* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download US Pharmacy Policy: A Public Health Perspective on Safety and Cost
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Accepted for Publication in Social Work in Public Health Volume 24, Issue #6, 2009 U.S. Pharmacy Policy: A Public Health Perspective on Safety and Cost Pauline Vaillancourt Rosenau, Ph.D, M.P.H. (Corresponding Author) Division of Management, Policy, and Community Health UT Houston - School of Public Health 1200 Herman Pressler E 915 Houston, Texas 77030 713 500 9491 (fax 713 500 9493) email: [email protected] Lincy S. Lal, Pharm.D, Ph.D Pharmacoeconomic Research Specialist Drug Use Policy and Pharmacoeconomics University of Texas – MD Anderson Cancer Center Jay H. Glasser, Ph.D. Professor Biostatistics UT Houston – School of Public Health Abstract This paper employs public health criteria to assess pharmacy policy as regards the safety and cost of medication. A public health perspective, based on social justice and a population health point of view, leads to substantive policy proposals and innovative insights. As regards safety, public health criteria emphasize regulation and substitute legislation for litigation. While generally considered a success by government and industry, the FDA’s policy initiatives to reduce drug approval time receive a more mixed appraisal. Public health emphasizes safety as much as speed of approval. Post-marketing surveillance policies regarding medication in the U.S. are mediocre from a public health perspective because they depend heavily on manufacturers’ voluntary compliance. Medication is assumed safe and effective but this confidence may be misplaced. Ten policy mechanisms for controlling pharmaceutical prices are assessed; not all of them are consistent with a public health perspective. Experience from other countries suggests that controlling profits, establishing profit targets, extending Rx providers, revising Rx classification schemes, emphasizing generic medications and establishing formularies are effective in controlling costs. Public education of patients and providers and some universal programs may reduce costs but co-pays and “cost-sharing” do not. Switching medications to over-the-counter status, pill-splitting, and importing medication from abroad, are poor substitutes for authentic public health pharmacy policy to control costs. Where policy changes yield savings, public health insists that these savings should be used to increase access and improve population health. A case study of direct-to-consumer advertising illustrates the complexity of balancing public health perspectives on safety and cost, with employer/payer concerns, and pharmaceutical industry interests. Page 1 of 33 U.S. Pharmacy Policy: A Public Health Perspective on Safety and Cost A public health perspective on pharmacy policy merits more attention (American Public Health Association, 2006). This is because of the expanding choices of medications, increased efficacy, and the explosion in cost of prescription drugs (Cockburn, 2004). A public health oriented pharmacy policy includes balancing safety of medicine with acceptable risk as well as controlling costs. But it requires a much broader consideration of pharmacy issues. For example, costs and utilization of prescription drugs are likely to increase with direct to consumer marketing and continuing efforts to influence providers (Kaiser Family Foundation, 2006c). How does a public health orientation inform this and the many other aspects of pharmacy policy? Public-health-based pharmacy policy takes into account both a populations perspective and social justice (Foege, 1987). By definition, public health is populationbased, community-oriented, and prevention-aware. Public health’s constituency includes consumers and citizens in the larger sense. Individual interest and personal choice play a role insofar as they do not result in harm to others or subordinate the welfare of society as a whole (Burris, 1997). Pharmacy policy from a public health perspective is grounded on a comprehensive view of societal needs, rather than narrowly, in terms of individual rights (Annas, 2004). It is based on the ethical principle of social justice—whether defined as equality of opportunity, equity of access, or fairness in benefits. Social justice is a broad concept with relevance to those of widely differing philosophical perspectives (Chandler, 2006). Page 2 of 33 Serving the total population, public health is concerned with equity among various social groups, with protecting vulnerable populations, with compensating persons for suffering disadvantage in health and health care, and with surveillance of the total health care system. Many players or stakeholders weigh heavily on any effort to develop or implement a public health oriented pharmacy policy in the U.S. The most important influence is that of the pharmaceutical industry.1 Others include the healthcares well as special disease and illness advocates. But a responsible public health oriented pharmacy policy must move beyond the interest of any societal component, advocate, or special interest group. It must be formulated with a broader population-based focus. While many aspects of public health policy merit attention, in this paper we focus on the most obvious aspects of public health pharmacy policy related to safety and cost. Access is of substantial importance as well, but issues regarding it are much the same as those associated with access to general health insurance. Pharmacy Policy and the Safety of Medication Safety of medication in its several dimensions is especially important for public health but problems abound. Half of all medical errors in the U.S. today are related to mistakes in medication. Significant data collected in trials goes missing (Lewis, Reichman, & So, 2007). Long-term safety is ignored and post-marketing surveillance is neglected. Special populations are underrepresented in studies. Clinical efficacy based 1 Pharmaceutical industry ads contribute a great deal to the financial viability of even the most prestigious peer reviewed journals. Importantly, industry sponsored clinical trials end up in published articles in these same prestigious journals which in turn enhance industry financial success (Smith, 2005). The vast majority of sponsored trials reported in these journals indicate that the sponsor’s product is superior to competitors or placebos. This result is 4 times more likely than research sponsored by other sources (J. Lexchin, Bero, Djulbegovic, & Clark, 2003; Rochon et al., 1994). Specific techniques are employed to obtain these highly favorable results, which include statistical manipulation. If all else fails, industry simply ignores negative results or consciously suppresses the publications of these results that are not favorable to their product. (Smith, 2005). Merck’s dishonesty with regard to results on Vioxx is a case study on this topic (Bombardier et al., 2000). Page 3 of 33 on surrogate endpoints has been adopted even when it is far from certain that they represent the true outcome (Henney, 1999). Off-label use is widely tolerated and little studied. The relative efficacy of different medications is too often unknown. Conflicts of interest are apparent throughout the process of drug approval (Steinbrook, 2005). Industry too often ignores agreed upon voluntary compliance with FDA directives (Bennett et al., 2005). Study designs are worrisome. Poor communication of information to practitioners is legendary (Ray & Stein, 2006). Elected government officials require scientists at the FDA to amend their conclusions to professional, scientific papers or presentations to FDA Advisory Committees (Okie, 2005b). In the end the role and performance of the FDA in protecting the public’s medication supply is in doubt as has been widely noted (Committee on the Assessment of the US Drug Safety 2006; Furberg, Levin, Gross, Shapiro, & Strom, 2006; U. S. Governmental Accountability Office, 2007). As regards the safety of medication, there is an inevitable dilemma concerning speed of approval. The public health community emphasizes that safety is as important a consideration as speeding drugs to market (American Public Health Association, 1999). In general public health is likely to side with slower approval, waiting until more information on safety in the long term is available, before making a drug available to the public (American Public Health Association, 1999). However, speedy approval is needed to bring new medication and vaccines to market when it is clear that patients and society stand to benefit. This is illustrated by the experience with the approval process for HIV/AIDS medication. AZT was made available before all clinical trials were complete due to the high levels of morbidity and mortality associated with this disease (United States Food and Drug Administration : Page 4 of 33 Department