* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download chapter overview
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability CHAPTER EIGHT INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INSTABILITY CHAPTER OVERVIEW This chapter previews economic growth, the business cycle, unemployment, and inflation. It sets the stage for the analytical presentation in later chapters. Economic growth is defined and the arithmetic and sources of economic growth are examined. The record of growth in the U.S. is viewed from several perspectives including an international comparison in Global Perspective. The business cycle is introduced in historical perspective and is presented in stylized form (Figure 8-1). While hinting at various business cycle theories, the authors stress the general belief that changes in aggregate spending, especially durable goods and investment spending, are the immediate cause of economic instability. Noncyclical fluctuations are also treated briefly before the analysis of unemployment and inflation. In the section on unemployment, the various types of unemployment—frictional, structural, and cyclical—are described. Then the problems involved in measuring unemployment and in defining the full-employment unemployment rate are considered. The economic and noneconomic costs of unemployment are presented, and finally, Global Perspective 8-2 gives an international comparison of unemployment rates. Inflation is accorded a rather detailed treatment from both a cause and an effect perspective. International comparisons of inflation rates in the post-1992 period are given in Global Perspective 8-3. Demand-pull and cost-push inflation are described. Considerable emphasis is placed on the fact that the redistributive effects of inflation will differ, depending on whether inflation is anticipated or unanticipated. The chapter ends with historical cases of extreme inflation to remind students that inflationary fears have some basis in fact. WHAT’S NEW A number of subtle but significant changes have been made from the previous edition. In addition to dates and data, terminology and theoretical presentation has been revised. Material from Chapter 7 on real per capita GDP and the Consumer Price Index has been moved to this chapter. In the discussion of the GDP price index and CPI, the previous focus on “fixed” v. “variable” weighting has been dropped in favor of a focus on the different scope of the GDP price index and CPI market baskets. The wording relating to the GDP gap has been revised to conform to contemporary usage. A positive GDP gap refers to a situation where actual GDP exceeds potential GDP. A negative GDP represents a shortfall in actual GDP relative to potential GDP. A new “Consider This” box on clipping coins has been added. It provides a nice illustration of the connection between money and demand-pull inflation, and appeared in the previous edition website “Analogies, Anecdotes, and Insights” section. The discussion of demand-pull inflation has been shortened, and the use of the three-range curve (essentially an aggregate supply curve) in the explanation has been dropped. The AD-AS curve will makes it first appearance in the text in Chapter 11. End-of-chapter-questions have been added and revised. 119 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability The “Last Word” on the stock market and macroeconomic instability has been updated. INSTRUCTIONAL OBJECTIVES After completing this chapter, students should be able to 1. Define two measures of economic growth. 2. Explain why growth is a desirable goal. 3. Identify two main sources of growth. 4. Explain the “rule of 70.” 5. Give average long-term growth rates for the U.S. and qualifications of raw data. 6. Summarize Global Perspective 8-1. 7. Explain what is meant by a business cycle. 8. Describe the four phases of an idealized business cycle. 9. Identify two types of noncyclical fluctuations in business activity. 10. Describe how innovation and/or random events might cause business cycles. 11. Explain why business cycles affect capital and consumer durable goods industries more than nondurable goods and service industries. 12. Describe how the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) measures unemployment. 13. Evaluate the strengths and limitations of BLS unemployment statistics. 14. State the causes of frictional, cyclical, and structural unemployment. 15. Identify full employment or the natural rate of unemployment. 16. Identify the economic costs of unemployment and the groups that bear unusually heavy unemployment burdens. 17. Define inflation and list two types of inflation. 18. List three groups who are hurt and two groups who may benefit from unanticipated inflation. 19. Present three possible effects of inflation on output and employment. 20. Compare U.S. inflation and unemployment rates to one or more industrialized nations. 21. Define and identify terms and concepts at the end of the chapter. COMMENTS AND TEACHING SUGGESTIONS 1. Many students will benefit from the use of numeric examples (real or hypothetical). A good springboard into the discussion of unemployment is to provide students with a set of profiles of individuals, where information is given as to employment status and reasons for unemployment or lack of participation in the labor force. 2. Most students have a vague idea of what is meant by unemployment or inflation. Few have considered how these problems impact the economy or themselves. Having students collect prices (at the beginning and end of term) not only provides the opportunity to construct a price index and calculate inflation, it also puts them more in tune with market conditions. 