* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Some Simple Models of Labor Market Equilibrium
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Some Simple Models of Labor Market Equilibrium 1. Monopsony and Minimum Wages. Let’s consider an industry in which a single firm employs all the labor. MFC = w(L) + L∙w′(L) w(L) (labor supply) a b wmin w0 pF′(L) = VMP L0 L1 L* L If w(L) is the labor supply curve facing the firm (and industry), this firm maximizes Π = pF(L) – w(L)L. FOC are pF′(L) = w(L) + L∙w′(L), or VMP = MFC, where MFC (marginal factor cost) is the derivative of total labor costs (w(L)∙L) wrt L. VMP (value of marginal product) is the marginal revenue from another unit of L. The monopsonist maximizes profits at point a, where VMP=MFC. It pays a wage of w0 and employs L0 units of labor. This is less than the socially efficient level, L*. Imposing a binding minimum wage at wmin changes the MFC curve to the bold line. The profit-maximizing firm again sets VMP=MFC, which now occurs at point b. The firm now employs L1 units of labor, which is more than before. So both wages and employment rise as a result of the minimum wage law. Note that, at least in the case where L is the firm’s only input, output = F(L) will rise as well. Finally, note that if this firm had some pricing power in product markets, the above tendency to increase output should translate into a endogenous decline in product prices. This prediction tends to be at odds with empirical evidence on the effects of minimum wages on prices. One way out of this dilemma (that respects similar studies’ effects of zero effects on employment) would be monopsonistic competition models, like Bhaskar and To, Economic Journal 109.455 (Apr 1999): 190-203. 2 2. Competitive Industry Labor Demand The simplest way to move from the firm and household level to the market is to imagine a fixed number of firms in an industry (endogenous entry decisions of firms can complicate matters), but large enough in number so that each firm takes factor and product prices as given. In this case, it is well known that we can derive an industry level factor demand curve by horizontally summing (i.e. summing over quantities demanded) the demand curves of the individual firms. This yields a market level demand curve of the form LD = LD(w) when we are thinking of a single factor, L in isolation. Theory says it must be downward sloping. More generally, the industry is characterized by a system of factor demand equations of the form: x1 = D1(p, w1 , w2 , … wn) x2 = D2(p, w1 , w2 , … wn) . = …….. (1) ……. xn = Dn(p, w1 , w2 , … wn) where the x’s are industry level input demands, the w’s are input prices, and p is the price of the industry’s output. The derivatives of (1) wrt p and w must satisfy the properties derived for the individual firm’s labor demand (e.g. negative definiteness and symmetry). In sum, the industrylevel factor demand relationship maps prices into quantities and has the same properties as firm-level demand. Definition (Hamermesh 1993): factors i and j are p-complements iff ∂xi/∂wj < 0 in (1). Otherwise they are p-substitutes. In other words, xi and xj are p-complements if an increase in the price of factor j leads firms to use less of factor i. Note two things about this: First, we could just as well define p-complements as occurring when “an increase in the price of one input reduces the demand for the other” because (recall our notes on single-firm factor demand) factor demand responses are predicted to be symmetric. Second, since own factor demand effects must be negative, p-complementarity means the quantities of xi and xj both fall when the price of either one rises. Now suppose there is also a system of factor supply equations of the form: x1 = S1(Y, w1 , w2 , … wn) x2 = S2(Y, w1 , w2 , … wn) . = …….. (2) ……. xn = Sn(Y, w1 , w2 , … wn) where Y is a shift variable, like household income. If certain regularity conditions hold, we can solve (1) and (2) for the vectors of equilibrium factor prices and quantities, w and x, as a function of the exogenous variables (p and Y). If we ignore interactions between factors in this context, we can answer some important questions about labor markets at the industry level using a simple diagrammatic approach. For example: 3 3. Payroll Tax Incidence S´ $1 w1 b Firms’ share a w0 w1-$1 S Workers’ share D L1 L0 L Consider a tax of one dollar per unit of labor supplied, levied on workers. This shifts the labor supply curve vertically (upwards) by one dollar, from S to S´. (Why? Because supplying L units of labor at a wage of $w per hour is the same as supplying L units of labor at $w+1 per hour, then paying a tax of one dollar per hour). So whatever amount of labor was supplied at $w before, will now be supplied at $w+1. The shift in the supply curve moves the equilibrium from point a to point b, so the equilibrium wage rises from w0 to w1 and the amount of labor exchanged falls from L0 to L1. Total tax revenues collected by the government will be $1 times the amount of labor exchanged in the new equilibrium, which equals the combined area of the two rectangles labeled “Firms’ share” and “Workers’ share”. How much of this total tax burden