Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
SEMIPERIPHERAL STATES IN THE WORLD .. EcONOMY Recent Titles in Contributions in Economics and Economic History Charitable Giving and Government Policy: An Economic Analysis Jerald Schiff Economic Law and Economic Growth: Antitrust, Regulation, and the American Growth System George E. Garvey and Gerald J. Garvey The Politics of Industrial Recruitment: Japanese Automobile Investment and Economic Development in the American States Ernest J. Yanarella and William C. Green, editors The Theory of Contestable Markets : Applications to Regulatory and Antitrust Problems in the Rail Industry William B. Tye Advertising and the Transformation of American Society, 1 865-1920 James D. Norris Privatization in the Developing World L. Gray Cowan Nuclear Power Goes On-Line: A History of Shippingport William Beaver The Impact of the Federal. Budget Process on National Forest Planning V. Alaric Sample American Management and British Labor: A Comparative Study of the Cotton Spinning Industry Isaac Cohen Monopoly Capital Theory: Hilferding and Twentieth-Century Capitalism Jonas Zoninsein Korean Economic Development Jene K. Kwon, editor From Industry to Arms: The Political Economy of High Technology Anthony DiFilippo SEMIPERIPHERAL STATES IN THE WORLD,.EcONOMY EDITED BY William G. Martin STUDIES IN THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE WORLD-SYSTEM Immanuel Wallerstein, ADVISORY EDITOR @.CONTRIBUTIONS IN ECONOMICSAND ECONOMIC HISTORY, N UMBER 113 "p, GR.EENWOOD PRESS New York· Westport, Connecticut· London Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Semi peripheral states in the world-economy / edited by William G. Martin. p. cm. - (Studies in the political economy of the world-system) (Contributions in economics and economic history, ISSN 0084-9235 ; no. 113) Papers from the Thirteenth Political Economy of the World-System Conference held at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, April 1989, and co-sponsored by the American Sociological Association and the University's Dept. of Sociology. Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 0-313-27489-4 1. Economic history-1945- -Congresses. 2. International economic relations-Congresses. 3. Capitalism-Congresses. 4. Competition, International-Congresses. 5. Developing countries Foreign economic relations-Congresses. I. Martin, William G., 1952- . II. Political Economy of the World-System Conference (13th : 1989 : University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign) III. American Sociological Association. IV. University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. Dept. of Sociology. V. Series. VI. Series: Contributions in economics and economic history, no. 113. HC13.S47 1990 330.9172 '3-dc20 90-36779 British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data is available. Copyright © 1990 by William G. Martin All rights reserved. No portion of this book may be reproduced, by any process or technique, without the express written consent of the publisher. Library of Congress Catalog Card Number: 90-36779 ISBN: 0-313-27489-4 ISSN: 0084-9235 First published in 1990 Greenwood Press, 88 Post Road West, Westport, CT 06881 An imprint of Greenwood Publishing Group, Inc. Printed in the United States of America The paper used in this book complies with the Permanent Paper Standard issued by the National Information Standards Organization (Z39.48-1984). 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 CONTENTS ILLUSTRATIONS SERIES FOREWORD Vll IX Invna nuel Wallerstein ACKNOWLEDGMENTS xi Part I. The Place of the Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System 1. Introduction: The Challenge of the Semiperiphery William G. Martin 2. The Developmentalist Illusion: A Reconceptualization of the Semiperiphery Giovanni Arrighi 3 Part II. Semiperipheral Success Stories? 3. Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports in the Semiperiphery Gary Gereffi and Miguel Ko rzeniewicz 4. State, Market, and Agriculture in Pinochet's Chile Walter Goldfrank 5. Limits on a Semiperipherai Success Story? State Dependent Development and the Prospects for South Korean Democratization David A. Smith and Su-Hoon Lee 45 69 79 vi Contents 6. The Limits to Semiperipheral Development: Argentina in the Twentieth Century 97 Roberto P. Korzeniewicz Part III. Semiperiphery or Core? 7. The Republic of Ireland in the World-Economy : An Exploration of Dynamics in the Semiperiphery 125 Richard Grant and Donald Lyons 8. Periphery in the Center: Canada in the North American Economy 141 Jorge Niosi Part IV. Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? 9. The Contradictions of Semiperipheral "Success": The Case of Israel 161 Beverly Silver 10. Ethnic Divisions and State-Centered Development: Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 183 Paul M. Lubeck and Donna Rae Palmer 11. From NIC to NUC: South Africa's Semiperipheral Regimes 203 William G. Martin BmLIOGRAPHY 225 INDEX 227 ABOUT THE C ONTRIBUTORS 237 ILLUSTRATrONS FIGURES 2. 1 Percentage of World Population in the Three Zones 20 2.2 Trends i n Relative Economic Command (Weighted Averages and Ranges of GNP Per Capita of Organic Members) 23 2.3 Trends in the Degree of Industrialization 25 3.1 Footwear Commodity Chain 52 3.2 Index of Industrial Upgrading for Footwear, Selected Countries 6.1 Per Capita Product, Selected Countries, 1 9 1 3-1982 7. 1 Trends in Modal GNP Per Capita of the Three Zones and Irish GNP Per Capita 11.1 South African GNP Per Capita as a Percentage of Organic Core GNP Per Capita 1 1 .2 GNP Per Capita of Selected Semiperipheral States as a Percentage of South African GNP Per Capita 207 TABLES 2. 1 3.1 Positions of States in 1 975- 1 983 Compared to Their Positions in 1 93 8- 1 95 0 21 Market Share of U . S. Footwear Imports from Selected Countries (SITC 85 1), 1 967- 1 987 53 viii 3.2 Illustrations Composition of Footwear Exports to the United States, Selected Countries, 1970-1987 62 7.1 Sectoral Origin of Irish GDP 129 7.2 Structural Change in Irish Manufacturing Industry 130 7.3 Ireland's Direction of Trade Exports 133 7.4 Ireland's Direction of Trade Imports 133 7.5 Ireland: Levels of Processing of Exports (LPE) 134 7.6 Ireland's Trading Partners: A Breakdown of LPE for 1987 136 8.1 GDP in Manufacturing Industries at Market Prices , 1986 148 8.2 Manufacturing Productivity (1984) in Current U.S. Dollars 149 8.3 Foreign Direct Investment Stock, Main Countries, 1984 150 8.4 Foreign Control of Canadian Industry, 1979 and 1986 150 8.5 8.6 8.7 8.8 Exports of Manufactured Goods, Selected Countries in Market Economies, 1975 and 1986 151 Manufactured Exports Per Capita, 1975 and/1986 152 Developed Countries , 1987: Main Foreign Market and Supplier 153 Government R&D Expenditures by Objective in 1987 154 SERIES FOREWORD Immanuel Wallerstein The Political Economy of the World-System Section of the American Sociological Association was created in the 1970s to bring together a small but growing number of social scientists concerned with analyzing the processes of world-systems in general, and our modern one in particular. Although organizationally located within the American Sociological Association, the PEWS Section bases its work on the relative insignificance of the traditional disciplinary boundaries. For that reason it has held an annual spring conference, open to and drawing participation from persons who work under multiple disci plinary labels. For PEWS members, not only is our work unidisciplinary, but the study the world-system is not simply another " specialty" to be placed beside so others. It is instead a different "perspective" with which to analyze all the tional issues of the social sciences. Hence, the themes of successive ferences are quite varied and cover a wide gamut of topics. What they the sense that the isolation of political, economic, and sociocultural ' ·.,",..i",hl'i' is a dubious enterprise, that all analysis must be simultaneously historical systemic, and that the conceptual bases of work in the historical social SClen(;eS must be rethought. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This volume is the product of the Thirteenth Annual Conference on the Political Economy of the World-System held at the University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign in April 1 989. ill addition to the authors of the essays, I would like to thank all the other participants, whose contributions played an important part in making the conference a lively success and sharpening the analyses presented here. Organized under the auspices of the Political Economy of the World-System section of the American Sociological Association, the conference was cospon sored by the University of Illinois's Sociology Department and generously sup ported by International Programs and Studies, the College of Liberal Arts Sciences, the Center for African Studies, the Center for East Asian and Studies, the Russian and East European Center, the Center for Latin and Caribbean Studies, and the Program in South and West Asian Studies, ly, generous thanks are owed to those who provided invaluable aMIM.HIIi. preparing and running the conference, especially Theodore Tsoukalas, Hill, Suzanne Wilson, Ann Reisner, and the staff of the Sociology and the Center for African Studies. PART 1 THE PLACE OF THE SEMIPERIPHERY IN THE MODERN WORLD.. SYSTEM 1 INTRODUCTION: THE CHALLENGE OF THE SEMIPERIPHERY William G. Martin SITUATING THE SEMIPERIPHERAL DEBATE We live in an unstable and uncertain world. Since the late 1 960s the world economy has been marked by economic stagnation, rivalry in the interstate system, anarchy in international monetary relations, and outbreaks of political and social instability across the globe . Such anomalous phenomena on so many fronts have swept away not only the stability of the post-World War II world order but also the intellectual and ideological certainties of Western social science . No better example of this condition exists than in the attention paid by social scientists over the course of the last decade to rapidly industrializing, Hl1'UUJ"<O� " income " countries. It is not hard to understand why this should be so. a condition of economic stagnation in core areas, the newly ' ' tries (NICs)-and especially the East Asian examples-stand out in stark Such cases become even more spectacu lar when set against the food pant along the periphery of the world-economy. Finally, it is often nrp'{,1�pl the middle-income countries that one finds the signs not only of rapid eC()flo'nuq advance but of continuous outbursts of social and political By the late 1 980s we thus faced a burgeoning literature on the so-cai led NICs. For many, they provided the subject matter of unique historical developments, explored through highly specific cultural, political, or historical heritages. For some, the NICs reveal the fundamental failure of dependency perspectives and the reaffirmation of not only the possibilities but also the benefits of progress and capitalist development. Other, more tempered analyses have attempted to discern replicable developmental patterns, generating models of "state-centered development," "bureaucratic-authoritarian-industrialization regimes , " or free enterprise, pro-Western, export-oriented industrialization. For yet others, the NICs herald a fundamental reorganization of the international economic and political 4 The Semiperiphery in the Madern Warld-System hierarchy-indeed, nothing less than a rupture in the world order we have known over the last fifty years. All of the chapters presented in this volume intersect this literature, but they do so from a distinctive and shared world-historical perspective. It is not, of course, simply that these chapters pay attention to the international division of labor-in the late twentieth century it has become impossible to deny the central impor tance of this arena. For most, however, this recognition takes the form of pro viding an international "context, " linking "internal" with "external" factors, comparing isolated and selective nation-state paths and policies, or ranking over time individual countries by developmental critera such as industrialization. The analyses contained in this volume, the result of the Thirteenth Annual Conference on the Political Economy of the World-System, diverge quite sharply from such interpretations. Even as we study the trajectory of individual countries, these paths are interpreted as part and parcel of a larger historical process: the contradictory development of a singular, capitalist world-economy. To place the novelties of today's middle-income countries within this historical unit of analysis reduces their individual importance even as it enhances their col lective importance for understanding modern capitalism. World-systems analysts have long stressed the existence of a middle zone of the world-economy. Where other short-term analyses see countries in spectacular transition between core and periphery, world-systems researchers have argued that a stable group of "semiperipheral" states has been in existence since the earliest day s of the modern world-economy. This stable tripartite partition is, moreover, constantly subject to waves of the redivisioning of the tasks associated with, and indeed individual states' positions within, the global division of labor. Seen in this light, the move ment of twentieth-century Japan or South Korea across the zones of the world economy is no less surprising a phenomenon than the path of the nineteenth-centul)' United States or sixteenth-century northwestern Europe. Finally, the much heralded centrality of contemporary states in propelling such movements has been constantly stressed by almost all work in this area. Approached from a historical and global perspective, the sense of startle ment induced by present-day NICs thus seems to disappear: neither the ex istence of areas between core and periphery nor movement between the zones of the world-economy is a surprising discovery. Yet to recognize the endurance of the semiperiphery raises far more questions than it answers in at least three ways. First, the shape, size, and methods of membership within-and entrance into and exit from-the zone remain an unexplored realm. If semiperipheral states sit astride core-peripheral networks, how is such a position attained and maintained in the face of the strongly polarizing forces of the world-economy? Second, if the semiperiphery is more than simply a statistical cutting point on developmental indices, how has the zone itself operated over time as part of a developing capitalist world? Indeed, what does the study of the zone itself reveal about the cross-cutting structure and processes of the global division of labor and the interstate system? Finally, how and why has the semiperiphery, Introduction 5 at least in the twentieth century, operated as a primary locus for social, labor, nationalist, and antisystemic movements? HOW DO WE KNOW THE SEMIPERIPHERY WHEN WE SEE IT? Of all these issues, none has proved more intractable and generated more debate than the shape and stability of the zone itself. As several of our authors note, past arguments regarding the outer boundaries of the semiperiphery have pin pointed a vast array of semiperipheral states, from the most obvious cases of Brazil, the East Asian NICs, and South Africa to the more contestable instances of China, Canada, Australia, Eastern Europe, and the Soviet Union. The initial source of such conflicting assessments can be illustrated straightforwardly: If the semiperiphery is approached as exhibiting a mix of core and peripheral characteristics, it is quite simple to generate multiple, opposed classifications depending upon one's definition of core-like or peripheral-like features. Further complicating such judgments is the ability to locate countries between core and periphery either in terms of the global division of labor or by standing in the interstate system; contestable cases along one dimension may thus find inclusion in the zone along a different dimension. The result is often a bewildering array of what might be termed semiperipheral states and, as a consequence, divergent assessments of the existence and dynamics of the zone. Giovanni Arrighi's contribution directly tackles this issue by eschewing such individual determinations. He endeavors instead to discern the stability and shape of the semiperiphery through an assessment of the worldwide struggle to ap propriate the benefits accruing from the operation of the global division of labor. In procedural terms this entails an analysis of long-term trends in the distribution of global income. This demarcates, for the first time, the long-term �'-�""J the core-semiperipheral-peripheral divisioning of the world-economy (as to arguments regarding an even gradation from core to periphery) and at the same time individual countries in the three zones. Arrighi's arguments generated considerable debate at the conference. have been expected, both the methodology of utilizing GNP per capita location of individual countries were seriously contested. Two additional "n,c111Afllrp far-reaching issues also emerged, reverberating through the chapters in this tion. First, many authors sought to locate contemporary semiperipheral through an analysis of the relational networks associated with the global of labor and/or processes of unequal exchange (either narrowly construed, follow ing Arghiri Emmanuel, or more broadly interpreted as relationships of surplus ex traction associated with networks such as those composing commodity production, trade, investment, and so on) . Richard Grant and Donald Lyons, for example, ex plicitly set Arrighi's arguments against other measures in examining Ireland's place in the world-economy, while Gary Gereffi and Miguel Korzeniewicz analogously utilize the concept of the commodity chains in the production of footwear to 6 The Semi periphery in the Modem World-System examine semiperipheral mobility. Jorge Niosi similarly examines the economic location and relationships of Canada and selected "late industrializers" to argue the case that while not semiperipheral, such countries remain along the border between core and semiperiphery as "central-peripheral" states. Second, considerable discussion emerged over the specification of the zone and individual states by their location in the interstate system. Distinguishing world systems analysis in this domain is the assumption that the modern world-economy contains one economy and mUltiple political structures-and, conversely, that states do not contain or control economies. While a clear parallel exists between the wealth derived from a position in the global division of labor and relational state power in the interstate system, many states' geostrategic positions belie any sim ple correlation. Whether and to what extent interstate relations may specify a semiperipheral status or be utilized to move between zones of the world-economy remains very much a contestable issue. This is easily illustrated by debates over classification: Are economically marginal states such as India or China peripheral, and highly dependent but economically advanced states such as Canada core? More substantively, such debates raise critical discussions of the tensions between in terstate struggles and global accumulation. To what extent, for example, can highly specialized, geostrategic positions assist upward movement, as in the relatively privileged ability of the South Korean or Israeli states to avert constraints from core states or capital in the post-World War II period? SEMIPERIPHERAL MOVEMENTS: SUCCESS AND FAILURE WITHIN THE WORLD-ECONOMY Such debates indicate that it is not self-contained, semiperipheral processes that engender the zone, but rather the encapsulation of global processes of, and strug gles over, wealth and power. It is here that the studies of individual states find their task: the exploration of the semiperiphery through the examination of multiple states' struggles to attain, retain, and move beyond semiperipheral status in the world-economy and not to fall from core to semiperipheral or semiperipheral to peripheral standing. As each and every one of our studies indicates, the exercise of state power has long been essential to such struggles. As should be evident, this is a far different exercise than charting and comparing the developmental trajectories of individual nation-states and national economies. One need only take the issue of industrializa tion, so central to the examination of advancing noncore states and the subject of considerable debate in the contemporary conjuncture. Approached from a perspective of national development, industrialization charts significant advances in, even a replication of, the stages of core countries' growth. A world-historical perspective substantively recasts such developmentalist accounts. As our authors document, the process of innovation and creative destruction in core zones dur ing the current global depression has accelerated the ongoing relocation of sim ple industrial production processes from core countries toward the semiperiphery. Introduction 7 Seen from the perspective of core states, deindustrialization may mark a successful defense of their status. For semiperipheral states, the challenges are quite differ fent. As Gereffi and Korzeniewicz indicate, for example, already-existing semiperipheral states are confronted by an intensifying struggle to upgrade their position within global industrial production and marketing networks. For semiperipheral states, rapid industrialization may mark little more than running very fast to stay in the same place. Failure to keep apace of these developments can-as Walter Goldfrank charts for Pinochet's Chile, William Martin for South Africa, and Beverly Silver for Israel-lead to downward movement through suc cumbing to polarizing forces emanating from core areas. For peripheral areas marked by highly competitive primary production, the capture of standardized and highly competitive industrial production for the world market may, of course, carry forward a movement toward the benefits of a semiperipheral position in the global division of labor. It is in this circumscribed arena that most discussion of the newly industrializing countries falls, and it is here that one perceives, in multiple ways, just how difficult such a transition is to achieve. In a conjuncture marked by an ongoing redivision of core and peripheral activities, significant if selective opportunities to seize more remunerative tasks do indeed exist. As David Smith and Su-Hoon Lee argue, South Korea demonstrates a remarkable case of filling an opening niche for export-oriented industrial production. The South Korean example of vigorous state action is, moreover, replicated in almost every case of such upward movement, including those of earlier historical periods, as indicated in the chapters on Canada, South Africa, and Argentina. For those seeking replicable models, such instances mandate a theory of state centered action. What our studies indicate, however, is the relatively rare set of conditions that make such actions both possible and successful. Advance seems most marked in a state able to break with local, invariably peripheral, accumula tion patterns and the local and transnational classes they support; the recognition and promotion of specialized niches in the global division of and favorable conditions in the interstate system (either geostrategic as for South Korea and Israel, or conditions of rivalry amidst the hegemonic orders, as during the interwar period for South Africa and Latin America). While the desire for capturing core-like accumulation patterns is common along the periphery of the world-economy, rarely indeed do these social and political conditions coalesce to make upward movement within the global division of labor possible. While exceptional cases capture contemporary attention, the historical analysis of states within the semiperiphery or along its borders indicates a far more common outcome: the failure of semiperipheral states to move toward core status and the daunting prospects for states located in the periphery. In large part such conclusions emerge from the investigation of forces, derived from the im brication of national and global class formation, that vigorously delimit or pre vent the initiation of innovative state intervention in the accumulation process. 