of Health and Human Services, no date). Since then, accelerated approval of many other drugs of possible benefit to specific groups of individuals seems to be more routine regardless of benefit (Henney, 1999)2. From a public health perspective, new medications on the “fast track” should be authentic innovations rather than copy cat drugs that will cost more but not increase efficiency. In the case of vaccines, public health is likely to emphasize speedy approval, especially if new forms of vaccines stand to benefit large, very poor populations (for example, vaccines that no longer require refrigeration). While generally considered a success by government and industry, the FDA’s initiatives to reduce drug approval time receive a mixed appraisal when public health performance criteria are employed. Congress did not appropriate funding adequate for the FDA to hire enough scientists to assure timely approval. As a result, user fees for speedier approval seemed like an appropriate means to solve the problem and the Prescription Drug User Fee Act (PDUFA) was adopted. Members of Congress liked the idea because they did not have to raise taxes or reduce financing commitments in other areas to fund the speedier drug approval process. Industry representatives favored this approach because they wanted to have drugs approved more quickly and they could recuperate the money they contributed by shifting these costs to the consumer. Quicker approval translates into a longer patent protection once a medication is on the market. A public health perspective questions the wisdom of allowing pharmaceutical companies to pay to increase the speed of the drug approval process. The interests of the pharmaceutical industry and the public are sometimes at odds, and some critics fear that PDUFA may have increased the FDA’s responsiveness to the former at the expense of 2 The Supreme Court upheld the constitutional right of the terminally ill to use medication even if it has not been proven effective. This decision is said to call into question standard FDA approval processes and to make it more difficult to test the efficacy of new medications because they will be distributed straight away outside the clinical trial environment (Okie, 2006) Page 5 of 33 the latter. In short, industry shapes the scope and nature of PDUFA goals. Critics argue, specifically, that PDUFA gives too much power to the pharmaceutical industry because the bulk of user fees go toward paying the salaries of employees hired to speed up that approval process rather than to monitor safety, thus prioritizing faster drug approvals over drug safety (Avorn, 2007). They also point out that the user fee system creates an environment of intense pressure on FDA reviewers due to the agency’s dependence on industry funding (FDALegislative Watch, 2007). Industry argues the contrary – that PDUFA do not influence approval decisions and that on balance user fees have a highly positive impact on the public’s health (McClellan, 2007). By 2007, the pharmaceutical industry and the FDA appeared to work in close collaboration. The FDA was criticized for being overly responsive to political pressure to be more free-enterprise oriented (Hilts, 2003). The FDA’s capacity to assure the safety of medication, especially post-market surveillance of drugs, was widely recognized as flawed (U. S. Governmental Accountability Office, 2006). This may well be an example of what policy scholars call agency “capture” (Egilman, Presler, & Valentin, 2007; Kaiser Family Foundation, 2006a). Public health oriented alternatives to PDUFA were called for with a goal of i) reducing the conflicts of interest inherent in user fees and ii) restoring the independence of the FDA (Hennessy & Strom, 2007; Vaughan, 2005; Viscusi, Vernon, & Harrington, 2000). Not surprisingly, in September 2007 Congress adopted the FDA Amendment Act in an attempt to balance the FDA’s mandate to both approve new medications as well as ensure the safety of the poulation. This law reauthorized the Prescription Drug User Fee Act (PDUFA IV) for five more years and strengthened the FDA’s post-marketing drug safety authority. It improved the FDA’s ability to force pharmaceutical manufacturers to Page 6 of 33 comply with required post-market clinical trials – fines may be imposed. It set up a new process for risk evaluation and reduction, Risk Evaluation and Mitigation Strategy (REMS). For low risk drugs, reporting and labeling of side effects is reiterated. For riskier medications, the FDA may require additional clinical trials, a program to train physicians in prescribing the medication safely, or limitations on advertising to the public. The bill also strengthened FDA safeguards against conflict of interests on scientific advisory committees by requiring all individuals under consideration for appointment on such committees disclose personal financial interests that might affected by the committee’s decisions (McGlew, 2007). Balancing risk and benefit in making medication available as soon as it is deemed safe, is also a public health priority. The dilemma is where to draw the line in striving to achieve this balance, especially since there will always be some patients who react negatively to any specific drug. If a medication is of great value to many people, are the potential negative effects on a few acceptable? If a drug were only of marginal benefit to a great many individuals, would the same highly negative effects on a few individuals be tolerable? Having accurate information based on careful post-market approval monitoring for widespread low-level side effects is an essential aspect of any pharmacy policy for public health. Similarly, any risk-benefit analysis would consider acceptable levels of risk and measurable population health improvement. From the perspective of public health, post-approval monitoring of medication is critical because side effects might be slow in developing but broad in terms of population consequences. Historically post-marketing surveillance policies have been judged mediocre from a public health point-of-view, in part because they depended heavily on manufacturers’ Page 7 of 33 good will and manufacturers’ fear of litigation. Today, efforts to monitor medication effects on the general population are dependent on the voluntary reporting by busy healthcare professionals who do not always take the time to register the problems they observe (Brewer & Colditz, 1999). While voluntary automated reporting programs are already in place, better technology and improved software would go a long way to improving systematic, comprehensive, mandatory, and routine methods of reporting adverse drug reactions to public health officials (Gottlieb, 2005, pp. 938-942; Kaiser Family Foundation, 2006d). To improve post-marketing safety of medication, personal health information databases and drug prescription databases should be linked. However, in the US today only the Veterans Administration adopts this approach of linking medical and pharmacy files for individuals to improve patient care and optimize research on the effects of medication (Platt & Ommaya, 2005). There are many reasons why this is the case: fears about privacy protection of individuals, absence of political will, lack of funding, and concerns of insurance companies who feel that would jeopardize proprietary information. The public health community is very sensitive to the problem of privacy versus research requirements in the matter of linking databases. The FDA attempts to monitor performance of prescription medications once they are on the market and, in many cases, it orders pharmaceutical companies to conduct further clinical studies. Industry’s compliance with these FDA post-marketing requirements has been very low. Many pharmaceutical companies simply ignored the FDA’s orders because there were no credible sanctions in place (Wood, 2006 p. 622).3 Historically, only about half to a third of the time did the pharmaceutical industry 3 On occasion long term studies funded by NIH have forced drugs off the market (Henney, 1999) Page 8 of 33 actually comply with FDA orders to further test already approved drugs on the market (Dooren, 2005; Office of Inspector General of the Department of Health and Human Services, 2006). There were few compelling incentives for the pharmaceutical industry to conduct such studies voluntarily in the absence of enforcement. As a result postmarketing surveillance in the US today was mediocre compared to that of other countries (Avorn, 2007). It is too soon to assess whether or not the “FDA Amendment Act” of 2007 will make a difference. The public health community calls for pharmaceutical assessment research and drug evaluation activities carried out independently of the FDA and the pharmaceutical industry (American Public Health Association, 2003). New approaches for studying post-marketing effects of medication are needed – one such approach