* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download 1 - EcoMod
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
DRAFT How Can Public Spending Help You Grow? An Empirical Analysis for Developing Countries1 Nihal Bayraktar Penn State University and World Bank and Blanca Moreno-Dodson World Bank December 16, 2009 Abstract: Many endogenous growth models introduce public spending or its components as determinants of economic growth. Even though many empirical studies indicate that both level and composition of public spending are significant for economic growth, the results, however, are still mixed. We try to understand the importance of sample selection to explain these conflicting results. Public spending can be a significant determinant of growth for countries that are capable of using expenditures for productive purposes. We investigate a set of fast-growing developing countries versus a mix of developing countries with different growth patterns. In the regression specifications, we include different components of public expenditure and fiscal revenues, always considering the overall government budget constraint. Total public spending is disaggregated using a definition based on Bleaney, Kneller, and Glemmell (2001), and Kneller, Bleaney and Gemmell (1998), which classifies public spending as productive versus unproductive components (a priori). The empirical analysis shows that the link between public spending, especially its productive components, and growth is strong only for the fast-growing group. The most important factor that affects the magnitude of the influence of public spending on growth is the priority given to productive over other spending. In addition, macroeconomic stability, openness, and private sector investment are also significant in the fast-growing group, which points out to the existence of complementarities between private and public sector spending. JEL codes: H50, O11, O23 Key words: Public spending, productive expenditure, government budget, economic growth 1 The authors would like to thank Pierre Richard Agénor, Professor at the University of Manchester and Center for Growth and Business Cycles Research; Vito Tanzi, former IMF Fiscal Affairs Department Director; and Gilles Nancy, Professor at the University of Aix-Marseille II, for their helpful comments. 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Even though, in many studies, it has been shown that total public spending and some of its components are significant for economic growth, the results are still mixed. We try to understand the importance of country sample selection to explain these conflicting results. We conclude that public spending can be a significant determinant of growth for countries that are capable of using expenditures for productive purposes. As a follow up to a previous study2, this paper investigates empirically how the impact of public spending on growth varies when countries are classified according to their overall growth performances. The analysis compares fast-growing versus a mix of countries with different growth patterns. Seven countries are included in each group and the dataset covers the period of 1970-2006. In the regression specifications, we include different components of public expenditure and fiscal revenues, always applying the overall government budget constraint. A priori, while the size of the government does not appear to be much different (on average) in these two groups, the composition of public expenditures varies significantly. The share of productive public spending is much larger for the fast-growing countries in our dataset, while the share of unproductive components of public spending is higher in the comparison group. The empirical analysis based on OLS and dynamic GMM techniques for panel data shows that the link between public spending, especially its productive component, and growth, after controlling for other macroeconomic and private sector variables, and taking into account country initial conditions, is both economically and statistically strong only for the fast-growing group. When all countries are combined in the same regression analysis, the link between government spending and growth gets much weaker on average and even turns negative in some cases. However, when group effects in the combined set are controlled for, through interactive dummies, the stronger link between public spending and growth in the fast-growing group is clearly confirmed. A possible nonlinear relationship between growth and public spending is also investigated but no statistical significance is found for it. Our study shows that the most important factor that affects the degree of influence of public spending on growth is the priority given to productive over other spending. In addition, macroeconomic stability, openness, and private sector investment are also significant in the fast-growing country group, which points out to the existence of complementarities between private and public sector spending. A final implication of the analysis is that differences in empirical findings of the previous literature linking public spending and economic growth may be explained by the selection of countries included. 2 Moreno-Dodson (2008) shows that the volume of total public spending as well as its composition are relevant in explaining economic growth for a set of fast-growing developing countries during 1970-2004. 2 I. INTRODUCTION The importance of public spending and its components on economic growth has been extensively studied in the literature. Within an endogenous growth framework, in 1990 Barro introduced public services in the production function. Many empirical studies have followed this seminal paper to investigate the possible link between different components of government spending and growth, using many different econometric techniques, empirical settings, and samples of countries. Results presented in the literature are mixed. Even though most studies support the substantial positive link between some components of public spending and growth, there is still no agreement on which categories of spending promote growth. The introduction of advanced econometric techniques and new variables in the empirical specifications could not solve the problem. One possible explanation for the mixed results obtained in the literature is sample selection. What we expect is that public spending can improve growth performance of countries only if they are able to use these expenditures productively. In light of this expectation, we raise the following questions: (1) Are there any obvious differences between fast-growing countries and others, in terms of the level of public spending, its components, and their link to growth? (2) Is the link between public spending and growth stronger for countries experiencing higher and sustained growth rates? (3) How different are public spending and its link to economic growth in other developing countries where growth records are less impressive? (4) Why do we observe differences in the response of growth to public spending among countries with a similar level of government spending? (5) What is the role of the composition of public spending on the growth performance of countries? Given that many governments in developing countries are considering increasing public spending to provide a short-term economic stimulus in the midst of the current global economic crisis, we believe that the questions above are more relevant than ever. Indeed, they have important implications for changes in the composition of public expenditure, to the extent that different allocations may involve dynamic tradeoffs in their short- and medium-term impact on growth. In addition to these questions, a possible nonlinear link between public spending and growth (also studied in the previous paper) is analyzed. It is important to see whether the link between different components of public expenditure and growth is statistically significantly positive or not. But the shape of the function is also essential for policy implications. For example, if the link between public spending and growth is positive and concave, higher and higher public spending may have less and less impact on growth. On the other hand, if the link is positive and convex, we expect higher public spending to lead to an even relatively larger effect on growth. In order to capture possible nonlinear effects, the square terms of public spending are introduced in the empirical model in a dynamic growth context.3 3 Another type of nonlinearities associated with the effect of government spending on growth relates to threshold effects. In particular, there is growing evidence that spending on infrastructure may be subject to 3 The analysis presented in this paper is applied to a sample including seven fast-growing developing countries (the same group considered in Moreno-Dodson [2008]) 4 and seven other developing countries whose growth rate patterns have been somehow less stable and consistent during the period of analysis. The first set contains Korea, Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia, Botswana, and Mauritius, which have been among the top performers in the world in terms of GDP per capita growth during the period between 1960 and 2006.5 The second set includes Chile, Costa Rica, Mexico, Philippines, Turkey, Uruguay and Venezuela, and is taken as a comparison group to enhance and validate the econometric estimates of Moreno-Dodson (2008) and to further examine the influence of public expenditures on growth.6 The paper presents a comparative analysis of the countries and panel regressions conducted using OLS and dynamic GMM techniques. Since we use annual data, the focus of the OLS results is on the short-run analysis, while the GMM results focus on a dynamic, multi-year framework. The paper is structured as follows. Section II presents the literature review. Section III presents the data and provides relevant facts and information about the two groups of countries during the period of analysis. Section IV describes the empirical methodology, function specification, and variables selected. Section V is dedicated to the results obtained with the panel regression analysis. Finally, Section VI draws policy implications and concludes. II. LITERATURE REVIEW Despite the fact that the link between public expenditure and economic growth has been investigated extensively in the literature, robust conclusions have been difficult to establish. Even though, in recent studies, there is some convergence in terms of the significance of public spending on growth, the results still change from country to country, or from sample to sample, and can be a function of many different factors. Some of the early empirical studies suggest that the link between public expenditure and growth is positive. In his very influential paper, Barro (1990) extends the endogenous growth framework including tax-financed government services. He concludes that “critical mass” or “network” effects, which imply that its impact on growth becomes significant (or is magnified) beyond a certain level; see for instance Pushak, Tiongson, and Varoudakis (2007) and Kellenberg (2009). However, this type of nonlinearities is mostly associated with the stock of public assets, rather than spending flows, as we discuss here. 4 Moreno-Dodson (2008) empirically investigates the impact of public spending and its components on economic growth, focusing on a sample of seven fast-growing developing countries. She finds that some components of public expenditure, particularly those considered “productive,” can significantly explain economic growth. Despite the fact that there are some differences at the country level, the results are consistent across different econometric techniques used to estimate the statistical significance of public spending items. 