8 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System Not the least of these obstacles, as Paul Lubeck and Donna Rae Palmer argue, may be constituted by the historically forged relationship of ethnicity, local ac cumulating classes, and statepower. Even where the rupture of a deeply entrenched relationship between peripheral accumulation and political power may be effected on the basis of ethnic mobilization-as, for example, in Israel and South Africa such a transition often generates countervailing ethnic mobilizations. These in turn can either undermine whatever advance has been achieved or prevent adap tations to future alterations in the interstate system or the distribution of core and peripheral activities. THE LIMITS AND CONTRADICTIONS OF THE SEMIPERIPHERY AND THE WORLD-ECONOMY As our authors stress, it is an enduring irony that semiperipheral states-both new and long-term members of the zone-find forward movement blocked by the very forces that generated or sustain their membership in the zone. As Roberto Korzeniewicz argues for Argentina and other nations of recent European settle ment, the very social and institutional ruptures necessary to achieve semiperipheral status quite often create social and political forces that prevent any further ad vance. Coupled with and complicating such impediments are the obstacles im posed by the collective struggles of semiperipheral states and the secular develop ment of the world-economy as a whole. If semiperipheral states have managed to escape the highly competitive and marginally remunerative production pro cesses of the periphery, they confront in the semiperiphery a zone of far more intense and capable political competition. Given the competitive pressures of lower wage rates and more attractive subsidies offered by other non core states, as well as unremitting pressures from core states and capital, semiperipheral states' further advance is quite often undercut by competitive struggles within or between members of the zone itself. In this sense the semiperiphery bears the burden of a modern Janus: facing oligopolistic and political pressures from core zones and economic competition from the periphery below. Such conclusions curiously rebound upon widespread notions of "bringing the state back in" and "state-centered dependent development." For even as the study of the semiperiphery necessarily highlights the role of state power in achieving and maintaining semiperipheral status in the world-economy, it reveals at the same time the interrelational character of state power in the world-economy and the highly cir cumscribed possibilities of state-led movements across the zones of the world economy. How one traces and interprets this condition remains a matter of con siderable debate, as is revealed in the chapters by Roberto Korzeniewicz and by Smith and Lee . Yet it remains evident that even the rare cases of highly autonomous, interventionist, and successful transition indicate that semiperipheral states remain captives of the polarizing relationships that constitute the capitalist world-economy. Such observations are further underlined if one recognizes the degree to which the development of the world-economy successively recasts the possibilities and Introduction 9 strategies of semiperipheral advancement. While the completion of the interstate system since 1945 has, for example, widened semiperipheral possibilities to a much larger group of states, it has simultaneously heightened the competitive character of such interstate struggles among semiperipheral and peripheral states. In addition, the transition to a world-economic order increasingly organized by capital and international organizations had undercut state strategies typical of the nineteenth century or even the period between World War I and World War II. As the South African study suggests, maintenance as well as attainment of a semiperipheral status after 1945 has required quite radical shifts in localized regimes of accumulation and state power. Or, as Goldfrank reminds us, the demise of the self-regulating market economy has everywhere imposed upon the state the necessity to regulate the economic and political order. One returns at this point to our opening observations. It is all too apparent that the anomalous phenomena surrounding the semiperiphery can hardly be understood, much less explained, by using individual "success" stories to create widely applicable models of national progress or development. Located at the crossroads of global accumulation networks and the interstate system, the semiperiphery reveals instead the very limits of what is commonly called "pro gress" or " development" in the modern world. This is, moreover, a dangerous location, encapsulating and compressing as it does central contradictions of both the global division of labor and the interstate system. Nowhere is this more evident than in the political and social upheavals of this epoch of global crisis and the collapse of the ideological fault lines associated with the fleeting era of U.S . hegemony. Indeed, for those struggling to under stand and change the contemporary world, the most striking of contemporary developments is the rising tide of political struggle in noncore zones. It takes but a moment's survey to indicate that contemporary social, labor, nationalist, and antisystemic movements are primarily, if not wholly, erupting in semi peripheral states . Such movements signal both a crisis o f semiperipheral regimes and wide contradictions. The most heralded of these movements are those under the rubric of "democratization," ranging from East Asia to Latin and Eastern Europe to South Africa. The features stressed by Smith and examination of democratization in South Korea-the forces unleashed by the and economic transformation of the semiperipheral zone in the nuclear endemic through most of the areas studied in this volume. Given the centrality of semiperipheral industrialization, it is hardly surprising that it is precisely within the semiperipheral zone that one finds, for example, the center of world labor unrest and politically engaged trade union movements. For many developmentalists, the confluence of both industrialization and demands for democratic participation glibly trumpets the arrival of the wisdom of following in the footsteps of Western parliamentary democracies. This is not a conclusion that our contributions would sustain. While the ongoing redivision of core and peripheral activities has generated powerful social forces-sustaining 10 The Semiperiphery in the Madern Warld-System not only labor but diverse social, national, and civilizational movements-it has hardly provided the means to meet the swelling demands of the peoples of the semiperiphery (not to mention the periphery) and thus provide legitimacy to in creasingly embattled states. Resolving labor-capital-state conflicts along the lines achieved in core countries-the so-called Fordist model-would require, for ex ample, far greater resources than can possibly be tapped within the semiperipheral zone. Meeting the demands for national sovereignty in the face of the increasing ly stringent demands of international fInancial organizations similarly undermines both semiperipheral states' stability and the very models being imposed by core states and capital. Under these conditions the volatility that marks the semiperipheral zone promises to be of long-standing importance. In interpreting the trajectory of this situation, the implications of our authors' analyses clearly diverge. For some, the evidence reveals the semiperiphery as the central location if not the fount of antisystemic movements. This can be seen in several ways: either as the semiperiphery emerging as the locus of demands for a new international economic order, or in antisystemic movements finally realizing the charade of the notion that demands for equality and social justice can be met by the capture and utilization of state power within national boundaries. For others, mounting allegiances to free enterprise and col laboration with international capital lay the seeds of a prosystemic stabilization of a world-economy. For yet others, the coalescence within the semiperiphery of such explosive forces and the clear-cut inability to defuse them portend con stant upheavals not of the world-economy but endemic civil war within semiperipheral states. Arrighi's depiction of Israel and South Africa as an arche typical semiperipheral future is but one example of this. The elaboration of the fate of antisystemic movements is far beyond the task set by the authors in this volume. Yet to the extent that the following chapters shed light on the underlying global forces that have amalgamated such turbulent forces in the semiperiphery, they will have succeeded in their purpose: not only to engender a more world-historical understanding of the transformation of par ticular areas of the world-economy, but to advance our understanding of the transformation and transformational possibilities of the capitalist world itself. 2 THE DEVELOPMENT ALIST ILLUSION: A RECONCEPTUALIZATION OF THE SEMIPERIPHERY Giovanni Arrighi THE BLIND ALLEY OF UNEQUAL EXCHANGE When we speak of "semiperiphery," we refer to an intermediate position in the core-periphery structure of the capitalist world-economy. Most studies assume that this core-periphery structure consists of networks of " unequal exchange" through which some states (often identified as "industrial" or "industrialized") appropriate a disproportionate share of the benefits of the international division of labor while most other states reap only such benefits as are necessary to keep them in the relationship of unequal exchange. The former states are said to con stitute the " core" of the capitalist world-economy and the latter to constitutejts . " periphery. " Semiperipheral states (often referred to as " semi-industrial" " semi-industrialized'') are then defined as states that occupy an tion in this network of unequal exchange: they reap only marginal OelleI:ltS they exchange with core states, but they reap most of the net benefits exchange with peripheral states.l This conceptualization is based on a number of assumptions that in my are highly questionable on both a priori and historical grounds. The first tionable assumption is that " industrialization' , is the equivalent of " and that "core" is the same as "industrial. " Interestingly enough, this assump-· tion cuts across the great divide between the dependency and the modernization schools. For both schools, to "develop" is to " industrialize" by definition . Needless to say, the two schools strongly disagree on how and why some coun tries have industrialized and others have not or have deindustrialized, but most of their practitioners take for granted that development and industrialization are one and the same thing. This view is so ingrained that it has remained unchallenged notwithstanding the recent wave of deindustrialization among the wealthiest states of the capitalist 12 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System world-economy. The corresponding rapid industrialization of comparatively poor states has been generally taken at face value as the equivalent of "development." To my knowledge, no one from within these schools has raised the question of whether these joint processes of deindustrialization and industrialization have been matched by a corresponding narrowing of the gap between the wealth, power, and welfare of the wealthy but deindustrializing group of states, on the one side, and the not-so-wealthy but industrializing group of states, on the other. No doubt, dependency and modernization practitioners would both agree that industrializa tion is generally pursued not as an end in itself but as a means in the pursuit of either wealth, or power, or welfare, or combinations thereof, and that this ques tion is therefore quite legitimate. But in order to be able to raise the question at all, it is necessary to abandon the postulate that industrialization is the equivalent of development. A second questionable assumption in this conceptualization is that core-periphery relations consist of relations of "unequal exchange" and that the core-periphery structure of the world-economy consists of a network of exchanges, typically a trade network. For one thing, it is not always clear what "unequal exchange" means to those who use the term. The standard reference is Emmanuel (1972), but very few of those who refer to it seem to be aware of what Emmanuel's con cept of unequal exchange involves and does not involve. Emmanuel's concept of unequal exchange has nothing to do with position in a network of trade. It refers to trade between states characterized by different wage levels but by the same rate of profit and level of productivity. It is premised on a lack of mobility of labor resources and a high mobility of capital resources between the trading partners, and it results in the appropriation of the benefits of trade by the partner with the higher level of wages, regardless of its position in trade networks. More importantly, unequal exchange has not been the only mechanism involved in core-periphery polarization, nor have its effects on the core-periphery structure of the world-economy been as unambiguous as those who use the term imply. I am not in any way denying the decisive role played by unequal exchange in creating and reproducing the core-periphery structure of the capitalist world economy. Historically, capital has been far more mobile than labor across the space of the capitalist world-economy, and wage differentials among the territories incorporated in the latter have been not only larger but growing faster than dif ferentials in productivity and in rates of profit. It is hardly conceivable that core states could have achieved their present standards of power, wealth, and welfare without a previous long history of direct and indirect exchanges of commodities with comparatively low-wage states and territories. Granted all this, it does not follow that unequal exchange has been the only or even the main mechanism of core-periphery polarization, or that core-periphery polarization is necessarily its outcome. Unequal exchange is only one of several mechanisms of core-periphery polarization. Equally important have been two other mechanisms, which we may designate as unilateral transfers of labor, on the one The Developmentalist Illusion 13 hand, and o f capital, on the other hand. Unlike unequal exchange, these unilateral transfers do not presuppose the existence of a trade relation and of a trade net work. Hence in principle, unilateral transfers from one state or territory to another are compatible with a complete absence of relationships of unequal exchange be tween the states or territories involved. 2 Historically, unilateral transfers of labor and capital have been both forcible and voluntary. Forcible transfers are transfers prompted by the use of violence or the credible threat thereof by the receiving state and its agents. The slave trade and the transfer and use of prisoners of war as workers are examples of forcible unilateral transfers of labor resources, while the extortion of monetary instruments from colonies or of war reparations from defeated enemies is an example of for cible unilateral transfers of capital resources. Voluntary transfers, in contrast, are transfers based exclusively on the self-interest of the owners of the resources that are being transferred, the most prominent examples being the emigration of workers and the " fl ight of capital. " Both kinds of unilateral transfers have been crucial in the constitution and reproduction of the core-periphery structure of the capitalist world-economy, although, over time, the importance of forcible transfers has been declining relative to that of voluntary transfers. The fact that voluntary transfers are considered morally less objectionable than forcible transfers does not mean that they are less efficacious as mechanisms of core-periphery polarization. On the contrary, volun tary transfers are far more efficacious than forcible transfers wherever and whenever differentials between and among locales in the level and security of rewards have become large enough to create a widespread and strong incentive for owners of labor and capital resources to transfer such resources to sites in which the returns are highest and most secure . Unilateral transfers of this kind have been far more important than unequal exchange in the expansion of the core to include most of the so-called lands new settlement, the United States in the first place, in the late nn·let(�erlth.� early twentieth centuries. The effects of these transfers on the " sending " tries were not at all uniform. Overall, however, the effect was an ullpn:cedel polarization in the hierarchies of wealth, power, and welfare of the world-economy. Unequal exchange is thus only one of several mechanisms through which core-periphery structure of the world-economy has been created, reproduced, deepened. But this is not all. As already mentioned, its effects on the core-periphery structure of the capitalist world-economy are far more contradictory than is nor mally supposed. A country that sells commodities embodying high-wage labor in exchange for commodities that embody low-wage labor can continue to do so and reap the benefits of the exchange only to the extent that the relationship in production and consumption between the two kinds of commodity is one of com plementarity rather than of competition. If for any reason the relationship of com plementarity weakens and that of competition becomes stronger, unequal exchange in this sense becomes the weapon of the " exploited" country to gain wealth, 14 The Semiperiphery in the Modem World-System power, and welfare relative to, and possibly at the expense of, the "exploiting" country. Under these circumstances Warren's (1980) thesis that the "exploita tion" of low-wage countries by high-wage countries may be better than no ex ploitation at all contains an important element of truth. In this connection, it should be noticed that the most striking instances of up ward "mobility" in the capitalist world-economy since World War II (Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan) have all relied heavily at one point or another of their ascent on the export of commodities embodying comparatively low-wage labor in exchange for commodities embodying comparatively high-wage labor. It does not follow from these historical experiences that all peripheral and semiperipheral states could or can enrich themselves in the same way as Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan did. As we shall see, this is out of the question. But it does follow that unequal exchange can cut or work both ways (toward polarization and toward depolarization) and that, therefore, the assumption of a fundamental identity be tween core-periphery relations and relations of unequal exchange is unwarranted. Mutatis mutandis, what has just been said of unequal exchange applies to unilateral transfers of capital and labor resources as well. Historically, the systematic export of capital resources has been as much a mechanism of "cor ification" as it has been of peripheralization. From sixteenth-century Holland to present-day Japan, the investment abroad (primarily in the form of interest bearing capital) of an ever-expanding share of a nation's capital resources has been a major instrument in the formation and consolidation of core positions. As for the unilateral transfer of labor resources, suffice it to note that the ascents to core position of Britain in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries and of Switzerland and Sweden in the late nineteenth century were both preceded or accompanied by massive out-migration of labor resources. In sum, unequal exchange and unilateral transfers of labor and capital resources have all contributed to the formation and reproduction of the core-periphery struc ture of the world-economy. However, they are not essential features of core periphery relations. If core-periphery relations pertain, as I think they do, to some fundamental and self-reproducing inequality in the distribution of wealth among the states and peoples of the capitalist world-economy, then unequal exchange and unilateral transfers of labor and capital resources are purely contingent at tributes of such relations , just like industrialization and deindustrialization. They may or may not coincide with core-periphery relations, depending on the par ticular circumstances of time and place under investigation. In and by themselves they can never tell who is benefiting and who is not benefiting from the struc tural inequalities of the capitalist world-economy. THE WEALTH OF NATIONS IN WORLD-SYSTEMS PERSPECTIVE World-systems analysis provides us with an easy way out of the theoretical impasse in which we are bound to find ourselves if we insist on identifying the core-periphery structure of the capitalist world-economy on the basis of networks The Developmentalist Illusion 15 of exchange, or, worse still, on the basis of comparative degrees of industrializa tion. Following Marx and Schumpeter, world-systems analysis conceives of capitalism as an evolutionary system in which the stability of the whole is premised on the perennial change in an d of the parts. Core-periphery relations are no ex ception. The kinds of inputs, outputs, and techniques of production and distribu tion and the positions in networks of trade and resource allocation that endow states with differential capabilities to appropriate the benefits of the world divi sion of labor are assumed to change continually as a consequence of the introduc tion and diffusion of political, economic, and social innovations.3 In this kind of conceptualization, what is a core and what is a peripheral mix of activities vary continually over the time and space of the world-economy. A particular mix of activities (e. g . , specialization in manufacturing; export of com modities embodying high-wage labor and import of commodities embodying low wage labor; export of capital and import of labor) may enable a particular state at a given time to appropriate a disproportionately large share of the benefits of the world division of labor, but other states may not be able to do the same at the same time, nor may the same state be able to do the same at another time . Core-periphery relations are determined not by particular mixes of activities, but by the systemic outcome of the perennial gale of creative and not-so-creative destruction engendered by the struggle over the benefits of the world division of labor. The central theoretiCal claim of world-systems analysis concerning this systemic outcome is that the capability of a state to appropriate the benefits of the world division of labor is determined primarily by its position, not in a net work of exchanges, but in a hierarchy of wealth. The further up in the hierarchy of wealth a state is, the better positioned its rulers and subjects are in the struggle for benefits. Their opportunities to initiate and control processes of innovation or to protect themselves from the negative effects of the processes of innovation initiated and controlled by others are distinctly better than the opportunities the rulers and subj ects positioned further down in the hierarchy of In addition, world-systems analysis claims that this hierarchy of sists of three distinct layers or clusters. States positioned in the upper routinely appropriate a disproportionate share of the benefits of the sion of labor and, in this sense, constitute the core of the capitalist WC)nCl-el�orlorr States positioned in the lower cluster reap benefits that at most cover the term costs of participation in the world division of labor and constitute periphery of the capitalist world-economy. States positioned in the mterr:necllat.e cluster (semiperipheral states) appropriate benefits in excess of the long-run costs of participation in the world division of labor but less than what is necessary to keep up with the standard of wealth set by core states. These three positions are defined not just in quantitative terms (that is, as an upper, a lower, and an intermediate position on a scale of wealth) but qualitative ly as well (as relational capabilities to appropriate the benefits of the world divi sion of labor). They parallel the concepts of " oligarchic" and " democratic" wealth first introduced by Harrod (195 8) and rescued from oblivion by Hirsch 16 The Semiperiphery in the Modem World-System (1976). Even though these concepts were formulated to explicate differentials in personal wealth, they can be used to explicate wealth differentials among nations. Harrod (1958) distinguishes two kinds of personal wealth, "democratic" and , "oligarchic, " and maintains that they are separated by "an unbridgeable gulf.' Democratic wealth is the kind of command over resources that, in principle, is available to everyone in direct relation to the intensity and efficiency of his or her efforts. Oligarchic wealth, in contrast, bears no relation to the intensity and efficiency of the efforts of its recipients and is never available to all no matter how intense and efficient their efforts are. This is so, according to Harrod, for two main reasons. The first reason corresponds to Emmanuel's concept of unequal exchange but refers to exchanges among persons. We cannot all command ser vices and products that embody the time and effort of more than one person of average efficiency. If someone does, it means that somebody else is laboring for less than what he or she should command if all efforts of equal intensity and effi ciency were rewarded equally. The second reason is that some resources are scarce in an absolute or relative sense or are sub ject to congestion or crowding through extensive use. Their use or enjoyment, therefore, presupposes the exclusion or crowding out of others either through a pricing or a rationing system and leads to the formation of rents and quasi-rents. The struggle to attain oligarchic wealth is thus inherently self-defeating. As underscored by Hirsch, the idea that all can attain it is an illusion. Acting alone, each individual seeks to make the best of his or her position. But satisfac tion of these individual preferences itself alters the situation that faces others seeking to satisfy similar wants. A round oftransactions