120 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability 3. It makes this chapter more relevant to have students find the latest data on these measures. See web-based questions at the end of the chapter or an Internet source such as www.dismal.com. 4. To help students better understand the types of unemployment, you may want to use the following “Concept Illustration” (that appeared in the previous edition’s “Analogies, Anecdotes, and Insights.”) Concept Illustration … Types of Unemployment Imagine a fictitious country named Miniature that has a stable population of 120 people, of which 100 are in the labor force. Of these 100 people, 95 are employed and 5 are unemployed. That means Miniature’s unemployment rate is 5 percent (= 5/100). Suppose we could take a group photo of the unemployed workers each month so as to obtain a continuing record of their monthly numbers and reveal whom they are. By comparing the monthly photos over long periods, we could sort out the types of unemployment occurring in Miniature. Suppose that in a typical month there are 5 people in the photo. Also, suppose that 4 of these people are never the same individuals who were in the photo the previous month and the other person never shows up in the photo for more than two or three consecutive months. We can reasonably conclude that Miniature is experiencing frictional unemployment and structural unemployment. The frictionally unemployed workers are quickly finding jobs, and after retraining or relocation, the structurally unemployed workers are obtaining new jobs within a few months. Taking the places of these formerly unemployed persons are newly unemployed people who are looking for new jobs, waiting for future jobs, retraining, or relocating. Five percent of the labor force is unemployed each month, but nobody is unemployed for any substantial length of time. Miniature is not suffering an “unemployment problem.” In contrast, suppose that over a six-month period we observe that the number of people in the unemployment photo increases from 5 to 10, with no change in the size of the labor force. Thereafter, the 10 percent unemployment rate continues for a full year. A comparison of the monthly photos reveals that it is mainly the same people who are employed month after month. We can reasonably conclude that Miniature is now experiencing cyclical unemployment. Total spending must have declined, reducing production and employment. The increase in the unemployment rate from 5 percent to 10 percent has accompanied this recession. Miniature now has a serious “unemployment problem.” Cyclical unemployment is involuntary, relatively long lasting, and creates serious financial hardship for those people unemployed. It also results in an irretrievable loss of output to society. 5. Table 8-3 can be used to discuss the definition of unemployment and its limitations. Current data to update the table can be found in the Monthly Labor Review, Employment and Earnings, Economic Indicators, or see Web-based question 16. Make it clear that a portion of each unemployment statistic is due to frictional and structural unemployment, which are found even in a “full employment” economy. Frictional unemployment indicates a healthy economy with labor mobility. Structural unemployment is viewed as serious, but not responsive to economic policies alone. 6. Have students consider the losses from unemployment. Perhaps they could write a feature article on losses due to GDP gap, higher inflation, or the social and personal losses incurred by those unemployed. 121 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability 7. Try web-based question 17 for current inflation data. While we have been concerned with inflation since World War II, it is interesting to note that past (and now current) economists have been as concerned about deflation. A good topic is to ask students how deflation can be a problem, as it is in Japan and threatens to be in the U.S. 8. For a deeper understanding of the costs of inflation, you may wish to share the following “Concept Illustration” with your students: Concept Illustration … Costs of Inflation On page 147 examples of the costs of inflation are given. The following metaphors may help you distinguish and remember the three examples listed. Menu costs Inflation requires firms to change the prices they charge from one period to another. This new pricing of products and the communication of the new prices to customers requires time and effort that could otherwise be used for more productive purposes. These inflation costs are sometimes called menu costs, because they are similar to the costs incurred by restaurants that need to print new menus when prices rise. Menu costs include all costs associated with the inflation-caused need to change prices. Yardstick costs Inflation interferes with money functioning as a measure of value and thus requires more time and effort to determine what something is worth (in real terms). Dollar price tags lose some of their meaning when inflation occurs, because the dollar’s value has declined relative to before. It is as if a yardstick that formerly measured 36 inches now measures 34, 33, or even fewer inches. All inflation-caused costs associated with determining real versus nominal values can be thought of as yardstick costs. Shoe-leather costs We have noted that people try to protect their financial assets against erosion from inflation by limiting the amounts of money they hold in their billfolds and in their noninterest-bearing checking accounts, putting those funds instead into interest-bearing saving accounts or stock and bond funds. But people actually need more money to buy the higher priced goods and services. So, they figuratively walk to and from financial institutions much more often in order to move money from these latter accounts to checking accounts or to get cash when it is needed. In the process they wear out their shoes—they incur so-called shoe-leather costs. These costs include all time and resource costs associated with the inflation-induced need to make more financial transactions. 9. The Wall Street Journal is a good source of information on the most current economic situation. They have a “Newspaper-in-Education” program that provides various teaching aids, in addition to favorable subscription rates for students. Call 1-800-JOURNAL contact their website for more information. Among their aids is a stylized Wall Street Journal Education edition, which gives information on dates on which important economic statistics are announced each month or each quarter. Your local newspaper and periodicals may have similar education programs. The Economist includes up-to-date macroeconomic information and presents stories of U.S. macroeconomic policies and conditions that are detailed but accessible. 