5 All the countries selected in the sample have sustained GDP per capita growth rates of at least 3% (by decade average) during 1960-2006. 6 It should be noted that the availability of data for the period of analysis has played an important role in selecting these countries. 4 government expenditure is positively linked to economic growth when the share of government expenditure (and consequently the tax rate) is low, but then turns negative due to increasing inefficiencies as the share of expenditure increases (related to the disincentive effect of higher tax rates on private capital accumulation), indicating a nonlinear relationship between government expenditure and growth.7 In a similar setting, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) show that if social returns on public investment are larger than private returns, public investment can increase economic growth. Barro (1991) tests empirically the link between government expenditure and growth, using cross-country analysis and including 98 developing countries for the period of 1960-1985. The study finds that public consumption is negatively correlated with growth, while public investment does not have a significant impact on economic development. Studies including both developed and developing countries also present similar results. Grossman (1990), using a sample consisting of 48 developed and developing countries, shows that government spending has both positive and negative impacts on growth; the positive one works through higher productivity and the negative one is caused by inefficient provision and distortionary effects of public taxation. However, he concludes that the positive influence dominates. There are also early studies indicating the opposite. Levine and Renelt (1992) also show that taking into account the components of government spending can make a difference. In their paper, they separate government spending in two broad categories, consumption expenditure and investment outlays. For 119 developed and developing countries during the period of 1974 to 1989, they find a negative relationship between government consumption and growth, but a clear positive link between public investment and growth. Empirical studies also show that not only the level of public spending but also its composition matters for economic growth. An empirical study of Easterly and Rebelo (1993), using a sample similar to the one used by Barro (1991), finds that public investment in communication and transportation as well as general government investment promotes economic growth. Glomm and Ravikumar (1997) review some of the papers studying the influence of productive government expenditures on long-run growth and conclude that government expenditures on health, education and infrastructure have large impacts on growth. Similarly, the results presented by Kneller, Bleaney, and Gemmell (1999) and Bleaney, Gemmell, and Kneller (2001), where 22 developed countries are included, support Barro (1990): productive expenditure is good for growth, but distortionary taxes lower its impact. When we focus on most recent studies, conflicting results still continue to be found. One of the recent papers by Schaltegger and Torgler (2006) suggests that large public expenditure lowers growth for high-income countries. Folster and Henrekson (2001) suggest that the more the econometric problems that are addressed, the more robust the link between government size and economic growth gets, while Agell, Ohlsson, and Thoursie (2006) object to this finding, indicating that there is no robust relationship between growth and the share of government expenditure. In his paper, Park (2006) tests whether the combination of productive public investment and lower taxes increases growth and whether current government consumption and higher taxes lower it. He 7 See Slemrod (1995) for the literature review on the link between government expenditure, taxes, and growth. 5 cannot find any robust empirical results using a set of countries combining both developed and developing countries. Gupta, Clements, Baldacci, and Mulas-Granados (2002) show that government expenditure, especially its capital component, has a positive impact on growth for developing countries when it is combined with a lower budget deficit. Similarly, Wahab (2004) and Colombier (2009), focusing on OECD countries, and Ang (2009), studying the case of Malaysia all support the significance of public capital expenditure for growth. In an empirical setting similar to our setting, Ghosh and Gregoriou (2008) show that the current component of spending has a positive impact on growth, while the capital component influences it negatively for a group of 15 developing countries. In a paper where a similar empirical setting and econometric methodologies are used, Bleaney, Gemmell, and Kneller (2001) show that the productive component of public spending, including capital expenditures, is significant for growth in OECD countries. While most empirical studies in the literature use a heterogeneous sample of countries to investigate the relationship between government spending and growth, Moreno-Dodson (2008) includes only fast-growing developing countries and shows that the link between total public spending and growth is overall positive with some components of public spending being particularly significant in affecting growth. For this group of countries, unproductive components of public expenditure are less effective8—or even have a negative impact on growth—while the productive component of public spending is statistically significantly. 9 Our paper extends this initial empirical study in a way to answer the question of whether the findings presented in that paper are sensitive to country sample selection bias. We try to accomplish this goal by extending the initial data set and including a mix of countries with different growth performances. We also try to identify, in a dynamic setting, whether the links among government spending, its components, and growth are linear or not when all countries are either investigated or combined separately. Similarly, the empirical specification introduced in the paper includes the government budget constraint to avoid biases associated with incomplete specification ignoring financing options of governments and budget balance, in line with other recent papers in the literature.10 8 Defined a priori using the definition by Bleaney, Gemmel , and Kneller (2001) and and Kneller, Bleaney and Gemmell (1998). 9 Similarly, Rogers (2008) shows that the impact of public schooling expenditures on economic growth is significantly higher in countries that are considered to use schooling productively. 10 For example, Bose, Haque, and Osborn (2007) introduce government financing variables (government budget surplus/deficit and tax revenue) in a study where they focus on a panel of 30 developing countries over the 1970s and 1980s. They find that while the capital component of government expenditure, especially education expenditure, is positively linked to growth, the current component does not have any significant impact on economic growth. Similarly, Ghosh and Gregoriou (2008) and Benos (2009) take 6 Another element introduced in the paper is the test of non-linearities in the empirical specification with the government budget constraint. There are many other papers focusing on a possible nonlinearity between government spending and growth. In addition to Barro (1990 and 1991), as indicated above, Grossman (1988) examines a nonlinear relationship between growth in the size of government and overall growth in the economy. The results for the United States indicate that this relationship is explained better with a nonlinear model. When compared with previous papers, the main difference of our nonlinear analysis is that we consider a dynamic setting where the overall budget constraint is also taken into account. III. DATA AND COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS Data As indicated in the introduction and the previous section, two sets of countries are included in the analysis. The first group consists of the seven fast-growing developing countries that were included in Moreno-Dodson (2008).11 The regression period is 19702006.12 The main data source is the Government Financial Statistics (GFS) of the International Monetary Fund (IMF).13 Comparative Analysis This section investigates some country facts and findings, and compares different country characteristics on public expenditure and growth that may be helpful when interpreting the subsequent econometric results. First, when the growth rates of GDP per capita in real terms are compared for these two groups of countries, it can be seen that the first set, by definition, have grown much faster on average between 1970 and 2005 (see Tables 1 and 2). While this group has almost 5 percent growth rate on average, the second group has a mean growth rate of 1.6 percent. As can be seen in Figure 1, the first group outperforms the second set of countries throughout the period of 1970 to 2005 except during the Asian financial crises of 1997- account of the revenue side of the government budget constraint considering tax and non-tax revenues, and also the government budget balance. Both papers use a GMM technique for panel datasets. But, they find conflicting results. Benos (2009) show that a reallocation of the components of government spending, especially toward infrastructure and human capital, can enhance growth using 14 European Union countries, while Ghosh and Gregoriou (2008) indicate current (capital) spending has a positive (negative) impact on the growth rate. 11 The list of countries in the fast-growing set and the comparison set is given in the introduction section. The time period may change slightly from one country to another depending on data availability at the country level. 13 Details on variables and data sources are presented in the Appendix to this paper as well as in MorenoDodson (2008). 