to act out personal wants ofthis kind therefore leaves each individual with a worse bargain than was reckoned with when the transaction was undertaken, because the sum of such acts does not correspondingly improve the posi tion of all individuals taken together. There is an "adding-up" problem. Opportunities for economic advance, as they present themselves serially to one person after another, do not constitute equivalent opportunities for economic advance by all. What each one of us can achieve, all cannot. (Hirsch 1976, 4-5) World-systems analysis maintains that states pursuing national wealth in a capitalist world-economy face an "adding-up" problem similar to, and in many ways more serious than, the one faced by individuals when they pursue personal wealth in a national economy. Opportunities for economic advance, as they present them selves serially to one state after another, do not constitute equivalent opportunities for economic advance by all states. As Wallerstein (1988) insists, development in this sense is an illusion. The wealth of core states is analogous to Harrod's oligarchic wealth. It cannot be generalized because it is based on relational pro cesses of exploitation and relational processes of exclusion that presuppose the continually reproduced poverty of the majority of the world population. Processes of exclusion are as important as processes of exploitation. As used here, the latter refer to the fact that the absolute or relative poverty of peripheral The Developmentalist Illusion 17 and semiperipheral states continually induces their rulers and subjects to participate in the world division of labor for marginal rewards that leave the bulk of the benefits to the rulers and subjects of core states. Processes of exclusion, in con trast, refer to the fact that the oligarchic wealth of core states provides their rulers and subjects with the means necessary to exclude or crowd out the rulers and subjects of peripheral and semiperipheral states from the use and enjoyment of resources that are scarce or subject to congestion. The two processes are distinct but complementary. Processes of exploitation provide core states and their agents with the means to initiate and sustain processes of exclusion. Processes of exclusion generate the poverty necessary to induce the rulers and subjects of peripheral and semiperipheral states to continually seek reentry into the world division of labor on conditions favorable to core states. If the wealth of core states corresponds to Harrod's concept of oligarchic wealth, the wealth of semiperipheral states corresponds to Harrod's concept of democratic wealth because, in principle, it could be generalized. If all human efforts of equal intensity and efficiency were rewarded equally and if all human beings had equal opportunities to use scarce resources, all peoples could enj oy the kind of com mand over resources that is already enjoyed, on average, by the peoples of the semiperiphery. In reality, however, the most essential feature of the capitalist world-economy is the unequal reward of equal human efforts and unequal op portunities to use scarce resources. As a consequence, only a minority of the world population enj oys democratic wealth and does so only by means of a perennial struggle against the exclusionary and exploitative tendencies through which the oligarchic wealth of core states is created and reproduced. The struggle against exclusion and the struggle against exploitation are different in kind. Some semiperipheral states rely more on one than on the other, but most alternate or combine the two. A struggle against exclusion is a struggle for a com paratively secure niche in the world division of labor. Success in this kind of struggle generally implies ( 1) greater specialization in activities in which semiperipheral state has or can acquire some kind of competitive an active involvement in relations o f unequal exchange in which the seIlliI>erlph state supplies commodities embodying low-wage labor to core states in for commodities embodying high-wage labor, and (3) a more thorough vA',lU"lVJll. of peripheral states from the activities in which the semiperipheral state seeks greater specialization. Struggles against exploitation move in the opposite direction. They are strug gles aimed at the creation of divisions of labor as autonomous as possible from the axial division of labor of the capitalist world-economy. The success of this kind of struggle generally implies ( 1) the undertaking by the semiperipheral state of a wide range of activities regardless of comparative advantage, (2) the self exclusion of the semiperipheral state from relationships of unequal exchange with core states, and (3) an active involvement in relations of unequal exchange in which the semiperipheral state supplies commodities embodying high-wage labor to peripheral states in exchange for commodities embodying low-wage labor. a,6 ::, "" -�:-">\, I'\ J V�. '-: ';:3, .x \ " I 18 The Semiperiphery in the Madern Warld-System By struggling in these two directions, semiperipheral states can keep ahead of the poverty of peripheral states but, as a group, can never bridge the gulf that separates their wealth from the oligarchic wealth of core states. Success in each kind of struggle has its inherent limitations. The very success of struggles against exclusion leads to a more intensive or extensive exploitation of semi peripheral states by core states and thereby enhances the capabilities of the latter to exclude the former from the most rewarding activities and from the use or enjoyment of scarce resources. The very success of struggles against exploitation leads to self-exclusion from access to the wealthiest markets and the most dynamic sources of innovations. Individual states can and do succeed in crossing the gulf that separates the modest wealth of the semiperiphery from the oligarchic wealth of the core, as Japan has recently done and a few others did before Japan. But individual successes lead to a tightening of the exclusionary and exploitative tendencies of core states and thereby deepen and widen the gulf for those who are left behind. It therefore becomes inherently more and more difficult to change status upward. This does not mean that the struggles of semi peripheral states against exclu sion and exploitation are ineffectual. On the contrary, it is precisely their capability to wage successfully these struggles that keeps semiperipheral states from falling into the abysmal poverty of peripheral states. Unfortunately, this is nothing to be proud of, at least from a humanitarian point of view. As we have seen, suc cess in the struggle against exclusion generally implies a more thorough exclu sion of peripheral states from the activities in which semiperipheral states seek specialization; and success in the struggle against exploitation generally implies a greater exploitation of peripheral states by semiperipheral states. Either way, a worsening of conditions f or peripheral states as a group is a re quirement of the success of semiperipheral states to attain and retain democratic wealth. Hence not all states can be or become semiperipheral. Individual states can cross the gulf that separates the periphery from the semiperiphery, but also in this case the opportunities for economic advance, as they present themselves serially to one peripheral state after another, do not constitute equivalent oppor tunities for economic advance by all peripheral states. What each peripheral state can achieve, others are thereby denied.4 ILLUSIONS OF DEVELOPMENT: 1938-1983 Wealth is long-term income. If the claims of world-systems analysis have any validity at all, observation of the distribution of incomes among the various political jurisdictions of the capitalist world-economy over relatively long periods of time should reveal the existence of three separate standards of wealth corresponding to the oligarchic wealth of core states, the democratic wealth of semiperipheral states, and the nonwealth, that is, the poverty, of peripheral states. It should also reveal that the vast majority of states have been unable to bridge the gulfs that separate the poverty of peripheral states from the modest wealth of semiperipheral The Developmentalist Illusion 19 and the modest wealth 0 f semiperipheral states from the oligarchic wealth core states. This is precisely what an investigation by Arrighi and Drangel ( 1 986) has By inspecting the distribution of world population by the log of gross national product (GNP) per capita for the years 1938, 1 948, 1 95 0, 1 960, 1 965, 1 970, 1 975, 1 980, and 1 983, they observed a recurrent trimodal pattern in the data.5 They took the income values corresponding to the three modes to be in dicative of peripheral, semiperipheral, and core positions, and the income values corresponding to the troughs in the distributions to be indicative of gulfs or thresholds separating the periphery from the semiperiphery and the semiperiphery from the core. They labeled the first �d of threshold " perimeter of the periphery" (PP) and the second kind "perimeter 0 f the core" (PC). A total 0 f five positions were thus identified: ( 1) the periphery, (2) the perimeter of the periphery , (3) the semiperiphery, (4) the perimeter of the core, and (5) the core. The distribution of world population among the five positions over the period 1938- 1 983 is shown in figure 2. 1. The spaces separating the periphery from the semiperiphery and the semiperiphery from the core correspond to the perimeter :-of the periphery and the perimeter of the core, respectively . The break between · " 1 940 and 1 95 0 designates a change in the source of the data. The most striking feature of this distribution is its long-term stability in spite of considerable changes in the relative size of the three zones in the shorter run. If one bears in mind that wealth is long-term income, this discrepancy may be interpreted as an indication of a greater stability of the distribution of world population by classes of wealth than by classes of income. Year-by-year or even decade·by-decade variations in the distribution of world population by classes of income are not necessarily symptomatic of a change in the three-tier structure of the capitalist world-economy. Only longer-term variations in income distribution can give some insight into this structure. As can be seen from figure 2. 1 , half a {,PT,nrnt' is probably the shortest period we should take in order to avoid major of the trends. Figure 2. 1 tells us nothing about " gulfs" separating the core, periphery semiperiphery, nor does it tell us anything about whether these gulfs, if they are "bridgeable " or not. To gain some insight into these issues, we vestigate the composition of periphery, semiperiphery, and core in terms states included in each zone and how it has changed over the period The relevant information is given in table 2.1. States that did not change position at all are located in the cells that run along a diagonal from the upper left core-core cell to the bottom right periphery periphery cell. The diagonals on each side of this main diagonal (entries on the diagonals from the two core-perimeter of the core cells in the upper left to the two periphery-perimeter of the periphery cells on the lower right) contain states that moved, but only from a zone to its contiguous perimeters-without crossing the boundary itself. By adding up the entries in the cells along these three diagonals we find that 88 out of 93 states, accounting for 94 percent of total population, 2.1 60 80 20 Source: � S '0 C 40 Q) :: <1) � 0 CL -c 5. " '" " 100 1948 1950 Arrighi and Drangel (1986, 39). 1938 Percentage of World Population i n the Three Zones Figure 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1983 '" > CL .� .<: Cl. The Developmentalist Illusion 21 Table 2 . 1 Positions o f States i n 1975-1983 Compared t o Their Positions i n 1938-1950 Position in 193 8 - 1 950 Core � 0 u u ("0 00 0� tA Cl.. r:- .S <.l ..c P·c <.l Cl.. Cl.. Cl.. 0- r-C\ � § :S 0 r:;!! P., ·c II) Cl.. 0; � (a) (b) (c) 11 13.1 10 . 4 (a) PC 4 2.6 1.8 3 5.6 4.3 1 4 .1 .1 (b) (c) 1 (a ) (b) (c) periphery .6 .8 PP 23 1 8.6 17.6 5 0.8 1.0 1 0.8 1.0 2 2.7 3.5 2 0.5 0.7 4 (a) (b) (c) 1 0.2 0.3 4 11 1 3 .1 6 3.3 Total 1.4 1.2 ( a) (b) (c) (a ) (b) (c) Periphery 33 26.3 0.3 0.5 1.2 1.5 27 51.6 55.5 13 2.3 30 5 5 .1 18 (+7) 1 6. 5 (+3.4) 5 (-1) 1 .3 (-2.0) 30 (-3) 20.4 (-3.9) 8 4.7 (- 5 ) (+2.4) 32 (+2) 57.3 ( +2 . 2 ) 93 100.1 100.2 (0) Source: Arrighi and Drange1 (1986, 43). Notes: (a) Number of states (b) Percentage of population in 1950 (c) Percentage of population in 1970 were in 1 975-1 983 still on or within the boundaries of the zone in which they. were located in 1 93 8- 1 95 0. In the period as a whole, upward and downward "mobility" in the hierarchy of wealth of the capitalist world-economy has been truly exceptional. Apart from the dubious case of Libya,6 the exceptions were two cases of upward mobility from semiperiphery to core (Japan and Italy) , one of transition from periphery to semiperiphery (South Korea, to which Taiwan would probably be added if data for the later years were available) , and one case of downward mobility from semiperiphery to periphery (Ghana). 22 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System Even more interesting is the fact that mobility has been greater over short periods than over the whole period. By comparing positions of states as in table 2.1, but for two sub periods (1938-1950 to 19 60-1970 and 19 60-1970 to 1980-1983), Arrighi and Drangel show that both sub periods were characterized by greater overall mobility than the whole period 1938-1950 to 1980-1983-the first sub period being characterized by greater overall downward mobility and the second subperiod being characterized by greater overall upward mobility. This finding is interesting for two related reasons. For one thing, it confirms the observation made earlier that the distribution of wealth (that is, of long-term income) is more stable than the distribution of short-term income. Ups and downs in relative in come may mean very little from the point of view of the underlying hierarchy of wealth, which in fact may remain quite stable. If this is the case, then the finding is interesting also because it unravels an important source of the developmentalist illusion. By taking relatively short periods as the unit of analysis (and periods of twenty to twenty-five years do indeed seem to be the norm), studies of development may easily mistake for generalized economic advancement what in fact is just an upswing in a pendulum-like move ment that simply brings things back to where they were forty to fifty years bef ore. In the course of the pendulum-like movement, there may be some reshuffling of states in the various positions (South Korea up, Ghana down), or even some genuine cases of upward mobility (Japan and Italy). Nevertheless, when the dust has settled, true cases of economic advance prove to be the exception, while the idea that many were advancing proves to have been an illusion. The analysis of the composition of core, periphery, and semiperiphery and of its changes over time allows us to identify groups of states that have consistently remained within or on the boundaries of a given position throughout the forty five year period. Arrighi and Drangel identify 75 such states out of the 93 in cluded in their analysis and call them "organic" members of the three structural positions of the world-economy-lO in the core, 21 in the semiperiphery, and 44 in the periphery. 7 The data of these organic members are then used to con struct indices of coreness , peripherality, and semiperipherality that presumably reflect sk'uctural (long-term) rather than conjunctural (middle-term) characteristics of the three positions. The first set of indices concerns''relative economic command," as measured by the logged weighted average and the range (mean plus/minus standard devia tion) of the GNP per capita of the organic members of the three positions. These indices are plotted in figure 2.2 and provide us with a striking visual image of the unbridgeable gulfs that separate the oligarchic wealth of core states from the democratic wealth of semiperipheral states and the latter from the poverty of peripheral states. When we look at groups of states rather than individual states, the hierarchy of wealth of the capitalist world-economy appears to be as well entrenched today as it was fifty years ago. During the period as a whole, the relative economic command of the core vis-a-vis the periphery and the semiperiphery has increased, Figure 2.2 0Z (J (J 0 u ...J 0- 2.0 3.0 I I �I - 19481950 �I I -� � --'- --- "" ":> It > +t� ' � GNP Per Capita of Organic 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 0- 9� � .c 1983 ¥ @{�:�:t���:��;�:��:t.��:t�:�t��t��::� ::.; ,':::�:���:�t���:�:��:�:: :: "' ._.,..._ · ::: . ...." ...."' ..:.:" . �.I! . .", �. .:., ..::"' �:.:::: ., . "' __.,:::"" , ,:", ::� "', :.:::� : "" : .::t: . "' .,i;-- -=--=-.:.:.::. �Y,," ���\ I ,-'----'---'-'�..;....� 1938 . ........,.., � 13 ···.·. · .· """"",,,,,,,,.,_ Trends in Relative Economic Command (Weighted Averages and Ranges of Members) 24 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System while that of the semiperiphery vis-a-vis the periphery has remained about the same. Core, periphery, and semiperiphery, as structural positions, are as wide apart today as they ever were. To be sure, in this picture there have also been periods in which either or both of the two gaps were narrowing (e. g. , 1950-1960, when they were both narrow ing). But whenever a narrowing took place, a widening soon followed to reestablish the gap. Particularly striking in this respect is the absolute and relative collapse of both indices of the semiperiphery (weighted average and range of GNP)-a collapse, incidentally, that has been confirmed by trends since 1983. This col lapse shows how the absolute and relative gains of thirty years can be wiped out in the short span of three years.8 Since the collapse has been closely associated with the explosion of so-called world-debt crisis, it also shows that unilateral transfers of monetary resources are as effective a weapon in keeping peripheral and semiperipheral states in their place as any other. 2.2 with those 2.3 is highly instructive. Figure 2.3 displays two alternative indices of In this connection, a corn parison of the indices plotted in figure in figure the degree of industrialization of the organic members of the three zones. They show, at first, a widening of the gap between core and both periphery and semi periphery, and then a progressive and marked closing of the gap that, according to one index, culminates in the overtaking of the core by the semiperiphery in degree of industrialization. For those who cannot tell the difference between industrialization and economic advance, this narrowing of gaps is taken as evidence of widespread development and catching up. In fact, the focus on industrialization is another source of developmentalist illusions. By comparing figure 2.2 and figure 2.3, we can clearly see that the narrowing of the industrialization gap has been matched by a basic stability of the gap in relative economic command, and that the final overtaking of the core by the semiperiphery in degree of industrialization corresponds to the collapse of the absolute and relative economic command of the latter. From this perspective, the spread of industrialization appears not as development of the semiperiphery but as peripheralization of industrial activities. [The] industrialization of the semiperiphery and periphery has ultimately been a channel , not of subversion but of reproduction of the hierarchy of the world-economy. This find ing illustrates the process . . . whereby the generalized attempt by political and economic actors to capture what at any given time are core activities stimulates competition that turns these activities into peripheral ones . . . . In the 1940s, industrial activities (or at least many of them) were indeed core activities. In the 1 950s, lured by the "spectacular prizes " thrown at such activities , political and economic actors of the periplle ry and semiperiphery threw themselves into' 'industrialization. " At first, they reaped some benefits and thereby induced others to follow suit. In the 1960s and 1970s, however, industrial activities became increasingly overcrowded so that not only the spectacular prizes disap peared, but even the smaller benefits reaped by the early-late-comers progressively turned into the widespread losses of the 1980s . (Arrighi and Drangel 1986, 56-57) 30 40 20 30 10 Semlperlphery Core . 1938 Source: � 0 !! 10 "- '0 0 <.:J "- � � 0 . � � 0 "-� 1l o '0 .D (; ::i 20 o u. !! � "C o � al 1948 1950 Per tphery .- 1965 19tiO Periphery 1�)65 S.!I1III>CIII>hery Core -- 1960 Core 1970 197� 1980 1983 Periphery ... Semlpertphery ______ (or9<1nIC memhersJ �910 ___ e 1975 1980 ;::-:-:,.c:::- 1!l83 Per Iphery Core ....... $t!nl\per tpher y hi �Imple avl!fi:lge 01 the �hi:lre at GOP In manufacturing (organic member')} .-. � ____ e-------.... S"Hnple allelilges of the percent of Idbor force t'mp!oYL'<t In "ul<lmlry" Figure 2.3 Trends in the Degree o f Industrializat ion 26 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System THE POLITICS OF SEMIPERIPHERAL DEVELOPMENT The fact that the industrialization of the semiperiphery has not changed the core periphery structure of the capitalist world-economy does not mean that nothing has changed. On the contrary , the industrialization of the semiperiphery has been part of a wider social revolution that has radically changed the conditions of accumu lation on a world scale. As Eric Hobsbawm has remarked, "The period from 1950 to 1975 . . . saw the most spectacular, rapid, far-reaching, profound, and world wide social change in global history. . . . [This] is the first period in which the peasantry became a minority, not merely in industrial developed countries, in several of which it had remained very strong, but even in third world countries" (198 6, 13). This quantum leap in the proletarianization of the world has created tensions and contradictions that will decisively influence the politics of the world-economy for generations to come. The semiperiphery is the epicenter of these tensions and contradictions. Widespread processes of proletarianization and industrialization have endowed the industrial proletariat of the semiperiphery with a social power comparable to that previously enjoyed only by the proletariat of the core but in a national context of relative deprivation long forgotten (if ever experienced) in core states. This combination of proletarian social power and relative depriva tion is at the roots of the general "crisis of dictatorships " that has swept the semiperiphery in the 1970s and 1980s. Parliamentary democracy has never been at home in the semiperiphery. The last f orty years have been no exception. Of the twenty-two states that qualify as organic members of the semiperiphery, only two comparatively small states (Costa Rica and Ireland) have been ruled throughout the last forty years by a parliamen tary democracy akin to that of core states. Another two small states (Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago) have had a similar experience, but only since they at tained independence from Great Britain in the early 19 60s. Apart from these four states , which account for 1.3 percent of the total population of the organic semiperiphery , all the other states positioned in the intermediate layer of the hier archy of wealth of the capitalist world-economy have been ruled by authoritarian regimes for some or all of the last f orty years. Leaving aside the special cases of Hong Kong (a British colony throughout the period) and of Israel and South Africa (to be dealt with in the final section of the chapter), the other fifteen states, which account for 92. 