* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download New Evidence from ECOWAS Countries Using
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Foreign Direct Investment, Governance and Economic Growth Trilogy: New Evidence from ECOWAS Countries Using Threshold Analysis Threshold By Ibrahim D. RAHEEM* *Department of Economics, University of Ibadan, Ibadan Nigeria. I_raheem @ymail.com. +2347032659866 Using a panel data from 7 Economic Community of West African State (ECOWAS) countries employing Ordinary Least Square (normal and fixed effect) and Threshold Auto Regressive (TAR) model, this study examines the interactive impact of governance on Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) – economic growth nexus. The study finds that FDI is positively related to growth in both normal effect and dynamic effect in the linear regression (OLS). Also, government consumption, Balance of Payment (BOP) and Governance contribute significantly to the growth process of the countries under study. For the non-linear effect (TAR), the study uses governance to act as sample split variable. The study further conducted the Likelihood Ratio test and obtained a value of about 3.326. The implication of the result obtained is that the positive effect of FDI would begin to manifest once governance reaches the threshold level of -1.2. The policy recommendation drawn from this is that policy makers should formulate policies that are not limited to attracting FDI alone but also that of FDI. INTRODUCTION The importance of economic growth cannot be overemphasized. Economic growth has often been used as a deciding factor for membership into group of influential Countries. The literature on economic growth shows diverse channels through which growth can be achieved. A prominent channel is through investment. The role played by externally financed investment in spurring growth is huge. Countries therefore lay emphasis on various efforts to drive Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) Economic growth is driven by certain economic activities which among other things, include policies and directives instituted by the government; as the government policies and institutions that make up the infrastructure of an economy determine investment and productivity, and therefore also determine the wealth of nations. (Jones, 1998). In recent times, developing countries, especially in Africa see the role of FDI as crucial to their development. FDI is seen as an engine of growth as it provides the much needed capital for investment, increases competition in the host country industries, and aid local firms to become more productive by adopting more efficient technology or by investing in human and/or physical capital. FDI contributes to growth in a substantial manner because it is more stable than other forms of capital flows because of its ownership structure1. The benefits of FDI include serving as a source of capital, employment generation, facilitating access to foreign markets, and generating both technological and efficiency spillover to local firms. FDI is the largest source of external finance of developing countries, and the inward stock of FDI in 2000 amounted to around one-third of their GDP, as compared to just 10 percent in 1980 (UNCTAD, 2006). It is expected that by providing access to foreign markets, transferring technology and generally building capacity in the host country firms, FDI will inevitably improve the 1 The minimum required level is 10% as stated by Ayanwale (2007). Hill (2003), OECD (1996) and Adeoye (2009) used the words “control” and “long term” to make distinction between FDI and portfolio investment. integration of the host country into the global economy and foster growth. FDI is seen as a key driver of economic growth and development. FDI not only boosts capital formation but also enhances the quality of capital stock. Though, the importance of FDI has been critized on the basis that it might lead to crowding out effect of the indigenous companies. In addition to this, Hill (2003) posits that FDI might adversely have effects on the host country’s balance of payments and the perceived loss of national sovereignty and autonomy. Though, these criticisms are logical and constructive but it is imperative to state that the benefits outweigh the cost. The empirical evidence to date on the effect of FDI on economic performance, however, is not conclusive. While some studies have indicated a positive impact of FDI on economic growth, other studies report otherwise. A third group of studies suggest that the effect of FDI on a host country's economy is dependent on the country's absorptive capacity in terms of its human capacity, the level of development, and financial development (Borenstein et al. 1998; Hermes and Lensink, 2004; Alfaro et al, 2000). The extent to which FDI contributes to growth depends on several factors. These include rate of savings in the host country, the degree of openness and the level of technological development, among others. FDI will have a positive effect on the growth prospect of the recipient economy if the host country has a high savings rate; an open trade regime and high