12 7 98, and the years 2004 and 2005 thanks to high growth performance of countries like Turkey, Uruguay, and Venezuela. A simple measure of (apparent) productivity, real GDP per worker (ratio of GDP to labor force), is calculated to understand possible differences between the two groups of countries. Figure 2 compares the average productivity in the two groups between 1980 and 2005. While the productivity level of the second group of developing countries has been almost flat, the fast-growing countries exhibit increasing productivity levels and the level of productivity for this group passes the one in the comparison group after 1990. The gap between the two groups continues to grow wider throughout the decades. Together with increasing productivity in the fast-growing countries, we see that the share of industrial production has also increased over time. Figure 3 summarizes changes in the value added activities in the industrial sector for these two groups of countries. While the share of industrial production is increasing and stays stable right above 40 percent of GDP for the first group, this share drops to around 30 percent of GDP in the second group of countries. The second column of Tables 1 and 2 gives information about the size of public spending as a share of GDP in the two groups of countries. While there are no sensible differences in the size of the government budget between the two groups, an upward trend is observed in the second group in recent years. For example it jumped to 33 percent in Turkey on average between 2000 and 2005 and 31 percent in Uruguay. Other than these trends, with the exception of Botswana, all countries in our sample have managed to keep a relatively small size of total public spending, which is around below 30 percent of GDP,14 with the exception of Botswana at 38 percent. On the other side, Singapore in the first sample, and the Philippines and Mexico in the second, managed to keep the share of government expenditure in GDP relatively stable and at low levels throughout the period analyzed. While Singapore has 18 percent public spending in percent of GDP on average, Mexico and the Philippines have 17 and 16 percent respectively. Regarding the budget deficit, we observe that it is slightly larger for the comparison group (-1.9 percent of GDP on average) compared to the one for the fast-growing countries (-1.3 percent). When we compare the share of productive expenditure in total public expenditure in Tables 1 and 2, we can see that the share is significantly higher for the first group of countries (62 percent), while it is only 50 percent for the second group throughout the 14 The definition used here refers to the consolidated central government only, which includes the central government plus all government entities associated to it, and excludes all public spending at sub-national level since it was not feasible to construct a reliable database for the consolidated general government including all countries in the sample. 8 period included in the study.15 The other interesting result is that this share tends to decline significantly for the second group (see Figure 4) especially after 1980. Thus, the gap between the shares of productive expenditure in the two groups increases significantly as time goes on, despite the fact that they were relatively close during the mid to late 1970s. Another major difference that can explain the gap between growth performances of the two groups of countries may be in the shares of public gross fixed capital formation as percent of GDP. Indeed, Figure 5 clearly shows that public investment is much larger in the fast-growing countries. The share of public investment in GDP is around 10 percent for the first group of countries, while it is only 5 percent for the second group. Given the significance of public investment, especially its infrastructure component, in economic growth, this difference between the two groups is striking. In addition, of course, there may also be significant differences in the quality of capital spending, which may explain differences in their impact on growth. The differences in the impact of public spending on growth may also be associated with the effectiveness and quality of governance. Figure 6 presents the percentiles for government effectiveness.16 The figure shows that, in terms of government effectiveness, all countries in the first group (with the exception of Indonesia) rank more favorably when compared with the comparison group. When we check the second group (last seven countries in Figure 6), we can see that the percentiles are much lower at around 60 with the exception of Chile who has a government effectiveness index above 80.17 In the whole sample of countries, Singapore enjoys the highest government effectiveness index. On the other extreme case, Venezuela’s government effectiveness is in the bottom 16 percentile. Similarly, Figure 7 shows the differences in the bureaucracy quality between the two groups. The gap between the two groups is obvious although it has gotten smaller in recent years. IV. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION AND ECONOMETRIC METHODS Basic empirical specification The empirical specification used in the analysis is similar to the one presented in MorenoDodson (2008). We add new techniques to control for possible differences between the two groups of countries, in order to better understand the impact of public expenditure and its components on growth. We also introduce nonlinearities in some specifications. 15 Productive expenditure is defined as the sum of general public services expenditure, defense expenditure, educational expenditure, health expenditure, housing expenditure, transportation and communication expenditure. See, for example, Bleaney, Kneller, and Glemmell (2001). 16 According to the KKM (Kraay, Kauffman and Mastruzzi) indicators, government effectiveness measures the quality of public services, the quality of the civil service, the degree of its independence from political pressures, the quality of policy formulation and implementation, and the credibility of the government’s commitment to such policies. 17 Kray, Kauffman and Mastruzzi (KKM) indicators using a (0-100) percentile rank, World Bank. No data exist before 1996. 9 The basic panel regression equation is first run separately for the fast-growing and the comparison group18: yˆ it b1 yˆ it 1 b2 pit b3 HC i b4 FRit b5 PEit b6 FSit b7 CPIINF where: i is the country index, t is the year index, ŷ is the rate of growth of GDP per capita, p is the ratio of private investment to GDP,19 HC is the initial human capital index, FR is the ratio of total fiscal revenues to GDP, PE is the ratio of total public expenditures to GDP,20 FS is the ratio of the fiscal balance (deficit or surplus) to GDP, CPIINF is the inflation rate, and b1, b2, b3, b4, b5, b6, and b7 are the coefficients assigned to the independent variables. The government budget constraint is included in the specification through revenues, expenditures and fiscal balance. In some specifications total fiscal revenues are disaggregated into tax and non-tax revenues. 18 Detailed explanation of the logic behind the specification is presented in Moreno-Dodson (2008). In some regressions, openness has been used, instead of the private investment-to-GDP ratio, as a control variable. 20 Unlike other studies testing only the impact of public investment on growth while ignoring current spending, this analysis includes total public spending, capital and current, without specifically separating them. The rationale for this decision is based on the evidence that some categories of current spending items are indeed critical to ensure the profitability of investments. For example, operations and maintenance expenditures, which are considered as current spending items, are critical to ensure the profitability of infrastructure investments since they can facilitate access and prevent accidents, permitting citizens to arrive safely to markets, schools, hospitals or any other destinations. Similarly, salaries of teachers, usually classified under the current spending rubric, are closely connected to the quality of education provided. In addition, it would not be realistic to try and isolate public investments completely since in many countries capital budgets include de facto, explicitly or implicitly, salaries and current spending items. 19 10 Total public spending is disaggregated using a definition based on Bleaney, Kneller, and Glemmell (2001), and Kneller, Bleaney and Gemmell (1998), which classifies public spending as productive versus unproductive components (a priori). As noted by these authors, government spending items are classified according to whether they are to be included in the private sector production function or not21. They are considered as productive if they are considered to be used by the private sector in its production function. If not, they are named as unproductive, a priori, meaning that they are not expected to have an effect on the steady-state rate of growth: Productive expenditure: General public services expenditure, Defense22 expenditure, Educational expenditure, Health expenditure, Housing expenditure, Transportation and communication expenditure Unproductive expenditure: Social security and welfare expenditure, Expenditure on recreation, Expenditure on fuel and energy, Expenditure on agriculture, forestry, fishing and hunting, Expenditure on mining, mineral resources, manufacturing, and construction, Expenditure on other economic affairs and services. Empirical specification capturing differences in the two groups of countries In an alternative empirical specification which is used when all countries in the data set are pooled together, interactive dummy variables are introduced to capture possible differences between fast-growing countries and the comparison group: yˆit b1 yˆit1 b2 pit b3 HCi b4 FRit b5 DFAST * PEit b6 DSLW * PEit b7 FSit b7CPIINF where: DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 for fast-growing countries and 0 otherwise, DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 for the other countries and 0 otherwise. The multiplication of these dummy variables with public expenditure produces the interaction variables that capture the possible impact of public expenditure on growth for two separate groups. Nonlinear empirical specification In a dynamic setting and using recent econometric techniques, we also try to estimate possible nonlinear effects of public expenditure on growth in fast-growing countries versus the comparison group.23 The nonlinear empirical specification together with interactive dummy variables capturing group effects is: 21 See Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2003). See page 18 for a slightly different classification that excludes defense from productive spending. 23 As specified by Barro (1990), and as discussed earlier, the nonlinearity in the impact of public expenditure on growth can be significant to understand the link between these two variables. 