6 percent of the total population of the organic semiperiphery , have experienced two kinds of authoritarian regime. One kind has been experienced for varying lengths of time by every organic semiperipheral state of Latin America and Southern Europe with the exception of Costa Rica (Argentina, Uruguay, Chile, Venezuela, Panama, Mexico, Portugal, Spain, Greece, and Turkey). The other kind has held sway f or the entire period over the USSR and the "popular democracies" of Eastern Europe, some of which also qualify as organic members of the semi periphery.9 Notwithstanding their different origins, forms, and designations (fascist, cor poratist, bureaucratic-authoritarian, military, and so on), the authoritarian regimes The Developmentalisc Illusion 27 of the first kind have been characterized by a common predisposition that sets them clearly apart from the authoritarian regimes of the second kind. This common predisposition has been (1) to preserve extreme class inequalities in the distribu tion of personal wealth within their domains, and (2) to perform subordinate func tions in global processes of capital accumulation. The fact that semiperipheral states as a group can never attain the national stan dards of wealth set by core states does not mean that particular classes or groups within the semi periphery cannot enjoy standards of wealth analogous to those of their counterparts in the core. On the contrary, fractions of the upper and mid dle classes of the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery have traditionally enjoyed standards of wealth that compare quite favorably with those of their counterparts in core states. These fractions are less numerous relative to total population than in the core, but they are just as wealthy. The other side of the coin has been a mass poverty for the lower classes of the semiperiphery that resembles or even exceeds that of their counterparts in the periphery.1O Faced with this kind of extreme inequality in the distribution of personal wealth, the authoritarian regimes of the Southern European and Latin American semiperi phery have generally performed one of two functions. They have either protected the accumulation and enjoyment of oligarchic wealth by the upper and middle classes from the demands and struggles of the excluded and exploited masses, or they have regulated the ..ansfer of oligarchic wealth from one fraction to another of the upper and middle classes. In any event, the authoritarian regimes, unlike the authoritarian regimes of the USSR and Eastern Europe, have seldom, if ever, purposefully undermined the structural foundations of oligarchic wealth and mass poverty within their domains. To the extent that these foundations have been under mined, the main force at work has been the unfolding of world-systemic tenden cies, which the ruling elites of these states neither initiated nor controlled. These world-systemic tendencies can be traced to the long-term effects of acute intracore hegemonic rivalries of the first half of the twentieth rivalries gave a tremendous impulse to the development of organized core states and of national liberation movements in the periphery. As of these parallel developments, which came to fruition after World W states and capitalist enterprises were forced to make major concessions to labor, while their capabilities to counterbalance these concessions with extensive and intensive exploitation of the human and natural resources periphery became more constrained than they had previously been. Under th'ese circumstances it became increasingly profitable for core capitalist enterprises to set up and expand production facilities in the semiperiphery and/or to recruit labor in the semiperiphery for exploitation in the core itself.)) The authoritarian regimes of the Southern European and Latin American semi periphery actively encouraged both the relocation of production facilities to their domains and the recruitment of labor from their domains, in sharp contrast with the authoritarian regimes of the USSR and Eastern Europe, which actively op posed them (with the partial exception of Yugoslavia insofar as labor recruitment 28 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System was concerned). As a matter of fact, from the early 1950s to the middle 1970s, the provision of safe and profitable production sites for core capitalist enterprises and the supply of comparatively cheap and disciplined labor power for exploita tion within their domains or, via migration, in core states became the main voca tion of the authoritarian regimes of the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery. The main attraction of this vocation was that it promised, and in most cases actually delivered, temporary but substantial surpluses of hard cur rencies, which could be used to maintain, reproduce, and expand the oligarchic wealth enjoyed by the most fortunate fractions of the upper and middle classes of these states. In the longer run, however, this "openness" of the authoritarian regimes of the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery has been self-defeating. The more semiperipheral states competed with one another in the provision of safe and profitable production sites and of cheap and disciplined labor sup plies, the worse the terms that each and every one of them obtained for the per formance of these subordinate functions in the global accumulation of capital. Furthermore, the spread of urbanization and the ever-widening participation of their labor forces in core processes of production and exchange, at home or abroad, progressively exhausted their comparatively large reserves of nonwage labor on which the competitiveness of their labor supplies had previously rested. As the labor supplies of the Southern European and Latin American semi periphery became less competitive, absolutely and in comparison with the labor force of select core and peripheral locales, the benefits to core capital of expanding pro duction in these regions or of recruiting labor from them decreased correspon dingly, and the previous surpluses of hard currencies turned into soaring deficits. Up to a point, the increasing social power of the expanding proletarian mass of these regions could be and was kept in check by a more intensive and exten sive use of coercive methods. Over time, however, coercive methods could not keep up with the ever-increasing contradiction of a process of proletarianization and industrialization that increased the social power of the lower classes without significantly alleviating their mass misery. The progressive displacement of authoritarian regimes by parliamentary democracies that has characterized the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery since 1974 can be inter preted as evidence of the inability of coercive rule to keep indefinitely under control the contradictions of prosystemic semiperipheral development. 12 Whether parliamentary democracy with its greater reliance on consent can control these contradictions more effectively than authoritarian regimes is a question to which we shall return in the concluding section of the chapter. F or now, let us notice that the prosystemic authoritarian regimes of the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery are not the only ones to have ex perienced a crisis. The crisis has lately caught up also with the authoritarian regimes of the USSR and of the Eastern European semiperiphery. As already mentioned, these authoritarian regimes have pursued policies vis-a-vis class ine qualities within their domains and vis-a-vis processes of capitalist accumulation The Developmentalist Illusion 29 in the world-economy that contrast sharply with those pursued b y the authoritarian regimes of Southern Europe and Latin America, at least up to the present crisis . If the orientation of the latter can be characterized as " prosystemic, " that of the former may well deserve the designation of "antisystemic. " This anti systemic orientation has not been pure rhetoric. In intrastate relations it has found expression in a more or less thorough revolution in the distribution of personal wealth, which has been extensively " democratized" in the sense that, comparatively speaking, oligarchic wealth has been largely eliminated and mass poverty considerably alleviated. In interstate relations it has found expression in a refusal, backed by force, to play the kind of subordinate role in global pro cesses of capital accumulation that has been played by the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery. Up to very recently, their "doors" have been kept as closed as they could possibly be both to foreign direct investment and (with the exception of Yugoslavia) to recruitment of labor for exploitation abroad. The coercive character of these regimes has been closely related to the pursuit of these antisystemic objectives. The purpose and dynamics of processes of proletarianization and industrializa tion in the Soviet and Eastern European semiperiphery have accordingly been quite different from what they have been in the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery. As already noted, in the latter these processes have been primarily the expression of world-systemic forces that local ruling elites neither initiated nor controlled but tried to exploit in order to create, reproduce, or expand within their domains one form or another of oligarchic wealth. In the Soviet and Eastern European semiperiphery, in contrast, proletarianization and industrialization were the expression of purposive actions undertaken by local ruling elites in order (1) to revolutionize social relations domestically and (2) to restructure power relations internationally. Domestically, the one-sided and forcible pursuit of proletarianization dustrialization was aimed at restructuring social relations so as to "'W'''''''''" power of the newly established antisystemic regimes over their rpcnp,'tn,TPcl societies. While proletarianization was used to destroy all possible autonomous social power for the bourgeoisie ("great" and "petty" alike), alization was used to create a proletariat thoroughly dependent for protection on the new ruling class. Internationally, proletarianization and industrialization were aimed at turing interstate relations so as to enhance the power of the regimes in in the world-system at large. While industrialization was used to develop capabilities comparable to those of core states, proletarianization was a key in strument in providing the resulting military-industrial complexes with the human and natural resources required by their development, maintenance, and competitive expansion. The success of antisystemic semiperipheral development in furthering these ob jectives has been considerable and accounts for the historically greater power and stability of the authoritarian regimes of the Soviet and Eastern European 30 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System semiperiphery in comparison to the authoritarian regimes of the Southern Euro pean and Latin American semiperiphery .13 In particular, the main contradiction of prosystemic proletarianization and industrialization-the fact, that is, that they increased the social power of the lower classes without significantly alleviating their mass misery-has affected to a much lesser extent, or not at all, the authoritarian regimes of the Soviet and Eastern European semiperiphery, primarily because the alleviation of mass misery has been part and parcel of their developmental strategy. But this developmental strategy had contradictions of its own that are coming to a head in the present crisis. As foreseen by Isaac Deutscher (19 67) with special reference to the Soviet Union, the most important such contradiction results from the fact that pro letarianization and industrialization bring about an increasing divergence between the power interests of the ruling elites (officials and clients of the various Com munist parties in power), on the one side, and the material interests of the in dustrial proletariat, on the other. As long as the industrial proletariat was a powerless and small minority of the subject population, the increase in its size due to proletarianization and industrialization was a factor of consolidation and enhancement of the political power of the ruling Communist parties, as the latter anticipated. However, the more the proletariat has come to include the vast ma jority of the population, the more difficult it has become for the ruling Com munist parties to claim credibly to represent it against the interests of groups and classes that have been by now largely or completely eliminated. The coercive methods of rule practiced by Communist parties have thus ap peared less and less a means to the end of protecting the interests of a weak pro letariat vis-a-vis more powerful social groups and classes, and more and more a means to the end of protecting the power and privileges of party officials and their clients from the effects of generalized proletarianization. At the same time, it has become more difficult f or the ruling Communist parties to improve further the standards of living of the expanding proletariat. The initial improvements were due primarily to the forcible "democratization" of national wealth. Once national wealth had been "democratized," improvements came to be constrained by systemic conditions (first and foremost the semiperipheral position of these states in the hierarchy of wealth of the capitalist world-economy), which these ruling elites could do little to change. This contradiction was compounded by the increasing difficulties the Communist regimes had in keeping up with the power of core states in the world-system. Initially, authoritarian rule could be presented as necessary in order to reallocate forcibly resources from the reproduction of the oligarchic wealth of the upper classes to the construction, maintenance, and reproduction of military-industrial complexes capable of protecting the subject population in general, and its lower classes in particular, from powerful and aggressive foes. But as this reallocation was completed, and the aggressiveness of neighboring and distant foes was suc cessfully tamed, the social costs of keeping up with the military-industrial com plexes of core states sharply increased, and its social benefits sharply decreased. The Developmentalist Illusion 31 Social costs increased sharply because the resources necessary to keep up with the military-industrial complexes of core states could no longer come from the curtailment of oligarchic wealth, which had largely vanished from the domains ·.,.ofthese regimes. Rather, they had to come from a curtailment of democratic wealth, that is, from the long-term income of a thoroughly proletarianized civil . society. Social benefits decreased sharply because once the aggressiveness of neighbors had been tamed, the endless accumulation of means of war brought less and not more security to the sub ject population. THE SEMIPERIPHERY AND THE FUTURE OF THE WORLD-ECONOMY In introducing the concept of semiperiphery, hnmanuel Wallerstein maintained that the existence of the semiperiphery is essential to the stability of the capitalist world-economy. Politically, a system polarized in a small distinct high-status and high-income sector, on the one side, and a large, relatively autonomous, low status, low-income sector, on the other side, would lead quite rapidly to acute and disintegrating struggles. The major political means by which such crises are averted is the creation of "middle" sectors, which tend to think of themselves primarily as better off than the lower sectors rather than worse off than the upper sector. This obvious mechanism, operative in all kinds of social structures, serves the same function in world-systems (Wallerstein 1979, 69). In addition to this political function, the semi periphery performs the economic function of relieving capital from congestion in the core. For individual capitalists, the ability to shift capital, from a declining sector to a rising sector, is the only way to survive the effects of cyclical shifts in the loci of the sectors. For this there must be sectors able to profit from the wage-productivity of the leading sector. Such sectors are what we are calling semiperipheral they weren't there, the capitalist system would as rapidly face an economic would a political crisis. (Wallerstein, 1979, 70; emphasis in the original) In contrast but not necessarily in contradiction to this view, Chase-Dunn 1990) has recently advanced the thesis that semiperipheries have been eX(;epIUOIlatt fertile grounds for antisystemic and transformative action. In his view, true of the capitalist world-economy as it has been true of all previous systems. The analysis developed in this chapter can be used to reconcile these contrasting emphases and to throw some light on the possible implications of the current crisis of authoritarian rule in the semiperiphery for the future of the capitalist world-economy. As a first approximation, we may say that over the last half century or so the experience of Southern Europe and Latin America provides evidence in support of Wallerstein's thesis of a prosystemic orientation and function of the semiperiphery, whereas the experience of the USSR and Eastern Europe provides 32 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System evidence in support of Chase-Dunn ' s thesis of an antisystemic orientation and function of the semiperiphery .14 If the existence of a prosystemic semi periphery is essential to the stability of the capitalist world-system, what are the implica tions of the general crisis of prosystemic and antisystemic authoritarian regimes in the semiperiphery? Is this general crisis likely to increase or to decrease the stability of the capitalist world-system? At the moment, the dominant trend seems to be a propagation to the entire semiperiphery of the prosystemic and stable parliamentary regimes that have been the norm in the organic core since World War II. Over the last fifteen years the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery has moved with unpre cedented determination toward parliamentary democracies without any noticeable change in the prosystemic orientation of its governments. At the same time, the regimes of the Soviet and Eastern European semiperiphery have greatly relaxed their antisystemic orientation and have begun to experiment with various forms of parliamentary democracy. This trend is an expression of the general crisis of coercive rule in the semiperiphery that, if our previous analysis is correct, has deep structural roots and therefore can be expected to continue into the foreseeable future. Yet this trend is more an expression of the crisis than a solution of the crisis. The even tual outcome of the crisis remains unclear. In particular, it is not clear what will happen to prosystemic parliamentary democracy as it becomes the rule rather than the exception in the semiperiphery. One possibility is that the semiperiphery will simply follow in the footsteps of the core without introducing any major innovation in the form and substance of parliamentary democracy. This possibility is unlikely. The close association since World War II between prosystemic and stable parliamentary democracies, on the one side, and the oligarchic wealth of the states that have experienced such regimes, on the other, has not been accidental. Abundance of means creates possibilities for mobilizing and reproducing prosystemic consent among the lower classes that are simply not available under conditions of relative or absolute scar city. Under the conditions of abnormal abundance that characterize and define core positions, the pursuit of power and wealth by the upper classes can be easily reconciled with the pursuit of livelihood by the lower classes. As the historical record shows, it is under these conditions that stable prosystemic parliamentary democracies have prospered, almost regardless of the historical peculiarities of the states and peoples involved. But under the conditions of relative and absolute scarcity typical of the periphery and semiperiphery , such democracies have been the exception rather than the rule. As already mentioned, among organic semiperipheral states there have been cases of stable prosystemic parliamentary democracies. The most stable have been Ireland, and Costa Rica, followed by Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago. Among the most recent acquisitions to the prosystemic parliamentary camp, Spain, Greece, and Portugal seem at the moment the most likely to replicate faithfully and lastingly the experience of the core. Elsewhere it is too soon to tell. The Developmentalist Illusion 33 Except for Spain, the states just mentioned are all very small. Including Spain, they account for less than 10 percent of the total population of the organic semiperiphery. Given their small individual and aggregate size and, above all, the peculiarities of their geography and history, it has been possible for these states to work out special deals, either with the North American or with the West European core (or both), that have strengthened simultaneously their parliamen tary institutions and their prosystemic orientation. However, it is doubtful that deals of this kind can be extended to the majority, let alone to the totality, of semiperipheral states. All available evidence seems to suggest that large parts of the semiperiphery are likely to be left out of such deals. A new and enlarged Marshall Plan would be required for most of the semiperiphery to be included. However, core states seem neither willing nor capable of such an undertaking. For one thing, they lack the collective will and intelligence that the conception and execution of such a plan require. The crisis of U .S. hegemony has left behind rather ineffectual world agencies whose main preoccupation is the day-to-day, case-by-case management of world monetary resources rather than the use of such resources to promote long-term, large-scale institutional change. In addition, the current trend toward greater " openness" on the part of the antisystemic semiperiphery can be expected to have a negative effect on the chances of semi peripheral states in general to squeeze advantageous deals out of the core. This trend weakens the predisposition of core states to make special deals with semiperipheral states, because much of that predisposition was previously due to the need to keep at least part of the semi periphery open to the global activities of core states and enterprises. But even if the predisposition of core states to of fer special deals to some semi peripheral states remains unchanged, the increase in the number of states offering special deals to the core reduces what semiperi pheral states can, on average, squeeze out of the core. What a few might all cannot. Last but not least, the acute economic competition among core states that has followed the full reconstruction of world-market rule-a tion completed in the early 1 970s-is inducing core states and enterprises the ante in the race to cut costs. Among other things, this has meant a of the semiperiphery (whose competitiveness has been exhausted anyway cessive exploitation and self-exploitation) and a search for closer links with peripheral locales. The recent economic " miracles" of South Korea and (their ascent from periphery to semiperiphery) are an expression of this tendenc cy. Far from providing a model for the future of the semiperiphery , these suc cessful transitions to the semiperiphery have aggravated the present troubles of the states that already were in the semiperiphery. 15 For all these reasons it is highly unlikely that the post-Franco experience of Spain will be replicated by many other semi peripheral states of comparable size. A few Eastern European states may replicate this experience, but for each new Spain the chances are that there are going to be a few more Argentinas-the state 34 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System that better than any other epitomizes the political impasse of a structural situation in which neither authoritarian rule nor parliamentary democracy can deliver the goods it promises . 16 Worse still, for each new Spain and a few more Argentinas, the current trend toward prosystemic parliamentary democracy in the semiperiphery may generate many South Africas and Israels. South Africa and Israel are organic semiperipheral states. Yet neither of them fits into any of the three main groups of organic semi peripheral states identified in the previous section (stable prosystemic parliamentary regimes, prosystemic authoritarian regimes, and antisystemic authoritarian regimes). Rather, they are hybrid regimes combining traits typical of the other three kinds of regime. Over the last forty years , South Africa and Israel have been stable prosystemic parliamentary regimes, like Ireland and Costa Rica. Nevertheless, particular groups among their sub jects (blacks in South Africa and Arabs in Israel) have been excluded from effective participation in the parliamentary process. Toward the groups deprived or excluded from the enjoyment of full political rights, both regimes have used methods of rule as coercive as those used by prosystemic and antisystemic authoritarian regimes. This use 0f coercive methods 0 f rule combined with a strong prosystemic orien tation has made these regimes resemble the prosystemic authoritarian regimes of the Southern European and Latin American semiperiphery. However, they have differed sharply from these regimes, not just because of the stability of their parliamentary institutions, but because their social base has consisted of a par ticular ethnonation (the Afrikaner ethnonation in South Africa , the Jewish ethnona tion in Israel) rather than of particular fractions of the upper and middle classes. 17 A s a matter o f fact, from this point o f view the regimes o f South Africa and Israel present important analogies with the antisystemic authoritarian regimes of the Soviet and Eastern European semiperiphery. Like the ruling elites of the lat ter, the ruling elites of the f ormer have been actively engaged in a policy of in dustrialization aimed at restructuring to their own advantage both social relations within their domains and power relations in the interstate system. In the process, they have considerably improved the life chances of the ethnonations on which their power rests (the life chances of the lower classes of such ethnonations in particular) and have built small but highly effective military-industrial complexes that have turned these states into regional powers of great significance. Up to the present, this kind of hybrid regime has been an anomaly among organic semi peripheral states. Nevertheless, it is quite possible that the ongoing crisis of the prosystemic and antisystemic authoritarian regimes of the semiperiphery will become a breeding ground of new varieties of extreme ethnonationalist democratic regimes, more or less parliamentary and more or less prosystemic according to circumstances. Unable either to satisfy or to repress popular demands for livelihood and democracy, an increasing number of regimes of the semiperi phery may be tempted to seek a way out of this political impasse by satisfying The Developmentalist Illusion 35 these demands selectively on the basis of racial, ethnic, and religious discrimina tions among their subjects. 