10. Unemployment and inflation have a human face. A dramatic reading of quotes from a book such as Studs Terkel’s Hard Times can be used to bring statistics to life. You or your students may be acquainted with individuals who lived through the depression years or who have suffered from periods of unemployment. Inviting them to discuss the impact of these experiences also helps to make this material more interesting for students. 122 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability STUDENT STUMBLING BLOCKS 1. This chapter includes lots of descriptive detail. Help your students sort out the forest from the trees—be clear about what you expect them to know from this chapter. 2. Struggling students often have difficulty because they lack very basic math skills. Sometimes, they simply have not used fractions, percentages or decimals lately. Do not take it for granted that college students will be prepared for the simple calculations in this chapter. One skill that is frequently missing is the ability to make reasonable estimates of a correct answer (a ball park guess) without actually crunching the numbers. Give students practice with simple questions first – for example, GDP loss when the unemployment rate is 1% above the natural rate (applying Okun’s Law). Then demonstrate the gap for every 1% beyond that. 3. Students often confuse being “unemployed” with being “not in the labor force.” You may need to stress to some that just because one of their parents is “not employed” (e.g. a homemaker) doesn’t mean they don’t work hard – simply that they don’t work in the paid labor force. Some students will be bothered that those in the underground economy are counted as “not in the labor force” or, in some cases, “unemployed.” Emphasize that the classification is based on the BLS survey and may not accurately represent their true status (such as we do in the discussion of discouraged workers). Keep students from reaching the conclusion that the underground economy is excluded because it produces economic “bads”. It also produces “goods,” just as the measured economy produces “bads.” 4. In anticipation of future chapters, the sections on demand-pull and cost-push inflation will be helpful. Emphasize the analysis of Figure 8-5. It also helps to reinforce Chapter 7’s distinction between nominal and real GDP. 5. Students are often confused between terms like “deflation” (falling prices) and “disinflation” (a falling rate of inflation). There may be similar confusion between “rising prices” and a “rising inflation.” As you look ahead to the policy chapters, you need to decide whether it is better now or later to define disinflation and distinguish between it and deflation, especially given that one is feared and the other is often considered desirable. LECTURE NOTES I. Introduction: This chapter provides an introductory look at trends of real GDP growth and the macroeconomic problems of the business cycle, unemployment, and inflation. II. Economic Growth-How to increase the economy’s productive capacity over time. A. Two definitions of economic growth are given. 1. The increase in real GDP, which occurs over a period of time. 2. The increase in real GDP per capita, which occurs over time. This definition is superior if comparison of living standards is desired. For example, China’s 2001 GDP was $1131 billion compared to Denmark’s $166 billion, but per capita GDP’s wee $890 and $31,090 respectively. 3. Growth in real GDP does not guarantee growth in real GDP per capita. If the growth in population exceeds the growth in real GDP, real GDP per capita will fall. B. Growth is an important economic goal because it means more material abundance and ability to meet the economizing problem. Growth lessens the burden of scarcity. C. The arithmetic of growth is impressive. Using the “rule of 70,” a growth rate of 2 percent annually would take 35 years for GDP to double, but a growth rate of 4 percent annually would only take about 18 years for GDP to double. (The “rule of 70” uses the absolute value 123 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability of a rate of change, divides it into 70, and the result is the number of years it takes the underlying quantity to double.) D. Main sources of growth are increasing inputs or increasing productivity of existing inputs. 1. About one-third of U.S. growth comes from more inputs. 2. About two-thirds comes from increased productivity. E. Growth Record of the United States (Table 8-1) is impressive. 1. Real GDP has increased almost tenfold since 1940, and real per capita GDP has risen over fourfold. (See columns 2 and 4, Table 8-1) 2. The rate of growth record shows that real GDP has grown 3.5 percent per year since 1950 and real GDP per capita has grown 2.3 percent per year. But the arithmetic needs to be qualified. a. Growth doesn’t measure quality improvements. b. Growth doesn’t measure increased leisure time. c. Growth doesn’t take into account adverse effects on environment or human security. d. International comparisons are useful in evaluating U.S. performance. For example, Japan grew more than twice as fast as U.S. until the 1990s when the U.S. far surpassed Japan. (see Global Perspective 8-1). There is also some tendency for growth rates to move together, reflecting the interdependence of the global economy. III. Overview of the Business Cycle A. Historical record. 1. The United States’ impressive long-run economic growth has been interrupted by periods of instability. 2. Uneven growth has been the pattern, with inflation often accompanying rapid growth, and declines in employment and output during periods of recession and depression (see Figure 8-1 and Table 8-2). B. Four phases of the business cycle are identified over a several-year period. (See Figure 8-1) 1. A peak is when business activity reaches a temporary maximum with full employment and near-capacity output. 2. A recession is a decline in total output, income, employment, and trade lasting six months or more. 3. A trough is the bottom of the recession period. 