Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Lecture 7: Deviations from PPP and LOOP explored and explained Birmingham MSc Open Economy Macro Autumn 2015 Tony Yates Recall lecture on DMF model • DMF model had short run fluctuations in the real exchange rate. • And these fluctuations caused by combination of sticky prices, money shocks, and overshooting. • Now we dive deeper into purchasing power parity, law of one price, and long run departures from these concepts. • More microfounded economics. • And traced back to Balassa-Samuelson. Law of one price P SP P SP LOOP holds if the price at home is the same as the nominal exchange rate times the foreign price level. Goods are more expensive if home price level exceeds RHS, cheaper otherwise. LOOP for Big Macs. P BigMac e BigMac S P BigMac Law of one price fails miserably, on the face of it, for Big Macs. Suggests failure of arbitrage to work across countries and borders? Or does it? A Big Mac is not just a hamburger. It’s food plus distribution services. Short and long run RER movements • Contrast between this lecture’s perspective on RER movement [ppp failure] and the lecture on the DMF model. • Today’s lecture provides reasons to explain why PPP will fail over the very long run. • DMF lecture provided reasons to expect damaging but short run RER movements. LOOP and PPP • Purchasing power parity= generalisation of the notion of the law of one price, for a basket of goods. • Think, eg, of a ‘McDonalds meal index’, including chips and soft drink, as a first step. • Typically/ideally, we study a representative basket of all goods, using expenditure surveys. • Measurement issues abound, not least since there are differences in consumption patterns across countries and within countries too. • Survey data not always available, or of the right quality. Balassa-Samuelson • There are traded and non-traded goods. • Productivity improvements in the traded goods sector bid up wages in both sectors. • Labour not mobile across countries [or not as mobile, anyway] Plan for the analysis • First use price index theory and the definition of the real exchange rate / PPP/ LOOP to diagnose proximate causes of failure of those laws. • Then study a static, competitive model of the economy to reproduce the Balassa-Samuelson result. Diagnosing proximate causes of LOOP/PPP failure P T SP T P N SP N Two groups of goods, traded, ‘T’ and non-traded ‘NT’. Think of retail distribution services as ‘non-traded’, for example. LOOP holds for traded, say. And suppose it does not hold for nontraded goods. The aggregate price index in theory P P T , P N We use a theoretical price index to aggregate across traded and non traded goods. P T , P N P T , P N It’s homogenous of degree 1. P P T P N /2 Two examples here of index functional forms that would obey this requirement to be homogenous of degree 1. P P T P N 1 You are asked to confirm this in an exercise. P T,P N e S PP S P e S. T,P N 1,P .P N/P T T 1,P N/P T .P T Substitute in the defn of the home and foreign price indices into the defn of the real exchange rate. Divide and multiply numerator by p_star_T, the foreign traded goods price Do same to denominator but using p_T, the home traded goods price. PPP failure due to ratio of traded/non traded prices at home compared to abroad P T SP T e S. 1,P .P N/P T T 1,P N/P T .P T e 1 P N /P T P N /P T Substitute in our ass. that LOOP holds for traded goods. e 1,P N/P T 1,P N/P T PPP failure diagnosed as a difference in the ratio of non-traded to traded goods prices across countries. Now we look at the BS model of why this ratio can differ across countries. Static model of competitive production QT T L T Production functions in the 2 sectors. QN N L N P i Qi wL i Profits = revenues less costs. Note wage common across sectors. 0 P i Qi wL i Free entry means zero profits. Substitute in production function to this ‘zero profit condition’. P i i L i wL i P i i w Deriving the B-S result P T T w P N N P T N [2] T PN Equate the ‘wage equation’ across sectors since the wage is common across sectors. Derive expression for ratio of traded to non-traded goods prices. P T P N N T e 1, 1, This relation holds for the home country, and, also, for the foreign economy too. T N T N Substitute into our earlier equation for the RER, and we get the BS result: PPP failures, due to differences in relative sectoral productivity. Microfoundations of price indices • So far we said nothing about where the price index function we used should come from. • This index should have a form that arises from a sound and empirically valid economic theory, and consistent with the theory we also use to diagnose the LOOP failure. • So let’s go back and explore this briefly. Microfounding our price index U u C 1 C C T C NT P minCT,CN P T C T P N C N 1 s.t. 1 C T C NT Assume consumers get utility from an aggregate consumption good C, Which is built using a Cobb-Douglas function from non traded and traded goods Price index is a weighting function that solves a minimisation problem. Min amount of expenditure to build 1 unit of the aggregate, subject to the aggregation ‘technology’. Note this is NOT the alpha that appears in production fn studied earlier. Plan for algebra-analysis • Remember we are trying to figure out a consistent microeconomic-theory-justified index function to use in our BS analysis of price indices in different countries. • We will do static constrained optimisation