18 To be sure, this kind of " solution" of the crisis of legitimacy faced by semiperi pheral authoritarian regimes has its own contradictions. Over time, exploitative and/or exclusionary ethnonationalisms tend to generate countermovements that effectively undermine the power of the dominant ethnonations, as witnessed by the current crisis of both the South African and the Israeli regimes. Nevertheless, as the experience of these regimes shows, the emergence of effective counter movements takes long periods of time during which human hatred and suffering may escalate beyond what is in anyone's power to control. What kind of world-system will emerge out of this turmoil is hard to say. On the one hand, the escalation of racial, ethnic, and religious animosities in the semiperiphery may link up with and enhance similar trends in the core and periphery. Left unchecked, this tendency may well plunge the world into a situa tion of systemic chaos worse than that of the first half of the twentieth century. On the other hand, the attempts and struggles to contain and counteract this escala tion may create in the semiperiphery new forms of popular democracy capable of laying the foundations of a less exploitative and exclusionary world-system. What these new forms of democracy will look like, no one can tell. Like all innovations, they will emerge out of a long-drawn-out process of trial and error and will come to seem obvious and " natural"· only after their consolidation. All we can say for now is that they will look neither like the ' 'popular democracies " that are being swept away by the general crisis 0 f coercive rule in the semiperiphery nor like the parliamentary democracies of the core that have been built on an abundance of means that cannot be generalized. NOTES In revising the chapter for publication I have benefited from comments and by Christopher Chase-Dunn, Walter L. Goldfrank, Terence K. Hopltins, William G. Gonzalo Santos, Beverly J. Silver, and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1 . This characterization sums up the stated and unstated premises of most have made use of the concepts of core, periphery, and semiperiphery . Very few studies have actually attempted to identify core, peripheral, and semiperipheral states on the basis of their positions in trade networks. Notable exceptions are Snyder and Kick ( 1 979), Nemeth and Smith ( 1 985), and Smith and White ( 1 9 89) . 2. On the distinction between peripheralization through the mobility of capital (or transfer of surplus) peripheralization through the mobility of goods (or unequal exchange), and peripheralization through the mobility of labor (or direct surplus extraction) , see Ar righi and Piselli (1987, 687-97). These authors show that each mechanism of peripheraliza tion is associated with a particular kind of social structure and social conflict. 3. See Arrighi and Drangel (1 986) for sources and arguments supporting this claim. To simplify matters and make exposition easier, I posit here that " states" rather than capitalist enterprises are the key actors in processes of capital accumulation. For the purposes 36 The Semiperiphery in the Madern Warld-System at hand this simplification is legitimate because it does not affect significantly the conclu sions of the analysis. Moreover, the assumption that states are the key actors in processes of capital accumulation is relaxed in the sections on "The Politics of Semiperipheral Development" and "The Semiperiphery and the Future of the World-Economy , " which focus on the class and ethnic structure of states . 4. As Wallerstein remarks (1979, 76) , developmental ideology is merely the global version of R. H. Tawney's Tadpole Philosophy : "It is possible that intelligent tadpoles reconcile themselves to the inconveniences of their position, by reflecting that, though most of them will live and die as tadpoles and nothing more, the more fortunate of the species will one day shed their tails, distend their mouths and stomachs , hop nimbly on to dry land, and croak addresses to their former friends on the virtues by means of which tadpoles of character and capacity can rise to be frogs. This conception of society may be described, perhaps, as the Tadpole Philosophy, since the consolation which it offers for social evils consists in the statement that exceptional individuals can succeed in evading them . . . . And what a view of human life such an attitude implies! As though oppor tunities for talents to rise could be equalized in a society where circumstances surround ing it from birth are themselves unequal ! As though, if they could, it were natural and proper that the position of the mass of mankind should permanently be such that they can attain civilization only by escaping from it! As though the noblest use of exceptional powers were to scramble to shore, undeterred by the thought of drowning companions! " (Tawney as quoted in Wallerstein 1979, 1 0 1 ) . 5 . Since the use o f GNP per capita to identify the position of states i n the core-periphery structure of the world-economy has been widely questioned (among others by Chase-Dunn 1989; Smith and White 1989; Glenday 1 989) , two clarifications on its use by Arrighi and Drangel are in order. First, they use GNP per capita only as a measure,ment of relative economic command over world resources by the residents of different political jurisdic tions. That is to say, they try to measure the command exercised by the residents of a given jurisdiction over the resources owned by the residents of all other jurisdictions, relative to the command exercised by the latter over the resources owned by the former. No significance is accordingly attached to the GNP per capita of a state except in relation to all the GNPs per capita of the other states in the system, each GNP being assigned a weight corresponding to its share of world population. Second, relative economic command in this sense is used to assess the position of a state in the core-periphery structure of the world-economy only through multiple obser vations covering as long a period of time as allowed by the availability of data. The dif ferent zones (or layers) of the world-economy are defined by the distribution of world population by GNP per capita at particular points in time. But a state is defined as an organic member of a given zone only if it appears to have been positioned in a given zone for the entire forty-five-year period covered by the analysis . The rationale of this pro cedure is that only over time can relative GNP per capita be taken to measure "wealth" rather than "income . " 6. For some reason, which would be interesting to investigate, Libya has the power of arousing strong emotions, not just among politicians , but among social scientists as well. The fact that according to Arrighi and Drangel ( 1 986, 44) , Libya rose to core posi tion in the 1970s has been considered by many as sufficient reason for dismissing as in valid their entire methodology. An Italian journal turned down the article apparently for this reason alone. Glenday states squarely that he is " skeptical of a methodology that would lead one to include Libya in the core while relegating the U . S . S . R . to the semiperiphery " The Developmentalist Illusion 37 (1989, 2 12) . I n a more serious but similar vein, Chase-Dunn ( 1 9 8 9 , 209) has stated that " [the] fact that Arrighi and Drangel . . . claim that Libya has moved into the core (based on their use of GNP per capita as a measure of core status) reveals the weakness of their identification of core activity with short-run returns based on any kind of activity . Libya sits on a fortune in oil but, by any other measure besides GNP per capita, Libya is clearly not a core state . " Since the position assigned to Libya seems to b e the ultimate test o f the validity o f the Arrighi and Drangel analysis, I shall quote at length from a letter that I wrote on May 20, 1987, to Chase-Dunn in response to his criticism. Let me point out first of all that we do not include Libya (or for that matter Italy or Japan) among the organic members of the core zone. Personally, I have serious doubts that it will ever become one, just as I am certain that Japan already has. (I have no strong views on Italy one way or another) . . . . However, ifby any chance Libya's GNP per capita of the 1990's or ofthe 2000's will still place Libya within the core zone, I see no reason for not including it among the organic members of the core zone, regardless of the way in which its core position was conquered initially and reproduced subsequently . Your assertion that at the moment Libya is where it is in the GNP per capita ranking because it sits on an oil well is indisputable. Yet, I cannot help but ask, "so what? " Of the ten states defined in our article as organic members of the core (p. 69), at least four (Australia, Canada, New Zealand and the U.S.A.) and possibly another two (Norway and Sweden) originally entered the core zone thanks (among other things) to the fact that they were "sitting" on an extremely favorable endow ment of material resources per head of population. At the same time, there are at least as many states (Argentina, Russia, South Africa and Brazil being only the most obvious instances) that at one point or another of their history had an equally favorable endowment but never became temporary, let alone organic, members of the core zone. In short, "sitting" on particular resources (or on particular loca tions) is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for stable membership of the core zone. In order to stabilize its present core position, Libya must meet a whole series of requirements which only in part depend on the "will and intelligence" of its political and economic entrepreneurs. To be skeptical about the chances of such stabilization means to be skeptical about the power of this "will and intelligence" in relation to systemic forces beyond the control of Libya's entrepreneurs . Only time can tell whether this skepticism is well founded. In the meantime, the more or less tern" porary core position of Libya is very real and is measured adequately by its GNP per capita. Libyan residents have a command over world-economic resources which is equal to that of members of the core zone (organic or not). This command has been exercised not only ports of commodities but also through the acquisition of foreign labor power for Libya and of claims over the profits of core enterprises (e. g. , Fiat). The command has been there. The particular way in which it has been (is being) used is a different matter the reasons why I thiok that the chances of Libya to become an organic member of the core To this I have only to add that the latest World Development Report (World Bank reporting GNP per capita for 1 987) gives figures for Libya's GNP per capita that back in the semiperiphery, as anticipated by the skepticism expressed in the letter. 7. The exact procedure followed in classifying states in these three categories is detailed in Appendix III of the Arrighi and Drangel article, which also gives a complete list of the organic members of the three zones (1986, 65-7 1 ) . 8. This finding shows the serious limitations o f Robert W. Jacnan' s empirical test of what he calls the Matthew Effect (from Matthew 1 3 : 1 2 , "For whosoever hath, to him shall be given, and he shall have more abundance: but whosoever hath not, from him shall be taken away even that he hath " ) . By regressing average annual growth rates in per capita GNP, 1960 to 1978, on per capita GNP, 1 960, he finds that "there is little evidence of the commonly-argued Matthew effect where the core has experienced higher rates of growth 38 The Semiperiphery in the Modern World-System than the periphery . " Instead, his estimates "suggest a modified Matthew effect within Third World countries , such that the initially wealthiest of these have grown more rapidly than the West which, in turn, has grown faster than the poorest countries of the Third World. It is important to remember, however, that even this modified Matthew effect is not a strong one" (Jackman 1982, 193-95). As can be seen from Figure 2 . 2 in the text, Jacnan's findings concern a period (1960-1978) in which the organic semiperiphery (and, hence, the wealthier Third World countries) performed exceptionally well relative to both the organic core and the organic periphery . But Figure 2 . 2 also shows that if we were to extend Jackman ' s analysis beyond 1980, we would probably find strong support for the hypothesis of a Matthew effect not just between the wealthy and the poor but also between the superwealthy and the moderately wealthy . 9. In this and in the next section I shall focus on the twenty-one states that Arrighi and Drangel identify as organic members of the semi periphery . To these I add Poland, which was excluded from their analysis, with four other Eastern European states (Ger man Democratic Republic, Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria, and Albania) , for lack of reliable data. The data that we do have suggest that Poland has almost certainly been an organic member of the semiperiphery like Hungary , the USSR, and Romania. The German Democratic Republic and Czechoslovakia have probably been' 'precarious " members of the core and Bulgaria and Albania either " precarious " members of the semiperiphery or more or less upwardly mobile members of the periphery . By "precarious " members of the core (semiperiphery) I mean states that were in the core (semi periphery) at the beginning and at the end of the period 1938-1983 but were temporarily demoted to semiperipheral (peripheral) status somewhere in the middle of the period. The most important precarious semiperipheral states have been Algeria, Brazil, Colombia, Iran, Iraq, Malaysia, Nicaragua, and Syria. These states, together with up wardly mobile semiperipheral states, are excluded from consideration in this and in the next section because my purpose is to construct a preliminary typology of semi peripheral political regimes controlling for stability in the hierarchy of wealth of the world economy. Future research should verify whether and how this typology can be usefully extended to include precarious and upwardly mobile semiperipheral states . 1 0 . This statement is consistent with the widely observed "inverted U-curve" that describes the relationship between levels of "economic development" and income ine quality (see Bornschier and Chase-Dunn 1985; Kuznets 196 3 ; Nolan 1983 ; Weede 1980). 1 1 . The historical preference of core enterprises for the serniperiphery over the periphery (once the latter had been decolonized) as production site and source of labor, notwithstand ing the lower wages of the periphery, has been due to several reasons . Some are purely geographical: most semiperipheral states happen to be closer to core regions than peripheral states. Some are cultural: most semi peripheral states happen to be civilizationally closer to core states than most peripheral states. Some are strictly economic: the domestic markets (including the labor markets) of most semi peripheral states are more developed than those of most peripheral states. As we shall see, however, all these comparative advantages of the semiperiphery vis-a.-vis the periphery are subject to erosion through extensive use and become less important with the intensification of competitive pressures on core enterprises to cut labor costs. 1 2 . The rapid succession of "crises in dictatorship" in Southern Europe (Greece, Por tugal, Spain) can be taken as the watershed between the "authoritarian" and the "democratic " phases of prosystemic semiperipheral development. The Developmentalist Illusion 39 1 3 . The much greater power and stability of the authoritarian regimes o f the antisystemic semiperiphery in comparison with the authoritarian regimes of the prosystemic semiperiphery have not received the careful attention that they deserve. Most current discus sions of the ' 'failure of communism" implicitly assume that the relevant comparison in assessing "success" and "failure" is between the economic performance of the antisystemic semiperiphery and that of the core (when they do not assume, more crudely, that the size, geography , and history of states matter little in determining their "life-chances" in the capitalist world-economy). This implicit assumption does not take into account the long term stability of the core-periphery structure of the world-economy and the practical and theoretical impossibility of large-scale replicas of the historical experience of the core. A less biased comparison would be between the experiences of the antisystemic and prosystemic semiperipheries as regions of the world-economy of comparable size, popula tion, and natural resources. This comparison would probably reveal that these two regions of the world-economy, each taken in its totality, have fared equally well in keeping ahead of the poverty of the periphery and equally badly in catching up with the wealth of the core. In the aggregate, that is to say, " closure" or "openness" probably made little or no difference in advancing or retarding the relative economic command of the semiperiphery in the world-economy. Nevertheless, it is difficult to deny that "closure" has made a big difference in pro moting the power of semiperipheral states in the world-system and social justice within semiperipheral states. Recent setbacks notwithstanding, the increase in the relative capabilities of the antisystemic semiperiphery to shape and influence world politics, on the one side, and the equalization of life-chances among classes and ethnic groups within its territories, on the other, have been incomparably greater than that of the prosystemic semiperiphery . As argued in the text, the crisis of authoritarian rule in the antisystemic semiperiphery must in fact be interpreted as the joint result of its failure to catch up with the standards of wealth of the core and of its successes in restructuring world politics and national societies . 14. Wallerstein's thesis, however, must be reformulated to take into account the social polarization typical of unreformed semiperipheries. The main reason why the semiperiphery or parts thereof show a prosystemic orientation and perform pro systemic functions is the "optical illusion" whereby semiperipheral states tend to see themselves �_;_r._". better off than peripheral states rather than worse off than core states, as �l1(H,,·�tF'jj Wallerstein ( 1 979, 69). This illusion may have played a role in the hegemony over some semi peripheral states some of the time. But it is doubtful states could have been fooled in this way for long periods of time unless those who trolled the coercive and ideological apparatuses of these states had some real prosystemic interest. According to our previous analysis, this real prosystemic interest has been the possibili ty afforded by the capitalist world-system to particulat'fractions of the upper and middle classes of the semiperiphery to enjoy standards of wealth that compare very favorably with those of their counterparts in the core. This possibility is not an illusion but a very real privilege that its actual or potential beneficiaries have always tried to protect from the antisystemic predispositions of the lower classes with whatever mix of coercion, cor ruption, fraud, and consent could be mobilized effectively for the purpose. However, the mobilization of prosystemic-consent among the lower classes has always been problematic on account of their mass poverty, which, as noted, has often resembled or even exceeded 40 The Semiperiphery in the Madem Warld-System that of their counterparts in the periphery . As a consequence, the typical mode of rule of prosystemic semiperipheral states up to the recent crisis of coercive rule has consisted primarily of a mix of coercion, fraud, and corruption and has been substantively oligar chic even when it has taken a parliamentary form (see Mouzelis 1986) . 1 5 . On the geopolitical and historical specificities of the South Korean and Taiwanese "miracles, " see Cumings (1984, 1989) . Besides these specificities, we should bear in mind that the competitiveness of South Korea and Taiwan has been a significant factor in the ' 'real ization" crisis of the industrialization efforts of the organic members of the semiperiphery . When these efforts were first undertaken in the 1960s and early 1970s, it was generally expected that future exports to core markets would provide the hard currencies necessary to pay back the debts incurred to step up industrialization . An important reason why these expectations are not being realized is that the actual or prospective exports of the organic members of the semiperiphery have been "crowded out" of core markets by the exports of upwardly mobile former peripheral states, of which South Korea and Taiwan are the two most prominent and successful examples. Organic semiperipheral states have thus been stranded with obsolete industrial apparatuses and debts in hard currencies on top of them. 1 6 . Argentina has been the "leader" among the organic members of the prosystemic semiperiphery in processes of proletarianization and industrialization. If the thesis that for each new Spain there will be a few more Argentinas holds true, Peronism may be more relevant than social democracy for the future of the semiperiphery . 17. This difference between South Africa and Israel, on the one side, and other semiperipheral states, on the other, should not be exaggerated. Many prosystemic (and some antisystemic) regimes of the semiperiphery have reJied heavily in the past, and still do, on particular ethnic groups as the central base of their rule. Particularly significant in this respect has been the success met by ethnicities of European extraction in monopolizing the wealth and power of many Latin American states at the expense of large ethnic groups of Amerindian and African extraction. The main difference between these states, on the one side, and South Africa and Israel, on the other, is that discrimination in favor of or against particular ethnic groups is sanctioned and enforced through market mechanisms rather than through more visible instruments of rule. 1 8 . For an important case study of the rise of ethnonationalism from the ashes of an authoritarian anti systemic regime (Yugoslavia), see Magas (1989) . The trend has begun to be noticed with some preoccupation by core media. An editorial of theN ew York Times (June 25, 1989, 26E), entitled "Perilous Tribalism in the Balkans," mentions ethnic tensions and conflicts in Bulgaria, Romania, Poland, Yugoslavia, the USSR, Turkey , Northern Ireland, and Spain and goes on to warn about what might lie ahead: "As superpower recedes, nationalism rises. As the Soviet empire unravels, nationalist rivalries resurface, sometimes angrily . . . . The unstable mix of national chauvinism and international hate has fueled much conflict and can again. The cold war is over, but war can erupt just as surely from tribal chaos as from superpower confrontation. " REFERENCES Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel. 1986. "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone . " Review 1 0 , 1 : 9-74. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Fortunata Piselli. 1987. "Capitalist Development in Hostile En vironments : Feuds, Class Struggles, and Migrations in a Peripheral Region of Southern Italy . " Review 10, 4: 648-75 1 . The Developmentalist Illusion 41 Bomschier, Volker, and Christopher Chase-Dunn. 1985. Transnational Corporations and Underdevelopment. New York: Praeger. unn, Christopher. 1988. " Comparing World-Systems: Toward a Theory of Semi se-D Cha peripheral Development. " Comparative Civilization Review 1 9 : 29-66 . . 1989. Global Formation . New York: Basil Blackwell . 1990. "Resistance to Imperialism: Semiperipheral Actors. " Review, 1 3 , 1 , 1-3 1 . Cuming s, Bruce. 1984. "The Origins and Development of the Northeast Asian Political Economy: Industrial Sectors, Product Cycles, and Political Consequences. " Inter national Organization 38, 1 : 1-40. 1989. "The Abortive Abertura: South Korea in the Light of Latin American Experience . " New Left Review 173: 5-32 . Deutscher, Isaac . 1967 . The Unfinished Revolution: Russia, 191 7-1 967. London: Oxford _ . University Press. Emmanuel, Arghiri. 1972. Unequal Exchange . New York: Monthly Review Press. Glenday, Daniel 1989. "Rich But Semiperipheral : Canada 's Ambiguous Position in the World -Econom y . " Review 12, 2: 209-6 1 . Harrod, Roy. 1 9 5 8 . "The Possibility of Economic Satiety-Use of Economic Growth for Improving the Quality of Education and Leisure. " In Problems of United States Economic Development, 1 :207- 1 3 . New York: Committee for Economic Devel opment. Hirsch, Fred. 1976. Social Limits to Growth . Cambridge, Mass. : Harvard University Press. Hobsbawm, Eric. 1986. Comment in "Reflecting on Labor in the West since Haymarket: A Roundtable Discussion. " In The Newberry Papers in Family and Community History, edited by J. B . Jenz and J. C. MacManus, 86, 2. Jackman, Robert. 