would be to employ Medicare claims data as an inexpensive means of post-marketing surveillance. It has also been suggested that user fees paid by the pharmaceutical industry or revenue from a tax on medication could be used for post-marketing surveillance (Carpenter, 2005) (Ray & Stein, 2006). However, the public health relevance of such proposals has not been assessed. If the FDA is to play a role in serious post-marketing surveillance it would have to be a renewed FDA with independence from the pharmaceutical industry. Another possibility is an agency outside the FDA, specializing in post-market approval surveillance with full responsibility for managing dedicated funds no matter what their source (industry or government). Medication is assumed safe and effective in the U.S. However, today drug manufacturers, in the last instance, are responsible for seeing to it that this is the case. If recent history is any guide, such confidence is misplaced (Psaty, Furberg, Ray, & Weiss, 2004). In the absence of effective regulation, the fallback mechanism for assuring that Page 9 of 33 manufacturers are watchful is the legal system. Today, a manufacturer’s incentive to behavior responsibility rests heavily on the fear of legal repercussions. This idea is discussed further in the conclusion. In countries where a national health system assumes responsibility for the health of the population, pharmacovigilance is associated with statutory compulsion much more than voluntary action on the part of industry (Clark, Layton, & Shakir, 2001). Many European countries have a far more public health oriented pharmacy policy as regards post-marketing surveillance; they require that a medication be reassessed once it has been on the market for 5 years. These follow-up monitoring assignments are carried out by an independent drug safety office (Bowe, 2004). Costs Costs are another area where public health brings a special perspective to pharmacy policy. In general, public health has no argument with pharmaceutical policies designed to control costs. In 2000 the American Public Health Association adopted a position paper on pharmacy policy which underlines all these essential elements of a pharmacy policy for public health (American Public Health Association, 2000). Overall, public health seeks a balance where fair distribution of medication is a priority. This means pharmaceutical costs must be controlled. Equitable distribution implies that a medication should be available to all who need it. “Price disparities among sectors in the U.S. market” should be minimized. This is especially important for vulnerable populations. Many mechanisms designed to control the costs of medication are available but some are more in line with public health goals than are others. In addition, some of the available options present public health dilemmas. Page 10 of 33 Pharmacy policy grounded in economic analyses such as cost-effectiveness (value for money) is consistent with public health values in a world where resources are scarce. Such information might contribute to more informed decisions on the part of both patients and practitioners. The value of medication is often assessed by economists based on this type of analysis. In actual use however, cost-effectiveness analysis is limited because it depends on the perspective employed: the patient, the society, the employer, or the insurer. Data to examine the cost-effectiveness ratio of a medication from the larger community point of view is not always readily available. Externalities that may change the outcome of such analyses are not always predictable. The default perspective is usually the third-party payer’s point of view regarding the costs included in the analysis. This is also because they are usually the funding agency for such research. However, this is far too narrow a perspective from the public health point of view. -- Price Controls Reducing prices of medication directly – such as regulating prices, reference pricing or setting profit levels, as is the case in many other industrialized countries – is in line with public health goals4. This makes it more likely that patients can purchase needed prescription medication. However, this mechanism is of questionable political viability in the U.S. It generates strong opposition from pharmaceutical companies whose representatives argue that price controls reduce funds available for pharmaceutical research and innovation. The problem with this response is that the actual costs of developing medication is very difficult to calculate and may be exaggerated (Donald W. Light, 2005; D.W. Light & Lexchin, 2004; Scherer, 2004; Vernon, 2005). 4 APHA supported limiting price increases to an average basket index of other industrialized countries (American Public Health Association, 2000) Page 11 of 33 -- Profit Targets Many mechanisms, especially regulations that are employed in other modern western industrialized countries to control pharmaceutical prices are in line with good public health pharmaceutical policy. The U.S. is among the least aggressive in controlling profits as a means to keep costs low and access equitable (Scherer, 2004). For example, the profit margin of the pharmaceutical industry is controlled or “targeted” in Britain (17-21%) and Spain (12-18%) by negotiated agreement (Ess, Schneeweiss, & Szucs, 2003, p 95-96). There is substantial evidence that such regulatory efforts in Europe are very effective in containing costs, especially “reference pricing.” The arguments from the pharmaceutical industry opposing profit targets are the same as those outlined above regarding price controls. As regards the industry’s claim that profit targets would adversely affect their ability to carry out research, several sources document that such worries are exaggerated(Donald W. Light, 2007; Donald W. Light & Lexchin, 2005). --Education and Transparency Education of patients and providers is another mechanism for lowering costs of medication that resonates with the public health community. Making more information available about the comparative efficiency of medication permits doctors and patients to be better, more cost-conscious consumers in choosing medication. It would require changes in how medications are tested so that population-costs-and-benefits would be calculated and overall societal benefit assessed. For example, testing a medication against a placebo in Phase 3 clinical trials should be supplemented with testing it against other existing standards of care. Extended periods of exclusivity might be approved for new medications found to be cost effective and clearly superior to already existing drugs Page 12 of 33 for the same medical conditions, in head-to-head trials that directly compare the performance of two or more medications that are used to treat the same medical condition (Wood, 2006). This kind of pharmacy policy would put a limit on cost increases except in cases where therapeutic superiority from the societal point of view was demonstrated (Scherer, 2004). The public health community supports head-to-head comparative evaluation of pharmaceuticals in general (American Public Health Association, 2003). -- Universal Programs and Volume Discounts Universal programs that include volume discounts are another means to control costs in line with public health pharmacy values (American Public Health Association, 2000).5 The logic is that the negotiating power of volume purchasers results in lower prices for the group as a whole. The Veterans Administration and many state Medicaid programs are examples. States make such purchases for their Medicaid populations through drug-discount programs. These efforts are aligned with public health views (American Public Health Association, 2001). The Medicare Part D program to provide insurance for pharmaceuticals to the over-65 population illustrates that universal programs do not always include a public health orientation to pharmacy policy. In this case the bill creating the Medicare pharmacy benefit prohibits traditional Medicare from negotiating with pharmaceutical companies for volume discounts for medication (Iglehart, 2004, p. 832). If permitted, the cost savings would likely be enormous thought pharmaceutical manufacturers dispute this view (Kaiser Family Foundation, 2006b). Negotiating for volume discounts is supported by the American Public Health Association (American Public Health Association). Volume discounts may mean medication is available at lower prices. This could improve manufacturers’ profits if lower prices mean a greater number of people purchase the drug. 5 Page 13 of 33 Overall, the future cost of pharmaceuticals for the elderly, for taxpayers, and for those enrolled will be greater than if the new Medicare Part D program had been fully integrated into traditional Medicare (Lueck, 2006). In addition, policy analysts worry that the Medicare Part D program as currently structured