4. A recovery is when output and employment are expanding toward the full-employment level. C. There are several theories about causation. 1. Major innovations may trigger new investment and/or consumption spending. 2. Changes in productivity may be a related cause. 3. Most agree that the level of aggregate spending is important, especially changes on capital goods and consumer durables. D. Cyclical fluctuations: Durable goods output is more volatile than nondurables and services because spending on latter usually cannot be postponed. 124 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability IV. Unemployment (One Result of Economic Downturns) A. Measuring unemployment (see Figure 8-2 for 2002): 1. The population is divided into three groups: those under age 16 or institutionalized, those “not in labor force,” and the labor force that includes those age 16 and over who are willing and able to work, and actively seeking work (demonstrated job search activity within the last four weeks). 2. The unemployment rate is defined as the percentage of the labor force that is not employed. (Note: Emphasize not the percentage of the population.) 3. The unemployment rate is calculated by random survey of 60,000 households nationwide. (Note: Households are in survey for four months, out for eight, back in for four, and then out for good; interviewers use the phone or home visits using laptops.) Two factors cause the official unemployment rate to understate actual unemployment. a. Part-time workers are counted as “employed.” b. “Discouraged workers” who want a job, but are not actively seeking one, are not counted as being in the labor force, so they are not part of unemployment statistic. B. Types of unemployment 1. Frictional unemployment consists of those searching for jobs or waiting to take jobs soon; it is regarded as somewhat desirable, because it indicates that there is mobility as people change or seek jobs. 2. Structural unemployment is due to changes in the structure of demand for labor; e.g., when certain skills become obsolete or geographic distribution of jobs changes. a. Glass blowers were replaced by bottle-making machines. b. Oil-field workers were displaced when oil demand fell in 1980s. c. Airline mergers displaced many airline workers in 1980s. d. Foreign competition has led to downsizing in U.S. industries and a loss of jobs. e. Military cutbacks have led to displacement of workers in military-related industries. 3. Cyclical unemployment is caused by the recession phase of the business cycle, which is sometimes called deficient demand unemployment. 4. It is sometimes not clear which type describes a person’s unemployment circumstances. C. Definition of “Full Employment” 1. Full employment does not mean zero unemployment. 2. The full-employment unemployment rate is equal to the total of frictional and structural unemployment. 3. The full-employment rate of unemployment is also referred to as the natural rate of unemployment. 4. The natural rate is achieved when labor markets are in balance; the number of job seekers equals the number of job vacancies. At the end of the last century the economy’s potential output was being achieved. The natural rate of unemployment is not fixed, but depends on the demographic makeup of the labor force and the laws and customs of the nations. The recent drop in the natural rate from 6% to 4 or 5% has occurred mainly because of the aging of the work force, improved information flows in job markets, work 125 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability requirements enacted with welfare reform, and a doubling of the U.S. prison population since 1985. 5. The natural rate of unemployment is not fixed but depends on the demographic makeup of the labor force and the laws and customs of the nations. 6. Recently the natural rate has dropped from 6% to 4 or 5%. This is attributed to: a. The aging of the work force as the baby boomers approach retirement. b. Improved job information through the Internet and temporary-help agencies. c. New work requirements passed with the most recent welfare reform. d. The doubling of the U.S. prison population since 1985. D. Economic cost of unemployment 1. GDP gap and Okun’s Law: the GDP gap is the difference between potential and actual GDP. (See Figure 8-3) Economist Arthur Okun quantified the relationship between unemployment and GDP as follows: For every 1 percent of unemployment above the natural rate, a negative GDP gap of 2 percent occurs. This is known as “Okun’s law.” 2. Unequal burdens of unemployment exist. (See Table 8-3) a. Rates are lower for white-collar workers. b. Teenagers have the highest rates. c. Blacks have higher rates than whites. d. Rates for males and females are comparable, though females had a lower rate in 2002. e. Less-educated workers, on average, have higher unemployment rates than workers with more education. f. The “long-term” (15 weeks or more) unemployment rate is much lower than the overall rate, although it has nearly doubled from 1.1% in 1999 to 2% in 2002. E. Noneconomic costs include loss of self-respect and social and political unrest. F. International comparisons. (See Global Perspective 8-2) V. Inflation: Defined and Measured A. Definition: Inflation is a rising general level of prices (not all prices rise at the same rate, and some may fall). B. The main index used to measure inflation is the Consumer Price Index (CPI). To measure inflation, subtract last year’s price index from this year’s price index and divide by last year’s index; then multiply by 100 to express as a percentage. C. The “rule of 70” permits quick calculation of the time it takes the price level to double: Divide 70 by the percentage rate of inflation and the result is the approximate number of years for the price level to double. If the inflation rate is 7 percent, then it will take about ten years for prices to double. (Note: You can also use this rule to calculate how long it takes savings to double at a given compounded interest rate.) D. Facts of inflation 126 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability 1. In the past, deflation has been as much a problem as inflation. For example, the 1930s depression was a period of declining prices and wages. The prospect of deflation is a recent concern of economic policymakers. 