1982. " Dependence o n Foreign Investment and Economic Growth in the Third World . " World Politics 34, 2: 175-96. Kuznets, Simon. 1 96 3 . " Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations, VIII : The Distribution of Income by Size . " Economic Development and Cultural Change 1 1 : 1-80 . Magas, Branka. 1 9 8 9 . "Yugoslavia: The Spectre of Balkanization . " New Left Review 1 74: 3-3 1 . Mouzelis, Nicos. 1 98 6 . Politics in the Semiperiphery: Early Parliamentarism and Industrialization in the Balkans and Latin America. London: Macmillan. Nemeth , Roger, and David Smith. 1 9 8 5 . "International Trade and World-System ture: A Multiple Network Analysis . " Review 8, 4 : 5 17-60. Nolan, Patrick. 1983 . "Status in the World System, Income Inequality , and hcon'Drnic Growth . " American Journal of Sociology 89: 410-4 1 9 . Smith, David, and Douglas White. 1989. "Structure and Dynamics of the Economy: Network Analysis of International Trade, 1 965-1980 . " manuscript. Snyder, David, and Edward Kick. 1 979. "Structural Position in the World System and Economic Growth, 1 955- 1 970: A Multiple-Net�ork Analysis of Transnational In teractions . " American Journal of Sociology 84, 5 : 1096- 1 126. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1 979. The Capitalist World-Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press. . 1 9 8 8 . "Development: Lodestar o r Illusion? " Economic and Political Weekly 23 , 39 (September 24) :2017-23. ___ Warren, Bill. 1980. Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism. London: New Left Books. 42 The Semiperiphery in the Modem World-System Weede, Erich. 1980. "Beyond Misspecification in Sociological Analysis of Income In equality . " American Sociological Review 45 :497-50 1 . World Bank. 1989. World Development Report. New York: Oxford University Press. PA R T II SEMIPERIPHERAL SUCCESS STORIES? 3 COMMODITY CHAINS AND FOOTWEAR EXPORTS IN THE SEMIPERIPHERY Gary Geref/i and Miguel Korzeniewicz THE DECLINING SIGNIFICANCE OF INDUSTRIALIZATION There have been striking changes in the structure and dynamics of the world economy during the past several decades. The international division of labor has evolved beyond the classic pattern by which developing nations exported primary commodities to the industrialized countries in exchange for manufactured goods. Industrialization today is the result of an integrated system of global trade and production. International trade has allowed nations to specialize between industry and other sectors, between different branches of manufacturing, and increasing ly even between different stages of production within a single industry. This cess, fueled by an explosion of new products and new technologies since War II, has led to the emergence of a global manufacturing system in which duction capacity is dispersed to an unprecedented number of developing as as industrialized countries (Gereffi 1989a). This process of tne globalization of production has had uneven COlnS{:qulence� however. One set of countries that has done exceedingly well in the postwar is that of the East Asian countries. Japan, and its regional neighbors South Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore not only registered record economic rates during the prosperous 1960s when international trade and investment was expanding worldwide but also managed to sustain their dynamism throughout the 1970s and 198 0s in the face of severe oil price hikes, a global recession, and rising protectionism in their major export markets. This rapid economic growth, furthermore, has been accompanied by a relatively egalitarian distribution of in come that in large part is a result of significant programs of agrarian reform under taken in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan in the late 1940s and early 1950s. The rapid growth of the East Asian economies stands in sharp contrast to the experience of Latin America, which was the most industrialized region in the 46 Semi peripheral Success Stories? developing world in the 1950s and 1960s. In the past decade, however, Latin American nations have found it difficult to maintain their previous levels of economic growth as they confront mountainous external debts, high rates of in flation, shortages of investment capital, and the growing social and economic marginalization of large segments of their population. A particularly dramatic indicator of this decline is the fact that the gross national product (GNP) per capita of the four newly industrialized countries (NICs) in East Asia has increased sharply during the 1980s, while the GNP per capita of the three Latin American NICs (Brazil, Mexico, and Argentina) has stagnated and declined during these years (see Gereffi and Wyman, 1990) . The disparate social and economic consequences of industrial growth in the East Asian and Latin American NICs over the past couple of decades underscore the fact that "industrialization" and "development" can no longer be treated as synonymous . Despite similarly high levels of industrialization in the NICs from both regions, the East Asian nations have performed significantly better than their Latin American counterparts in terms of standard indicators of development such as GNP per capita, income distribution, literacy, health, and education (see World Bank 1988, tables 1, 26, 30) . Just as industrialization can not be equated with development, neither can it be equated with proximity to core status in the world-system. By the late 1970s the NICs not only caught up with but overtook the core countries in terms of degree of industrialization (Arrighi and Drangel 1986, 55; World Bank 1988, table 3) . This achievement, however, has not necessarily led to a substantive change in the position of the NICs in the hierarchy of nations in the world economy . Core countries now accumulate wealth by concentrating on the ser vice sector and on the most productive, high-value-added segments of manufac turing. While industrialization may be a necessary condition for core status in the world-system, it no longer is sufficient. Continued innovations by the most developed nations make core status an ever-receding frontier. The central objective of this chapter is to use the dynamism and heterogeneity of the East Asian and Latin American NICs to address a key issue in world-system theory : the diverse sources, paths, and consequences of mobility in the semi periphery . To explore this topic, we focus on the footwear industry. As a basic consumer good, footwear has been a central building block in the NICs' construction of linkages to the world-economy. This study provides u s with new insights about short-term patterns of semi peripheral mobility and their broader significance for the changing structure of the world-economy . Our discussion is organized as follows. First, we review the world-system literature in order to identify key concepts and propositions about semiperipheral mobility . Second, we use the notion of "commodity chains" to spatially map the location and sequence of "core" and "peripheral" economic activities across national boundaries f or the global footwear industry. Third, we describe the emergence of South Korea , Taiwan, and Brazil as the world 's leading footwear exporters in the late 1970s and the 1980s . Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 47 Fourth, we show how an analysis of the four segments of the commodity chain footwear-raw material supply, production, exports, and retail marketing Wloes a broader understanding of the opportunities and constraints for mobili � "r.. the NICs within the footwear industry. Fifth, we identify two key elements NICs ' strategy for export success: the establishment of specialized export e th ': . ' / es in the U.S. footwear market and industrial upgrading (i. e . , an increase h , nic " . in the unit value of footwear exports) within these niches to stay ahead of their , � comp etitors. Sixth, we relate our findings about relative mobility in the semiperiphery to the larger issue of the significance of industrialization for the changing structure of the world-economy. EM � \ " )' THE SEMIPERIPHERY AND MOBILITY IN THE WORLD-SYST The concept of the semiperiphery is simultaneously a crucial constituent unit : , : , of world-system theory and one of its least explicated parts. It is a crucial con < cept because the countries grouped within this category encompass some of the , most turbulent and dynamic areas of the world-economy. The term semiperiphery _ ", .identifies countries undergoing extraordinary economic growth (South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong), processes of political democratization (Argentina, Brazil, Spain, Portugal) , control over key natural resources (Venezuela, Mexico, Saudi Arabia) , and regionally critical ethnic conflicts (South Africa, Israel, Iran). Many features of the semiperiphery remain unclear, however. Part of this am biguity is the consequence of the conventional tendency to treat the semiperiphery as a negative or residual category (not core/not periphery). Other problems with the concept of the semiperiphery include the sheer diversity of the countries it ' encompasses, the tendency to generalize what is true of specific countries to the , . conceptual aggregate, and a pattern of emphasizing similarities and disregarding differences (Gereffi 1989b) . The question of semi peripheral mobility is one of the least clearly and understood topics in world-system theory. In an effort to shed more on this phenomenon, we will address three sets of related issues: (1) the structure of core-periphery relations through which mobility is defined? How prevalent is sustained mobility between the core, semiperipheral, peripheral zones in the world-economy? (3) What is the significance of the shortterm mobility that occurs via the competition among nations within a world-system zone, such as the semiperiphery? . "; l · · · The Structure of Core-Periphery Relations The core-periphery dichotomy designates the unequal distribution of rewards among the various economic activities in the single overarching division of labor that defines and bounds the world-economy. All these activities are assumed to be integrated in commodity chains, which are made up of nodes that combine different factors of production (labor, capital, and entrepreneurship) . According , 48 Semiperipheral Success Stories? to Arrighi and Drangel (1986, 11-12). "Core activities are those that command a large share of the total surplus produced within a commodity chain and peripheral activities are those that command little or no such surplus. " From a world-system perspective in which all states enclose within their boun daries both core and peripheral activities, "core states" contain predominantly core activities and "peripheral states" encompass mainly peripheral economic activities, while "semiperipheral states" are those that contain a more or less even mix of core-peripheral activities within their boundaries. This balance of core-peripheral economic activities is what gives semiperipheral states "the .chance to resist peripheralization by exploiting their revenue advantage vis-a-vis peripheral states and their cost advantage vis-a-vis core states" (Arrighi and Drangel 1986, 26-27) . One of the major implications of this framework is that it allows us to disen tangle the concept of core-periphery relations from any particular kinds of pro ducts, industries, countries, or regions. Peripheral states do not just specialize in traditional (resource-intensive and labor-intensive) industries, nor do core states solely contain modem (capital-intensive and skill-intensive) industries. Every com modity chain encompasses some products and techniques that are core-like and others that are periphery-like at any one time. Mobility between Zones Mobility from the semi periphery to the core or from the periphery to the semi periphery , therefore, is not defined in terms of degree of industrialization, but rather by a country's success in upgrading its mix of core-peripheral economic activities. Here the role of the state can make a real difference. World-system theory predicts that semiperipheral states will actively seek to upgrade their core peripheral mix by protecting the core activities within their boundaries and by intensifying their competition for the core activities located outside of their boun daries. Paradoxically, however, this competition actually may be counterproduc tive to the extent that it turns core-like activities into peripheral ones with relatively low levels of value added, thus keeping the mix of the semiperipheral zone more or less even (Arrighi and Drangel 1986, 27). Upward structural mobility or ascent is possible for individual semiperipheral or peripheral states that pursue a particularly innovative combination of economic policies and/or are favored by a world-economic conjuncture that gives them some strong competitive advantage. These exceptions, though, tend to reinforce the rule that mobility between the three separate zones in the world-economy is ex tremely difficult, in large part because the development frontier represented by the most advanced activities of the core zone is continually receding. The exceptional nature of lasting upward or downward mobility in the world system is dramatically illustrated by the findings of Arrighi and Drangel (1986, 44) , who attempted to measure mobility in the world-system over the past fifty years. They found that 95 percent of the states that were classified in the boundaries Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 49 of one of the three world-system zones in 1938-195 0 were in the same zone in 1975 - 19 83 . Among the few exceptional cases of mobility were Japan and Italy, which moved from the semiperiphery to the core, South Korea and Taiwan, which moved from the periphery to the semipheriphery, and Ghana, which moved downward from the semiperiphery to the periphery. Competition and Mobility within Zones Whereas studies like that by Arrighi and Drangel tend to give us a clearer picture of the limited mobility that occurs in the long run between zones in the world system, they are not particularly useful in studying the patterns of intense com petition and short-term mobility that occur within a particular zone, such as the semiperiphery. The latter kinds of issues have been of utmost importance in the comparisons of the uneven development of the East Asian and Latin American NICs during the past quarter of a century. Serious questions are being raised about whether the distinct development strategies associated with the East Asian and Latin American NICs will have a lasting impact on their industrial competitiveness, social welfare, and potential to enter the core (see Gereffi and Wyman, 1990). While we believe that these issues of short-term mobility and change are important, they should be studied within a world-system context. The competi tion among the NICs, which all fall within the semiperipheral zone of the world-economy, has become especially significant in the current era of global manufacturing characterized by dramatically new patterns of international pro duction, subcontracting, and export specialization. Increasingly the export-oriented NICs are battling one another, and core countries as well, for access to core country markets. In the remainder of this chapter, we will explore some of the world-system issues raised by a closer examination of the pattern of competition and among the NICs in the global footwear industry. Although our focus on Asian and Latin American NICs during the past twenty-five years will not questions of long-run mobility and change in the world-system, it provide us with insights about the strategies semiperipheral states are to upgrade their mix of economic activities and also about some of the tunities and constraints they face in the contemporary capitalist COMMODITY CHAINS In the global manufacturing system of today, production of a single good com monly spans several countries, with each nation performing hisks in which it has a cost advantage. This is true for traditional manufactures, such as footwear and garments, as well as for modem products, like automobiles and computers (Gereffi 1989a) . In order to analyze some of the implications of this worldwide division of labor for specific sets of countries like the East Asian and Latin American NICs, it is very helpful to utilize the concept of commodity chains. 50 Semiperipheral Success Stories? A "commodity chain," as defined by Hopkins and Wallerstein (1986 , 15 9), refers t o " a network of labor and production processes whose end result i s a finished commodity." One must follow two steps in building such a chain. First, to delineate the anatomy of the chain, one typically starts with the final produc tion operation for a consumable good and moves sequentially backward until one reaches the raw material inputs. The second step in constructing a commodity chain involves identifying four properties for each operation or node in the chain (1) the commodity flows to and from the node and those opera (2) the relations of production (i.e., forms of the labor force) within the node; (3) the dominant organization of production, including technology and the scale of the production unit; and (4) the geographic loci of the operation in question (Hopkins and Wallerstein 1986, 160-63). (except for labor): tions that occur immediately prior to and after it; The NICs are pivotal production sites i n the commodity chains that cut across national boundaries and help define core-periphery relations in the world-system. However, the complexity of commodity chains for the kinds of export-oriented manufacturing industries in which the NICs are predominant today requires us to extend the model proposed by Hopkins and Wallerstein in several ways. First, the dynamic growth of the NICs has revolved around their success in expanding their production and exports of a wide range of consumer products destined mainly for core-country markets. This ll}eanS that it is extremely impor tant to include forward as well as backward linkages from the production stage in the commodity chain. In the footwear industry a full commodity chain takes us across the entire spectrum of activities in the world-economy: the agroextrac tive sector (cattle for leather and crude oil as the basis for plastic and synthetic rubber inputs) , the industrial sector (footwear manufacturing) , and the service sector (the activities associated with the export, marketing, and retailing of shoes). Second, the extension of commodity chains beyond production to include the flow of products to the final consumer market has important implications for our ability to detect where economic surplus is concentrated in a global industry . In the case of footwear, the comparative advantage of the NICs lies primarily in footwear production because of the relatively low labor costs in these non core countries . A corollary of this fact, however, is that the main source of economic surplus within the footwear commodity chain generally is not at the production stage but rather at the last stage of the chain, where service activities predominate (i.e., the marketing and retailing of shoes). Product differentiation by means of heavily advertised brand names (e.g. , Nike, Reebok, Florsheim) and the use of diverse retail outlets allows core-country firms, rather than those in the semiperi phery, to capture the lion's share of economic rents in this industry. Third, our focus on an export-oriented industry like footwear provides us with a convenient baseline for measuring the relative success of countries as they com pete with one another for shares of the world market. We will concentrate on footwear exports to the United States, which is the world's largest market for manufactured consumer exports from the NICs (Keesing 1982). By mapping the Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 51 changing shares of the major footwear exporters in the U .S. market during the past two decades, we get a remarkably clear picture of competition not only among the East Asian and Latin American NICs, but also between these NICs and core country exporters like Japan and Italy. Figure 3 . 1 outlines our depiction of a commodity chain for the global footwear industry. It is composed of four maj or segments : (1) raw material supply; (2) production; (3) exporting; and (4) marketing and retailing. In addition, we in clude the maj or footwear export niches in the U.S. market in order to illustrate the specialized nature of the competition that occurs among the maj or footwear exporters. STEPPING INTO CORE MARKETS: FOOTWEAR EXPORTS BY THE NICs The footwear industry is a very instructive case for exploring semi peripheral mobility in the contemporary world-economy. It has been a key component of the NICs' extraordinary export success in recent years. Footwear was the top export item from South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil to the United States throughout most of the 1980s . Although each of these countries has a very diversified pro file of manufactured exports, it is notable that footwear continues to be a leading export commodity, along with more sophisticated products such as automobiles, computers, and color television sets. The United States is the largest footwear market in the world. During the past two decades imports have steadily displaced local production within the American market. In 1967 imports accounted for 18 percent of all nonrubber footwear con sumed in the United States; ten years later, in 1977, one out of every two pairs of shoes purchased in the United States was imported; and by 198 7, 80 of all shoes bought in the United States were imported (U.S. Department of merce, 1989; Mutti 1980). The pattern of footwear exports to the American market shows very clear This can be seen in table 3 . 1 , which designates with boxes the years in the maj or footwear exporters to the United States had an overall market of 10 percent or higher. Japan, Spain, and Italy were the main exporters to American market during the late 1960s and early 1970s. In 1971 these three m:l","" tions accounted for two-thirds of the $760 million in footwear that was to the United States. In 1972 the East Asian and Latin American NICs began to play an increasingly prominent role as U.S. footwear suppliers. First Taiwan, then South Korea in the mid-1 970s, and finally Brazil in the early 1980s began to make major inroads into the American footwear market. By 1987 these three NICs accounted for two thirds oftotal American footwear imports, thus reversing the dominance establish ed sixteen years earlier by Japan, Italy, and Spain. The stakes were also much higher, however, since the U.S. market for footwear imports in 1987 was valued at over $7.6 billion, an increase of more than tenfold since 1971 (see table 3 . 1 : " ',i · . V, N 3.1 I m ' 'w';o " Figure - chem icals . l Pelro- (PYC) Symhetlc - (S BR) Rubber Production FInootegtwratedr Produclion Network S uPVly Parts Footwear fr " ; H "� Raw Material Supply Network -- I H 011 '",0' - Footwear Commodity Chain I I I I Small amI Export Network Wholesalers international Importers Tlaocrs Exporl Marketi n g Network Stores Shoe Specially Stmes DeparUllent "- � r- Niches E x port Shoe s Plastic Shoe s Leather Men's Shoe s Leather Women's Shoes IIthletie I � Table 3 . 1 91 5,014 1 ,079 , 1 66 1 , 1 53,391 1 972 1 973 1 ,805 ,824 2,584 ,979 2,859,446 3 ,0 1 9 ,374 1 97 7 1978 1 979 J 98 1 6, ! 03 ,679c 6 ,472,89 1 7 ,654 ,055c 1985 J 986 1987 0 0 I .b 1 1 1 1 1 1 5 6 II 13 5 6 7 7 6 7 32 II 13 13 23 32 14 23 15 19 31 15 17 13 19 29 16 21 22 30 27 18 17 18 !O 9 17 27 17 30 19 7 7 8 13 21 28 10 7 7 8 9 15 16 16 !O 8 8 23 24 21 16 15 I 3 4 9 2 2 2 I 2 2 5 2 2 I I I I I 2 6 9 0 2 4 5 I I 22 20 20 26 28 34 37 38 2 0 3 4 3 Hong Kong 3 Brazil K o re a Taiwan 11 12 14 18 19 17 42 41 15 13 41 12 39 Ital y 851 , 1967-1987) t· C . I .F. value. b Data not available. a Customs value except where noted. United S lates Department of Comm.:rce. V a ri ou s years; United S ta tes Department of Comll1erce. 1 987. 