* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download 4. Aggregate Demand Policy Under Alternative Supply Assumptions
Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup
Economic bubble wikipedia , lookup
Real bills doctrine wikipedia , lookup
Full employment wikipedia , lookup
Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup
2000s commodities boom wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Long Depression wikipedia , lookup
Phillips curve wikipedia , lookup
Money supply wikipedia , lookup
Business cycle wikipedia , lookup
AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND 5 1 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND FOCUS OF THE CHAPTER • In this chapter we begin to study how output varies over the short and long run, when potential output is fixed. • We develop the aggregate supply/demand model, in the short and long run, to show how the supply and demand sides of the economy interact to uniquely determine output and the price level. SECTION SUMMARIES 1. The Aggregate Supply Curve The aggregate supply (AS) curve describes the amount of output that firms are willing to supply at different price levels. The fact that there is a relationship between output and the price level should be somewhat disturbingif everyone is perfectly informed and all markets clear (so that supply equals demand in each of them), output should be fixed at the level of potential output whatever the price level. In the long run, when markets clear and all inputs are fully employed, output is fixed at the level of potential output, and the AS curve is vertical. We call this the classical case. If we characterize the short run as a period over which prices cannot adjust, the short-run AS curve must be horizontal. (We call this a Keynesian aggregate supply curve.) The assumption that prices are fixed (and therefore that the AS curve is horizontal) in the short run works well when output is below potential output. It does not work, however, when output is above potential output. In this case resources are over employed. Workers must be paid a 2 CHAPTER 5 higher wage to entice them to work more; the owners of capital must similarly be paid a higher rate of interest. These higher wages drive up the price level, making the short-run AS curve slope sharply upwards at the point where output equals potential output. P short-runshort–run AS AS The AS curve, even in the short run, is really a curve and not a straight line. Y Figure 51 A MORE ACCURATE PICTURE OF AGGREGATE SUPPLY IN THE SHORT RUN The fact that resources can be over-employed suggests that the natural rate of unemployment is not zero. This is true. Some frictional unemployment exists even when resources are “fully employed,” as there are always people switching jobs and looking for new ones. 2. The Aggregate Supply Curve and the Price Adjustment Mechanism The aggregate supply curve describes the price adjustment mechanism of the economy. In the very short run, when prices are fixed, the AS curve is horizontal. In the medium run, because prices are able to partially adjust, it slopes upward. In the long run, when prices are able to fully adjust and all markets are in equilibrium, it is vertical. The progression of time in the AS-AD model is represented by a gradual (counterclockwise) rotation of the AS curve. As time passes, prices are able to better adjust to old shocks, and output is less able to deviate from potential output. The rate at which the AS curve rotates reflects the rate at which prices in an economy are able to changewhen prices adjust quickly to macroeconomic shocks, the AS rotates quickly, reaching its long-run equilibrium earlier than it would, were its prices less able to respond to changing market conditions. We use the following equation to describe the adjustment of prices over time: AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND Pt 1 Pt 1 Y Y 3 This simply says that the price level rises when output is above potential output, and falls when output is below potential output. describes the speed of price adjustment—high values of mean that prices adjust quickly to clear markets, so that output will return quickly to potential output. Low values mean that prices adjust slowly. We also can visualize the transition from the short to the long run as a series of inward shifts in the short-run AS curve. Suppose, for example, that we had a monetary expansion at a time when P AS AS1 AS0 We can visualize the transition form the short run to the long run as a series of inward shifts in the short-run AS curve. AD0 Y* AD1 Y Figure 52 THE TRANSITION FROM THE SHORT RUN TO THE LONG RUN output was already equal to potential output. The expansion would increase both output and the price level in the short run, but over time prices would have to rise and output would have to return to its long-run equilibrium; the AS curve would have to shift gradually inward. 3. The Aggregate Demand Curve The aggregate demand curve describes all of the combinations of output and the price level for which the goods and assets markets are simultaneously in equilibrium. It slopes downward because of the interaction between these markets: a decrease in the price level, because it increases the real money supply, causes the real interest rate to fall. Lower interest rates make investment less costly, so that more occurs. Aggregate demand increases. Most of us have great intuition about goods markets. We know that a tax cut will leave us with more money to spend. We are also willing to believe that an increase in consumer confidence causes people to spend more of the money that they already have, as they do not need to save as much in anticipation of trouble. It isn’t terribly difficult to convince us that aggregate demand increases in either of these cases. 