2. All industrial nations have experienced the problem (see Global Perspective 8-3). 3. Some nations experience astronomical rates of inflation (Angola’s was 4,145 percent in 1996). 4. The inside covers of the text contain historical rates for the U.S. E. Causes and theories of inflation 1. Demand-pull inflation: Spending increases faster than production. It is often described as “too much spending chasing too few goods.” 2. CONSIDER THIS … Clipping Coins a. Princes would clip coins, paying peasants with the clipped coins and using the clippings to mint new coins. b. Clipping was essentially a tax on the population as the increased money supply caused inflation and reduced the purchasing power of each coin. 3. Cost-push or supply-side inflation: Prices rise because of a rise in per-unit production costs (Unit cost = total input cost/units of output). a. Output and employment decline while the price level is rising. b. Supply shocks have been the major source of cost-push inflation. These typically occur with dramatic increases in the price of raw materials or energy. 4. Complexities: It is difficult to distinguish between demand-pull and cost-push causes of inflation, although cost-push will die out in a recession if spending does not also rise. VI. Redistributive effects of inflation A. The price index is used to deflate nominal income into real income. Inflation may reduce the real income of individuals in the economy, but won’t necessarily reduce real income for the economy as a whole (someone receives the higher prices that people are paying). B. Unanticipated inflation has stronger impacts; those expecting inflation may be able to adjust their work or spending activities to avoid or lessen the effects. C. Fixed-income groups will be hurt because their real income suffers. Their nominal income does not rise with prices. D. Savers will be hurt by unanticipated inflation, because interest rate returns may not cover the cost of inflation. Their savings will lose purchasing power. E. Debtors (borrowers) can be helped and lenders hurt by unanticipated inflation. Interest payments may be less than the inflation rate, so borrowers receive “dear” money and are paying back “cheap” dollars that have less purchasing power for the lender. F. If inflation is anticipated, the effects of inflation may be less severe, since wage and pension contracts may have inflation clauses built in, and interest rates will be high enough to cover the cost of inflation to savers and lenders. 1. “Inflation premium” is amount that the interest rate is raised to cover effects of anticipated inflation. 2. “Real interest rate” is defined as nominal rate minus inflation premium. (See Figure 8-6) 127 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability G. Final points 1. Unexpected deflation, a decline in price level, will have the opposite effect of unexpected inflation. 2. Many families are simultaneously helped and hurt by inflation because they are both borrowers and earners and savers. 3. Effects of inflation are arbitrary, regardless of society’s goals. VII. Output Effects of Inflation A. Cost-push inflation, where resource prices rise unexpectedly, could cause both output and employment to decline. Real income falls. B. Mild inflation (<3%) has uncertain effects. It may be a healthy by-product of a prosperous economy, or it may have an undesirable impact on real income. C. Danger of creeping inflation turning into hyperinflation, which can cause speculation, reckless spending, and more inflation (see examples in text of Hungary and Japan following World War II, and Germany following World War I). VIII. LAST WORD: The Stock Market and The Economy: How, if at all, do changes in stock prices relate to macroeconomic stability? A. Do changes in stock prices and stock market wealth cause instability? The answer is yes, but usually the effect is weak. 1. There is a wealth effect: Consumer spending rises as asset values rise and vice versa if stock prices decline substantially. 2. Also, there is an investment effect: Rising share prices lead to more capital goods investment and the reverse in true for falling share prices. B. Stock market “bubbles” can hurt the economy by encouraging reckless speculation with borrowed funds or savings needed for other purposes. A “crash” can cause unwarranted pessimism about the underlying economy. C. A related question concerns forecasting value of stock market averages. Stock price averages are included as one of ten “Leading Indicators” used to forecast the future direction of the economy. (See Last Word, Chapter 12.) However, by themselves, stock values are not a reliable predictor of economic conditions. ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 8-1 Why is economic growth important? Why could the difference between a 2.5 percent and a 3.0 percent annual growth rate make a great difference over several decades? Economic growth means a higher standard of living, provided population does not grow even faster. And if it does, then economic growth is even more important to maintain the current standard of living. Economic growth allows the lessening of poverty even without an outright redistribution of wealth. If population is growing at 2.5 percent a year—and it is in some of the poorest nations—then a 2.5 percent growth rate of real GDP means no change in living standards. A 3.0 percent growth rate means a gradual rise in living standards. For a wealthy nation, such as the United States, with a GDP in the neighborhood of $10 trillion, the 0.5 percentage point difference between 2.5 and 3.0 percent amounts to $50 billion a year, or more than $150 per person per year. 128 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability Using the “Rule of 70,” it would take 28 years for output to double with a 2.5 percent growth rate, and just over 23 years with 3.0 percent growth. 