5 ,034 ,436 1 984 SOl/rees: 3 , 4 3 7,455 4 ,009 ,54 1 1 982 1983 1 9 RO 2,807 ,937 1 ,724 ,547 1 976 1975 2 7 5 8 ,095 1971 I 1 629,402 1 9 70 1 ,3 0 1 ,404 17 48 8 , 1 72 1 969 1 974 18 388, 1 3 5 9 263,220 1 968 Spain 1 967 Japan of uol lars);! Year (1lJollsnnds Total Market Share o f U . S . Footwear Imports from Selected Countries (SITC 2 1 I .b 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 P.R.C. I .b 2 2 2 2 2 2 I 2 2 I I I I I I I Mexi c o 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 2 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 Argentina 54 Semiperipheral Success Stories? SITC signifies Standard International Trade Classification and C.I.F. means cost, insurance and freight). This dramatic increase in the role of the East Asian and Latin American NICs in the American footwear market during the late 1970s and 1980s, a period when they displaced their Japanese and European competitors, is evidence of substan tial semiperipheral mobility in a dynamic global industry. In the following sec tions of this chapter, we try to identify some salient aspects of the successful strategies pursued by footwear exporters in the NICs. To put this in an appropriate context, however, we first need to outline several distinctive features that affect mobility in the footwear industry. Mobility within the world-system is tied to a country's ability to upgrade its mix of core-peripheral economic activities. In order to advance in the world economy, countries typically strive to play a major role in those segments of com modity chains with the highest ratio of core to peripheral activities-that is, where the economic surplus is greatest. The location of economic surplus in the footwear commodity chain is condi tioned by four factors: labor, core and peripheral capital, the state, and economic organizations. First, footwear production is a relatively labor-intensive activity. Labor costs thus tend to drive the competitive strategies of footwear exporters and are a major factor in explaining geographical shifts in the industry. Relative ly inexpensive labor in the NICs is the key reason these nations acquired a signifi cant cost advantage vis-a-vis core rivals like Japan and Italy. Since labor costs in the NICs (especially in East Asia) have been rising quite rapidly, however, these semiperipheral nations have had to select export niches that allow them to economize on labor and attain higher levels of value added in the industry. This offers some measure of protection from cheap-labor footwear exporters like those in China, Mexico, and Thailand. Second, the footwear industry forces us to take a new look at the roles of core and peripheral capital in contemporary consumer-goods export industries in the world-economy. The footwear industry is highly competitive at the international level, with little direct involvement by multinational corporations in the produc tion and exporting of footwear. Local private capital, usually made up of small and medium-sized firms, is the principal actor in the footwear industry in the NICs. Core capital does play a significant role, however, in the distribution and marketing stage of the footwear commodity chain. Unlike capital- and technology intensive industries where multinational corporations frequently set up facilities for overseas production, core capital shapes the growth and evolution of the footwear industry in a more indirect way, mainly as a subcontractor and buyer of footwear made to the specifications of shoe companies and retail outlets in the United States. The available information suggests that the most profitable segment of the footwear commodity chain is the distribution and marketing of shoes rather than footwear production. The distributors' margins in the core countries are very large. In the United States these margins averaged 50 percent in the mid-1970s but were Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 55 closer to 60 percent for imported goods. In Japan "the price [of footwear] ap proximately doubles between the departure of the goods from the factory and their purchase by the consumer. The successive increases appear to be as follows: factory 55 percent, wholesaler 70 percent, and retailer 100 percent" (OECD 1 976, 3 9). A similar situation seems to prevail in Europe, where distribution costs amount to at least 1 00 percent of the manufacturers' price. The economic surplus that accrues to footwear distributors and retailers in core countries undoubtedly is much higher when production is done overseas rather than domestically. Third, the state so far has maintained a relatively low profile in the footwear industry in both the semiperiphery and the core, contrary to the expectation in world-system theory that semiperipheral states will play a leading role in upgrading the mix of core-peripheral economic activities. Within the semiperiphery the state has no involvement in footwear production at all (in contrast to the prominence of state enterprises in heavy or strategic industries such as steel, oil, petrochemi cals, and mining). The main impact of the state on manufactured exports from the NICs is in the area of exchange-rate policies, export-promotion schemes, and protection for domestic producers. State policies in a core country like the United States are primarily important in terms of selectively restrictive trade measures such as tariffs, quotas, and other nontariff barriers that could impede footwear imports. Until recently, state policies in both the semiperiphery and the core have fostered a rapid expansion of footwear exports from the NICs. There is a growing percep tion, however, that the more or less open trading environment that has been sup ported by core states in the postwar world-economy will become more closed. In particular, the favorable access to the U.S. consumer market on the part of East Asian manufacturers may be reduced as the geopolitical map of Asia is redrawn. An even more drastic scenario that has been mentioned is the _ � " " ;·L..l � emergence of regional trading blocs (Garten 1 989). This would alter the role of the NICs in the world-economy and transform the structure export-oriented industries like footwear. Finally, the footwear industry demonstrates convincingly the importance of ing at economic organizations and other institutions within the NICs to their individual patterns for export success. Footwear firms in South Taiwan, and Brazil are quite different from one another in organizational terms , reflecting their distinct national industrial structures and social contexts. These contrasts help us understand why these three nations have targeted diverse footwear export niches in the U.S. market and why their future strategies in the industry are likely to vary. THE FOOTWEAR INDUSTRY: A COMMODITY-CHAIN ANALYSIS Our analysis of the footwear industry will be organized around the four main segments of a commodity chain outlined in figure 3. 1 : raw material supply, 56 Semiperipheral Success Stories? production, exporting, and marketing. A crucial feature of this commodity chain is that each of the segments encompasses a variety of differences in terms of the geographical locus of operations, the forms of the labor force, the technology used, and the scale and type of production unit. These characteristics all affect the distribution of economic surplus throughout the commodity chain, which is a key factor in determining the degree of mobility of semiperipheral states in the footwear industry. Raw Material Supply Networks There are two fundamentally different raw materials used in the production of footwear: livestock and crude oil. The f ormer is converted into leather and other animal hides, while the petrochemicals derived from crude oil are used to make plastics and synthetic rubber for shoes. Leather and petrochemicals are linked to distinct regional clusters of footwear exporters. Latin American and European producers have specialized in leather shoes and thus rely on tanned leather as the key input, while East Asian pro ducers have specialized in footwear products that require synthetic materials. The flows of raw materials into footwear production have always tended to be problematic and unstable. There are at least four different sources of instabili ty : price, quantity, quality, and geographical origin. The footwear industry has to cope with broad fluctuations in the price of its raw material inputs because footwear accounts for a very small percentage of the total demand for crude oil and cattle. The major sources of demand for oil are energy consumption and a wide range of finished consumer goods based on petrochemical inputs. The bulk of synthetic rubber output, for example, is used to manufacture automobile tires, with only a fraction going to shoes. Similarly, rawhides account f or only about 5 percent of the total sale value of bovines; the demand for cattle is mainly determined by patterns of beef consumption, which depend on factors such as a country's caloric intake, income levels, and volume of beef exports . The primary materials used for footwear are subject to fluctuations i n the quantity of supply. Oil is a nonrenewable resource whose supply has been extremely vulnerable to political changes and control by economic cartels. The supply of rawhides and skins is dependent on so-called " cattle cycles " : Over a relatively long period of time, when the price of beef drops below a certain level, the number of bovine kills increases and the stocks are reduced. This leads to a higher price for beef and the recomposition of stocks until the cycle commences again. While the quality of petrochemicals is generally uniform, differences in the texture, thickness, and color patterns in leather are a potential source of difficulties for footwear producers. The quality of rawhides and tanned leather is affected by a variety of factors: cattle-slaughtering techniques, climatic change, pests, and other environmental conditions. Footwear producers, and particularly those who export to world markets, need to find means to insure not only an adequate supply Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 57 of leather a t predictable prices but also consistent quality, a condition that is dif ficult to establish with precision in leather transactions. Many Argentine producers, for example, argue that Argentine-made shoes lack international competitiveness because the best grades of Argentine-produced leather are shipped abroad (Korzeniewicz, 1 990) . In the last two decades there have been important shifts in the geographical location of rawhide and tanned-leather production in the world-economy. Non core countries have sharply reduced exports of unprocessed rawhides and skins, while core countries have increased them. Argentina, for example, exported 65 percent of its rawhides in 1 970, but only 12 percent in 1 980 and none in 1 985. Brazil exported 20 percent of its total production in 1 970, but none in 1 98 0. Con versely, core countries have increased their rawhide exports. The United States exported 42 percent of its production in 1 970 and 59 percent in 1 980 (FAD 1 983, 1 5-24, 55-69). The trend for tanned leather is in the opposite direction: produc tion and exports have rapidly shifted in location from core to developing coun tries. In Latin America alone, exports of tanned leather increased from an annual average of US$9.6 million in 1 961- 1 965 to $400 million in 1 980 (FAD 1 98 3 , 122-23) . The fluctuations in the price, quantity, quality, and geographic origin of the raw materials used in footwear production create an organizational imperative for the shoe manufacturers to create stable and effective networks for the supply of raw materials. There are at least two options available to manufacturers. The first option is vertical integration. In Brazil the largest footwear manufacturers have purchased local tanneries in order to control the flow of rawhides and leather. Vertical integration of footwear producers with petrochemical firms is much less likely, given the scales involved. The second option is the establishment of stable procurement networks. The stability of these networks may rest upon personal ties, common ethnic backgrounds, and a history of previous common uUW"'¥", tions. Footwear producers in the Vale dos Sinos area of southern Brazil, ample, rely upon ties based on common Germanic descent (Korzeniewicz, Production Networks This section will focus on the organizational characteristics and the of production in the three most important semi peripheral footwear exporters . the U.S. market in the past decade: Taiwan, South Korea, and Brazil. Size of firms and labor patterns are the key variables that define production networks. In terms of size, the Taiwanese footwear industry is composed mainly of small firms, the Brazilian industry is made up of a combination of small and medium sized firms, and the Korean industry is dominated by relatively large firms. In Taiwan the number of establishments with 500 workers or more comprised about 20 percent of the value added in the footwear sector in 1 976, while in South Korea establishments of this size provided 90 percent of all value added in the footwear industry (Levy 1 988). In Brazil there is a mix of both small and medium-sized 58 Semiperipheral Success Stories? firms. In a survey of 112 Brazilian firms, 75.9 percent employed between 11 and 500 employees (qualifying as small and medium), and 27 firms, or about 25 percent of the total, were classified as large (500 employees or more) (Fadigas de Almeida 1983). Footwear production and exports hinge upon the availability of cheap labor. There is a sharp contrast between labor costs in the footwear industries of core and semi peripheral countries. In 1987 the average hourly wage in the U.S. footwear industry was just over $6.00, compared with about $4.50 in Italy, but additional benefits raised the average salary for footwear workers in both coun tries to around $8.00 an hour. Among serniperipheral countries, Hong Kong's average hourly wage was about $2.00 (U.S.) in 198 7, compared to $1.20 in Taiwan and $0.90 in South Korea. Average hourly wages in Brazil, Mexico, and Argentina were about $ 0.65 (BancomextiSecofi 1988, 69; ILO 1988, 810-71 ). The evolution 0 f labor costs in the semiperiphery between the mid-1970s and the mid-1980s shows a very interesting trend. The relative cost advantage of Latin American and East Asian countries was reversed during this period. In 1976 labor costs in the footwear industries of Brazil and Mexico were about one-fifth of those in the United States, while labor costs in South Korea and Taiwan were about one-tenth of the U.S. average. By 198 7 labor costs in Brazil and Mexico had declined to about one-tenth of U.S. costs, while the salaries of footwear workers in South Korea and Taiwan rose to about one-fifth of the U.S. level (Bancomextl Secofi 1988, 69). These figures suggest that low wages are a necessary but not sufficient condition for footwear exports, given the relatively poor perf ormance by the three main Latin American countries during the 1980s (see table 3.1). Wages i n the footwear industry are considerably lower than wages in other manufacturing sectors. In South Korea, for example, footwear wages were only about one-half of the average wage for all industrial sectors combined (U.S. Department of Labor 1986, 4). The f ootwear sector extensively employs f emale workers whose wages and working conditions are inferior to those of their male counterparts. In Brazil the use of f emale labor is widespread in the export-intensive regions in the from of semiclandestine " footwear ateliers, " where workers concentrate on labor-intensive activities such as cutting and light stitching. In South Korea it is estimated that up to 62 percent of footwear workers are female. They earn less than male footwear workers (the wage differential of female to male earnings in South Korea was estimated at 43.4 percent in 1972), and they are typically less protected by laws that regulate extensive overtime and night work (Chang 1988; 16-2 1; U.S. Depart ment of Labor 1986, 4-12). As a result of labor organizing, the wage differential by gender has become less dramatic, but it still is significant. In 1985 female footwear workers in South Korea earned $233 per month, compared to $2 73 for their male counterparts. In Hong Kong male footwear workers earned about $384 per month , compared to $299 for f emale workers (ILO 1988, 795). In short, the organization of production networks has crucial consequences for export competitiveness and for semiperipheral mobility. Our analysis of firm size, Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 59 location, and the relations of production in the footwear sector not only helps us exp lain why some semiperipheral countries have been successful until now, but it also allows us to identify opportunities and constraints that semiperipheral countries may confront in the future. The size of firms, in particular, seems to have important consequences for the capturing and consolidation of export niches. The Taiwanese producers' greater organizational flexibility permits them to be responsive to design and fashion changes in core-country consumer markets and thus to respond more rapidly to shifting consumer preferences. This may account for the relative success of the Taiwanese footwear industry in diversifying its range of footwear products. The Korean producers' concentrated industrial structure has been enormously helpful in the mass production of athletic footwear that followed the rapid boom in the demand for jogging shoes and the entry of Nike into South Korea in 1 976 and Reebok in the early 1 980s (Levy 1 988, 9-1 0). However, the Korean footwear sector as a whole has remained dependent on this one product (athletic footwear) , which has shown cyclical patterns o f growth. It is reasonable to assume that the relative concentration and productive rigidity of Korean footwear producers may have prevented South Korea from breaking effectively and successfully into other segments of the world footwear market. Based on this clearly contrasting pair of productive structures, one would tend to predict a more highly diversified Brazilian industry since, similar to Taiwan, it is dominated by small and medium-sized firms and by a more flexible produc tive structure. But Brazil has not successfully diversified. Perhaps part of the ex planation rests in the currency instability that has affected Brazil since 1 984. Export Networks Export networks contain the different forms of export intermediation producers in the manufacturing location and the distribution networks in sumer markets. They describe the specific organizational forms that porting firms and countries to capture segments of the world footwear There are two main features of export networks that help explain the U�'"W�,�� South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil in becoming major exporters to the U.S. m,rrket> First, the initial impulse for the creation o f export networks was to a large a consequence of increasing demand in the core countries. Second, each country has adopted a strategy of export intermediation that best reflects its industrial structure and the composition of the product niche in which it specializes. The initial impetus for footwear exports from East Asia in the mid-1 960s originated in the decision of Mitsubishi (the leading Japanese trading company dealing in footwear) to relocate the manufacture of plastic sandals for the U.S. market from Kobe, Japan, to Taiwan and the production of all-rubber shoes to South Korea, given a long-standing Korean experience in manufacturing rubber footwear dating back to the Japanese occupation. This background and experience was crucial in the evolution of South Korean manufacturers toward the production 60 Semiperipheral Success Stories? of vulcanized rubber and "cold-process" athletic shoes that was to become their successful niche in the 1980s (Levy 1988, 10). The main f actor behind the ex pansion of the Brazilian footwear export industry was the increasing demand for leather shoes in the U. S. market in the early 1970s and the inability of Italy and Spain to fully meet that additional demand (Fadigas de Almeida 1983). The shape of export networks in the NICs is closely associated with their in dustrial structures and patterns of product specialization. The Taiwanese and Brazilian footwear industries, composed mostly of small and medium-sized sup pliers, have relied extensively on small export traders. In Taiwan the number of export traders grew from a total of 2, 777 in 1973 to 20, 597 in 1984. In that span of time the average value of industrial exports per trader remained virtually constant at US$1, 400, 000 (Levy 1988, 8-9). Small export traders also are very common in Brazil (Fadigas de Almeida 1983). Small export traders are typically individuals or small firms that operate as a linkage between the manufacturers in the producing countries and the retailers in the destination markets. They channel demand for export orders to local pro ducers, oversee the subdivision and subcontracting of large orders among smaller suppliers, perform quality control on outgoing orders, and attempt to anticipate future trends in fashion and marketing in the most important core markets. The scope of these functions changes from country to country and also within the footwear industry in each country, but small trading agents retain two basic purposes. First, they help isolate individual and small footwear producers from the potentially disruptive demands of international markets and international com petition by parceling big orders among many suppliers, thereby allowing the size of firms to remain small. Second, the flexible and dynamic relationship between trading agents and small producers has permitted a greater adaptation to fashion and marketing changes in core footwear markets. The South Korean footwear industry has relied on a far more concentrated struc ture of export networks. The number of export traders in South Korea has grown more slowly than in Taiwan, from 1,200 in 1973 to 5, 300 in 1984. In that span of time the average value of industrial exports per trader rose from US$2, 400,OOO to US$5,200,000 (Levy 1988, 8-9). The relatively small number of traders reflects three features that are particular to South Korea: (1) the firm size of the Korean footwear industry is itself more concentrated; (2) large and diversified general trading companies (modeled on Japan's giant trading companies, or sogo-shosha) are very active in South Korea's trade in manufactures; and (3) South Korea has specialized in the production of large volumes of brand-name athletic footwear, such as Nike and Reebok, which have a more direct route from production to marketing. Distribution and Marketing Networks The specialized footwear products of South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil reach the final consumers through distinct marketing channels, which are the end point Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 61 of our footwear commodity chain. There are two main components to this marketing network: distributors and retailers. In the u . s . market footwear imports are distributed by two major kinds of organizations: generic distributors/wholesalers and brand-specific distributors such as Nike or Gucci. From these two major distribution points, shoes reach the U . S. consumer through department stores and specialty shoe stores (Keesing, 1 982). Well-known upscale department stores, such as Saks Fifth Avenue, Bloom ingdale' s and Harrods, sell shoes to the upper segment of the American footwear market, typically Italian leather shoes. Chain discount stores such as J . C. Pen ney and K Mart, sell a large number of relatively inexpensive plastic and rubber footwear, manufactured mostly in Taiwan, and the low-end leather shoes that Brazilian producers make. Small specialty shoe stores generally sell either ex pensive, top-of-the-line shoes (such as the Gucci brand) or athletic footwear made in Taiwan and South Korea. EXPORT NICHES AND INDUSTRIAL UPGRADING IN THE FOOTWEAR INDUSTRY Each of the four segments of the footwear commodity chain that we described in the preceding section is a key component in the process by which semiperipheral states establish export linkages to global markets. The final outcome of this se quence is the creation and consolidation of export niches. Export niches are segments or shares of world and national markets captured by firms of a single nationality within an industrial sector. The concept of export niches is a crucial analytical node in understanding the trajectories of semiperipheral mobility. It is closely tied to the notion of a com modity chain because it is the consequence of the specific configuration of chain. It also is related to the broader outcomes of market penetration. niches help explain how South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil captured large of the American footwear market by specializing in products that were well to their raw material supply networks and domestic industrial Export Niches The total value and product shares of footwear exports to the United States by the three NICs, Italy, and the world as a whole between 1 970 and 1 987 are depicted in table 3.2. One of the most interesting phenomena is the shift toward athletic footwear as a growing share in overall U.S . footwear imports. The sub category of plastic and rubber shoes increased steadily, but not as dramatically as athletic footwear, which rose from 3 percent in 1 970 to 2 1 percent in 1 987. From a $20 million market in 1 970, athletic footwear evolved into a $ 1 . 5 billion industry seventeen years later. The shares of leather footwear, for both men and women, have declined significantly since 1 970. Semi peripheral Success Stories? 