22 11 yˆ it b1 yˆ it 1 b2 pit b3 HC i b4 FRit b5 DFAST * PEit b6 DFAST * PE 2 it b7 DCOMP * PEit b8 DCOMP * PE 2 it b9 FSit b10CPIINF where the square terms of total or productive component of government expenditure capture the nonlinearity.24 Econometric methodology Three alternative econometric methods for panel data are used (OLS, SURE, and GMM) and their results are then compared.25 For each empirical specification, the first sets of results are obtained using OLS and/or SURE methods. Then, a dynamic panel technique (GMM) is applied and the results are compared with those obtained with the static panel regressions. In the empirical analysis, due to data limitations, annual data are used instead of longer-term averages, thus basically the focus is on the short-term growth impact of government spending.26 OLS and SURE methods are based on the assumption that the right-hand-side variables are exogenous. But it is quite likely that these variables may not be because they can be determined by each other, or by the growth rate, or by other variables that are not controlled for in the empirical specifications. The GMM dynamic panel method is used to allow for a more rigorous treatment of the endogeneity of public spending with respect to growth in order to have more reliable and precise results.27 More specifically, we use a two-step GMM methodology, taking first differences of the variables. Since a set of instrumental variables is used with the GMM technique, it helps us control for possible endogenity among regressors. In the regressions, the set of instruments consists of lagged values of dependent and independent variables. The complete set of instrumental variables is: the second and third lags of the growth rate of GDP per capita, initial human capital (or initial life expectancy or initial GDP per capita), 24 The dummy variables (DFAST and DCOMP, as defined above) control for the group effects. Of course, there could also be nonlinearities related to other variables, most particularly private investment or differences in inflation; it could be, for instance, that countries in the fast-growing group also have higher rates of private investment and better macroeconomic policies. However, given the size of our sample, and the issue at hand, we limit ourselves to studying nonlinearities associated with government spending. 25 See Moreno-Dodson (2008) for a detailed description of the three methods. 26 The SURE methodology used in the paper is a type of OLS technique which can be estimated to account for various patterns of correlation among the residuals. In the paper, the variance structure introduced by the SURE methodology is cross-section specific heteroskedasticity. This methodology is used to check whether or not our results with ordinary least square change when we introduced cross-section specific heteroskedasticity, given that the countries in the data set are different from each other. 27 The dynamic general method of moments (GMM) was introduced by Arellano and Bond (1991). As indicated in the next section, OLS and SURE methodologies produce similar results, and GMM confirms most of them. 12 the first, second, and third lags of private investment in percent of GDP, the second and third lags of tax revenue, total public expenditure or productive expenditure, unproductive expenditure, all in percent of GDP, the first, second, and third lags of other revenue and budget balance, all as a share of GDP. V. REGRESSION ANALYSIS Each empirical specification introduced in the previous section is run in four different settings, using the three econometric methods defined above. The first set of empirical estimations, which is presented in the first column of the tables, is based on regressions with the dataset for fast-growing countries.28 The second set of results (see the second column of the tables) is for the comparison group. The third set of results, presented in the third column of the tables, is obtained by combining the two groups of countries in a panel data setting. Then the fourth set of results, as presented in the last column of the tables, is obtained again by combining all countries in a single dataset but also by introducing interactive dummy variables for public expenditure, to control for possible group effects. The overall results suggest that total public spending, especially its productive component, has a statistically significant, positive impact on the GDP per capita growth rate for fast-growing countries, while a similar link for the comparison group cannot be established robustly. V.1. Linear regression results 1.1 Total Public Spending The linear regression specifications involve public spending and its components as percents of GDP, ignoring any higher order variables. First we include total public spending in the regressions. One common finding is that the differences in the size of estimated coefficients for the fast-growing group versus the comparison group, as well as their level of statistical significance, are both large. Table 3 presents the first set of results obtained with both OLS and SURE methodologies. For the fast-growing countries in our dataset (first two columns in Table 3), all the estimated coefficients of government budget components including public spending are statistically and economically significant determinants of economic growth at 1 percent significance level. Both OLS and SURE results produce the same results. However, we do not see similar results for the comparison group (columns 3 and 4 in Table 3). Only the budget surplus has the expected positive sign and statistically significant at 5 percent level. The impact of public spending on GDP per capita growth is positive but the 28 It should be noted that these first sets of results are the ones also presented in Moreno-Dodson (2008) since we use the same fast growing countries in our analyses. 13 coefficient is not significant using neither OLS nor SURE methodologies. Similarly, total fiscal revenue as a share of GDP does not have any significant impact on growth.29 When we compare the magnitudes of the coefficients, they are much larger for the first group, indicating the economic importance of budget components on economic development. For example, a one-percent increase in the public spending to GDP ratio leads to almost half a percent increase in GDP per capita growth rates for the fastgrowing group, while the same increase in spending causes only a 0.04 percent increase in GDP per capita growth in the comparison group. Although the focus of this paper is on the link between public spending and growth, it is also worth acknowledging the contribution of private investment. The presence and significance of this variable is critical to assess whether or not complementary effects between public expenditure and private investment have been triggered, leading to higher growth. As indicated in Table 3, the empirical results state that private investment is significant only for the fast-growing group. Similarly, inflation, which is included to capture the impact of macroeconomic stability on growth, is a statistically significant determinant of growth (with a negative coefficient) only for the fast-growing group. The other interesting result is that when we combine the two sets together, the economic and statistical significance of total public expenditure in determining growth drops substantially. Columns 5 and 6 of Table 3 show the results when two country groups are combined in one data set. In this case, the coefficient of total public spending is significant only at 10 percent and only with the SURE methodology. The magnitude of the coefficients is much smaller compared to the one produced when we consider only fast-growing countries (columns 1 and 2 in Table 3). Similarly, other components of the budget – fiscal revenue and budget surplus – are significant at 10 and 5 percent, successively.30 Private investment continues to have a statistically significant coefficient at the 1 percent level, indicating that the fast-growing group dominates. These results lead us to conclude that when more heterogeneous countries (in terms of their growth performance) are all included in the dataset, the significance of public spending and other budget components drops. This may partially explain why some empirical studies in the literature mixing countries with very different growth patterns cannot find a statistically significant link between government spending and economic growth. In other words, in order to avoid parameter bias in cross-country regression results, distinguishing “clusters” by either specific characteristics and performance, or more formal pooling tests, can be critical. As explained in the empirical specification section of the paper, interactive dummy variables are introduced to capture the possible differences in the impact between the two groups in the combined panel regressions. The interactive dummy variable for the fast29 The lack of significance or robustness of the initial human capital variable may be due to the fact that the indicator that we use does not capture well quality differences across countries and over time; see Rogers (2008) for a more detailed discussion. 30 This finding supports the results presented in Lee and Gordon (2005). 14 growing countries (DFAST × public spending) has an economically and statistically significant coefficient at 5 percent with OLS, while the similar interactive dummy variable for the comparison group leads to a lower estimated coefficient and less statistical significance (see columns 7 and 8 in Table 3). The results in this setting clearly suggest that the impact of total public expenditures on growth is much more significant for fast-growing countries when we use the combined dataset, after controlling for other macroeconomic variables and budget components. The estimated coefficients using OLS and SURE methodology are confirmed also by a dynamic GMM methodology as presented in Table 4. On the one hand, total fiscal spending is again a statistically and economically significant determinant of growth for the fast-growing group (see column 1). Inflation also has expected signs and statistically significant coefficients at 1 percent level. Openness, which is included here to capture possible effects of private sector transactions on growth through exports and imports (instead of private investment), and it is expected to have a positive impact on growth, has indeed a statistically significant coefficient at 1 percent level.31 On the other hand, none of the variables are statistically significant in the case of the comparison group, except inflation (see column 2). Total public spending even has an unexpected negative impact on growth but it is not statistically significant. The insignificant coefficient of openness for the comparison group again shows that export and import flows are not successful in explaining growth for this group. When the two sets are combined, the significance of total public spending in determining growth disappears and the sign of the variable turns negative. But when the group effects in the combined data setting are controlled for with the interactive dummies used with total fiscal spending, it can be seen that the fast-growing group has a statistically significant public spending impact on growth, while for the comparison group, the influence of public spending on growth is negative (see column 4). 1.2. Expenditure Classifications: Productive versus Unproductive The remaining question is how the impact of different components of public spending on growth varies in these two groups of countries. The classification of public spending considers productive versus unproductive public spending, as explained in the previous section. 32 31 In each GMM specification, we include openness instead of private investment since this variable produces better results. 