8-2 (Key Question) Suppose an economy’s real GDP is $30,000 in year 1 and $31,200 in year 2. What is the growth rate of its real GDP? Assume that population was 100 in year 1 and 102 in year 2. What is the growth rate of GDP per capita? Growth rate of real GDP = 4 percent (= $31,200 - $30,000)/$30,000). GDP per capita in year 1 = $300 (= $30,000/100). GDP per capita in year 2 = $305.88 (= $31,200/102). Growth rate of GDP per capita is 1.96 percent = ($305.88 - $300)/300). 8-3 Briefly describe the economic growth record of the United States. Compare the rates of growth in real GDP and real GDP per capita, explaining any differences. Compare the average growth rates of Japan and the U.S. between 1992 and 2002. To what extent might growth rates understate or overstate economic well-being? The growth record of the United States, as seen in Table 8-1, shows that real GDP grew from $822 billion in 1929 to $9440 billion in 2002 (14.4% per year), while per capita GDP (in 1996 constant dollars) grew from $6,738 in 1929 to $32,664 in 2002 (5.2% per year). It is evident that real GDP grows more rapidly than real GDP per capita because the population is growing at the same time that GDP is growing. Since GDP per capita is GDP/population, this will show a smaller rate of growth than GDP if the denominator, population, is expanding. Looking at Global Perspective 8-1, we can see that the average annual growth rates of real GDP have been more rapid in the U.S., averaging almost 3 percent in the 1992-2002 period. Meanwhile, Japan’s growth has been sluggish (and negative for three of the years during the period), following years of growth nearly double that of the U.S. The real GDP and per capita real GDP figures may understate economic well-being to the extent they do not fully take into account improvements in product quality; and they take no account at all of the very considerable increase in leisure since 1929. On the other hand, the measures of growth also leave out increases in pollution and the possible increase in stress caused by growth, and also do not measure the extent of inequality in distribution. If inequality is great, many may have less GDP per capita than shown.. 8-4 (Key Question) What are the four phases of the business cycle? How long do business cycles last? How do seasonal variations and secular trends complicate measurement of the business cycle? Why does the business cycle affect output and employment in capital goods and consumer durable goods industries more severely than in industries producing nondurables? The four phases of a typical business cycle, starting at the bottom, are trough, recovery, peak, and recession. As seen in Table 8-2, the length of a complete cycle varies from about 2 to 3 years to as long as 15 years. There is a pre-Christmas spurt in production and sales and a January slackening. This normal seasonal variation does not signal boom or recession. From decade to decade, the long-term trend (the secular trend) of the U.S. economy has been upward. A period of no GDP growth thus does not mean all is normal, but that the economy is operating below its trend growth of output. Because capital goods and durable goods last, purchases can be postponed. This may happen when a recession is forecast. Capital and durable goods industries therefore suffer large output declines during recessions. In contrast, consumers cannot long postpone the buying of nondurables such as food; therefore recessions only slightly reduce nondurable output. Also, capital and durable goods expenditures tend to be “lumpy.” Usually, a large expenditure is needed to purchase them, and this shrinks to zero after purchase is made. 129 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability 8-5 What factors make it difficult to determine the unemployment rate? Why is it difficult to distinguish between frictional, structural, and cyclical unemployment? Why is unemployment an economic problem? What are the consequences of a negative GDP gap? What are the noneconomic effects of unemployment? Measuring the unemployment rate means first determining who is eligible and available to work. The total U.S. population is divided into three groups. One group is made up of people less than 16 years of age and people who are institutionalized. The second group, labeled “not in the labor force” are adults who are potential workers but for some reason—age, in school, or homemakers – are not seeking work. The third group is the labor force, those who are employed and those who are unemployed but actively seeking work. It is not easy to distinguish between these three types and since the unavoidable minimum of frictional and structural unemployment is itself changing, it is difficult to determine the full-employment unemployment rate. For example, a person who quits a job in search of a better one would normally be considered frictionally unemployed. But suppose the former job then disappears completely because the firm is in a declining industry and can no longer make money. Our still jobless worker could now be considered structurally unemployed. And then suppose the economy slips into a severe recession so that our worker cannot find any job and has become cyclically unemployed. The unavoidable minimums of frictional and structural unemployment fluctuate as the labor force structure changes. In other words, there is no automatic label on the type of unemployment when someone is counted as unemployed. Unemployment is an economic problem because of the concept of opportunity cost. Quite apart from any idea of consideration for others, unemployment is economic waste: A unit of labor resource that could be engaged in production is sitting idle. The “GDP gap” is the difference between what the economy could produce at its potential GDP and what it is producing at its actual GDP. The consequence of a negative GDP gap is that what is not produced – the amount represented by the gap—is lost forever. Moreover, to the extent that this lost production represents capital goods, the potential production for the future is impaired. Future economic growth will be less. The noneconomic effects of unemployment include the sense of failure created in parents and in their children, the feeling of being useless to society, of no longer belonging. 