technology (see Akinlo 2004). A country’s institutional framework that could engender the ideal absorptive capacity that attracts FDI largely lean on good governance. Governance is broadly defined as “the traditions and institutions that determine how authority is exercised in a country” (Kaufmann et al. 2005). However, worthy of note that the relationship between governance and growth is ambiguous in most developing countries which forms the core of Sub-Sahara African countries (SSA), basically because of structural and fiscal constraints as well as attitudinal limitations. Ngov (2011) stated that the definition and the usage of governance remains unclear and differs depending on the users. The virtues of good governance had been highly extolled by several international organizations and numerous claims were made that it is one of the precondition for economic development take off (Litjobo, 2005). A growing volume of available literature suggests that lack of quality governance hinders growth and investment, and aggravates poverty and inequality. In fact, governance problem foils every effort to improve infrastructure, attract investment, and raise educational standards. Weak governance poses a major challenge not only to further gains in development but also to sustain economic growth achieved so far (Roy, 2005). A number of efforts have been put in place by the government to attract FDI inflow into the country. Policies such as tax rebate and holidays, low interest loan, grants, subsidies, increased spending on infrastructure, creation of export processing zones and other concessions have been put in place to attract FDI inflow. It appears that the benefits of such flow might be short lived based on the ability of stakeholders to create an enabling and business friendly environment that can exhibit high level of governance and environments that is free from corruption. The importance of this study emerged from the fact that not much attention has been devoted to the triplex issue of governance, FDI and growth. It is the objective of this study to determine the relationship between governance and FDI-growth nexus. To achieve this, we employ Threshold Auto Regressive (TAR) model as our estimation technique. The advantage of this methodology is its ability to determine the threshold level of governance that would facilitate positive relationship between FDI-growth nexus. Prior to this threshold, the benefit(s) of FDI is “non-existence”. The scope of this study is limited to developing ECOWAS countries2 only so as to avoid bias of any form when developed and developing countries are analysed simultaneously (Mensistu and Adam, 2007). In sum, we are seeking answers to these questions: what is the relationship between governance and FDI on economic growth process of a particular country? What effect 2 The countries are: Benin, Cote d’ Ivoire, Ghana, Nigeria Sierra Leone, Senegal and Togo. The choice of these countries is based on data availability consideration. would other control variables have on economic growth? Is the threshold value of governance achievable? The rest of the study following the introductory part is arranged as follows: section two dwells on some stylized facts on FDI, governance and economic growth in the selected ECOWAS Countries. Section three enumerates both theoretical and empirical issues of the debate. It also gave a brief insight of the various governance indicators. In section four, methodological issues are adequately treated and the result of the study is presented in section five of the study. While section six wraps up the study by giving a conclusion of the study and also to proffer policy recommendations. 2.1 Flows of FDI This section is further divided into three parts. The first part discusses FDI’s flow on the global perspective, a brief historical exposition of FDI into both developed and developing regions of the world would be analysed. The second aspect of this sub-section focuses majorly on developing countries while the last part would be dedicated to selected countries in Africa. Global FDI Flow Table 2.1: Global FDI Flow (inward) as a Percentage of GDP (1970-2010) 1996-99 2000-04 World 100 100 Developing Economies 31.744 27.248 Developed Economies 66.901 69.011 Africa 1.607 2.474 America 24.785 18.833 Asia 18.606 16.871 Europe 39.112 46.152 LDCs 0.644 1.315 Source: Author’s Computation from UNCTADSTAT, 2011 2005-10 100 36.534 64.516 3.993 17.707 22.472 37.939 1.753 Average 100 31.842 66.809 2.691 20.775 19.316 41.068 1.244 From the Table 2.1 above, developed economies had continually had the largest share of the global flow. The reasons attributed to this cannot be far fetched from the well developed and organized infrastructures as well as stable government policies which could b considered as major determinants of FDI. It is not surprising why the developing countries were only able to attract about 32 per cent of the total flow despite the existing policies to attract FDI inflow. Another reason could be linked to their inability to adequately provide pre-requisite determinants of FDI (i.e. infrastructure, well functioning institutions, and stable policies to mention but