32 According to the “a priori” definition introduced by Bleaney, Kneller, and Glemmell (2001) as explained before, it is expected that the productive component of public spending will have a higher impact on growth relative to the unproductive component. When we focus on fast-growing countries, the result is as expected (column 1 in Table 5). In an empirical specification where we control for some macroeconomic variables and lagged value of growth, fiscal revenue and budget balance, productive public spending has a 15 Column 3 of Table 5 shows that productive expenditure gets insignificant in explaining growth in the pooled sample, again illustrating the caveats of pooling a disparate group of countries. The estimation result with the interactive dummies for the two groups as presented in column 4 of Table 5 also supports the previous findings: the coefficient of the interactive dummy variable for productive expenditure in the fast-growing group is statistically significant at 1 percent, while the one in the comparison group is not significant. The estimation results with the composition of public spending, based on the dynamic GMM technique, are given in Table 6. Since they are similar to previous results obtained with the panel OLS methodology, this suggests that the findings are robust across different econometric methods. Again for fast-growing countries, productive public spending has a positive and statistically significant impact at 10 percent on growth, which is lower than the significance level reported in Table 5. The sign of the non-productive component for the fast-growing group becomes negative in the GMM specifications, but it does not have any statistically significant influence on growth even though it was positively significant at the 10 percent level in Table 5 with the OLS specification. Openness continues to have a statistically significant impact on growth at the 10 percent level. The comparison group, on the other hand, does not show any significant coefficient for any component of government spending. The nonproductive component of government spending continues to produce statistically insignificant coefficients. When we combine two groups in one set, the sign of productive public expenditure is positive and its significance is close to 10 percent. The nonproductive component turns out to have a statistically significant, negative sign in the GMM specification. When we separate the effects of two groups in the combined dataset with interactive dummy variables (Column 4 in Table 6), it can be seen that the positive impact of productive public spending on growth in the combined set is confirmed only for the fast-growing country group, as was the case with OLS. V.2. Nonlinear regression results As argued by Barro (1990, 1991), the link between public spending and growth is expected to be positive when the size of government is small but it may turn negative as the size gets larger. To capture nonlinearity, the additional explanatory variable introduced in the nonlinear specification is either the squared value of total public spending or the squared term of productive public spending, depending on which specification is used. The OLS panel regression methodology is first used to test nonlinearity. Then we also use the dynamic GMM methodology to confirm the results. higher impact on growth in the fast-growing group, while it has a negative but insignificant impact for the comparison group (compare columns 1 and 2 in Table 5). 16 Table 7 presents the coefficients estimated by the panel OLS methodology. In the table, total public spending is considered. In none of the specifications, neither total public expenditure nor its square term has a statistically significant effect on growth. This result is consistent across the country groups and the combined set. When we control for the group effects with the help of interactive dummy variables in the combined set, not much difference is observed. These findings do not change with any alternative econometric technique. Table 8 shows the same specifications estimated this time with the GMM technique. The results are robust: total public expenditure and its square term again are not significant in any column of Table 8. As presented previously, the empirical results in the linear setting suggest that some components of public spending are more influential in determining the growth rate of GDP per capita. Thus, we expect that the inclusion of those components of public spending instead of total public spending may matter in the nonlinear setting as well. Table 9 shows the estimated coefficients with the level and the squared value of productive public expenditure, using panel OLS estimation technique. As was the case before, the productive component of government spending is a statistically significant determinant of the growth rate of GDP per capita only for fast-growing countries. The squared value of productive expenditures has a negative sign, but it is not statistically significant. Table 10, which uses the GMM estimation technique, confirms the results presented in Table 9. Similarly, the productive component is significant only for fastgrowing countries, while the squared value of this variable is not statistically significant in any case. Overall the results based on the nonlinear specifications do not identify any nonlinearity between total public spending or its productive components and economic growth. V.3. Robustness check of the classification of public spending The inclusion of defense spending item in the a priori definition of productive public spending can raise some questions. There is still a controversy on whether defense spending promotes economic growth. For example, Benoit (1973 and 1978) explains that defense expenditures can increase growth through contributing to providing education and health services to staff in the military, lowering unemployment, engaging in public works, and increasing scientific and technological innovations. It may also promote growth by providing a more secure environment for private investors. However, another group of papers argues that the relationship between defense spending and growth is not robust across different countries.33 Since we do not have much knowledge of the defense sector and to test the robustness of the empirical results to alternative classifications, we rerun our regressions by excluding defense spending from productive public spending. It is added to “other” public spending and therefore excluded from the regression. Table 11 shows the empirical results with 33 For example, see Biswas and Ram (1986), and Looney and Frederiksen (1986). 17 this alternative definition of a priori productive spending.34 When we compare both findings, we can see that the original results are robust. The productive spending group is still a statistically and economically significant determinant of growth only for the fastgrowing group. It is not significant for the comparison group, or when we pool all countries together. VI. CONCLUSIONS The main purpose of this paper has been to empirically investigate the link between public spending and its components, and growth with a panel dataset where developing countries are classified according to their GDP per capita rates of growth in two groups: fast-growing countries and a comparison group including a mix of countries with different growth patterns (a lower growth rate on average). The main result of the study is that the influence of public spending on economic growth is clearly different in the two groups, even though the size of government measured as total public expenditures as percent of GDP is similar. The main explanation is found in the composition of public expenditure.35 On average, the fast-growing group has a much higher share of productive expenditure in total, while unproductive components of public spending are larger for the comparison group. In the fast-growing countries, the productive components of public spending consistently have a positive and statistically significant impact on economic growth, after controlling for macroeconomic and private sector variables, initial conditions of countries, and other budget components. This statistically significant effect cannot be established in a robust fashion for the comparison group. Our results are consistent with several other studies focusing on developed and developing countries, such as Bose, Haque, and Osborn (2007), and Benos (2009).36 In addition to the differences that we observe in the response of growth to the composition of public spending between two groups of countries, we also find differences in the impact of private sector and macroeconomic stability. Two alternative indicators of private sector involvement used in the specifications, private investment and openness, tend to have higher significance in explaining growth for the fast-growing group. One possible explanation can be that the expected complementarity effect between public and private sector in the growth process is only manifested in the first group. Another reason can be differences in investment climate between the two groups. 34 Due to space limitations, they are not included in the paper, but other empirical specifications are also robust to the alternative definition of productive public spending. 35 We also observe some differences in government effectiveness and bureaucracy quality. Due to data limitations, we could not explicitly include these variables in our regressions. But because the limited data that we could find indicate that the quality of governance (as measured by government effectiveness and bureaucracy quality) is consistently higher for the fast-growing group, we believe that the group effects that are introduced in the empirical specification partially capture the quality of governance. 36 For dissenting results, however, see Ghosh and Gregoriou (2008). 18 Similarly, inflation is negatively correlated with growth only for the fast-growing group, indicating that reducing inflation leads to faster growth and therefore growth is responsive to improvements in macroeconomic stability in those countries. When we combine the two groups of countries in the regression analysis, the link between government spending and growth again gets weaker or disappears. In the regressions with combined data, when we control the group effects by interactive dummy variables, it can be seen that only the fast-growing panel produces a positive and statistically significant link between the productive component of public spending and growth. Our overall conclusion therefore is that public spending can be a significant determinant of growth, if countries are able to devote a significant fraction of these expenditures to productive uses. 19 REFERENCES Agell, J., H. Ohlsson, and Skogmann Thoursie P., 2006, “Growth Effects of Government Expenditure and Taxation in Rich Countries: A comment,” European Economic Review, 50, 211-18. Agénor, Pierre-Richard, The Economics of Adjustment and Growth, Harvard University Press (Cambridge, Mass.: 2004). ------, "Fiscal Policy and Endogenous Growth with Public Infrastructure," Oxford Economic Papers, 60 (January 2008), 57-88. Agénor, Pierre-Richard, and Blanca Moreno-Dodson, "Public Infrastructure and Growth: New Channels and Policy Implications," in Public Expenditure, ed. By Maura Francese, Daniele Franco, and Raffaela Giordano, Banca d'Italia (Rome: 2007); and WB Working Paper. Agénor, Pierre-Richard, and Kyriakos Neanidis, "The Allocation of Public Expenditure and Economic Growth," Working Paper No. 69, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, University of Manchester (March 2006). Ang, James B., 2009, “Do public investment and FDI crowd in or crowd out private domestic investment in Malaysia?” Applied Economics, 41, 913–919. Arellano, M. and S. Bond, 1991, “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Montecarlo Evidence and Application to Employment Equations,” Review of Economic Studies 58(2), 277-297. Barro, Robert J., "Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth," Journal of Political Economy, 98 (October 1990), s103-s25. Barro, Robert J., "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 106 (May 1991), 407-43. Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 1992, “Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth,” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 99, No.4, 645-61. Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, Economic Growth, 2nd. ed., McGraw-Hill (New York: 2003). Benoit, E., 1973, Defense and Economic Growth in Developing Countries. Lexington: Lexington Books. Benoit, E., 1978, “Growth and defense in developing countries.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 26(January): 271-280. 20 Benos, Nikos, 2009, “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from EU Countries,” unpublished, University of Ioannina (September 2009). Biswas, B. and R. Ram (1986) “Military expenditures and economic growth in less developed countries: an augmented model and further evidence.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 34(January): 361-372. Bleaney, Michael, Norman Gemmell, and Richard Kneller, 2001, “Testing the Endogenous Growth Model: Public Expenditure, Taxation, and Growth over the Long Run,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 34, pp.36-57. Bose, N., Haque M.E., and Osborn, D. R., 2007, “Public Expenditure and Economic Growth: A disaggregated analysis for developing countries,” The Manchester School, 75, 533-56. Colombier, C., 2009, “Growth effects of fiscal policies: an application of robust modified M-estimator,” Applied Economics, 41, 899–912. Easterly, William and Sergio Rebelo, 1993, “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Emperical Investment,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 32, no: 3, pp. 417-58. Folster, Stefan and Magnus Henrekson, 2001, “Growth Effects of Government Expenditure and Taxation in Rich Countries,” European Economic Review, vol. 45(8), 1501-20. Ghosh, Sugata, and Andros Gregoriou, 2008, “The Composition of Government Spending and Growth: Is Current or Capital Spending Better?,” Oxford Economic Papers, 60 (June), 484-516. Glomm, Gerhard and B. Ravikumar, 1997, “Productive Government Expendituers and Long-run Growth,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 21, No.1, 183-204. Grossman, Philip J., 1990, “Government and Growth: Cross-sectional Evidenece,” Public Choice Vol.65: 217-227. Grossman, Philip J., 1988, “Government and economic growth: A nonlinear relationship,” Public Choice vol. 56(2): 193-200. Gupta, Sanjeev, Benedict Clements, Emanuele Baldacci, and Carlos Mulas-Granados, 2002, “Expenditure Composition, Fiscal Adjustment, and Growth in Low-income Countries,” IMF Working paper 02/77 (Washington DC). Kellenberg, Derek K., 2009, “US Affiliates, Infrastructure and Growth: A Simultaneous Investigation of Critical Mass,” Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, 18 (September), 311-45. 21 Kneller, Richard, Michael F. Bleaney, and Norman Gemmell, 1998, “Growth, Public Policy and the Government Budget Constraint: Evidence from OECD Countries,” Discussion Paper No. 98/14, School of Economics, University of Nottingham. Kneller, Richard, Michael Bleaney, and Norman Gemmell, 1999, “Fiscal Policy and Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 74, no. 2, 171-190. Lee, Young and Roger H. Gordon, 2005, “Tax Structure and Economic Growth,” Journal of Public Economics, 89:1027-1043. Levine, Ross and David Renelt, 1992, “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions,” American Economic Review, vol. 82, no. 4, 942-63. Looney, Robert and P.C. Frederiksen, 1986, “Profiles of Current Latin American Military Producers”, International Organization, 40(3): 745-752. Moreno-Dodson, Blanca, 2008, “Assessing the Impact of Public Spending on Growth: An Empirical Analysis for seven fast Growing Countries,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4663. Park, Hyun, 2006, “Expenditure Composition and Distortionary Tax for Equitable Economic Growth,” IMF Working Paper No: WP/06/165. Pushak, Tearas, Erwin R. Tiongson, and Aristomene Varoudakis, 2007, “Public Finnace, Governance, and Growth in Transition Economies,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4255. Rogers, Mark L., 2008, “Directly Unproductive Schooling: How Country Characteristics Affect the Impact of Schooling on Growth,” European Economic Review, 53, 356-85. Schaltegger, Christoph A. and Benno Torgler, 2006, “Growth effects of public expenditure on the state and local level: evidence from a sample of rich governments,” Applied Economics, 2006, 38, 1181–1192. Slemrod, J., 1995, “What Do Cross-Country Studies Teach about Government Involvement, Prosperity, and Economic Growth?” Brookings Papers on economic Activity, pp.373-431. Wahab, M., 2004, “Economic growth and Government Expenditure: Evidence from a new test specification,” Applied Economics, 36, 2125-35. Zagler, Martin, and Georg Durnecker, "Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth," Journal of Economic Surveys, 17 (July 2003), 397-418. 22 APPENDIX – INFORMATION ON DATA COUNTRIES INCLUDED Fast growing countries: Botswana, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mauritius, Singapore, Thailand. Comparison group: Chile, Costa Rica, Mexico, Philippines, Turkey, Uruguay and Venezuela YEARS INCLUDED BY COUNTRIES The years included are according to the data availability of government budget items. Botswana: 1970-96 and 2001-2005 Indonesia: 1972-1999 and 2001-2005 Korea: 1970-97 and 2001-2005 Malaysia: 1972-87 and 2001-2005 Mauritius: 1973-2005 Singapore: 1972-2005 Thailand: 1972-2001 Chile: 1972-2001 Costa Rica: 1972-2001 Mexico: 1972-2000 Philippines: 1972-2001 Turkey: 1970-2001 Uruguay: 1972-2001 Venezuela: 1970-2001 LIST OF VARIABLES 1. Control Variables Private Investment: Gross fixed capital formation by the private sector includes land improvements (fences, ditches, drains, and so on); plant, machinery, and equipment purchases; and the construction of roads, railways, and the like, including schools, offices, hospitals, private residential dwellings, and commercial and industrial buildings. Source: WDI and IFC working paper. Imports of goods and services (% of GDP): Imports of goods and services represent the value of all goods and other market services received from the rest of the world. They include the value of merchandise, freight, insurance, transport, travel, royalties, license fees, and other services, such as communication, construction, financial, information, business, personal, and government services. They exclude labor and property income (formerly called factor services) as well as transfer payments. Source: WDI. 23 Exports of goods and services (% of GDP): Exports of goods and services represent the value of all goods and other market services provided to the rest of the world. They include the value of merchandise, freight, insurance, transport, travel, royalties, license fees, and other services, such as communication, construction, financial, information, business, personal, and government services. They exclude labor and property income (formerly called factor services) as well as transfer payments. Source: WDI. Openness (% of GDP): Exports of goods and services (% of GDP) plus imports of goods and services (% of GDP). Bureaucracy Quality Index: Indexed series between 1 and 4 measuring the quality of bureaucracy. Higher numbers indicate higher quality. Source: International Country Risk Guide. 2. Initial Condition Variables GDP per capita in constant 2000 U.S. dollar: GDP per capita is gross domestic product divided by midyear population. GDP is the sum of gross value added by all resident producers in the economy plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the value of the products. It is calculated without making deductions for depreciation of fabricated assets or for depletion and degradation of natural resources. Data are in constant U.S. dollars. Source: WDI. Initial Human Index: Following Bose, Haque, and Osborn (2007), we construct the initial human capital variable as the weighted sum of the initial enrolment ratios (%) in primary and secondary schools and in higher education. The weights are 1 for primary school enrolment ratio, 2 for secondary school and 3 for enrolment in higher education. The weights are approximations to the relative values of three types of education. The initial year is 1970. Source: Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995, 1999). 3. Government Budget Items Tax Revenue: Tax revenue refers to compulsory transfers to the central government for public purposes. Certain compulsory transfers such as fines, penalties, and most social security contributions are excluded. Refunds and corrections of erroneously collected tax revenue are treated as negative revenue. For central government. Source: GFS. Total Government Revenue: Revenue is cash receipts from taxes, social contributions, and other revenues such as fines, fees, rent, and income from property or sales. Grants are also excluded here. For central government. Source: GFS. 24 Other Revenue: Total government revenue minus tax revenues. For central government. Source: Calculated by author. Total Government expenditure: Total central government expenditure: economic plus social, plus general public services, plus defense, plus other expenditure. Source: GFS. Budget balance: Before 2001, it is calculated as total government revenue plus grants minus total expenditure minus net lending. After 2001, it is total revenue plus grants minus total expenditure. For central government. Source: Calculated by author. Productive expenditure: General public services expenditure Defense expenditure Educational expenditure Health expenditure Housing expenditure Transportation and communication expenditure Source: Calculated by author. Unproductive expenditure: Social security and welfare expenditure Expenditure on recreation Expenditure on fuel and energy Expenditure on agriculture, forestry, fishing and hunting Expenditure on mining, mineral resources, manufacturing, and construction Expenditure on other economic affairs and services Source: Calculated by author. Other expenditure: Public order and safety Other expenditures Source: Calculated by author. 