8-6 (Key Question) Use the following data to calculate (a) the size of the labor force and (b) the official unemployment rate: total population, 500; population under 16 years of age or institutionalized, 120; not in labor force, 150; unemployed, 23; part-time workers looking for full-time jobs, 10. Labor force 230 500 - 120 150; official unemployme nt rate 10% 23/ 230 100 8-7 Since the U.S. has an unemployment compensation program, which provides income for those out of work, why should we worry about unemployment? The unemployment compensation program merely gives the unemployed enough funds for basic needs. Furthermore, many of the unemployed do not qualify for unemployment benefits. The programs apply only to those workers who were covered by the insurance, and this may be as few as one-third of those without jobs. Most of the unemployed get no sense of self-worth or accomplishment out of drawing this compensation. Moreover, from the economic point of view, unemployment is a waste of resources; when the unemployed go back to work, nothing is forgone except undesired leisure. Finally, unemployment could be inflationary and costly to taxpayers: 130 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability The unemployed are producing nothing—their supply is zero – but the compensation helps keep demand in the economy high. 8-8 (Key Question) Assume that in a particular year the natural rate of unemployment is 5 percent and the actual rate of unemployment is 9 percent. Use Okun’s law to determine the size of the GDP gap in percentage-point terms. If the nominal GDP is $500 billion in that year, how much output is being foregone because of cyclical unemployment? GDP gap = 8 percent [=(9-5)] x 2; forgone output estimated at $40 billion (=8% of $500 billion). 8-9 Explain how an increase in your nominal income and a decrease in your real income might occur simultaneously. Who loses from inflation? Who loses from unemployment? If you had to choose between (a) full employment with a 6 percent annual rate of inflation or (b) price stability with an 8 percent unemployment rate, which would you choose? Why? If a person’s nominal income increases by 10 percent while the cost of living increases by 15 percent, then her real income has decreased from 100 to 95.65 (= 110/1.15). Alternatively expressed, her real income has decreased by 4.35 percent (= 100 - 95.65). Generally, whenever the cost of living increases faster than nominal income, real income decreases. The losers from inflation are those on incomes fixed in nominal terms or, at least, those with incomes that do not increase as fast as the rate of inflation. Creditors and savers also lose. In the worst recession since the Great Depression (1981-82), those who lost the most from unemployment were, in descending order, blacks (who also suffer the most in good times), teenagers, and blue-collar workers generally. In addition to the specific groups who lose the most, the economy as a whole loses in terms of the living standards of its members because of the lost production. The choice between (a) and (b) illustrates why economists are unpopular. Option (a) spreads the pain by not having a small percentage of the population bear the burden of employment. There is the risk, however, that inflationary expectations will give rise to creeping inflation and ultimately hyperinflation; or that the central bank will raise interest rates to reduce inflation, stalling economic growth. If one chooses (b) the central bank will have no cause to raise interest rates and cut off the economic expansion needed to get unemployment down from the unforgivable 8 percent. However, the weakness in spending resulting from an 8% unemployment rate might push the economy into deflation, which would ultimately exacerbate the weak economic conditions. 8-10 What is the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and how is it determined each month? How does the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) calculate the rate of inflation from one year to the next? What effect does inflation have on the purchasing power of a dollar? How does it explain differences between nominal and real interest rates? How does deflation differ from inflation? The CPI is constructed from a “market basket” sampling of goods that consumers typically purchase. Prices for goods in the market basket are collected each month, weighted by the importance of the good in the basket (cars are more expensive than bread, but we buy a lot more bread), and averaged to form the price level. To calculate the rate of inflation for year 5, the BLS subtracts the CPI of year 4 from the CPI of year 5, and then divides by the CPI of year 4 (percentage change in the price level). Inflation reduces the purchasing power of the dollar. Facing higher prices with a given number of dollars means that each dollar buys less than it did before. The rate of inflation in the CPI approximates the difference between the nominal and real interest rates. A nominal interest rate of 10% with a 6% inflation rate will mean that real interest rates are approximately 4%. 131 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability Deflation means that the price level is falling, whereas with inflation overall prices are rising. Deflation is undesirable because the falling prices mean that incomes are also falling, which reduces spending, output, employment, and, in turn, the price level (a downward spiral). Inflation in modest amounts (<3%) is tolerable, although there is not universal agreement on this point. 8-11 (Key Question) If the price index was 110 last year and is 121 this year, what is this year’s rate of inflation? What is the “rule of 70”? How long would it take for the price level to double if inflation persisted at (a) 2, (b) 5, and (c) 10 percent per year? This year’s rate of inflation is 10% or [(121 – 110)/110] x 100. Dividing 70 by the annual percentage rate of increase of any variable (for instance, the rate of inflation or population growth) will give the approximate number of years for doubling of the variable. (a) 35 years ( 70/2); (b) 14 years ( 70/5); (c) 7 years ( 70/10). 