few). Classifying the flow into regions, Europe recorded the lion share. It recorded an overall 41 per cent of the total flow. This is followed by America, all through the period under study, its share had been relatively stable with an overall average of about 21 per cent. The existence of the “Asian Tigers” helped Asian region to record about 19 per cent. The distribution of the flow has been biased against Africa. This pattern remains palpable in spite of policy initiatives in a number of African countries and the significant improvements in the factors governing FDI flows. These factors include, but are not restricted to, economic reform, democratization, privatization and enduring peace and stability. The possible reason for this can be related to the fact that FDI flow to countries in the region which can boast of natural endowments (Oil and Agricultural product). Therefore, this means that major FDI inflows into Africa are resource seeking FDI. Regional Distribution of FDI The Table 2.2 below clearly depicts that the larger share of the flow to developing countries was recorded in the Asian countries. The region was able to attract over half of the total global flow to developing countries. Asia was able to attract a weighted average of about 53 per cent. America sits on the second step of the ladder with a share value of about 37 per cent. Africa continent as a whole was only able to attract a meagre share as it was unable to attract 10 per cent of the total flow to developing countries. A plausible reason to this might be related to poor governance 3 among others. The same reasons explained above can also be attributed to the case of LDCs. Table 2.2: Share of FDI Flows to developing countries by Region, 1996-2010 (in percent) 1996 - 99 2000 - 04 2005 - 10 1996-2010 Developing Economies 100 100 100 100 Africa 4.818 7.252 9.567 7.212 Caribbean and American 41.140 36.181 32.502 36.608 Asia 51.772 52.688 53.491 52.650 Oceania 0.197 0.102 0.235 0.178 LDCs 2.073 3.777 4.205 3.352 Source: Author’s Computation from UNCTADSTAT, 2011 Pattern of FDI to Selected ECOWAS Countries The table below indicates that the choice of investment by Multinational Corporation is Ghana, which recorded an overall average of about 21 per cent. This is closely followed by Nigeria. Prior to 2005, Nigeria has been in the front seat of recipients of FDI inflow in the continent. However, due to what could be termed “evolutional years (beginning of 2005)”, Ghana took over the position from Nigeria. This then justifies the industrialization plan of the Ghanaian government. Côte d'Ivoire, Togo and Sierra Leone fairly did well as they were able to attract over 10 per cent share of its GDP as FDI inflow. Table 2.3: Share of FDI Flows to developing countries by Region, 1996-2010 (in percent) 1996-1999 2000-2004 2005-2010 1996-2010 Benin 4.085628 7.612007 13.27088 8.322838 Côte d'Ivoire 11.34497 9.592956 11.21472 10.71755 Ghana 8.312584 9.32453 44.99375 20.87695 Nigeria 18.33797 14.79952 23.04146 18.72632 Senegal 8.070866 5.024883 10.79535 7.963699 Sierra Leone 0.258741 10.74927 19.62079 10.2096 3 All the six indicators used by Kauffman et al (1999) Togo Source: 16.68217 Author’s Computation from UNCTADSTAT, 2011 Table 2.4a Country 12.69089 11.59983 Governance Indicator4 for selected ECOWAS Countries Voice and Accountability 1996200320072002 2006 2010 Political Stability 199620032002 2006 20072010 Government Effectiveness 1996200320072002 2006 2010 Benin Cote d' Ivoire 0.7358 0.4334 0.3639 0.2377 0.1464 0.3322 -0.3314 -0.4412 -0.5274 -0.9072 -1.3509 -1.1905 -0.8995 -2.077 -1.6808 -0.5205 -1.2122 -1.2451 Ghana -0.2162 -0.2781 -0.4782 -0.8995 -1.0852 -1.6808 -0.1094 -0.1939 0 Nigeria -0.8999 -0.717 -0.7875 -1.1347 -1.7325 -1.9175 -1.0081 -0.8528 -1.0866 Senegal Sierra Leone 0.1101 0.1522 -0.2491 -0.7043 -0.1825 -0.2263 -0.0568 -0.2397 -0.3955 -1.112 -0.4432 -0.2257 -1.7968 -0.557 -0.1855 -1.474 1.2196 -1.1876 -1.2192 -1.3081 -1.1348 -0.431 -0.685 -0.2273 -1.0974 -1.5471 -1.4453 Togo Table 2.4b Country Benin Cote d' Ivoire Ghana Nigeria Senegal Sierra 4 5.426434 Governance Indicator5 for selected ECOWAS Countries Regulatory Qualities Rule of Law 1996200320071996200320072002 2006 2010 2002 2006 2010 -0.2566 -0.5169 -0.4235 -0.2212 -0.5607 -0.6415 Control of Corruption 1996200320072002 2006 2010 -0.7073 -0.6568 -0.5841 -0.4409 -0.2937 -0.9443 -0.1661 -1.3912 -0.5032 -0.1029 -1.1681 -0.2069 -0.8297 -0.887 -0.1971 -1.08 -0.2363 -1.1002 -0.8996 -0.0637 -0.804 -0.2913 -0.8844 -1.0745 -0.1636 -1.2375 -0.067 -1.3538 -1.4925 -0.0916 -1.3848 -0.1883 -1.141 -1.3533 -0.0563 -1.136 -0.2628 -0.9518 An update version of governance indicator created Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2010) www.govindicators.org 5 An update version of governance indicator created Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2010) www.govindicators.org -1.1569 -0.2187 -1.2023 -0.1718 -0.9806 -1.0989 0.0471 -0.936 -0.5765 -0.8768 Leone Togo -0.5707 -0.7991 -0.8822 -0.6905 -1.028 -0.8735 -0.7101 Source: Authors computation from www.govindicators.org 0.9307 -0.9726 In the governance table above, Benin Republic performed fairly well than others on the average when