25 Correlation matrix In order to give some initial idea about the possible links between public spending and its components and economic growth, a simple correlation coefficient matrix is presented in Table A.1. The correlation may change in the dynamic settings of the econometric analysis, but overall we can see that the simple relationship between GDP per capita growth and public expenditure (and its components) is much weaker and even negative in some cases for the second group of countries. For the first group, the highest correlation coefficients for growth belong to productive expenditures, economic expenditures, and transportation expenditures. All these correlation coefficients are negative but close to zero for the second group, indicating almost no correlation between the components of public spending and growth. Table A1 - Correlation matrix of variables SET OF FAST GROWING COUNTRIES Pub spending GDPPCGR /GDP GDPPCGR Pub spending/GDP Fiscal balance/GDP Pro/TEXP Edu/TEXP Hea/TEXP TRA/TEXP 1.000 0.126 0.088 0.333 0.005 -0.043 0.383 1.000 -0.067 -0.038 0.231 0.396 0.103 SET OF OTHER DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Pub spending GDPPCGR /GDP GDPPCGR Pub spending/GDP Fiscal balance/GDP Pro/TEXP Edu/TEXP Hea/TEXP TRA/TEXP 1.000 -0.035 -0.205 -0.058 0.007 -0.027 -0.003 1.000 -0.401 -0.539 -0.563 0.010 -0.574 Fiscal balance/GDP Pro/TEXP 1.000 0.487 0.273 -0.144 0.044 1.000 0.593 0.184 0.456 Fiscal balance/GDP Pro/TEXP 1.000 0.389 0.289 0.283 0.264 1.000 0.484 0.276 0.680 Edu/TEXP 1.000 0.491 0.140 Edu/TEXP 1.000 0.313 0.254 Hea/TEXP 1.000 -0.053 Hea/TEXP 1.000 -0.041 TRA/TEXP 1.000 TRA/TEXP 1.000 Note: GDPPCGR is the growth rate of GDP per capita in real terms. Pub spending/GDP is the ratio of total public spending in %. Fiscal balance is the ratio of fiscal balance to GDP in %. Pro/TEXP is public productive expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Edu/TEXP is public education expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Hea/TEXP is public health expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Tra/TEXP is public transportation expenditure in total public expenditure in %. 26 TABLES Table 1 - SET OF FAST GROWING COUNTRIES Pub Fiscal spending balance/ GDPPCGR /GDP GDP Pro/TEXP Edu/TEXP Hea/TEXP TRA/TEXP Botswana Botswana Botswana Botswana Indonesia Indonesia Indonesia Indonesia Korea, Rep. Korea, Rep. Korea, Rep. Korea, Rep. Malaysia Malaysia Malaysia Malaysia Mauritius Mauritius Mauritius Mauritius Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Thailand Thailand Thailand Thailand AVERAGE 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 11.93 8.00 3.74 5.60 5.31 4.41 3.26 3.37 6.32 6.38 5.24 4.60 5.18 3.18 4.52 3.15 4.90 4.24 3.15 7.55 5.32 4.39 3.44 4.83 5.48 3.99 4.08 5.02 28.37 32.53 36.91 38.83 18.36 21.17 17.23 18.33 15.48 15.91 16.39 20.71 23.70 30.58 24.23 26.99 30.16 26.81 23.59 24.36 18.07 24.99 15.60 16.58 15.49 18.39 17.61 19.59 22.75 -5.03 9.65 7.60 0.53 -3.35 -3.59 -0.85 -1.31 -0.79 0.19 1.21 1.83 -6.33 -9.55 -6.48 -11.28 -6.62 -3.26 -3.32 0.87 2.68 7.80 4.73 -2.71 -3.53 -0.25 -3.41 -1.28 76.61 68.87 74.11 62.79 63.20 53.02 15.72 68.33 65.52 55.99 59.87 58.93 57.90 60.92 61.09 51.42 46.29 45.85 52.89 79.37 71.59 90.26 91.49 62.21 57.40 61.35 59.96 61.96 16.54 19.23 23.01 23.52 8.42 9.15 8.72 4.88 16.21 18.66 18.90 15.38 22.45 18.80 20.95 24.60 14.10 14.86 15.95 15.74 16.74 18.62 24.24 23.70 20.70 19.64 20.38 21.30 17.69 5.66 5.52 5.22 8.48 2.03 2.18 2.54 1.33 1.29 1.65 1.04 0.45 6.71 4.85 5.85 7.06 8.50 7.78 8.56 8.70 7.89 5.72 7.67 6.65 4.11 5.41 7.51 8.97 5.33 13.71 9.92 6.76 12.24 9.83 7.35 1.09 5.47 3.77 5.94 6.67 5.87 8.36 8.02 8.03 4.30 4.50 4.37 3.40 5.31 8.01 6.02 7.82 10.29 7.02 11.28 7.11 7.13 Note: GDPPCGR is the growth rate of GDP per capita in real terms. Pub spending/GDP is the ratio of total public spending in %. Fiscal balance is the ratio of fiscal balance to GDP in %. Pro/TEXP is public productive expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Edu/TEXP is public education expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Hea/TEXP is public health expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Tra/TEXP is public transportation expenditure in total public expenditure in %. 27 Table 2 - COMPARISON GROUP Pub Fiscal spending balance/ GDPPCGR /GDP GDP Pro/TEXP Edu/TEXP Hea/TEXP TRA/TEXP Chile Chile Chile Chile Costa Rica Costa Rica Costa Rica Costa Rica Mexico Mexico Mexico Mexico Philippines Philippines Philippines Philippines Turkey Turkey Turkey Turkey Uruguay Uruguay Uruguay Uruguay Venezuela Venezuela Venezuela Venezuela AVERAGE 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05 0.86 2.72 4.66 3.09 3.70 -0.46 2.90 1.69 3.33 0.12 1.66 1.49 2.90 -0.45 0.53 2.57 2.28 1.70 2.03 3.60 2.33 0.07 2.60 0.71 0.45 -2.89 0.30 1.35 1.64 33.20 28.29 19.79 14.73 20.18 20.01 21.37 22.91 14.53 23.21 15.44 15.93 13.86 13.70 18.98 19.35 18.64 17.44 18.35 33.14 23.18 25.23 28.89 31.41 19.44 21.93 20.21 24.07 21.34 -1.85 -0.51 1.21 0.02 -2.75 -2.02 -1.62 -1.26 -2.48 -7.85 -0.69 -1.17 0.20 -0.42 -0.91 -3.92 -2.02 -3.35 -4.59 -11.18 -1.73 -2.46 -0.93 -4.05 4.26 1.94 0.11 -2.62 -1.88 58.77 50.04 67.87 70.40 54.62 53.15 41.47 31.65 43.54 48.53 70.39 73.91 50.69 38.94 66.64 71.98 59.12 26.38 45.95 38.62 28.51 26.06 54.77 49.30 41.52 49.34 50.47 14.24 13.41 14.62 18.02 28.00 20.14 19.18 20.98 17.92 12.97 23.37 24.73 14.53 17.23 17.57 17.95 19.50 13.10 14.49 8.78 10.64 7.34 6.91 7.33 16.47 18.55 17.03 21.22 16.29 7.41 7.23 11.47 12.54 9.32 25.26 23.20 22.03 4.28 1.58 3.25 4.95 4.42 5.01 3.17 2.10 2.98 2.25 3.28 3.24 4.19 4.14 5.49 6.17 9.99 8.62 7.05 6.65 7.55 4.75 3.29 14.51 9.67 4.84 6.10 9.50 5.03 4.23 2.32 17.15 21.18 11.08 8.54 15.46 8.20 5.11 2.32 5.20 6.29 4.45 2.89 9.75 6.19 2.38 2.69 7.43 Note: GDPPCGR is the growth rate of GDP per capita in real terms. Pub spending/GDP is the ratio of total public spending in %. Fiscal balance is the ratio of fiscal balance to GDP in %. Pro/TEXP is public productive expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Edu/TEXP is public education expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Hea/TEXP is public health expenditure in total public expenditure in %. Tra/TEXP is public transportation expenditure in total public expenditure in %. 28 29 -0.205 (-5.65)*** 0.406 (3.928)*** 120 0.443 Inflation - consumer price index Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) No. of observations Adjusted R2 120 0.473 0.378 (4.11)*** -0.177 (-4.908)*** 0.304 (3.942)*** … -0.296 (-4.175)*** 167 0.095 0.284 (3.611)*** -0.009 (-0.706) 0.250 (2.149)** … … 0.043 (0.808) -0.064 (-0.745) -0.008 (-0.732) 0.061 (0.557) 167 0.072 0.240 (3.237)*** -0.018 (-1.63) 0.090 (0.816) … … 0.026 (0.448) 0.002 (0.028) -0.004 (-0.476) 0.080 (0.817) (4) 287 0.312 0.296 (4.666)*** -0.023 (-2.4)** 0.161 (2.317)** … … 0.068 (1.481) -0.084 (-1.765)* -0.006 (-1.228) 0.143 (3.148)*** (5) OLS 287 0.284 0.299 (5.141)*** -0.022 (-2.47)** 0.071 (1.365) … … 0.069 (1.896)* -0.059 (-1.503) -0.010 (-2.183)** 0.102 (2.652)*** (6) SURE Whole sample pooled 287 0.321 0.290 (4.609)*** -0.017 (-1.645)* 0.202 (2.825)*** 0.059 (1.3) 0.159 (2.562)** -0.129 (-2.492)** 0.001 (0.184) 0.087 (1.678)* (7) OLS 287 0.301 0.294 (5.116)*** -0.023 (-2.489)** 0.134 (2.545)** 0.063 (1.838)* 0.163 (3.298)*** -0.119 (-2.807)*** -0.002 (-0.399) 0.037 (0.86) (8) SURE Whole sample with dummies Note: The estimation method is the ordinary least squares f or panel data in the f irst column and the cross-section seeminly unrelated regression f or panel data in the second column. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probabil ity of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. 0.341 (3.668)*** Budget surplus (% of GDP) … DFAST*(Productive plus unproductive expenditures (-1)) (% of GDP) … … 0.477 (3.876)*** Productive plus unproductive expenditures (-1) (% of GDP) DCOMP*(Productive plus unproductive expenditures (-1)) (% of GDP) 0.448 (4.263)*** -0.323 (-3.884)*** Total fiscal revenue (% of GDP) 0.006 (0.931) 0.007 (0.96) Initial human capital 0.115 (2.698)*** 0.107 (1.917)* (2) (1) (3) OLS SURE OLS SURE Comparison group Fast growing countries Private investment (% of GDP) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Table 3: Results with Total Public Expenditures (panel OLS and SURE) Table 4: Results with Total Public Expenditures (Dynamic Panel - GMM) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries (1) Comparison group (2) Whole sample pooled (3) Whole sample with dummies (4) Openness (% of GDP) 0.062 (6.032)*** -0.006 (-0.073) 0.005 (0.141) -0.004 (-0.123) Total fiscal revenue (% of GDP) -0.207 (-0.662) -0.136 (-0.146) 0.686 (0.94) 1.773 (1.523) Total fiscal expenditures (-1) (% of GDP) 0.318 (1.572)* -0.326 (-1.091) -0.019 (-0.117) … DFAST*(Total fiscal expenditures (-1)) (% of GDP) … … … 1.698 (1.856)* DCOMP*(Total fiscal expenditures (-1)) (% of GDP) … … … -0.918 (-1.72)* Budget surplus (% of GDP) -0.020 (-0.097) 0.281 (0.275) -0.164 (-0.321) -0.946 (-1.479) Inflation - consumer price index -0.492 (-6.579)*** -0.056 (-4.782)*** -0.086 (-6.756)*** -0.088 (-3.671)*** Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) 0.125 (0.906) -0.092 (-1.675)* -0.089 (-0.807) -0.006 (-0.031) No. of observations J-statistics 94 7.542 169 2.461 264 2.001 264 1.301 Note: The estimation method is a dynamic GMM. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. J -test is f or overidentif ication problem where H0: there is no overidentif ication problem. We f ail to reject in each case. 30 Table 5: Results with Productive and Non-productive Expenditures (panel OLS) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries (1) Comparison group (2) Whole sample pooled (3) Whole sample with dummies (4) Private investment (% of GDP) 0.071 (1.235) 0.111 (0.975) 0.154 (3.244)*** 0.086 (1.629) Initial human capital 0.007 (0.987) -0.015 (-1.326) -0.010 (-1.689)* -0.005 (-0.747) Tax revenue (% of GDP) -0.201 (-1.877)* -0.038 (-0.313) -0.023 (-0.287) -0.037 (-0.438) Other revenue (% of GDP) -0.531 (-4.051)*** -0.346 (-1.548) -0.144 (-1.853)* -0.242 (-3.143)*** Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.664 (4.314)*** -0.051 (-0.574) 0.048 (0.698) … DFAST*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.219 (2.985)*** DCOMP*Productive expenditure (-1) … (% of GDP) … … 0.153 (1.3) Non-productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.312 (1.786)* 0.107 (0.944) 0.076 (0.904) -0.060 (-0.657) Budget surplus (% of GDP) 0.450 (4.182)*** 0.275 (2.318)** 0.184 (2.571)** 0.231 (3.106)*** Inflation - consumer price index -0.208 (-5.76)*** -0.013 (-1.015) -0.023 (-2.332)** -0.019 (-1.813)* Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) 0.377 (3.644)*** 0.255 (3.181)*** 0.284 (4.442)*** 0.264 (4.169)*** No. of observations Adjusted R2 120 0.454 167 0.101 287 0.312 287 0.327 Note: The estimation method is the ordinary least squares f or panel data. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. D-FAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. 31 Method: Pan Date: 05/11/ Sample: 197 Table 6: Results with Productive and Non-productive Expenditures (Dynamic Panel - GMM) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries (1) Comparison group (2) Whole sample pooled (3) Whole sample with dummies (4) Openness (% of GDP) 0.058 (1.834)* -0.348 (-1.335) 0.047 (0.936) -0.014 (-0.17) Tax revenue (% of GDP) -0.153 (-0.355) 1.481 (1.037) 0.154 (0.22) 0.377 (0.445) Other revenue (% of GDP) -0.400 (-0.905) -0.639 (-0.26) -0.374 (-0.504) -0.081 (-0.089) Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.777 (1.673)* 0.397 (0.393) 0.866 (1.513) … DFAST*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 3.217 (1.465) DCOMP*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … -0.331 (-0.263) Non-productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) -0.890 (-1.301) -1.187 (-0.975) -2.003 (-2.641)*** -2.181 (-2.402)** Budget surplus (% of GDP) 0.126 (0.316) 0.115 (0.13) -0.058 (-0.108) -0.017 (-0.027) Inflation - consumer price index -0.375 (-3.12)*** -0.105 (-2.743)*** -0.103 (-2.972)*** -0.116 (-2.735)*** Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) -0.03 (-0.151) -0.378 (-1.436) -0.382 (-1.749)* -0.331 (-1.27) No. of observations J-test 98 1.993 171 2.07 269 6.97 269 3.75 Note: The estimation method is a dynamic GMM. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. J-test is f or overidentif ication problem where H0: there is no overidentif ication problem. We f ail to reject in each case. 32 Table 7: Nonlinear Results with Total Public Expenditures (OLS) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries Comparison group Whole sample pooled Whole sample with dummies Private investment (% of GDP) 0.091 (1.584) 0.076 (0.673) 0.151 (3.241)*** 0.101 (1.912)* Initial human capital 0.009 (1.161) -0.01 (-0.923) -0.01 (-1.685)* -0.001 (-0.094) Tax revenue (% of GDP) -0.216 (-1.883)* 0.036 (0.324) -0.015 (-0.202) -0.029 (-0.376) Other revenue (% of GDP) -0.407 (-3.664)*** -0.287 (-1.13) -0.153 (-1.944)* -0.300 (-3.072)*** Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.225 (0.486) 0.088 (0.552) 0.054 (0.456) … Square term of productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.673 (0.652) -0.275 (-0.502) 0.018 (0.047) … DFAST*Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.046 (0.323) DFAST*Square term of Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.548 (1.052) DCOMP*Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.069 (0.568) DCOMP*Square term of Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … -0.158 (-0.382) Budget surplus (% of GDP) 0.378 (3.524)*** 0.241 (2.052)** 0.186 (2.557)** 0.252 (3.328)*** Inflation - consumer price index -0.210 (-5.494)*** -0.01 (-0.803) -0.023 (-2.326)** -0.016 (-1.566) Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) 0.386 (3.699)*** 0.268 (3.356)*** 0.285 (4.467)*** 0.279 (4.413)*** No. of observations Adjusted R2 99 0.442 171 0.096 270 0.311 270 0.326 Note: The estimation method is the ordinary least squares for panel data. Annual data are used. ( -1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 for fast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 for the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% significance level, ** indicates 5% significance level, and *** indicates 1% significance level. These significance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coefficients. 33 Table 8: Nonlinear Results with Total Public Expenditures (Dynamic Panel - GMM) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries Comparison group Whole sample pooled Whole sample with dummies Openness (% of GDP) 0.044 (2.106)** -0.281 (-1.344) 0.068 (1.971)** 0.014 (0.171) Total government revenue (% of GDP) -0.492 (-1.58) 0.192 (0.332) -0.443 (-1.062) -0.393 (-0.653) Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.508 (0.547) 0.775 (0.735) 1.098 (1.104) … Square term of productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) -0.997 (-0.465) -3.210 (-1.004) -3.408 (-1.349) … DFAST*Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 2.593 (0.63) DFAST*Square term of Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … -2.972 (-0.339) DCOMP*Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 2.943 (1.468) DCOMP*Square term of Productive + nonproductive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … -11.894 (-1.565) Budget surplus (% of GDP) -0.089 (-0.261) 0.051 (0.081) 0.278 (0.563) 0.099 (0.157) Inflation - consumer price index -0.388 (-4.015)*** -0.052 (-2.672)*** -0.065 (-2.341)** -0.055 (-1.521) Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) 0.082 (0.484) -0.400 (-2.513)** -0.650 (-4.742)*** -0.386 (-1.544) No. of observations J-test 99 1.035 171 2.514 270 1.346 270 2.996 Note: The estimation method is a dynamic GMM. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicate s 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. J-test is f or overidentif ication problem where H0: there is no overidentif ication problem. We f ail to reject in each case. 34 Table 9: Nonlinearity of Productive Expenditures (panel OLS) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries Comparison group Whole sample pooled Whole sample with dummies Private investment (% of GDP) 0.072 (1.238) 0.096 (0.829) 0.161 (3.337)*** 0.099 (1.807)* Initial human capital 0.006 (0.791) -0.015 (-1.363) -0.009 (-1.514) -0.004 (-0.584) Tax revenue (% of GDP) -0.213 (-1.895)* -0.011 (-0.084) -0.037 (-0.451) -0.050 (-0.597) Other revenue (% of GDP) -0.540 (-4.039)*** -0.298 (-1.284) -0.190 (-1.98)** -0.303 (-2.915)*** Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.826 (1.756)* 0.153 (0.545) -0.080 (-0.473) … Square term of Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) -0.464 (-0.365) -1.133 (-0.764) 0.621 (0.823) … DFAST*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.093 (0.507) DFAST*Square term of Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.611 (0.793) DCOMP*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.137 (0.613) DCOMP*Square term of Productive expenditure (-1) … (% of GDP) … … -0.943 (-0.77) Non-productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.316 (1.799)* 0.068 (0.552) 0.097 (1.1) 0.077 (0.859) Budget surplus (% of GDP) 0.463 (4.073)*** 0.264 (2.207)** 0.194 (2.67)*** 0.249 (3.32)*** Inflation - consumer price index -0.205 (-5.456)*** -0.012 (-0.959) -0.024 (-2.422)** -0.018 (-1.769)* Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) 0.376 (3.617)*** 0.259 (3.216)*** 0.284 (4.436)*** 0.271 (4.263)*** No. of observations Adjusted R2 120 0.449 167 0.097 287 0.311 287 0.326 Note: The estimation method is the ordinary least squares f or panel data. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels ar e equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. 35 Table 10: Nonlinear Results with Productive and Non-productive Expenditures (Dynamic Panel - GMM) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries Comparison group Whole sample pooled Whole sample with dummies Openness (% of GDP) 0.024 (0.734) -0.197 (-0.96) 0.056 (1.026) 0.014 (0.118) Total government revenue (% of GDP) -0.665 (-2.164)** 0.655 (1.102) 0.050 (0.113) 0.017 (0.03) Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 6.061 (1.687)* 0.659 (0.456) 1.06 (1.037) … Square term of Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) -12.969 (-1.508) 0.354 (0.046) -0.687 (-0.187) … DFAST*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 4.016 (0.457) DFAST*Square term of Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … -8.252 (-0.426) DCOMP*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.209 (0.089) DCOMP*Square term of Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 3.393 (0.212) Non-productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) -2.125 (-2.5)** -1.179 (-1.608) -1.377 (-2.06)** -1.440 (-2.031)** Budget surplus (% of GDP) 0.735 (1.58) -0.225 (-0.321) -0.009 (-0.024) 0.073 (0.114) Inflation - consumer price index -0.214 (-1.816)* -0.089 (-3.245)*** -0.08 (-4.407)*** -0.088 (-1.866)* Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) -0.306 (-1.487) -0.387 (-2.328)** -0.393 (-2.564)** -0.355 (-1.553) No. of observations J-test 99 1.007 171 2.321 270 2.511 270 2.919 Note: The estimation method is a dynamic GMM. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. DFAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. J -test is f or overidentification problem where H0: there is no overidentif ication problem. We f ail to reject in each case. 36 Table 11: Results with Alternative Definiiton of Productive Expenditures (panel OLS) Dependent variable: Growth rate of GDP per capita Fast growing countries (1) Comparison group (2) Whole sample pooled (3) Whole sample with dummies (4) Private investment (% of GDP) 0.095 (1.597) 0.116 (1.021) 0.163 (3.525)*** 0.104 (2.016)** Initial human capital 0.009 (1.091) -0.016 (-1.402) -0.011 (-1.795)* -0.003 (-0.472) Tax revenue (% of GDP) -0.168 (-1.564) -0.033 (-0.274) -0.032 (-0.398) -0.044 (-0.527) Other revenue (% of GDP) -0.264 (-2.173)** -0.364 (-1.61) -0.105 (-1.429) -0.236 (-2.99)*** Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.400 (2.348)** -0.074 (-0.754) -0.005 (-0.071) … DFAST*Productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) … … … 0.259 (2.7)*** DCOMP*Productive expenditure (-1) … (% of GDP) … … 0.158 (1.311) Non-productive expenditure (-1) (% of GDP) 0.029 (0.153) 0.106 (0.961) 0.098 (1.175) -0.075 (-0.792) Budget surplus (% of GDP) 0.276 (2.621)*** 0.274 (2.315)** 0.165 (2.347)** 0.223 (2.991)*** Inflation - consumer price index -0.210 (-5.545)*** -0.014 (-1.073) -0.024 (-2.492)** -0.020 (-1.934)* Growth rate of GDP per capita (-1) 0.371 (3.422)*** 0.252 (3.14)*** 0.280 (4.373)*** 0.270 (4.271)*** No. of observations Adjusted R2 122 0.390 167 0.102 289 0.312 289 0.324 Note: The alternative def inition of the productive component is the original def inition of productive spending minus def ense spending. The estimation method is the ordinary least squares f or panel data. Annual data are used. (-1) indicates variables lagged one period. D-FAST is the dummy variable which is 1 f or f ast growing countries and 0 otherwise. DCOMP is the dummy variable which is 1 f or the comparison group and 0 otherwise. t-statistics are given in parenthesis. * indicates 10% signif icance level, ** indicates 5% signif icance level, and *** indicates 1% signif icance level. These signif icance levels are equal to one minus the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of zero coef f icients. 37 Da Sa FIGURES Figure 1 - GDP per capita growth (annual %) 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 Fast growing countries Other developing countries Figure 2 - GDP (in constant 2000 US$) per labor force 18000 16000 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 Fast growing countries Other developing countries 38 Figure 3 - Industry, value added (% of GDP) 45 40 35 30 25 20 2004 2006 2002 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 Fast growing countries Other developing countries Figure 4 - Productive component of public spending (in % of total expenditure) 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 Fast growing countries Other developing countries 39 Figure 5 - Gross public fixed capital formation (in % of GDP) 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 Venezuela Uruguay Turkey Philippines Mexico Costa Rica Chile Thailand Singapore Mauritius Malaysia Korea, Rep. Indonesia Botswana 40 2007 1996 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 Other developing countries Fast growing countries Figure 6 - Government Effectiveness 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Figure 7 - Average Bureaucracy Quality (index between 0-4, higher index higher quality) 3.1 2.9 2.7 2.5 2.3 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.5 2008 2007 41 2006 Other developing countries 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 Fast growing countries