is ‘borne’ by firms? Firms pay no taxes, but now pay w1 instead of w0 for labor. Multiplying this difference by the amount of labor employed yields the rectangle labeled “firms’ share”. Thus, even though firms are not ‘physically’ paying any taxes to the government, they do share in the tax burden. Workers receive a higher wage, w1 than they did before the tax was imposed (w0), but they also pay $1 in tax per unit of labor sold. The difference between their old and new situation is therefore w0 – (w1-$1). Multiplying this by the amount of labor employed yields the rectangle labeled “workers’ share”, which is less than the total amount workers are physically paying to the government ($1∙L0). Thus, workers bear only part of the tax they are ‘physically’ paying; the rest is shifted to firms via a higher equilibrium wage. How much of the tax is shifted? The share of the tax shifted to firms rises with the elasticity of labor supply, and falls with the elasticity of labor demand. In general, as in any market, the inelastic side of the market bears the burden of the tax. 4 Exercises: 1. Re-draw the above figure for the case of a very elastic labor supply curve and a very inelastic labor demand curve, and show that in this case almost all of a tax on workers is shifted from workers to firms. 2. How would the diagram change if the tax was a percentage of wages (e.g. like U.S. Social Security taxes) rather than a dollar amount per unit of labor supplied? 3. Re-draw the above figure for the case of a one dollar tax per unit of labor, levied on firms instead of workers. Show that: (a) the new equilibrium level of L is exactly the same as if workers paid the tax, but this time the wage falls instead of rising. (b) the incidence of the tax is exactly the same as if it were levied on workers. In other words, the distribution of the tax burden is completely unaffected by which party ‘physically’ pays the tax. 4. Some Simple Economics of Mandated Benefits (Summers, AER May 1989) S0 S1 $α w1+$1 w0 w1+$α firms’ share workers’ share a b w1 c $1 D0 D1 L Consider a law that compels firms to give workers a benefit that costs one dollar to provide for every unit of labor hired. If this benefit is not valued by workers at all, this is just like a one-dollar unit tax levied on firms: it shifts the labor demand curve down by $1, and moves the equilibrium from point a to point b. Wages fall, meaning that part of the tax burden is shifted from firms to workers, and the amount of labor exchanged falls too. So mandated benefits are indeed ‘job killers’. 5 But suppose that the benefit firms are forced to give to workers is valued by workers at $α per unit, where 0 < α < 1. This means that the mandated benefit shifts the labor supply curve down by $α, to S1. Why? (be sure work it out). This puts the new equilibrium at point c, at an even lower wage, but a higher level of employment. At the new equilibrium, firms pay a wage of w1 (much lower than before) but must provide benefits costing $1, so the difference in unit labor costs between the new and old equilibrium is w1 + $1 - w0. Multiplying this by L yields the rectangle labeled “firms’ share”. Likewise, at the new equilibrium, workers receive a wage of w1 (much lower than before) but receive a benefit that is worth $α to them. So the difference between the old and new equilibrium to them is w0 - (w1+$α). Multiplying this by L yields the rectangle labeled “workers’ share”. Note that the total burden of the mandated benefit is the sum of these rectangles, or L(1- α), which is smaller than the burden of a pure tax. As before, the division of this burden depends on the relative elasticities of demand and supply, but its total amount now depends on how much workers value the benefit. Exercise: Show, diagramatically, that (as the above formula for the total burden suggests) a mandated benefit has zero allocative or distributional effect on labor markets when α=1, i.e. when workers fully value the benefit that is mandated. Show that equilibrium wages will, however, fall by the full cost of supplying the benefit, i.e. by $1 in the above example. Finally, consider the case where workers value the mandated benefit by more than one dollar. This might apply to benefits (like insurance) that run into adverse selection problems when voluntarily provided by firms or private providers; problems which are avoided when provision is mandated. Who benefits, and who loses? 