Voice and Accountability and Political Stability are used as indicators of governance. This is followed by Senegal and Ghana respectively. In terms of political stability, Nigeria, Cote d’Ivoire and Ghana is not encouraging as they sit at the bottom of the ladder. Available data shows that overall, governments of Togo and Nigeria need to improve governance. When governance is measured by regulatory quality, it is imperative to report that Benin led the chart, followed by Ghana and Senegal. The same can also be said for Togo when rule of law and control of corruption are used. In sum, it is can be equivocally be stated that Benin is the only governed country in the ECOWAS sub-region with the best governance indicator. This suggests an open accountable, transparent form of governance that exists in the country. However, Nigeria could be said to be the worst governed country in the ECOWAS sub-region. Thus, it appears that size, political will and strength and high economic growth rate is not a function of good governance. 3 Theoretical and Empirical Literature The theoretical theories underlying the relationship between FDI and growth can be classified into two: the modernization and the dependency theory. The modernization theory is regarded as the pro FDI which can be classified into neoclassical growth and endogenous growth theories. The neoclassical model of growth was first devised by Nobel Prize winning Economist Robert Solow (1956). The model believes that with a sustained increase in capital investment increases the growth rate temporarily: because the ratio of capital to labour goes up but the additional unit of marginal product of additional unit of capital is assumed to decline and the economy eventually moves back to a long-term growth path, while the real GDP growing at the same rate as the workforce plus a factor to reflect improving “productivity”. A “steady-state” growth path is attained when output, capital and labour grow at the same rate, so output per worker and capital per worker are constant. Neoclassical economists believe that to raise an economy’s long term trend rate of growth requires an increase in the supply and an improvement in the productivity of labour and capital. The neoclassical model treats productivity improvements as an “exogenous” variable meaning that productivity is assumed to be independent of capital investment. The endogenous or new growth theory lays more emphasis on human capital as the cause of economic growth. The theory believes that improvements in productivity can be linked to a faster pace of innovation and extra investment in human capital. The theory predicts positive externalities and spill-over effects from development of a high value-added knowledge economy which is able to develop and maintain a competitive advantage in growth industries in the global economy. They believe that the rate of technological progress should not be taken as a given in a growth model. There are potential increasing returns from higher levels of capital investment. The theory emphasizes that private investment in R&D is the central source of technical progress. Protection of property rights and patents can provide the incentive to engage in R&D. investment in human capital (education and training of the workforce) is an essential ingredient of growth. If all the above stated conditions are satisfied, it is expected that the economy will b on the growing trend. The dependency theorist could be termed anti-FDI. They assert that FDI in whatever form will retard the growth process of the economy and thus called for an end to FDI as it is not favourable. This can be justified by the work of Rand and Tarp (2002) who found that FDI inflows are very volatile. In their assessment of the relationship between FDI and output, there is no general relationship between the two variables. Falki (2009) examined the Impact of FDI on Economic Growth of Pakistan and who concluded that FDI has negative statistically insignificant relationship between GDP and FDI inflows in Pakistan. In a similar dimension, Carkovic and Levine (2002) analyzed the relationship between FDI and Growth by constructing a panel data set for 72 countries for a period of seven five- year periods between 1960 and 1995. Their study finds that the exogenous component of FDI does not exert a positive, robust influence on economic growth though it was stated that their result was not a call for an end in the flow of FDI. Thus, the unsettled argument in the two camp might have necessitated varying results as regards the impact of FDI on growth hence, leading to an inconclusive debate on the FDIgrowth nexus. Good governance would include an effective, impartial and transparent legal system that protects property and individual rights; public institutions that are stable, credible and honest; and government policies that favor free and open markets (Chandra and Yokoyama, 2011). These conditions encourage FDI and presumably private domestic investment as well, by protecting privately held assets from arbitrary direct or indirect appropriation. Generally, “good governance” indicators have six dimensions: i) Voice & Accountability, ii) Political