Corruption. University of California Press, Berkeley.
Knack, S., Keefer, P., 1995. Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative
institutional measures. Economics and Politics 3, 207 – 227.
Leff, N.H., 1964. Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. American Behavioural Scientist 8,
8 – 14.
Levin, M., Satarov, G.A., 2000. Corruption and institutions in Russia. European Journal of Political Economy 16,
113 – 132.
Li, H., Xu, C.L., Zou, H., 2000. Corruption, income distribution and growth. Economics and Politics 12, 155 – 182.
Liew, L.H., 1992. Corruption as a form of insurance. European Journal of Political Economy 8, 427 – 443.
Lui, F.T., 1985. An equilibrium queuing model of bribery. Journal of Political Economy 93, 760 – 781.
98
F. Méndez, F. Sepúlveda / European Journal of Political Economy 22 (2006) 82–98
Mauro, P., 1995. Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 681 – 712.
Mauro, P., 1998. Corruption and the composition of government expenditure. Journal of Public Economics 69,
263 – 279;
(Reprinted in). Abed, G.T., Gupta, S. (Eds.), 2002. Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance.
International Monetary Fund, Washington DC, pp. 225 – 244.
Myrdal, G., 1989. Corruption: its causes and effects. Political Corruption: A Handbook. Transaction Books, New
Brunswick N.J., pp. 953 – 961.
Nye, J.S., 1989. Corruption and political development: a cost–benefit analysis. Political Corruption: A Handbook.
Transaction Books, New Brunswick N.J., pp. 963 – 984.
Paldam, M., 2002. The cross-country pattern of corruption: economics, culture and the seesaw dynamics.
European Journal of Political Economy 18, 215 – 240.
Rock, M.T., Bonnett, H., 2004. The comparative politics of corruption: accounting for the east Asian paradox in
empirical studies of corruption, growth and investment. World Development 32, 999 – 1017.
Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1993. Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 599 – 617.
Tanzi, V., Davoodi, H., 1998. Corruption, Public Investment and Growth. In: Shibata, H., Ihiro, T. (Eds.), The
Welfare State, Public Investment and Growth. Springer-Verlag, Tokyo, pp. 41 – 60;
(Reprinted in). Abed, G.T., Gupta, S. (Eds.), 2002. Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance.
International Monetary Fund, Washington DC, pp. 280 – 299.