encourages the pharmaceutical industry to focus on development and approval of very expensive drugs that may be useful to small populations, rather than on cheaper medication of use to broader populations.6 It will give additional benefit to unique drugs still under patent protection that are expensive. This is because the program provides unlimited access at very low co-payment levels (5%) to all medications once a patient gets beyond the initial shared payments (donut hole) – a little over $3,000 in 2006 (Iglehart, 2004). In this instance, the Medicare Drug Plan with its “donut hole” is doubly problematic from a public health policy perspective.7 It gives the wrong incentive to pharmaceutical manufacturers and at the same time it is a substantial financial obstacle for the poor. This same problem in supplemental coverage for lower income seniors has been noted for the Medicare insurance in general (Taylor, Chernew, & McLaughlin, 2006). -- Co-pays or “Cost-Sharing” Public health goals are not in line with certain “cost sharing” measures aimed at patients (these include co-pays, caps on the number of prescriptions, co-insurance, and deductibles). In the long term, they often end up costing more than they save because 6 While this pharmacy policy may be welcomed at the moment by the private pharmaceutical companies, how long they will remain content in the future is hard to say – the federal government as the payer behind the scenes could at any time move to reduce profit levels and this could bring government and the pharmaceutical industry onto a collision course. Price Waterhouse Cooper sees the US as inevitably moving in the direction of countries with a national health service system (Bowe, 2006). The Wall Street Journal concludes that the Medicare Drug Plan will benefit those pharmaceutical companies that “make drugs that have less competition and higher markups….” The early winners include as well “the nation’s largest health plans, which are peddling the drug coverage” (Lueck & Fuhrmans, 2006, B 1) This is a case where insurance for pharmaceuticals “enhances the ability of pharmaceutical companies to set their prices well above the cost of production and distribution, all else being equal” (Scherer, 2004, 928). 7 Page 14 of 33 they reduce the probability that the patient will obtain needed medications. Ironically in some situations they result in greater health system costs often borne by taxpayers (Hsu et al., 2006; Thorpe, 2006). These measures are especially detrimental to vulnerable populations including the elderly and the poor because these groups are the most likely to suffer serious adverse events when they skip needed medication. In general patients who forego essential medications are more likely to need emergency room services and their use of health services rises (Anis et al., 2005; Ess et al., 2003; Joel Lexchin & Grootendorst, 2004; Tamblyn et al., 2001). The findings of the Rand Health Insurance Experiment has, for 20 years, been used to justify these cost-sharing measures but reanalysis suggests that voluntary attrition in the cost-sharing arm of the study jeopradizes its conclusion, that cost-sharing is without serious effecs on populatin health (Nyman, 2007). -- Switching from Rx Status to OTC as a Means to Cost Control Switching medication from brand name, prescription status, to over-the-counter (OTC) status may reduce costs (Cohen, Paquette, & Cairns, 2005). Whether this is in line with a public health oriented pharmacy policy is not an easy question. Switching may provide for greater access to medications at lower costs for uninsured patients because they do not need a prescription from a physician. It saves the patient money if the medication is safe and effective and if the patient can easily self-diagnose and treat the problem (Strom, 2005). If self-diagnosis does not result in serious harm, OTC access is appropriate because the patient can always schedule a doctor’s visit if the condition does not improve. However, from a public health pharmacy policy point of view, switching medication from prescription status to over-the-counter is ambiguous for several reasons. Page 15 of 33 Switched drugs are very expensive immediately after they leave prescription status. While the cost of a doctor visit is avoided, patients who have insurance can no longer use it to help cover the cost of the medication (Cohen et al., 2005; P. V. Rosenau, 2000). Switched drugs can cause harm if taken by individuals who self-prescribe but who do not really need a medication; these individuals put themselves at risk for the various sideeffects associated with the medication (Brass, 2001). Also of concern to public health is the possibility that switching leads to unsupervised patients developing resistance to the medications preventing their future use.8 --Extending Rx Providers & Adopting New Rx Classifications Expanding the power to write prescriptions may lower costs and increase access to medication. If healthcare providers, including nurses, nurse practitioners, naturopathic doctors, and psychologists were given such rights to prescribe certain classes of medication, it might help reduce costs and it is in line with public health policy priorities. Some states in the U.S. have successfully experimented with these mechanisms for lower health care costs (Spencer, 2004). Many countries outside the U.S. have more than two (over-the-counter and prescription status) categories of access to pharmaceuticals. For example, pharmacists play useful roles as medical practitioners in countries where medication might be kept “behind the counter” requiring a pharmacist consult with the patient as to how to take the medication before it will be sold (Ess et al., 2003). The U.S. state of Florida also 8 Pharmaceutical manufacturers are thought to always gain from switching a medication but this is not clear-cut. Sometimes switching is part of their advance planning and their marketing strategy early on in the development of a drug. In these cases, there is no doubt that the manufacturers will profit from it. Manufacturers also benefit because they receive extended patent protection to compensate for the additional costs of the research they must undertake concerning how a medication will be used by the public after it is switched. In a few cases the FDA recommends for switching a medication though the manufacturer is against this action (Cohen et al., 2005, p. 40). Such was the case with Claritin. Sometimes manufacturers and insurance companies are on opposite sides of the switch movement. Insurance companies have publicly lobbied for increasing switches and filed “interested third party” requests for specific cases with the FDA. Their incentive is that insurance companies do not have to cover drugs once they are overthe counter (Reynolds, 2002). Page 16 of 33 attributes a more complex role to pharmacists (Carmichael et al., 1997; Florida Administrative Code, 1986). --Pill Splitting In the U.S., controlling costs is so important that sometimes providers feel compelled to employ extreme measures. One mechanism, pill splitting, is almost never encountered in other countries. It involves prescribing medication in doses that are twice the dose a patient actually needs and then instructing the patient to divide the pill in half at home and take half of a pill at each administration of the medication. Pill splitting as a cost control mechanism is in line with public health perspective when it reduces costs without jeopardizing population health. Those patients who take medication that can be split and whose physicians agree to write prescriptions for larger-than-needed doses gain, if it is the only way that they can afford needed medication (Parker-Pope, 2005). However, “pill splitting” sometimes leads to medication errors and it is therefore hardly a suitable pharmacy policy alternative to systematic attention to the problem of cost and affordability of needed medication. -- Generics and Formularies Public health pharmaceutical policy supports increased incentives to use cheaper generic versions of medication rather than brand name drugs where possible(American Public Health Association, 2000). Generics are generally considered equivalent to brand name drugs. From a societal point of view this can translate into large-scale savings, as much as $8 billion per year (Frank, 2007). Formularies are another cost-cutting means to confront the growing price of medicine. Formularies are consistent with a public health perspective where they are practiced with “accountability for reasonableness” that assures transparency, fairPage 17 of 33 mindedness, and provides mechanisms for challenging decisions about the formulary (Levinson & Laupacis, 2006). For example, the province of British Columbia in Canada uses outcomes-based research on medications as a criterion for inclusion on the province’s formulary, thus controlling both cost and quality at