Stability and Lack of Violence/Terrorism, iii) Government Effectiveness, iv) Regulatory Quality, v) Rule of Law, and vi) Control of Corruption (Kaufmann et al., 1999). Different organizations have offered dissimilar means of measuring governance and as such this study will limit its scope to just six indicators: Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA); International Country Risk Guide (ICRG); Freedom House indicator; Transparency International and World Bank (KKZ) governance indicator. It is important to note that Transparency International limit its definition of governance to just corruption while others define governance in a broader sense. Chandra and Yokoyama (2011) contributed to this debate by exploring the role of good governance in promoting knowledge based indicator (KBI) as the cause of the positive relationship in the FDI-growth nexus. KBI was measured through the use of Knowledge Index and Knowledge Economy Index. It was concluded that there is a positive relationship between good governance and KBI. Thus, it is expected that this will influence the positive impact of FDI on growth. Brusse and Griozard (2006) captured governance with government regulations (business and labour regulations) based their analysis on 84 countries that span through the period of 19942003. It was asserted that governance in also a major determinant of FDI aside from education attainment level and financial market development as raised by Borensztein et al. (1998) and Alfaro et al (2000) respectively. The positive impact of FDI on growth is conditioned upon the fact that “…governments first have to tackle the institutional setting and regulatory framework in their countries”. Other studies employ more specific measures of governance. Hellman, Jones and Kaufman (2002) find that corruption reduces FDI inflows for a sample of transition economies. Carstensen and Toubal (2003) use a macroeconomic risk ranking found in Euromoney to estimate a panel data model of the determinants of FDI into Central and Eastern European countries. The less risky the country by the Euromoney ranking, the more attractive is the country for FDI. As sited in Globerman, Shapiro and Tang (2004), a variable related to governance that has also been identified as an important determinant of FDI is privatization. Holland and Pain (1998) identify the privatization process as one of the key determinants of the level of direct investment in the early years of transition. Specifically, for eleven European economies for the period 1992-1996, they find that indicators of privatization are positively related to levels of inward FDI. Carstensen and Toubal (2003) also find that the level of privatization plays an important role in determining the flows of FDI into a sample of Central and Eastern European countries over the period of the 1990s. Globerman, Shapiro and Tang (2004) in their work on the determinant of both inward and outward FDI concluded that the importance of governance on FDI and economic growth relationship as it is very important in attracting FDI in whatever form. It should also be noted that outward FDI should not be seen as a cause of poor and/or low level of governance rather “…as part of a process that promotes international specialization of production and trade with the associated efficiency gains that economists traditionally associate with economic specialization”. Ford, Sen and Wei (2010) considered a disaggregated governance indicator and used china as a case study for a sample period of 1970 to 2005. Both Two Stage Least Square (TSLS) and Generalised Method of Moment (GMM) were adopted. The result reached was that all the disaggregated form of governance is beneficial to economic growth. Trade liberalization and government expenditure on education are the two government policy that has influence on FDI. However, it was concluded that even in the face of good governance, FDI has no positive impact on growth. Farooque, Yarram and khandaker (2009) based their argument on a sample of 173 countries and the time frame was from 1996 to 2007 adopted both OLS and TSLS as estimation technique. The result indicated that both FDI and governance are interdependent i.e. they are co-deterministic. The same result was reached when there was control for time, region and income factors. A possible reason for difference in results by previous researchers could be related the arguments raised by Blonigen and Wang (2005) who showed importance of controlling for country-specific effects in cross national studies. In order to take this into consideration, this study takes cue from the works of Mengistus and Adams (2007) and Nath (2005) by employing dynamic fixed effects estimation approach to examine the effect of FDI dependence on economic growth in the selected developing countries. In sum, there is consensus in the literature about the positive impact of governance on growth. This means good governance leads to economic growth. However, there are diverse views about the impact of FDI on growth. The literature on governance, FDI and growth limited which requires further research. Figure 1: Conceptual framework of governance, FDI and economic growth Governance Growth FDI inflow Source: Authors graphical explanations. The figure above depicts the relationship between Governance, FDI and Growth. The black arrows show there is a unidirectional relationship between the variables which run from governance – attraction of FDI inflow – economic growth. This relationship precedes the red arrows. The red arrows could be term second other condition which shows bi-directional relationship amongst the relationship. 