5. The one-good general-equilibrium model. Now imagine an entire closed economy (not trading with other economies) where a fixed but large number, N, of identical firms all produce the same good, y using a vector of inputs, x. Each of these firms is small enough that it takes the economy’s vector of factor prices, w, as fixed. The supply of factors to the entire economy, however, is fixed. Denote the economy’s factor endowment vector by X. Thus, for the economy as a whole, X is exogenous, while the vector of input prices, w, is endogenously determined. (In principle the price of the single output good is endogenous too, but we need a numeraire commodity and it is the natural one. So we set its price equal to one; effectively this means we measure wages and other factor prices in terms of units of output –GDP if you prefer—that are paid to each factor owner.) Referring back to the first-order conditions for profit-maximization by a single, representative firm and setting p=1, we note that each firm’s use of inputs must satisfy: w1 = F1(x1 , x2 , … xn) w2 = F2(x1 , x2 , … xn) . = …….. ……. wn = Fn(x1 , x2 , … xn) (3) 6 where F is the representative firm’s production function and the x’s are the amounts of factors used by a representative firm. Finally, note that since all the firms are identical, we must have xi = Xi/ N for all i. Thus (3) gives us a system of equations that gives the economy’s equilibrium factor prices, w, as a function of the economy’s factor endowment vector, X. Note that the predicted effect of an increase in the economy’s endowment of a factor i on factor j’s equilibrium price is simply given by the appropriate term of the Hessian matrix of the production function. So, in some sense, this relationship is mathematically more ‘immediate’ than the effects of prices on quantities at the firm level summarized in (1): in order to derive those factor demand functions, we had to invert the matrix of FOCs represented by equation (3). Finally, note that concavity of the production function (Fii < 0) means that the ‘own’ effects of increases in factor endowments on factor prices should be negative. Definition (Hamermesh 1993): factors i and j are q-complements iff ∂wi/∂Xj > 0. Otherwise they are q-substitutes. In other words, xi and xj are q-complements if an increase in the economy’s endowment of factor j leads an increase in the equilibrium price of factor i. Thus, another term for q-complements in the trade literature is “friends”. Note three things about this: First, every factor is its own enemy, since Fii < 0 for all i. Second, as for p-complementarity, q-complementarity is symmetric. So we can just as well say that two factors are q-complements iff “an increase in the endowed quantity of one raises the equilibrium price of the other”. Third, whether a pair of factors are p-complements has little or nothing to do with whether they are q-complements. To illustrate this, do the following exercise: Exercise: Show that, for a Cobb-Douglas production function, all factors are psubstitutes, and q-complements. One-good general-equilibrium models like the above have frequently been used as an interpretive framework for estimating the effects of changes in factor endowments (such as immigration, cohort size, and expansions in higher education) on (the distribution of) wages. Because estimating these effects usually requires functional form assumptions, we’ll engage in one last digression before discussing empirical approaches: understanding the CES production function. 6. The CES production function. a) The elasticity of substitution To set the stage, we first define the “elasticity of substitution” between two factors of production. Imagine a firm that uses two inputs, say L and K. Suppose it produces a fixed amount of output, Q , at the minimum possible total cost, TC = wL +rK. As is well known, the cost-minimizing point is where the isoquant for Q (whose slope equals the ratio of marginal products, MPL/ MPK) equals the slope of a tangent isocost curve, whose slope equals w/r (both slopes are in absolute values), as shown in the figure below. Next, consider how this firm would respond to an increase in the relative price of labor, w/r. As shown in the figure below, its input ratio, K/L, will rise from (K/L)0 to (K/L)1. This is the familiar pure substitution effect of a factor price increase, now framed in terms 7 of input ratios (i.e. capital intensity in this particular example) instead of the levels of the individual inputs. K (K/L)1 Slope = (-w/r)1 (K/L)0 Isoquant for Q Slope = (-w/r)0 L Now, notice that the rate of increase in the input ratio, K/L, when w/r rises is a natural indicator of how easy it is for the firm to substitute K for L in response to factor price changes: For example, if the isoquants are straight lines (the polar case where K and L are perfect substitutes), even small increases in w/r can lead the firm to switch from using no capital (K/L =0) to using only capital (K/L= ∞). At the opposite extreme of zero substitutability between inputs (i.e. a Leontief production function, whose isoquants are rectangular), the cost-minimizing input mix does not respond to factor price changes at all. For intermediate cases, it therefore seems natural to define the elasticity of substitution: log( K / L) along an isoquant (i.e. holding output constant). log( MPL / MPK ) as a measure of how substitutable any two inputs are for one another. (Note that I have expressed σ as a function of the ratio of marginal products, rather than w/r –which would have been equivalent— to emphasize the fact that σ is a property of the production function only. This property of course has consequences for how a firm responds to price changes, but it is purely a feature of the ‘shape’ of the production function). b) The CES production function. Notice that σ, as defined above, is a local property of a production function; this ratio of derivatives will in general change as we move along an isoquant, and in general will vary with the level of output, Q, as well.1 If we want just a single, overall indicator of how substitutable inputs are for a particular firm (or other productive unit), it is helpful to have 1 If the slope of the tangent isoquant does not change along a ray from the origin (i.e. as we expand output holding K/L fixed), the production function is said to be homothetic. 