the same time (Morgan, Bassett, & Mintzes, 2004). Australia and Britain both use cost effectiveness assessments to manage formularies and reduce costs (Ess et al., 2003, p 95-96; Pearson & Rawlins, 2005). --Importation of Medications from Abroad The American Public Health Association has endorsed importing medication from abroad from countries where prices are lower as a means to reduce costs (American Public Health Association, 2004). This approach to public health pharmacy policy has both strengths and weaknesses. Cost reductions must be balanced off against possible safety reductions in some, but not all, countries that sell to U.S. citizens over the internet. Importing medication from abroad is a way to reduce costs but individual patient initiative and sophisticated consumer activity is required. For example, systematic research indicated that brand name prescription pharmaceuticals were cheaper in Canada than in the U.S., at least prior to the rise of the value of the Canadian dollar relative to the U.S. currency (Bradley, Firszt, & Eisenberg, 2005). This is not always the case for generic medications where differences between the two countries vary widely and market competition appears to be more efficient (Consumer Reports, 2005). Several states in the US have employed importation as a method to reduce costs. For example, the Board of Pharmacy in Nevada has certified several Canadian online pharmacies to sell medication to its residents – this is public health policy to the extent that it makes medication Page 18 of 33 available at lower price to more people, including some who would otherwise have to do without it (Vogel, 2006).9 Important as a cost control mechanism, importation requires the good will and cooperation of another country on a continuing basis.10 Good public health oriented pharmacy policy must be reliable and predictable on a long-term basis and importation from countries that heavily regulate prices is not the best solution. While public health pharmacy policy is aligned with less protection of the US pharmaceutical market from foreign competition, a sustained solution requires regulation regarding price and safety of the internal market (P. Rosenau, 2003). A Public Health Assessment of Direct to Consumer Ads While the focus of most of the advertisement and marketing efforts of the pharmaceutical industry have historically been physicians and providers, today patients are increasingly targeted. Unrestricted direct to consumer (DTC) ads are not in line with public health pharmacy policy.11 On balance these ads produce more awareness than knowledge, are ineffective as a means to patient education, and increase costs by encouraging the consumption of unneeded medication. The underlying assumption of DTC ads is that patients are able to self-diagnose and assess the potential dangers of a medication with accuracy (Okie, 2005a, Brian Strom quoted here). In many cases this is 9 Some Americans travel to Mexico or Canada to purchase medication but this involves additional indirect costs (Calvillo & Lal, 2003). 10 There is clearly little problem with the safety of medication ordered from Canada (Choudry & Detsky, 2005) though the FDA regularly warns consumers about bogus Canadian drugs (FDA, News July, 13, 2004). Concerns about safety that emerge for the growing global market in pharmaceuticals are unlikely to be without legislative remedy in the long term. An open global market in pharmaceuticals appears inevitable; almost all medication is manufactured outside the country in which it is consumed today in any case (Choudry & Detsky, 2005). Problems with fake drugs are not only a cross-border problem. They have been found internal to the US market as well though in a far lower proportion than in Asia, Africa or South Americas (Rudolf & Bernsteing, 2004) In a global marketplace fake drugs find their way into all countries in the end (Zamiska & Tesoriero, 2006). 11 The American Public Health Association has not, however, taken a position on this topic (American Public Health Association, 2000). Page 19 of 33 unrealistic because medications are so complicated that even highly trained medical specialists have problems making these assessments. In addition, medication mistakes are costly to society and to the individual. The pharmaceutical industry employs direct-toconsumer ads largely because they increase consumption. While DTC ads are not explicitly prohibited, historically in the U.S. they were rare until the early 1980s and of minor importance until the 1990s. The amount of money spent on them has increased from 100 million in 1990 to close to 4 billion in 2004 (Mintzes, 2006). Today DTC ads are common and regulated by the FDA (U.S. General Accounting Office, 2002, pp 1724). Only one western industrialized country outside the U.S. has permitted DTC ads on and off for several years (Mansfield, Mintzes, Richards, & Toop, 2005). No European county is expected to to change this prohibition in the near future (Loftus, 2007).12 The problem of assuring compliance with regulation of advertising is one major reason why so many countries prohibit DTC ads (Mintzes, 2006, p 9-12). In the U.S. even voluntary industry guidelines are not always respected though the pharmaceutical industry takes the formulation of these guidelines quite seriously (Mintzes, 2006, p 15) (PhRMA, 2005). The pharmaceutical industry offers a broad defense for advertising pharmaceuticals to patients. They argue that these ads are beneficial, contending that they educate patients, increase patient compliance, and draw attention to medications that the patient might not know about (Calfee, 2002). Patients in turn can alert their physician to the availability of these medications. DTC ads are said to lead to earlier diagnoses of important illnesses. 12 In the case of New Zealand, the Christchurch School of Medicine and Health Sciences has posted on its website a report to the Minister of Health supporting a ban on DTC ads in the strongest terms possible (Toop, Richards, Tilyard, Fraser, & Arroll, 2003). Page 20 of 33 There is, however, very little evidence to support these claims that DTC ads improve quality of health services in any way (Gilbody, Wilson, & Watt, 2005). Those opposing DTC ads report that the educational role of advertisement is, at best minimal, and at worst, nonexistent (J. Lexchin & Mintzes, 2002). Research on printed media in the 1990s found ads that targeted patients did not mention the probability of treatment success, other non-pharmaceutical activities that could help, risk factors, or side effects (R. Bell, M. Wilkes, & R. Kravitz, 2000; Mintzes, 2006, page 25 for a summary). In many cases even false or inaccurate information is transmitted though vigilant monitoring by the FDA could assure that this does not happen (R. Bell, M. Wilkes, & R. L. Kravitz, 2000; Chao, 2005; Huh & Cude, 2004). Unfortunately, the number of direct-toconsumer prescription drug advertisements reviewed by FDA decreased by about half between the 1997-2001 and 2002-2005. The agency lacks an effective system to track and review the more than 10,000 DTC ads and the Web sites reported to the agency on an annual basis (Kaiser Family Foundation, 2005). It is imperative that FDA develop criteria for review and prioritization of the DTC ads to decrease the negative impact of these ads. Doctors are pressured by patients who are influenced by DTC ads to prescribe regardless of quality, appropriateness, or cost considerations weighing in the opposite direction (Mintzes, 2002; Mintzes et al., 2003; Mintzes et al., 2002; Toop et al., 2003). It is estimated that about 8.5 million patients each year “both requested and received from their physician a prescription for a particular drug in response to seeing a DTC advertisement” (U.S. General Accounting Office, 2002, page 4). The pharmaceutical industry’s advertising too often distorts results of head-tohead research comparing medications, and supports the continued, sometimes even Page 21 of 33 inappropriate, use of inferior medication (Liebman, 2006). For example the ALLHAT study found greater patient safety with inexpensive diuretics for hypertension and greater chance of heart failure with expensive newer medications such as Norvasc (generic amlodipine) (ALLHAT Officers and Coordinators for the ALLHAT Collaborative Research Group, 2002). But DTC ads emphasized the safety and efficacy of Norvasc and claimed that it was equally effective to diuretics. DTC ads may not be in line with good public health pharmacy policy but not all U.S. professional health services associations have come out strongly against them. In 2004 the American Pharmacists Association’s House of Delegates endorsed DTC ads as long as they conformed to rules concerning clarity and accuracy of information (American Pharmacists Association, 2004). This group argued that there is a lack of solid evidence about these ads and call for more