4 CHAPTER 5 Few of us have as strong an intuitive understanding of the way that asset markets work. For this reason, we provide a brief introduction to them here. The key to understanding asset markets is to think in terms of interest rates. The real interest rate is the equilibrium “price” of money, and, like all prices, is determined by the intersection of supply and demand. It is also a variable that firms care a lot about: the real interest rate is the cost, for firms, of investing. (Think of these firms as having to borrow money in order to invest.) So the first step is to ask how a particular change in some asset market affects the real interest rate. The second is to ask how the change in the real interest rate affects investment demand. By looking at the effect of the real interest rate on investment, we connect assets and goods markets, and are able to translate changes in assets markets into shifts in AD. It is necessary to distinguish between nominal and real money balances when looking at the market for money. Nominal balances are just the number of bills and coins floating around (M); real balances are the value of these bills and coins (M/P). The real interest rate is determined by the supply of and demand for real money balances. Although the central bank only has direct control over nominal money balances, it is able to affect real money balances in the short run, when the price level is fixed. A decrease in nominal balances lowers real balances for any given price level, and therefore shifts out the AD curve. Always think in terms of interest rates when analyzing monetary policy: How does the real interest rate change, and how does that change affect investment demand? An increase in investment demand will increase AD; a decrease will cause it to fall. The quantity theory of money provides more good intuition. It tells us that the total value of output must equal the number of dollars circulating in the economy multiplied by the number of times the average dollar changes hands: MxV=PxY “M” here represents the money supply; “V” is a term representing the velocity of money, or the number of times one dollar changes hands in the course of a year. “P” is the price level, and “Y” outputtogether, they represent either nominal GDP or nominal GNP. Notice that when both velocity and the money supply are assumed to be constant, there is an inverse relationship between P and Y; when one rises, the other must fall. This is consistent with our downwardsloping aggregate demand curve. Likewise, an increase in the money supply will increase output for any given price level (or increase the price level for a given level of output); it will cause the aggregate demand curve to shift outwards. 5 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND Long–run AS P An increase in the money supply will raise output for any given price level, shifting the AD curve outward. Still, we can’t say what will happen P2 P1 AD’ to output and the price level until we AD introduce an AS curve. Y* Y Figure 53 THE LONG-RUN EFFECT OF A SHIFT IN AD P Demand management policies (policies that shift only the P1 AD curve) cannot affect output AD’ in the long run. AD Y Figure 54 AN INCREASE IN THE MONEY SUPPLY SHIFTS THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE OUTWARD 6 CHAPTER 5 4. Aggregate Demand Policy Under Alternative Supply Assumptions Changes in aggregate demand only affect output in the short and medium run, when the AS curve is not vertical. When the AS curve is vertical (in the long run, or classical case), neither fiscal nor monetary policy can affect output. Shifts in the AD curve only change the price level. Output is fixed at potential output (Y*). 5. Supply-Side Economics Because the AS curve is vertical in the long run, only supply-side policies (policies which shift the aggregate supply curve) can produce long-run growth. Deregulating industries, making laws and regulations easier to comply with, and changing or removing unnecessary laws all have the capacity to do this. You might wonder how the long-run AS curve can shift at all, as all factors of production are fixed in the long run by definition. The answer, of course, is that this shift does not occur because more inputs are being used. It occurs because these inputs are being used more effectively. It is similar, in this way, to technological improvement. The political meaning of the term “supply-side economics” is slightly different than the more general economic one. This term has been used, in recent years, to refer to the idea that tax cuts will increase output by so much that tax receipts will rise or remain constant, rather than fall. The assumption that tax cuts increase aggregate supply as well as aggregate demand results from an incentive effect: Tax cuts, because they allow people to keep more of the money they earn, significantly increase the incentive to work, and therefore lower the natural rate of unemployment (raise potential output). Economists don’t argue about whether this incentive effect exists, or about whether a shift in long-run AS is likely to occur. What they do argue about is the magnitude of this shiftspecifically, about whether the AS curve shifts far enough to the right to compensate for the effect of the lower tax rate on total tax receipts. 6. Putting Aggregate Supply and Demand Together in the Long Run Over time, productive capacity of the economy increases at a stable rate. Graphically, this means the long run aggregate supply curve moves steadily to the right. The aggregate demand behavior depends on the money supply process. At each point in time, the aggregate demand and the long run aggregate supply intersect to determine the equilibrium price and output. Since the long run aggregate supply curve is vertical, the equilibrium output is in essence determined by the aggregate supply. The changes in aggregate demand, relative to shifts in aggregate supply, determine the price level.