8-12 Distinguish between demand-pull inflation and cost-push inflation. Which of the two types is most likely to be associated with a (negative) GDP gap? Which with a positive GDP gap, in which actual GDP exceeds potential GDP? Demand-pull inflation occurs when prices rise because of an increase in aggregate spending not fully matched by an increase in aggregate output. It is sometimes expressed as “too much spending (or money) chasing too few goods.” Cost-push inflation describes prices rising because of increases in per unit costs of production. Cost-push inflation is most likely to be associated with a negative GDP gap, as the rising production costs reduce spending and output. Demand-pull inflation is more likely to occur with a positive GDP gap, because actual GDP will exceed its potential only when aggregate spending is strong and rising. As the economy produces above its potential, bottlenecks and more severe resource scarcity occur, driving up prices. 8-13 Explain how “hyperinflation” might lead to a severe decline in total output. With inflation running into the double, triple, quadruple, or an even greater number of digits per year, it makes little sense to save. The only sensible thing to do with money is to spend it before its value is cut in half within a month, a week, or a day. This very fact of everyone trying to spend as fast as possible will speed the inflationary spiral and cause people to spend more and more time trying to figure out what goods are most likely to go up fastest in price. More and more people will turn away from productive activity, because wages and salaries are not keeping up with inflation. Instead, they will spend their time speculating, transferring goods already in existence and producing nothing. Eventually, money may become worthless. No one will work for money. Barter and living by one’s wits become the only means of survival. Production falls for this reason and also because investment in productive capital practically ceases. Unemployment soars. A massive depression is at hand. 8-14 Evaluate as accurately as you can how each of the following individuals would be affected by unanticipated inflation of 10 percent per year: a. A pensioned railroad worker b. A department store clerk c. A unionized automobile assembly-line worker 132 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability d. A heavily indebted farmer e. A retired business executive whose current income comes entirely from interest on government bonds f. The owner of an independent small-town department store (a) Assuming the pensioned railway worker has no other income and that the pension is not indexed against inflation, the retired worker’s real income would decrease every year by approximately 10 percent of its former value. (b) Assuming the clerk was unionized and the contract had over a year to run, the clerk’s real income would decrease in the same manner as the pensioner. However, the clerk could expect to recoup at least part of the loss at contract renewal time. In the more likely event of the clerk not being unionized, the clerk’s real income would decrease, possibly by as much as the pensioned railroad worker. (c) Since the UAW worker is unionized, the loss in the first year would be the same as in (b) but it is likely—barring a deep recession—that the loss will be made up at contract renewal time plus the usual real increase that may or may not be related to increased productivity. If the contract had a cost-of-living allowance clause in it, the wage would automatically be raised at the end of the year to cover the loss in purchasing power. Next year’s wage would rise by 10 percent. (d) If the inflation is also in the price the farmer gets for his products, he could gain. But more likely the price increases are mostly in what he buys, since farm machinery, fertilizer, etc., tend to be sold by less-competitive sellers with more power to raise their prices. The farmer faces a lot of competition and has to rely on the market price to go up—the farmer has little control over prices on an individual basis. Moreover, if interest rates on the farmer’s new debts have gone up with the prices, the farmer could be even worse off. The other side of the coin is that if no new borrowing is necessary, the inflation will reduce the real burden of the farmer’s debt, because the purchasing power declines on the fixed payments he contracted to make before inflation. (e) The retired executive is in the same boat as the pensioned railroad worker, except that the executive’s income from the bonds or other interest bearing assets is probably greater than that of the worker from the pension. The increase in inflation has most probably been accompanied by rising interest rates, with a proportional drop in the price of bonds. Therefore, the retired executive would suffer a capital loss if he or she decided to cash in some of the bonds at this time and the fixed interest received on these existing bonds is worth less in terms of purchasing power. In other words, the executive, although wealthier than the retired worker, may be affected just as much or more by inflation. (f) Assuming the store owner’s prices and revenues have been keeping pace with inflation, his or her real income will not change unless the costs have risen more than the product prices. 8-15 (Last Word) Suppose that stock prices were to fall by 10 percent in the stock market. All else equal, would the lower stock prices be likely to cause a decrease in real GDP? How might they predict a decline in real GDP? GDP could be reduced if stock owners feel significantly poorer and reduce their spending on goods and services, including investment in real capital goods. However, research indicates that downturns in the stock market have not had major impacts on GDP. A fall in stock prices might signal a change in expectations. Evidence does suggest that there is a link between falling stock prices and future recessions. However, this is only one factor related 133 Introduction to Economic Growth and Instability to predicting recessions and, by itself, a fall in stock prices is not a reliable predictor of recession. 134