assessment of them (Lyles, 2002). The American Medical Association’s (AMA) published policy on DTC ads is balanced and carefully worded. Only recently has AMA come close to asking that DTC ads be prohibited in certain circumstances. It proposes that newly approved drugs “not be advertised immediately” (American Medical Association, 2005) (American Medical Association, 2006). This makes sense because half of the drugs in the US that are withdrawn from the market are removed within two years of being approved (Lasser, 2002). The American Public Health Association’s official policy is much weaker – it recommends that health care professionals and the general public report misleading ads to the FDA but it made no call for a ban on ads (American Public Health Association, 1995). Direct to Consumer ads could serve a public health pharmacy policy function if they were used to educate and inform the public as part of public education or health Page 22 of 33 promotion programs. For example, low dose aspirin taken for cardiovascular health could save lives (Almasi, Stafford, Kravitz, & Mansfield, 2006; Chan et al., 2007). However, almost all DTC ads are privately financed and designed with the goal of maximizing the sale of the most profitable pharmaceuticals (Goodbody, 2005). Conclusion Bringing public health into pharmacy policy challenges the status quo because it destabilizes the fragile alliances between players and stakeholders throughout this health sector. The future, of course, is difficult to predict but public health pharmacy policy is likely to be increasingly important and public health should strive to influence policy in this health sector. As tax payer responsibility for providing medication expands via the Medicare Prescription Drug Act and tax subsidized Health Savings Accounts, pressure for policy innovations are less likely to stress individual liberty and more likely to emphasize public health accountability because of potential cost savings. DTC advertising will come under scrutiny as policy makers are required to respond to a closer alignment of public health perspectives and employer/payer interests.13 Public health requires that the whole society and the most vulnerable populations be given more attention. This is not a threat so much as an opportunity to come to grips with changes that in some way must be met. As regards to safety of prescription pharmaceuticals, public health has much to contribute to policy on topics ranging from drug approval to post-marketing surveillance. Overall, if it is to conform to a public health perspective, policy must move from informal mechanisms of enforcement grounded in the legal system and pharmaceutical 13 There is a role for public health advocacy on this issue because other groups are actively pursuing it as well (American Medical Association, 2005). Page 23 of 33 manufacturer’s fear of litigation, to a more active regulatory role on the part of government (American Public Health Association, 1999). A better means to achieve safety of the medication supply is surely warranted. For example, a strong case can be made for public funding and government oversight of clinical trials (Lewis et al., 2007). Litigation, as an informal mechanism of focusing manufacturer’s attention on safety, is inefficient. For the most part, litigation seeks justice one person at a time or by groups of injured patients at a time via class action cases. It is a clumsy incentive and not at all in line with a public health orientation toward pharmacy policy. It is also ineffective because those injured are geographically dispersed. When cases of postapproval problems emerge, injured individuals are hard to identify, and many are missed. Too often the legal approach to safety of medication permits prolonged efforts to avoid compliance with the law. Research on malpractice dating from the time of the Harvard Medical Practice Study in the late 1980s and 1990s demonstrated that only a tiny percent of those injured are ever reached, that many who benefit have abused the legal system, and administrative expenses for achieving safety via litigation are very high (Localio et al., 1991). While many of the cost saving mechanisms discussed above are compatible with a public health pharmacy policy, none by itself is a substitute for a more comprehensive consideration of pharmaceutical prices. Profit controls and price targets are consistent with public health values (American Public Health Association, 2000). However, they have never been tried in the U.S. and are not politically viable at the present time. They do however, reflect the fact that the pharmaceutical sector is an important market and the usual supply and demand mechanisms do not apply (Rice, 2002). Other cost control mechanisms such as education and transparency are more politically feasible. Negotiated Page 24 of 33 price reductions, including volume discounts in universal programs, already exist and they work. In the future, regulation may well encourage, or even require, large purchasers in state and federal public programs -- such as the Medicare Prescription Drug Part D program – to actively negotiate for volume discounts. Extending pharmaceutical prescription writing authority, using generics first, and developing formularies, are also examples of public health pharmacy policies. Pill splitting is more a temporary, stopgap measure than real public health pharmacy policy. The U.S. is under pressure to recognize a global market in pharmaceuticals and to reduce restrictions on medication importation. This is another means to control to cost of pharmaceuticals though it has many weaknesses. It is compatible with a public health approach and is likely to continue to be utilized in the U.S. in the absence of universal health insurance coverage that includes pharmaceuticals.. What actually happens to the “saved resources” is a matter of concern for the public health community. If “cost savings” deprive patients of essential medication or if “savings” go only to increase pharmaceutical companies’ profits, then there is a problem. Cost-sharing and switching medication from prescription status to over-the-counter status, are examples of mixed approaches to cost savings. Whether they are acceptable forms of controlling costs or not depends on how they are structured. Certain forms of cost sharing appear to be counterproductive and can jeopardize the health of the most vulnerable populations. If “cost savings” are designed to maximize the health of the population, by broadening availability of essential medications, then such “savings” strategies are in line with public health pharmacy policy and should be adopted. Page 25 of 33 References ALLHAT Officers and Coordinators for the ALLHAT Collaborative Research Group. (2002). Major Outcomes in High-Risk Hypertensive Patients Randomized to Agiotensin-Converting Enzyme Inhibitor or Calcium Channel Blocker vs. Diuretic:The Antihypertensive and Lipid-Lowering Treatment to Prevent Heart Attack Trial (ALLHAT) JAMA, 288(23), 2981-2997. Almasi, E. A., Stafford, R. S., Kravitz, R. L., & Mansfield, P. R. (2006). What Are the Public Health Effects of Direct-to-Consumer Drug Advertising? PLoS Medicine, 3(3), e145. American Medical Association. (2005, June 14, 2006). AMA calls for temporary moratorium on direct-to-consumer advertising of new prescription drugs. Retrieved 6/17/2006, 2006, from http://www.amaassn.org/ama/pub/category/16467.html American Medical Association. (2006). Direct-to-Consumer Advertisements of Presciption Drugs. Retrieved March 3, 2006, from http://www.amaassn.org/apps/pf_new/pf_online?f_n=resultLink&doc=policyfiles/HnE/E5.015.HTM&s_t=e+5.015&catg=AMA/HnE&catg=AMA/BnGnC&catg=AMA/D IR&&nth=1&&st_p=0&nth=2& American Pharmacists Association. (2004). Report of the Policy Review Committee: American Pharmacists Association. American Public Health Association. (1995). Direct-to-Consumer Prescription Drug Advertising (No. 9516 Position Paper Number): American Public Health Association. American Public Health Association. (1999). Concern About the Food and Drug Administration's Drug Approval Process (No. 9915 Position Paper Number): American Public Health Association. American Public Health Association. (2000). Making Medicines Affordable: The Price Factor (No. 20006 Postion Paper Number): American Public Health Association. American Public Health Association. (2001). Condemnation of Pharmaceutical Companies Retaliatory Tactics (No. 200126 Position Paper Number): American Public Health Association. American Public Health Association. (2003). Supporting Legislation for Independent Post-Marketing (Phase IV) Comparative Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals (No. 20031 Postition Paper Number): American Public Health Association. American Public Health Association. (2004). Letter Reaffirming Support for S. 2328, the Pharmaceutical Market Access and Drug Safety Act of 2004, and Expressing