4 Methodology It is the objectives of this study to capture both the linear and non-linear (TAR) growth model. Hence, we begin our analysis with the linear growth model. This paper serves as a follow up to the works of (Mengistus and Adams, 2007; Nath, 2005; and Hermes and Lensink, 2003 to mention a few). The empirical analysis is based on a panel data set of 7 ECOWAS member countries over a period of 15 years (1996 - 2010) Linear Growth Regression We estimate a cross-section regression of the form; 𝑌𝑖𝑡= 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 𝑋𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽2 𝑍𝑖𝑡 + 𝜇𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 (1) Where Yit is measured by GDP per Capita growth rate, for country i and at time t. X is a vector variable set that contains trade openness (BOP), Stock of human capital (SCH) and foreign direct investment (FDI). Z is an additional vector variable set which are considered as determinant of growth (Barro, 1991) and they include government consumption (GOC), inflation (INF), and proxy for governance (GOV). μi represent country specific effects which is assumed to be time invariant and 𝓔it is the error term. The fixed effect specification allows us to control for unobserved country heterogeneity and the associated omitted bias, a problem that seriously afflicts cross-sectional country regression (Mengistus and Adams, 2007). Non-Linear Growth Regression To the best of our knowledge, no previous studies have captured the threshold effect of governance on FDI-growth nexus. Hence, we estimate the growth regression of the form; Yit = αXit +α2 Zit + β1FDIt + ε1, GOV ≤ γ Β2FDIt + ε2, GOV ˃ γ (2) Equation 2 can be re-written in the following form; Y it = β1 FDI it DM (GOV it≤ γ1) + β2 FDI it DM (GOVit > γ2) + θ’ X it + εit + μi (3) Where all variables remain has earlier defined with the exception that GOV is no longer a variable in the Z vector and DM represent Dummy variable which is equal to 1 if GOV> γ or 0 if otherwise. GOV serves as sample split in the growth equation. This means once GOV reach the threshold value, the perceived benefits of FDI on growth will start to manifest. Until then the cause of economic growth (if any) is not attributed to FDI. Data Measurement The choice of our variables was informed by previous studies such as (Borensztein et al, 1998; Alfaro et al, 2003; Hermes and Lensink, 2003; Blonigen and Wang, 2005 and Mengistus and Adams, 2007). It is of our view that the variable of interest in this study is FDI and it is measured as total FDI inflow as a percentage of GDP. As a result of augmenting the low savings rate in the host country, it is expected that FDI will propel economic growth. Trade openness (export minus import) which is measured as a percentage of GDP reflects the degree to which an economy liberalizes its borders with trading partners’. Positive trade openness will lead to economic growth because it means the country is exporting more than its import of goods and services. Human capital is proxied by a percentage of total population. Economic growth and human capital are positively related because a higher rate of human capital will improve the productivity level of the host country. Inflation is also measured in percentages and it captures the macroeconomic stability. Inflation-economic growth nexus exhibit a negative relationship because higher inflation rate reduces real income and hence, making the economy worse-off. We include government consumption to determine the level of government involvement in the economy. It is expected that there is a negative relationship between economic growth and government consumption. This is because GOC crowds out private participation. It is conventional in the literature to assess economic growth by the use to GDP. Finally, governance6 is computed by using the average of the six indicators of KKM. Data sources and aprioir expectation are presented in the Appendix section. 