now. • Instead of Lagrangian, use the constraint to substitute out for one of the variables…. Optimising wrt C_T Use aggregation technology constraint to substitute out for C_N. This leaves just 1 choice variable left to minimise wrt. 1 C N C T 1 P P T C T P N C T CT 1 PN P T 1 This is the new objective function that we will minimise, now with just one ‘choice variable’. Now differentiate wrt C_T, and set equal to zero. 1 C N C T CN P T 1 PN We can use expression for C_T derived on last slide to substitute in here…. …To get C_N in terms of things other than C_T. And once that’s done… We go back to the expression for the unconstrained objective function [the expression for P we are minimising]… and substitute in both C_T and C_N…. Substituting in C_T and C_N expressions into the unconstrained objective fn… Substitute into this unconstrained ‘objective fn’ expressions for C_T, C_N P P T C T P N C N P P T 1 PN P N P T 1 P P T P N 1A A 1 1 P T 1 PN Yields this expression for the price index. We can simplify to get this, with the constant A defined in terms of the utility parameter alpha. Remarks about apples and oranges • Often encounter the informal comment that you can’t compare apples and oranges. • Well, with utility theory and optimisation, you can! • Only problem is, how do we find alpha? • Neuro-economics attempts to do things like this by experiments and brain monitoring. • But we can do it by following through with the same theory. • Obviously, the answer we get is only as good as the theory we use. Measurement and theory • Before we go on…. • Note how we are required to use theory even to create the data… • …that we will use in empirical work…. • …to test other theories. • …a theory that we ought to hope to test with other data…. • …constructed how… • Intimate two way relationship between theory and data. Finding an empirical, theory consistent measure of the alpha 1 One of the equations we worked out earlier…. C N C T PN C P TC T N PN C P TC T N PN C P TC T N 1 PPCN C T * Both sides by P_N/(P_T*C_T) T T 1 PN 1 C T PT 1 Collect terms on the RHS in C_T to get this. Substitute for C_T on the RHS only, to get this equation….. Finding the alpha as f(expenditure weights) P TCPTTCPTNCN 1 P P T PN A We find that alpha=share of spending (consumption*price) of one good in total spending. So, no need to look inside brain. Just get data on spending patterns across goods. Where we use alpha in this optimal price index formula. e 1, P T, T N T N And recall whole point is to use this price index to model and diagnose the cause of RER movements [PPP failure] in this expression. NB the index is the phi function here. Stock take on what we have done • We wanted a model to help diagnose deviations from PPP, or, equivalently, fluctuations in the real exchange rate. • To do this we compared price indices that combine goods from 2 different sectors in each country. • We then realised we needed a theory-consistent way of doing this. • Static consumer optimisation gave us the answer, in terms of the utility parameter alpha. Recap on DMF • Single good model. Not microfounded. Small country assumption. • One period sticky prices combined with exogenous money stock movements causes nominal and therefore real exchange rates to move. Recap on today • Microfounded model. 2 large countries. 2 goods in each country. Arbitrage in traded goods prices. No labour movement permitted. • Theory consistent construction of aggregate price index. • RER moves due to productivity differences in the traded goods sectors. Failure of ‘absolute PPP’ Source: used by SGU, W textbook, p263 Success of ‘relative PPP’ Price indices should move in tandem [foreign price expressed in home currency] to make sure real exchange rate does not continually grow or fall. Seems to hold for US/UK over 2 centuries. Source: taken from SGUW textbook, p265 Borders, distance and LOOP failures • Famous paper ‘How wide is the border?’ • Study of US/Canada prices of different goods in different cities. • Price differences for the same good=f(distance between cities) • Yet price difference much greater, for same distance if cities have the US-Canada border between them. Real exchange rate persistence • Regress RER on a lag of itself. • High coefficient means high ‘persistence’: – Shock hits, takes a long time to die out, since tomorrow’s RER depends heavily on today. • Many interesting themes in this work. • Let’s mention briefly 3 of them. – Chari Kehoe, McGrattan – Benigno – Giraitis, Kapetanios and Yates [yes, that’s me]. Chari, Kehoe, McGrattan • Part of RER persistence explanation rested on price stickiness. • Recall DMF model with 1 period sticky prices. • But CKM simulate modern, microfounded sticky price, RE model, and conclude that RER in that model much less persistent than data. Benigno • Takes CKM as his starting point. • Simulates a modern, microfounded, sticky prie RE model with different central bank interest rules. • Notices that the higher the coefficient on lagged interest rates in those rules, the more persistent is the RER. • So explanation is sticky prices+interest rate inertia in policy rules. Giraitis, Kapetanios, Yates • Developing techniques to detect structural change in time series processes. • Investigate whether RER persistence changes over time in different countries. • Finding: it changes a lot. • Conclusion: suggests contribution of policy rules, since these are things mostly likely to be changing.