Concern Regarding S. 2493, the Safe IMPORT Act of 2004: American Public Health Association. American Public Health Association. (2006). The Role of the Pharmacist in Public Health (Policy Position Paper number 200614). Washington DC: American Public Health Associatin. Page 26 of 33 American Public Health Association. (no date). Medicare Prescription Drug Coverage: Drug Benefits Can Help Senior Citizens Stay Healthy: American Public Health Association. Anis, A. H., Guh, D. P., Lacaille, D., Marra, C. A., Rashidi, A. A., Li, X., et al. (2005). When Patients Have to Pay A Share of Drug Costs: Effects of Frequencey of Physician Visits, Hospital Admissions and Filling of Prescriptions. Canadian Medical Association Journal, 173(11), 1335. Annas, G. J. (2004). American Bioethics: Crossing Human Rights and Health Law. London: Oxford University Press. Avorn, J. (2007). Paying for Drug Approvals - Who's Using Whom? The New England Journal of Medicine, 356(17), 1697-1700. Bell, R., Wilkes, M., & Kravitz, R. (2000). The Educational Value of Consumer-Targeted Prescriptiond Drug Print Advertising. Journal of Family Practice, 49(12), 10921098. Bell, R., Wilkes, M., & Kravitz, R. L. (2000). The Educational Value of ConsumerTargeted Prescription Drug Print Advertising. Journal of Family Practice, 49, 1092-1098. Bennett, C. L., Nebeker, J. R., Lyons, E. A., Samore, M. H., Feldman, M. D., Mckoy, J. M., et al. (2005). The Research on Adverse Drug Events and Reports (RADAR) Project. JAMA, 293(17), 21312140. Bombardier, C., Laine, L., Reicin, A., Shapiro, D., Burgos-Vargas, R., Davis, B., et al. (2000). Comparison of Upper Gastrointesintal Toxicity of Rofecoxib and Naproxen in Patients with Rheumatoid Arthritis. New England Journal of Medicine, 343(21), 1520-1528. Bowe, C. (2004, November 25 ). Safety Fears Plague US Drug System. Financial Times. Bowe, C. (2006, January 4). US Pharmaceutical Industry Limbers Up for Medicare's Brave New World. Financial Times. Bradley, Q. S., Firszt, R., & Eisenberg, M. J. (2005). A Comparison of Brand-Name Drug Prices Between Canadian-Based Internet Pharmacies and Major U.S. Drug Chain Pharmacies. Annals of Internal Medicine, 143(6), 397-404. Brass, E. P. (2001). Changing the Status of Drugs from Prescription to Over-the-Counter Availability. New England Journal of Medicine, 345(11), 810-816. Brewer, T., & Colditz, G. A. (1999). Postmarketing Surveillance and Adverse Drug Reactions: Current Perspectives and Future Needs. JAMA, 281(9), 824-829. Burris, S. (1997). The Invisibility of Public Health: Population-Level Measures in a Politics of Market Individualism. American Journal of Public Health, 87(10), 1607-1610. Calfee, J. E. (2002). public Policy Issues in Direct-to-Consumer Advertising fo Prescription Drugs. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 21(2), 174-190. Page 27 of 33 Calvillo, J., & Lal, L. (2003). Pilot Study of a Survey of US Residents Purchasing Medications in Mexico: Demographics, Reasons, and Types of Medications Purchased. Clinical Theraputics, 25(2), 561-577. Carmichael, J. M., O'Connell, M. B., Devine, B., Kelly, W., Ereshefsky, L., Linn, W. D., et al. (1997). Collaborative Drug Therapy Management By Pharmacists. Pharmacotherapy, 17(5), 1050-1061. Carpenter, D. (2005). A Proposal for Financing Postmarketing Drug Safety Studies by Augmenting FDA User Fees. Health Affairs, W5 469-480. Chan, A. T., Manson, J. E., Feskanich, D., Stampfer, M. J., Colditz, G. A., & Fuchs, C. (2007). Long-term Aspirin Use and Mortality in Women. Archives of Internal Medicine, 167(March 26), 562-572. Chandler, M. (2006). The Rights of the Medically Uninsured: An Analysis of Social Justice and Disparate Health Outcomes. Jounarl of Health & Social Policy, 21(3), 17+. Chao, B. (2005). Evaluating The Educational Content of Direct-To-Consumer Fulfillment Materials. American Journal of Helath System Pharmaceuticals, 62, 620-625. Choudry, N. K., & Detsky, A. S. (2005). A Perspective on US Drug Importation. JAMA, 293(3), 358-362. Clark, D., Layton, D., & Shakir, S. A. W. (2001). Monitoring the Safety of Over the Counter Drugs: We Need a Better Way than Spontaneous Reports. British Medical Journal, 323, 706-707. Cockburn, I. M. (2004). The Changing Structure of the Pharmaceutical Industry. Health Affairs, 23(1), 10-22. Cohen, J., Paquette, C., & Cairns, C. P. (2005). Switching Prescription Drugs to Over the Counter. British Medical Journal, 330, 39-41. Committee on the Assessment of the US Drug Safety (2006). The Future of Drug Safety: Promoting and Protecting the Health of the Public. Washington DC: The National Academies Press - The Institute of Medicine. Consumer Reports. (2005). Prescription Drugs: The Facts About Canada. Consumer Reports. Dooren, J. C. (2005, June 1). Drug Makers Seen as Slow to Finish Postmarket Studies. Wall Street Journal. Egilman, D. S., Presler, A. H., & Valentin, C. S. (2007). Avoiding the Regulatory Capture of the Food and Drug Administration. Archives of Internal Medicine, 167(7). Ess, S. M., Schneeweiss, S., & Szucs, T. D. (2003). European Health Care Policies for Controlling Drug Expenditure. Pharmacoeconomics, 21(2), 89-103. FDALegislative Watch. (2007). PDUFA IV Is "Golden Opportunity" to Improve Drug Safety Funding and Staff, FDALegislative Watch: F-D-C Reports & The Pink Sheet. Page 28 of 33 Florida Administrative Code. (1986). Medicinal Drugs Which May Be Ordered By Pharmacists, Florida Administrative Code (465.186 FS Specific Authority ed., Vol. 64B 26-27.220, pp. 234-236). Foege, W. (1987). Public Health: Moving From Debt to Legacy. American Journal of Public Health, 77(10), 1276-1278. Frank, R. (2007). The Ongoing Regulation of Generic Drugs. The New England Journal of Medicine, 357(20), 1193-1996. Furberg, C. D., Levin, A. A., Gross, P. A., Shapiro, R. S., & Strom, B. L. (2006). The FDA and Drug Safety: A Proposal for Sweeping Changes. Archi ves of Internal Medicine, 166, 1938-1942. Gilbody, S., Wilson, P., & Watt, I. (2005). Benefits and Harms of Direct-to-Consumer Advertising: A Systematic Review. Qual Saf Health Care, 14, 146-250. Gottlieb, S. (2005). Opening Pandora's Pillbox: Using Modern Information Tools to Improve Drug Safety. Health Affairs, 24(4), 938-948. Hennessy, S., & Strom, B. L. (2007). PDUFA Reauthorization -- Drug Safety's Golden Moment of Opportunity? The New England Journal of Medicine, 356(17), 17031704. Henney, J. E. (1999). International Conference on Surrogate Endpoints and Biomarkers. Paper presented at the International Conference on Surrogate Endpoints. Hilts, P. J. (2003). Protecting America's Health: The FDA, Business, and One Hundred Years of Regulation (1st ed.). New York: Knopf. Hsu, J., Price, M., Huang, J., Brand, R., Fung, V., Hui, R., et al. (2006). Unintended Consequences of Caps on Medicare Drug Benefits. New England Journal of Medicine, 354(22), 2349-2359. Huh, J., & Cude, B. (2004). Is The Information "Fair and Balanced" in Direct-ToConsumer Prescription Drug Websites? Journal of Health Communitites, 9, 529540. Iglehart, J. K. (2004). The New Medicare Prescription-Drug Benefit: A Pure Power Play. New England Journal of Medicine, 350(8), 826-833. Kaiser Family Foundation. (2005). 23 Drug Companies Agree to New Guidelines on Advertising, 2006, from http://www.kaisernetwork.org/daily_reports/print_report.cfm?DR_ID=31804&dr _cat=3 Kaiser Family Foundation. (2006a). FDA Does Not Have Effective Process for Monitoring Post-Market Drug Studies, GAO Report Says. Retrieved April 27, 2006, from http://www.kaisernetwork.org/daily_reports/rep_index.cfm?hint=3&DR_ID=367 97 Kaiser Family Foundation. (2006b). Increased Bargaining Power of Bulk Prescription Drug Buyers Examined. Retrieved 6/22/2006, 2006, from www.kaisernetwork.org/daily_reports/print_report.cfm?DR_ID=38076&dr_cat=3 Page 29 of 33 Kaiser Family Foundation. (2006c). Prescription Drug Costs; Backgrounder Brief. Retrieved February 1, 2006, from www.kaiseredu.org/topics_im.asp?id=352&parentID=68&imID=1 Kaiser Family Foundation. (2006d). Prescriptions Drugs: IOM Report Calls on FDA to Improve Consuemr Safety: Recommendations include Restrictions on Prescription Drug Advertisements, Increased Post-Market Drug Reviews: The Kaiser Family Foundation. Lasser, K. E. (2002). Timing of New Black Box Warnings and Withdrawals for Prescription Medications. Journal of the American Medical Association, 287(17), 2215-2220. Levinson, W., & Laupacis, A. (2006). A Call for Fairness in Formulary Decisions. Archives of Internal Medicine, 166, 16-18. Lewis, T. R., Reichman, J. H., & So, A. D. (2007). The Case for Public Funding and Public Oversight of Clinical Trials, Economists' Voice (Vol. 4). Berkeley, California: The Berkeley Electronic Press. Lexchin, J., Bero, L., Djulbegovic, B., & Clark, O. (2003). Pharmaceutical Industry Sponsorship and Research Outcome and Quality. British Medical Journal, 326, 1167-1170. Lexchin, J., & Grootendorst, P. (2004). Effects of Prescription Drug User Fees on Drug and Health Services Use and on Health Statuse in Vulnerable Populations: A Systematic Review of the Evidence. International Journal of Health Services, 34(1), 101-122. Lexchin, J., & Mintzes, B. (2002). Direct-to-Consumer Advertising of Presciption Drugs: The Evidence Says No. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 21(2), 194-201. Liebman. (2006). Producer's Notebook: Spin Doctors. Retrieved January 5, 2006, from http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/shows/prescription/etc/notebook.html Light, D. W. (2005). Extraordinary Claims Require Extraordinary Evidence. Journal of Health Economics, 24, 1030-1033. Light, D. W. (2007). Misleading Congress about Drug Development. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 32(5), 895-913. Light, D. W., & Lexchin, J. (2004). Will Lower Drug Prices Jeopardize Drug Research? A Policy Fact Sheet. The American Journal of Bioethics, 4(1), W3-W6. Light, D. W., & Lexchin, J. (2005). Foreign Free Riders and the High Price of US Medicines. British Medical Journal, 331, 958-960. Localio, A. R., Lawthers, A., Brennan, T. A., Laird, N. M., Hebert, L. E., Peterson, L. M., et al. (1991). Relation between malpractice claims and adverse events due to negligence - results of the Harvard Medical Practice Study. New England Journal of Medicine, 325(4), 245-251. Loftus, P. (2007, November 7). Drug Ads Don't Tempt Europe. The Wall Street Journal, p. 1. Page 30 of 33 Lueck, S. (2006, February 6). Tax Breaks to Boost Cost of Bush's Health Budget. The Wall Street Journal. Lueck, S., & Fuhrmans, V. (2006, April 21). Large Insurers Are Big Winners in New Medicare Benefit. Wall Street Journal, p. B1. Lyles, A. (2002). Direct Marketing of Pharmaceuticals to Consumers. Annual Review of Public Health, 23, 73-91. Mansfield, P. R., Mintzes, B., Richards, D., & Toop, L. (2005). Direct to Consumer Advertising. British Medical Journal, 330, 5-6. McClellan, M. (2007). Drug Safety Reform at the FDA -- Pendulum Swing or Systematic Improvement? The New England Journal of Medicine, 356(17), 1700-1702. McGlew, J. (2007). FDA Reauthorization Expands Agency's Funding and Authority, Washington Report (ACCP Report) (Vol. 26). Washington DC: Amaerican college of Clinical Pharmacy. Mintzes, B. (2002). Direct to Consumer Advertising Is Medicalising Normal Human Experience. British Medical Journal, 324, 908-909. Mintzes, B. (2006). Direct-to-Consumer Advertising of Prescription Drugs in Canada. Toronto, Ontario: Health Council of Canada. Mintzes, B., Barer, M. L., Kravitz, R. L., Bassett, K., Lexchin, J., Kazajian, A., et al. (2003). How Does Direct-to-Consumer Advertising (DTCA) Affect Prescribing? A Survey in Primary Care Environments With and Without Legal DTCA. Canadian Medical Association Journal, 169(5), 405-412. Mintzes, B., Barer, M. L., Kravitz, R. L., Kazajian, K. B., Lexchin, J., Evans, R. G., et al. (2002). Influence of Direct to Consumer Pharmaceutical Advertising and Patients' Requests on Prescribing Decisions: Two Site Cross Sectional Survey. British Medical Journal, 324, 278-279. Morgan, S., Bassett, K., & Mintzes, B. (2004). Outcomes-Based Drug Coverage in British Columbia. Health Affairs, 23(1), 269-347. Nyman, J. A. (2007). American Health Policy: Cracks in the Foundation. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 32(5), 759-783. Office of Inspector General of the Department of Health and Human Services. (2006). FDA's Monitoring of Postmarketing Study Committments (No. OEI-01-0400390). Washington DC: Dept of Health and Human Services. Okie, S. (2005a). Safety in Numbers-Monitoring Risk in Approved Drugs. New England Journal of Medicine, 352(12), 1173-1176. Okie, S. (2005b). What Ails the FDA? New England Journal of Medicine, 352(11), 10631066. Okie, S. (2006). Access before Approval - A Right to Take Experimental Drug? New England Journal of Medicine, 355(5), 437-440. Parker-Pope, T. (2005, November 22). Health Insurers Push Pill Splitting As A Way to Save Money on Drugs. The Wall Street Journal. Page 31 of 33 Pearson, S. D., & Rawlins, M. D. (2005). Quality, Innovation, and Value for Money: Nice and the ritish National Health Service. JAMA, 294(20), 2618-2623. PhRMA. (2005). PhRMA Guiding Principles: Direct to Consumer Advertisements about Prescription Medicines, Washington DC Platt, R., & Ommaya, A. (2005). A Beneficial Side Effect of the Medicare Drug Benefit. New England Journal of Medicine, 353(26), 2742. Psaty, B., Furberg, C., Ray, W. A., & Weiss, N. (2004). Potential for Conflict of Interest in the Evaluation of Suspected Adverse Drug Reactions: Use of Cervastatin and Risk of Rhabdomyolysis. JAMA, 292(21), 2622-2631. Ray, W. A., & Stein, M. (2006). Reform of Drug Regulation--Beyond an Independant Drug-Safety Board. New England Journal of Medicine, 354(2), 194-201. Reynolds, T. (2002). Switching from Prescription to Over-the-Counter Drugs. Annals of Internal Medicine, 136(2), 177-179. Rice, T. (2002). The Economics of Health Reconsidered (2nd ed.). Chicago: Health Administration Press. Rochon, P., Gurwitz, J. H., Simms, R., Fortin, P., Felson, D., & al, e. (1994). A Study of Manufacturer-Supported Trials of Nonsteroidal Anti-Inflammatory Drugs in the Treatment of Arthritis. Archives of Internal Medicine, 154, 157-163. Rosenau, P. (2003). The Competition Paradigm; America's Romance with Conflict, Contest, and Commerce. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. Rosenau, P. V. (2000). Managing Medical Technology: Lessons For The United States from Quebec and France. International Journal of Health Services, 30(2), 617-. Rudolf, P. M., & Bernsteing, I. (2004). Counterfeit Drugs. New England Journal of Medicine, 350(14), 1384-1386. Scherer, F. (2004). The Pharmaceutical Industry--Prices and Progress. New England Journal of Medicine, 351(9), 927-932. Smith, R. (2005). Medical Journals Are an Extension of the Marketing Arm of Pharmaceutical Companies. PLoS Medicine, 2(5), 364-366. Spencer, J. (2004, June 1). Getting Drugs without the Doctor: States Extend PrescriptionWriting Powers to Growing Rande of Nonphysicians. Wall Street Journal, p. D1. Steinbrook, R. (2005). Financial Conflicts of Interest and the Food and Drug Administration's Advisory Committees. New England Journal of Medicine, 353(2), 116-118. Strom, B. L. (2005). Statins and Over-the-Counter Availability. New England Journal of Medicine, 352(14), 1403-1405. Tamblyn, R., Laprise, R., Hanley, J. A., Abrahamowicz, M., Scott, S., Mayo, N., et al. (2001). Adverse Events Associated with Prescription Drug Cost-Sharing among Poor and Elderly Persons. Journal of the American Medical Association, 285(4), 421-429. Page 32 of 33 Taylor, E. F., Chernew, M., & McLaughlin, C. (2006). Do Determinants of Medicare Supplemental Coerage Choice Vary By Income? Jounarl of Health & Social Policy, 22(1), 1-13. Thorpe, K. E. (2006). Cost Sharing, Caps on Benefits, and the Chronically Ill - A Policy Mismatch. New England Journal of Medicine, 354(22), 2385-2386. Toop, L., Richards, D., Tilyard, M., Fraser, T., & Arroll, B. (2003). Direct to Consumer Advertising of Prescription Drugs in New Zealand: For Health of For Profit?, 2006, from http://www.chmeds.ac.nz/report.pdf U. S. Governmental Accountability Office. (2006). Drug Safety: Improvement Needed in FDA's Postmarket Decision -making and Oversight Process (No. GAO-06-402): Department of Health and Human Services. U. S. Governmental Accountability Office. (2007). Drug Safety: FDA Needs to Further Address Shortcomings in Its Postmarket Decision-making Process (Testimony before the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations, Committee on Energy and Commerce, House of Representatives No. GAO-07-599T). Washington Dc: U. S. Governmental Accountability Office. U.S. General Accounting Office. (2002). Prescription Drugs: FDA Oversight of DTC Advertising Has Limitations. Washington, DC: United States General Accounting Office. United States Food and Drug Administration : Department of Health and Human Services. (no date). Expanded Access and Expedited Approval of new Therapies Related to HIV/AIDS. Retrieved April 29, 2006, from http://www.fda.gov/oashi/aids/expanded.html Vaughan, B. (2005). PDUFA IV: Putting the Public Health First. Yonkers, NY: Consumers Union. Vernon, J. A. (2005). Examining the Link between Price Regulation and Pharmaceutical R&D Investment. Health Economics, 14, 1-16. Viscusi, W. K., Vernon, J. M., & Harrington, J. E. (2000). Economics of Regulation and Antitrust (3rd ed.). Massachusetts MIT Press. Vogel, E. (2006, March 2). Board Approves Regulations Allowing Nevadans to Acquire Prescription Drugs from Canada. Las Vegas Review-Journal. Wood, A. J. J. (2006). A Proposal for Radical Changes in the Drug- Approval Process. The New England Journal of Medicine, 355(6), 618-623. Zamiska, N., & Tesoriero, H. (2006, January 26, 2006). As Pfizer Battles Fakes in China, Nation's Police Are Uneasy Allies. The Wall Street Journal. Page 33 of 33