8 a production function where σ is the same at all points in the diagram. That way we can refer to “the” elasticity of substitution for that firm. About 50 years ago, economists proved that there exists only one functional form for the production function with this property; this is the CES (“constant elasticity of substitution) production function. In the case of two inputs, L and K, it has the formula: Q L L K K 1/ (4) This production function has constant returns to scale iff αL + αK =1, which is often assumed. The parameter ρ can take on any value from minus infinity to plus one, and is related to the elasticity of substitution in production, σ, via the simple formula: σ = 1/(1- ρ). (5) The relationship between ρ, σ and the type of production function for some important special cases is summarized in the table below: Ρ 1 0 -∞ σ ∞ 1 0 Production function Perfect substitutes: Q= αLL+ αKK Cobb Douglas Leontief: Q= min(L, K) Isoquants Straight lines “Typical”, convex Rectangular Suppose now that a firm with a CES production function was behaving optimally, by minimizing its cost for any given output. Can we work out what its input ratio would be? To do this, recall that at an optimum, (MPL/ MPK) = w/r, and calculate the ratio of marginal products: MPL (1 / ) L L K K MPK (1 / ) L L K K [(1/ ) 1] [(1/ ) 1] L L 1 (6) K K 1 (7) Taking the ratio of these and using the optimality condition yields: w MPL L L r MPK K K 1 (8) Solving this for L/K as a function of w/r yields a simple expression for the firm’s optimal input mix as a function of the input price ratio it faces: 1 1 1 w 1 w L L L K K r K r (9) Taking logs, log( L / K ) log( L / K ) log( w / r ) (10) 9 Differentiating (10) reveals that log( L / K ) , as required by the definition of σ. log( w / r ) An implication of (10) is that if you had (say) time-series data on a firm facing varying input prices, you could estimate σ by running the linear regression suggested by (10). One advantage of estimating σ this way (rather than calibration) is that the regression doesn’t impose any restrictions on the sign of the estimate (which theory says must be positive). Thus the data can reject the model. c) Application to one-good general equilibrium models and estimation. Consider now a country (or city) producing a single aggregate output Q from two inputs, LH and LC, via the CES production function: Q H ( LH ) C ( LC ) 1/ (11) where LH are the economy’s exogenous endowments of “high-school-equivalent” labor, and LC is “college-equivalent” labor. If the firms in this economy all minimize costs, the equilibrium ratio of input prices (wC / wR ) must again equal the ratio of marginal products; i.e. writing (8) for the inputs LH and LC: wH H wC C L H LC 1 (12) Taking logs, w log H wC L log H ( 1) log H C LC (13) Now imagine we had data on a bunch of economies (they will be U.S. cities empirically) that had CES production functions and were identical in all respects except for their exogenous relative endowments of LH and LC . If, in this sample of economies, we regressed the log of the relative prices of these two factors, wH/wC , on the log of their relative factor endowments, LH/LC, the resulting coefficient is an estimate of ρ-1 = -1/σ (where the last equality follows from equation 5). In words, suppose we looked at a cross-section of cities. If our framework is correct, we expect to find that cities where high-school-equivalent labor, LH, is relatively abundant (for example because of high levels of unskilled immigration) have a lower relative wage of high-school-equivalent workers, i.e. a lower wH/wC.. Further, the magnitude of this effect is an estimate of 1/σ: Large effects indicate that it is difficult for firms to substitute LH for LC, while small effects indicate that substitution is easy. In the latter case, economies can easily absorb large inflows of a particular type of labor without leading to large changes in the relative wages of different labor types, because it is easy to substitute one type of labor for the other. 