5 Empirical Result Linear Growth Equation We presented our growth regression in the appendix section as indicated in Table 2. FDI is positively related to GDP in both OLS and Fixed- effects estimation with 5 and 10% level of significance respectively. We included the lagged value of both FDI and GDP in order to capture the dynamic effect of the. The result of the dynamic effects confirms the positive relationship in the FDI and growth nexus which is both significant at 5% level of significance. Table 5.1: Linear Equation Regression Result Variables OLS FIXED EFFECT NORMAL EFFECT DYNAMIC EFFECT NORMAL EFFECT DYNAMIC EFFECT FDI 0.2531* -0.6779 0.0038** -0.6458 INF -0.0376* 0.0537 -0.0909** 0.0198* GOC 0.5913* 0.2800 0.3918 0.0358** BOP 0.2496** 0.0179* 0.2935 0.0259* GOV 2.9984* 0.3185** 6.0699 -0.2471 FDTt-1 0.9317* 0.9572* GDPt-1 0.439** 0.4366** R2 0.1441 0.3295 0.1606 0.3472 DW 1.104 2.2863 1.1755 2.3577 6 The governance index we use was first developed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton (1999a and 1999b), and recently expanded upon and updated by Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2003). They estimate six separate indices (which we will refer to as KKM indices) including measures of political instability, rule of law, graft, regulatory burden, voice and political freedom, and government effectiveness. The indices have been estimated (using an unobserved components model) employing 31 different qualitative indicators from 13 different sources, including BERI, DRI/McGraw Hill, the Heritage Foundation, the World Bank, the World Economic Forum and the Economist Intelligence Unit. The indices are highly correlated with each other such that it is very difficult to use them all in a single equation (Globerman, Tang and Shapiro, 2004). We measure it by finding the average of the fist component (estimate) of the six indicators created by KKM. This is in contrast to how Globerman, Tang and Shapiro (2004) who aggregated the indicators. If this is done in for the selected countries, it would be found that the aggregate would exceed the range (-2.5 to 2.5) used by Kauffman et al as measuring yardstick. The result confirms the apriori expectation of the negative relationship between INF and economic growth in both OLS and fixed-effects estimation which is significant at 5%. This confirms the results of Romer and Romer (1998). Government consumption is positively related and significant to growth in our OLS estimation. However, this ceases to be the case for fixedeffects estimation and result obtained was not significant. This negates the assertion of Barro (1991) who opined that increase in government consumption is related to decline in the rate of economic growth. The effect of trade openness on growth is positive and mostly statistically significant. Thus, a favourable the balance of payment enhances the growth process. The effect of governance on economic growth is positive and significant for our OLS estimation. This confirms the assertion of (Chandra and Yokoyama, 2011; Ndulu and O’Connell, 1999; Rodrik, 2006) who all stated institution plays a major role in the growth process of a country because it ensures formation of property rights and efficient allocation of resources. In addition, North (1996) affirm that “…it may indeed be the single most important determinant of economic performance after capturing for efficient markets”. Non-Linear Growth Equation For this section, our estimation is based solely on OLS as we neglect Fixed and dynamic-effects. A repeated estimation of equation 3 was done using different values for our sample split, it was found that the threshold level of governance for the positive relationship in the FDI-growth nexus is about -1.2. Until this threshold is achieved, governance has no role to play in the nexus. When the significance test proposed by Hansen (2000) was carried out, the Likelihood Ratio obtained was 3.3263 which then led us to state that the threshold value of governance is not statistically significant at 1% and 5% in Hansen’s Asymptotic Critical Value. The reason(s) for this is hard to explain. Thus, this is a cause for future research. This result is presented in table 3 in the appendix section. Table 5.2: Variable Non-Linear Equation Regression Result Coefficients S.E T Stat fdi*(gov<-1.2) 6.433174 1.121624 5.735589 fdi*(gov>-1.2) -0.15322 0.477989 -0.32055 inf 0.018048 0.048276 0.373843 LR Value goc 0.868842 0.267627 3.246468 R-squared 0.626128 gov 0.886712 1.375348 0.644718 Sum squared resid 524.3167 bop 0.207706 0.077401 2.683515 6 3.3263 Conclusion This study examines the triplex issue of FDI, Governance and Economic Growth in seven ECOWAS Countries from 1996 -2010. Our linear equation result confirms positive impact of FDI and Governance on economic growth process. Thus, it should be emphasized that policy makers should formulate policies that is not limited to attracting FDI but also those that are could improve governance in the country. Trade openness and government consumption follow the expected impact and are significant. Our TAR result estimated a threshold value for governance to be -1.2 though, this is not statistically significant at the 5% level. REFERENCES Ade Oyedijo Akinlabi, Babatunde Hammed and Awoniyi M. A (2011) “Corruption, Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Nigeria: An Empirical Investigation” Journal of research in International Business Management Vol. 1(9) pp. 278-292 Alfaro, L., Areendam, C, Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and Sayek S. (2004) “FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of the Financial Markets”, Joumai of Intemational Economics, 64(1): 89 - 112. Asiedu, E. ( 2002) “ On the determinants of FDI to developing countries: Is Africa different?” World Development 30 (1): 107-119. Ayanwale, A. (2007) “FDI and Economic Growth: Evidence from Nigeria”. AERC Research Paper 165. African Economic Research