10 d) Extensions Mathematically, it is straightforward to generalize the CES production function to more than two inputs. When there are n inputs, x1 , x2 , … xn, the CES production function is simply: 1/ Q 1 x1 2 x2 ... n xn 1/ n i xi i 1 (12) which emphasizes the fact that the CES production function is nothing more than a (weighted) geometric mean of the input levels. An advantage of the multifactor CES is that a firm’s relative demand for any two factors (xi /xj) depends only on those two factors’ relative prices, (wi /wj). A disadvantage of the multifactor CES is that it forces the elasticity of substitution to be the same for all pairs of factors. The function has only one σ that applies to all input pairs. To address this limitation, many applied researchers have used the nested CES. For example, suppose there are three inputs: capital (K), skilled labor (S) and unskilled labor (U). To allow for “capital-skill complementarity” one could specify the following: T S S K K 1/ (13) and Q T T U U 1/ (14) where T is an aggregate “technology” input. To get the firm’s ‘overall’ production function, just substitute (13) into (14). Because ρ and ν are distinct, the elasticity of substitution between S and K can differ from the elasticity of substitution between the technology aggregate, T, and unskilled labor U. 7. Estimating the effects of factor supply shocks on wages Empirically, the basic idea is to estimate the effects of immigration-induced changes in the supply of different types of labor on the equilibrium prices of all labor types. Modeling choices include: The production function framework that is assumed: no framework; log-linear system of factor price or share equations (consistent with translog production function); CES (usually nested). How labor is disaggregated: natives versus migrants; migrants by years since arrival; education groups; experience groups). The unit of analysis: city versus national (This is important because cities can adjust to immigration shocks in some ways that are harder for nations: flows of native workers, capital and goods trade). 11 Instrumenting for factor supplies? Especially at the city level, unobserved labor demand shocks (like a technology boom) can both attract immigrants and raise wages; thus immigrant inflows may be endogenous. Some key studies: Grossman, J. B. (1982). The substitutability of natives and immigrants in production. Review of Economics and Statistics, 64(4), 596-603. Factor shares/translog approach; labor disaggregated by migrant and education status; cities. . Lalonde, R. J., and R. Topel, "Labor Market Adjustments to Increased Immigration", in J. Abowd and R. Freeman, eds., Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1991. Log-linear system of wage equations; cities in two Census years; labor disaggregated by natives and (migrants x years since arrival). Card, D. "The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Labor Market", Industrial and Labor Relations Review 43 (January 1990): 245-58. Nonstructural approach, labor disaggregated by skill and migrant status; Miami versus ‘control’ cities. Borjas, G. "The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Re-examining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market". Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4) (November 2003): 1335-1374. Nonstructural and three-level CES approach; labor disaggregated by experience/education cells; national level. Card, David. “Immigration and Inequality” American Economic Review 99(2) (May 2009): 1-21. CES approach; three education groups; panel-of-cities context. Introduces the lagged stock of immigrants by origin country in a city, interacted with current national inflows by origin country, to generate an instrument for immigrant inflows. 12 Limitations to the basic one-sector general-equilibrium model as an interpretive lens: 1. It is commonplace to think of immigrant inflows as flows of labor only. But if immigrants bring some other factor with them (capital, entrepreneurship), or if immigrant inflows induce other factor flows (e.g. endogenous capital inflows in a model with free capital mobility), immigration can have no effect on wages. For example, with a CRS production function, a balanced inflow of factors has no effect on any factor prices. Agglomeration effects or externalities can also create positive own wage effects of immigration. See Beaudry, Green and Sand (2014) for a model where migrants bring entrepreneurship. 2. Predictions can also change dramatically if we allow for multiple goods and trade. For example, in the ‘classic’ trade model, Samuelson’s factor price equalization theorem holds, which argues that free trade between countries (or cities) with the same production function will equalize their factor prices, even when no factor flows are possible between the countries. Thus, immigration can have zero effects on equilibrium factor prices in this model as well (See Kuhn and Wooton for an early statement of this result in the immigration context.) Other effects of immigration: On prices: Cortes, Patricia. “The Effect of Low-Skilled Immigration on U.S. Prices: Evidence from CPI Data”. Journal of Political Economy 116(3) (June 2008): 381-422. On natives’ geographical migration: Card, David. “Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labor market impacts of higher immigration”. Journal of Labor Economics 19: 22-64. (2001). On natives’ occupational/industrial migration: Peri, Giovanni; and Chad Sparber. “Task Specialization, Immigration, and Wages” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. Vol. 1 (3). p 135-69. July 2009. On trade: Peri, Giovanni and Francisco Requena. “The Trade Creation Effect of Immigrants: Evidence from the Remarkable Case of Spain” NBER working paper no. 15625 (December 2009) On automation: Lewis, Ethan. “Immigration, Skill Mix, and Capital Skill Complementarity” The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2011) 126(2): 1029-1069 (May)