Consortium, Nairobi Barro R.J (1991) “Economic growth in a cross section of countries”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, No. 2. (May); 407-443 Barro, R. (1991) “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407 - 443. Berhanu Mengistus and Samuel Adams (2007) “FDI, Governance and Economic Development in Developing Countries”, The Journal of Social, Political and Economics Studies. Vol. 32 Number, 2 pp 213-241 Borensztein, E., J., De Gregorio, J. W. and Lee, J. W. (1998) “How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?” Journal of International Economics, 45(1): 115 - 135. Carstensen, Kai and Farid Toubal (2003), “Foreign Direct Investment in Central and Eastern European Countries: A Dynamic Panel Analysis”, Kiel Institute for World Economies, mimeo. Debnath Sajit Chandra and Kenji Yakoyama (2011) “The role of good governance in the knowledgebased economic growth of East Asia- A study on Japan, Newly Industrialized Economies, Malaysia and China” pp23-49 Ezeoha, A and Cattaneo, N (2011) “FDI flow to Sub-Saharan Africa: The Impact of Finance, Institution and Natural Resource Endowment”, CSAE Conference 2011: Economic Development in Africa Global Development Finance (2005) “Financial flows to developing countries: Recent Trends and near-Term prospects”, Washington, DC: World Bank. Globerman, s. and Shapiro, D. (2002) “Governance Infrastructure and U.S. Foreign Direct Investment”. Journal of International Business Studies. May: 1-36 Globerman, Steven & Shapiro, Daniel (1999), “The impact of government policies on foreign direct investment: the Canadian experience”, Journal of International Business Studies, 30 (3), 513532. Hellman, Joel, Geraint Jones and Daniel Kaufman (2002), “Far From Home: Do Foreign Investors Import Higher Standards of Governance in Transition Economies?” , Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, mimeo. Hermes, N. and Lensink, Robert. (2003) “Foreign Direct Investment, Financial Development and Economic Growth”, Journal of Development Studies, 40(1): 142-153. Holland, Dawn and Nigel Pain (1998), “The Determinants and Impact of Foreign Direct Investment in the Transition Economies” in V. Edwards, ed., Convergence or Divergence: Aspirations and Reality in Central and Eastern Europe and Russia, Centre for Research into East European Business, University of Buckingham. J. L Ford, Somnath Sen, Hong Xu Wei (2010) “A simultaneous equation model of economic growth, FDI and Government Policy in China”, Department of Economics discussion paper. pp1-48 Kaufmann, D & Kraay, A (2002) “Growth without Governance”. 5th Economia Panel Meeting, held at Harvard University. The World Bank (July) Kaufmann, D, Kraay, A and Massimo Mastruzzi. (2005). "Governance Matters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996- 2004." World Bank Policy Research Paper. No. 3630: 1-60 Kottaridi, C. (2005) “FDI, Growth and the Role of Governance: Changing the Rules of the Game”, Contributions to Political Economy, 24: 79 - 98. Matthias Busse and Jose Luis Groizar (2006) “FDI, Regulations and Growth” pp 1-26 Nath Hiranya (2005) “Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and Growth: Evidence from Transition Economies”. SHSU Economics and International Business Working paper No. SHSU_Eco_WP05_04. Sam Houston State University, Huntsville, Texas Ndulu, B. J. and O'Connell, S, A. (1999) “Governance and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(1): 41 - 66. North, D. (1996) “Privatization, Incentives and Economic Performance”. In T. Anderson & P. Hill (Eds.), The Privatization Process: A Worldwide Perspective, pp. 25-37. Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc. Nunnenkamp, P. and Spatz, Julius, (2004) “FDI and Economic Growth in Developing Economies: How Relevant is Host-Economy and Industry Characteristics?” Transnational Corporations, 13(1): 5486. Omar Al Farooque, Subba Reddy Yarram and Sarod Khandaker (2010). “International Evidence on Governance and Foreign Direct Investment Interactions” pp1-35 Raghavan, Chakravarthi (2000) “Development: FDI Useful Only When Hosts Control, Direct, and Regulate”. South North Development Monitor No. 4621. Geneva, Switzerland. Romer, C. & Romer, D. (1998) “Monetary Policy and the Weil-Being of the Poor.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 793. Cambridge, Massachusetts.Schneider, Patricia H. Roy, D.K. (2005) “Governance and Development: The Challenges for Bangladesh." The Bangladesh Development Studies Vol. XXXI, Nos. 3 & 4(Sep-Dec): 99-136. Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies Zhang, K. H. (2001) “Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Economic Growth? Evidence from East Asia and Latin America”, Contemporary Economic Policy, 19(2): 175 – 185 APPENDIX Table 1 Variables, Symbols, Sign and Sources of Data Collection Variable Symbol Sign Source of Data Economic Growth GDP + World Development Indicator Foreign Direct Investment FDI + World Development Indicator Trade Openness BOP + United Nations Conference on Trade And Development Government Consumption GOC - World Development Indicator Governance GOV + www.govindicator.org Inflation INF - World Development Indicator