62 Table 3.2 Composition of Footwear Exports to the United States, Selected Countries, Sch. A Code Description Total Exports 85 1 0 1 80/90 CUSS thousands) P1astic/Rubber 8 5 1 0242 Athletic 8 5 1 0243 Leather, Men 1970-1987 8 5 1 0246/48/52 Leather, Women World 1 970 1975 1980 1985 1987 3 9 13 21 15 15 20 19 22 629,402 1 ,3 0 1,404 2.969,982 6, 1 03,679 7,236,496 21 17 18 10 11 12 37 34 23 33 29 1 12 1 I Republic of Korea 1 970 1975 1980 1985 1 987 7 1 1 4 12,965 1 29,163 472,379 1 , 1 70,426 1 ,750,700 9 3 6 8 I 3 3 o 4 1 4 o I 2 Taiwan 1970 1975 1980 1985 1 987 55 39,974 206,2 1 1 53 50 50 50 834,390 1 ,886.789 2,4 1 1 ,4 8 1 o 4 7 21 17 6 6 II 46 21 17 13 14 41 23 61 Brazil 1 970 1 975 1980 1 985 1987 o o o o o 6,535 1 2 1 ,528 244,244 9 3 5 , 1 05 920,262 o o o o o 75 76 85 83 Italy 1 970 1 975 1980 1985 1987 Source: U.S. 4 14 267,445 336,666 520,560 18 9 9 928,858 852,373 o 2 2 2 2 19 17 17 19 54 53 68 64 Department of Commerce. Various years. The boxes in table 3.2 highlight the specialized niches for each of the four leading footwear exporters to the United States. South Korea has specialized in athletic footwear, which comprised close to two-thirds of all Korean footwear exports to the American market by 1985. Although Korean footwear producers have made inroads into other types of footwear, such as leather shoes for men, these attempts to diversify remain modest. A consistent one-half of Taiwan's footwear exports are concentrated in the sub category of plastic and rubber shoes. In contrast to South Korea, however, Taiwan Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 63 has shown a steady trend toward diversification into other subcategories of footwear products. It has made successful inroads into the athletic footwear seg ment that South Korea dominates. Between 1 980 and 1 985 Taiwan tripled its ex ports of athletic footwear to the United States. Taiwan' s shoe producers also are moving into the women's leather footwear segment that Brazil has focused on. Brazil and Italy show clear trends toward product concentration in their footwear exports to the American market. About 85 percent of all Brazilian footwear ex ports are in the women's leather category, and over two-thirds of Italian exports fall within this same niche (which is the largest subcategory of footwear products within the Standard International Trade Classification [SITC] 851 product code). In terms of their shares of the U.S. market, both Italian and Brazilian producers are more concentrated in a single type of product that their East Asian counterparts. Industrial Upgrading An important dimension of export niches is the unit value of footwear exports in these product markets. The size of a niche in terms of market share does not necessarily tell us about the mix of core-peripheral activities or economic surplus that it represents. This is best reflected in trends and comparisons of the average price for different kinds of shoe imports. The unit value of American footwear imports is derived by dividing the total value of footwear imports by the quantity of shoes imported (usually expressed as pairs of shoes). This was done for each of the four main subcategories of footwear imports into the United States at five-year intervals from 1 970 to 1 985, plus 1 987. To come u p with a unit-value measure for each of the NICs and Italy that reflects the major footwear subcategories presented in table 3.2, the average unit value for each of the four market niches was weighted by the share of the niche in total U. S. footwear imports. The results of this calculation are Uv"'�""l<i,,; ,;" H in figure 3.2 and constitute an " industrial-upgrading index" for exporters American footwear market. The figure shows that all four countries have upgraded the unit value footwear exports, even when one controls for the growth in the average unit of all footwear exported into the United States in these years. Between 1 987 Italy upgraded the unit value of its footwear mix well above the average. South Korea and Brazil remained close to the world average, unit value of Taiwan' s footwear exports was below the world average. Italy South Korea both doubled the average unit value of their footwear exports during this period, and Brazil went up by about 25 percent, while the unit value of Taiwan' s exports rose by about 450 percent, although its base value in 1 970 was quite low. An even more telling pattern emerges if we differentiate the 1 970- 1 987 inter val into two discrete periods: the first half of the 1 970s and the 1 980s. The trend lines show that in the first half of the 1 970s, all four countries upgraded their activities at a somewhat similar rate despite the different points of takeoff. In 64 Semiperipheral Success Stories? Figure 3.2 Index of Industrial Upgrading for Footwear, Selected Countries 250 200 8 .." II -c: 0 ::::: 1 50 1 00 ... . ... . _ . -. .- 0 ' -. .-' . -' _. _. - ... . 0 '·'· ' ·' · ' · '·'· ' · 0 ,. , ' ' -/Itt - - _ _ _ _ . 0 · ·· ······ ·· ··· ·······0 ·· ·-· · · · ·· · · · 50 . ."". ··· ·· ·· · · · · · ·· · · · ·· -··. .......... ..•.... · � . .. ... 0 ···-. --� -- � . .�··� ··� •· � 0. � _� • � - -. . 0• --� r� � j-O, .. . . .-, .....� 1 970 1 9 85 1 980 1 9 75 _ _------- - ___ World -'. . . - <'1 Taiwan S. Korea • Italy Brazil . . 9'" " -0 - 0- '.' • ........-6-0 ....... • • . Source: U.S . Department of Commerce. Various Y=s. . the 1980s, however, the patterns diverge sharply: while the upgrading trends of Taiwan and Italy _ keep growing at a steady rate, the upgrading trajectories of Brazil and South Korea are relatively stagnant. In short, ·the "industrial-upgrading in dex" shows us that all four countries upgraded their manufacturing activities be tween 1970 and 1987, but South Korea and Brazil reached a peak around 1980, while Taiwan and Italy grew consistently throughout the 1980s. Three Paths to the Consolidation of Export Niches The empirical evidence presented here helps piece together three interesting "stories" about global footwear production in the 1970s and 1980s. Three semiperipheral countries-South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil-came to dominate substantial niches of the U.S. market, whereas the other East Asian and Latin American NICs (Hong Kong, Singapore, Argentina, and Mexico) did not. However, the three countries that succeeded in capturing important segments of the U.S. market did so in different ways. South Korean producers captured an extraordinarily dynamic market for athletic footwear at the time when the fitness boom hit a peak in the United States. South Korean producers showed an amazing ability to dominate a niche that in a few years grew to comprise about 20 percent of the overall U.S. footwear import market. On the other hand, South Korea has not diversified to a great extent into exporting other footwear products. South Korea upgraded the unit value of its footwear production mix throughout the 1970s, but there was no further increase in the average value of Korean footwear exports in the 1980s. Taiwanese producers captured a rapidly growing market that was already in place, that of plastic and rubber shoes, and competed most directly with American Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 65 ;;"..I",..,pr� . In contrast to South Korea' s shoemakers, Taiwanese firms have been to diversify their exports into other footwear sectors (particularly athletic and to upgrade the unit value of their overall footwear exports. , Brazilian producers showed a capacity to capture a very large niche exports of women's leather footwear, in effect cutting Italy's share of product market by more than one-half between 1 970 and 1 987. This is an ve record, even if part of this outcome reflects Brazilian producers fill niche s that the Italian producers abandoned by moving to higher-value shoes. a pattern resembling that of the Korean producers, Brazilian firms upgraded unit value from 1 970 to 1 980, but the " upgrading index" remained stag throughout the 1 980s. USIONS AND IMPLICATIONS What conclusions can we derive about semiperipheral mobility in the world study of the international footwear industry? Has the export suc of South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil in footwear during the past ten years these semiperipheral countries any closer to the core? Or has it merely to consolidate their position within the semiperiphery? To answer these questions, we need to return to the notion of " core" and 'peripheral" economic activities within the world-economy. The footwear in is not homogeneous. Like all industries, footwear is stratified according the economic value added created by different sets of producers. Italy has suc in capturing the upper end of the footwear market in the United States an emphasis on expensive, fashionable leather shoes. South Korea, Taiwan, and Brazil are in the middle stratum of the footwear industry in terms of value added, with each country carving out distinctive export niches in the U.S. market through subcontracting arrangements with well-I.Iown footwear firms. countries like China, India, and Thailand are becoming major exporters of pensive shoes at the lower end of the market. Thus the stratification of footwear exporters within the American market replicates the core, setIDI)eripli¢ and peripheral position of these countries in the world-economy. Our focus on footwear commodity chains provides us with an aU'UH<V<W< for understanding the dynamics of this international industry. The footwear dustry actually encompasses the full spectrum of economic activities from agroextractive sector (cattle and crude oil as raw materials) to the industrial sec tor (footwear production) and the service sector (the exporting, marketing, and retailing of shoes). The amount of economic surplus in the industry varies by sector. The " core" activities with the highest economic surplus overall are at the marketing and retail end of the commodity chain, where American and Euro pean shoe companies and retailers are able to reap the profits generated by footwear brand names, control over retail chains of department stores and specialized shoe outlets, and the steady growth in U. S. consumer demand for a wide range of shoes. The ' 'peripheral" economic activities, on the other hand, are concentrated , 'S." �UOIH from the 66 Semiperipheral Success Stories? at earlier stages of the commodity chain, including footwear production in develop ing nations. The bulk of the profits in the footwear industry thus is concentrated in the core countries. While the NICs have been extraordinarily successful in footwear pro duction and exporting, their share of the total economic surplus in footwear has not grown proportionately. This supports Arrighi and Drangel's view that in dustrialization itself has become peripheralized. This conclusion does not mean that there is no mobility by semiperipheral coun tries, nor that this mobility is unimportant. Our "industrial-upgrading index" showed that Italy, Brazil, South Korea, and Taiwan all made substantial gains in the unit value added of their footwear exports since 1970, although only Italy and Taiwan were able to sustain these increases throughout the 1980s. While the relative ranking of these four countries remained unchanged in value-added terms during this period, and in fact the gap between Italy and the other three nations widened considerably, each of the NICs has surpassed Italy in its share of the U.S. footwear market. The mobility we see is twofold: (1) the NICs are climb ing the value-added ladder in footwear, with some countries like Japan jumping off the ladder when they are at the top, while other nations clamber to get on the lower rungs; and (2) the NICs have succeeded in capturing larger world ex port shares in specific product niches. Industrialization in the world-economy is a very �omplex process. The footwear industry was one of the earliest export sectors th rough which semiperipheral na tions sought to maintain or improve their position in the international division of labor. The NICs that have been successful in exporting footwear are versatile and diversified; they also manufacture and export a wide range of technology intensive products, such as computers, automobiles, and industrial machinery. International competitiveness in the semiperiphery has spread from traditional to more sophisticated goods. Whether the East Asian and Latin American NICs will get closer to the core countries, or whether any of them will actually enter the core, ultimately depends on their capacity for technological and institutional innovation and their ability to adjust to the changing opportunities and constraints in the international political economy. What succeeded in the past is no guarantee for the future. The open ness of the u.S. market has been a key factor in the rapid economic growth of all the export-oriented NICs, especially those in East Asia. Continued easy ac cess to the American market is very much in doubt, given the staggering trade deficits that confront the world ' s leading core nation. For semiperipheral coun tries to ascend in the world-economy, they will have to find new ways to move to the most profitable end of commodity chains. This requires a fundamental shift from manufacturing in the semiperiphery to marketing in the core, a daunting task indeed. Commodity Chains and Footwear Exports 67 NOTE The authors would like to thank Immanuel Wallerstein and Bill Martin for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper. REFERENCES Arrighi, Giovanni , and Jessica DrangeL 1986. " The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone. " Review 10, 1 :9-74. Banco Nacional de Comercio Exterior and Secretaria de Comercio y Fomento Industrial (Bancomext/Secofi) . 1 9 8 8 . Industria del Calzado. Mexico, D . F . : Bancomext and Secofi. Chang, Insook. 1 9 8 � . "The Contrasts in Labor Sectors in South Korea and Taiwan. " Duke University. Unpublished manuscript. Fadi gas de Almeida, Luis Fernando. 1983. PerceprilO dos Obstaculos as Exportarpes Pelas Empresas Brasileiras Produtoras e Exportadoras de Calcados. Master's thesis, Un viersidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro. Food and Agricultural Organization (FAO) . 1983. World Statistical Compendium for Raw Hides and Skins, Leather, and Leather Footwear. Rome: FAO of the United Nations. Garten, Jeffrey E. 1989. "Trading Blocs and the Evolving World Economy . " Current History 8 8 , 534: 15-56. Gereffi, Gary. 1989a. " Development Strategies and the Global Factory . " Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, no. 505 : 92-104. . 1989b. " Rethinking Development Theory : Insights from East Asia and Latin America. " Sociological Forum 4, 4 : 505-33 . Gereffi, Gary, and Donald Wyman. 1990. Manufactured Miracles: Development Strategies in Latin America and East Asia. Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press. Hopkins, Terence K . , and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1986. "Commodity Chains in the World Economy prior to 1 800 . " Review 10, 1 : 157-70. __ International Labor Office. 1988. Yearbook ofLabor Statistics. Geneva: International Office. Keesing, Donald. 1 982. "Exporting Manufactured Consumer Goods from De,velloo to Developed Economies: Marketing by Local Firms and Effects of Country Policies . " Washington, D . C . : World Bank. Mimeo. Korzeniewicz, Miguel. 1990. "The Social Foundations of International rnmr,p.ti,ti Footwear Exports in Argentina and Brazil 1973-1989. " Ph.D . diss. Duke Levy, Brian. 1988. " Transaction Costs, the Size of Firms and Industrial Policy: from a Comparative Case Study of the Footwear Industry in Korea and Taiwan. Research Memorandum Series, Williams College. Mutti, John H. 1980. Output and Employment in a "Trade Sensitive " Sector: Adjustment in the U. S. Footwear Industry. Washington, D . C . : The World Bank. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 1976. The Footwear Industry: Structure and Governmental Policies. Paris: OECD. U.S. Department of Commerce. Various years. U.S. General Imports. Washington, D . C . : Bureau o f the Census. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1987. U. S. Foreign Trade Highlights 1 987. Washington, D . C . : Bureau of the Census . 68 Semiperipheral Success Stories? U.S. Department of Commerce. Various years . U.S. Industrial Outlook. Washington, D . C . : Bureau o f the Census . U . S . Department of Labor. 1986. Foreign Labor Trends: Korea. Washington, D . C . : U . S . Department 0 f Labor. World Bank. 1988. World Development Report, 1988. New York: Oxford University Press. STATE , MARKET, AND AGRICULTURE IN PINOCHET'S C HILE Walter Gold/rank The fascist solution of the impasse reached by liberal capitalism can be de scribed as a reform of the market economy achieved at the price of the extir pation of all democratic institutions, both in the industrial and in the political realms. Polanyi 1 944, 237 In The Great Transformation Karl Polanyi accounts for the rise and spread of European fascism-in which the state assumed a perversely protective role vis-a vis the market-in terms of the interwar crisis of the world-economy and a par alyzing stalemate of the class struggle. Roughly speaking, his orientation to frame the rise and spread of military-led bureaucratic-authoritarian in the Southern Cone of South America, starting with the Brazilian coup and culminating in Argentina in 1 976. In each of the four cases, 1IDIDOIt-SUO!>UU industrialization as a mode of insertion in the world market had reached expressed most visibly in uncontrollable inflation. In each, the organized of the working class, exercised through unions and parties, had reached a at which it threatened-but fell well short of being able to dislodge-the rogatives of capitalists and their allies. In each, military regimes seized in the names of national security and national salvation-General Pinochet was recently chastised by two bishops for comparing his defeat in the 1988 plebiscite to the crucifixion of Jesus Christ. In spite of nationalist rhetoric, however, each military regime increased significantly the roles of multinational capital and in ternational financial institutions. Economic reorientations toward neoliberalism, weakest in Brazil and strongest in Chile, were accompanied by states of siege, ferocious political repression, and severe restrictions on the organization of labor. In a sense, Polanyi's formulation was reversed, in that the antidemocratic methods of fascism were applied so that market mechanisms could have wider rather than 70 Semiperipheral Success Stories? narrower scope. Rather than protecting society from the market, the state would become the market's instrumentality, institutionally and ideologically. In this project, as in its folk reputation among the Southern Cone countries , Chile stands out for its thoroughness. In both the extent and duration of its repres sion and in the transformation of its economy, Chile went considerably farther than its neighbors. This comparison holds true for other institutional realms as well: the state's role as welfare provider was drastically cut back, and the ideology of free-market liberal individualism was promulgated with a vengeance. Marx ism, socialism, communism, and even populism were constantly attacked. Before the revival of political parties in the mid- 1 980s, the Catholic church remained as the sole effectively functioning national-level organization with a commitment to the priority of community well-being over individual enrichment. (Perhaps those of us who are sociologists should take pride in the fact that our discipline, with its theoretical commitment to the societal level , was banished from the univer sities.) Due in part to this ecclesiastical steadfastness , the Christian ethic of each individual's worth, which Polanyi identified as a major basis of Western civiliza tion, seems to have survived Pinochet's ideological onslaught. But support for heavy governmental involvement in the economy, an increasingly prominent feature of Chile up to 1 973, has not survived fifteen years of reorientation. To judge from the press and from personal observations during the electoral cam paign of summer/fall 1 988, one would conclude that only on the left-and even there without f ervent conviction-would one find the desire for a return to the previous state-centered economy. Most Chileans recognize the major institutional economic changes as permanent (for the medium term, at least) and hope rather to reduce the burdens these changes have loaded onto the poorer half of the population. This chapter, then, will discuss the transformed relationship between state and market under Pinochet's military dictatorship, with special reference to the agricultural sector. The role of the state in giving wider scope to the market and the distributional consequences of this change will be reviewed. Prospects in the current democratic transition for the reconstruction of national community and the reduction of the negative effects of the market will be assessed. STATE AND MARKET BEFORE 1973 P ?puIist developmentali sm, with its emphasis on import-substituting industrial . �zatlOn, took hold in Chile as elsewhere in the 1 930s, a response to the depression mdu ced colla�se of foreign trade. Of forty-nine primary-exporting countries . . studIed by TnantIs ( 1 9 67, 1 9), Chile ranked first in the percentage decline of exports between 1 928- 1 929 and 1 932 - 1 93 3 and was in fact the only country with mor � than an 80 percent drop y the �id-19 60s the state controlled, either directly : or VIa parastatals, many baSIC mdustnes and either subsidized or otherwise con � trolled the prices of basic commodities. High tariffs protected small and medium sized industrial producers as well as large-scale monopolies that supplied the State, Market, and Agriculture in Chile 71 domestic market, shielding them from competition with multinational firms whose technologies had advanced well beyond Chilean levels. Imported capital goods (over two-thirds from the United States) were bought with foreign exchange from a stagnating copper sector. Inflationary pressures would not succumb to monetarist remedies in the mid- 1 95 0s; as a showcase of the Alliance for Progress (United States's response to the Cuban revolution), Chile under the Christian Democrat Eduardo Frei ( 1 964- 1 970) would attempt structural reforms. To this point, the agricultural sector had been dominated by large landowners with a disproportionately large role in national politics. In a pact with the devil, urban-based radical and leftist parties had for several decades assented to severe legal restrictions on rural labor organization in return for price controls on basic foodstuffs (Loveman 1 974). This arrangement perpetuated hacendado power and caused a decline in the already-low living standards of the cultivators while pro viding little incentive for increased food production. The result was a predictable increase in the demand for imported food, with the consequence that precious foreign exchange was unavailable for industrial investment. By breaking up un productive estates and providing technical assistance and credit to smallholders, the Frei land reforms were intended to improve the domestic food situation, to increase justice as well as the capacity of the rural populace to consume, and, not incidentally, to strengthen the Christian Democratic electoral base in the coun tryside. The land reform was accompanied by increased state aid to small-scale urban producers, rises in social-service spending, and " generous wage policies" (Foxley 1 983, 1 3- 1 4). The Frei reform package, however, failed to control in flation, while it split the center from the right and thus set the stage for Allende' s electoral victory and for his regime' s populist and statist project of carrying out a peaceful transition to socialism. The accomplishments and failures of the Allende period continue to generate such controversy that a recent account (Gomez and Echenique 1 988) of ,-,,,un;,,,,,', ,:,, " agriculture sidesteps that era in order to retain credibility among a wide trum of readers. In brief, the regime attempted to use the state as a for reclaiming the national patrimony from multinational capital and tive domestic capital, in part through encouraging and protecting the "nlltl("," I vance of the popular sectors. Via expropriation and intervention, mines, l a,",LUl 1v�,i and landed estates were transferred to government control. Although considerable redistribution was achieved in both individual and collective consumption, the regime fell. Allende' s U nidad Popular promised its supporters more than it could deliver in its brief moment, and in so doing it threatened its enemies with extinction before it had developed the politico-military capacity to contain them. Never in complete control of the state, internally divided among sharply differing political parties and groupings, obstructed and eventually abandoned by the democratic center, denied international financial backing and even ordinary commercial credit, attacked by the defenders of private property within and without Chile, it was overthrown by a military junta that proceeded to use assassination, imprisonment, torture, and exile to insure a definitive victory. 72 Semiperipheral Success Stories? If agrarian reform under Frei was remarkable for its incompleteness, and under Allende for its incoherence, along with other factors it contributed to the moder nization of agriculture so notable in the last few years (Goldfrank 1 9 89). The threat of reform induced some landlords to break up their holdings before the state did and to bring more terrain under cultivation. The encouragement of agricultural unions led to a new emphasis on technical change, to new levels of social participation by the formerly excluded, and to income redistribution. The developmentalist state fostered the fruit- and forestry-export industries that would later rebound to the credit of the military regime. In 1 9 68 the CORFO (state development corporation) published its plan for the fruit sector, resulting in vast ly increased plantings. The 1965-1973 period saw over 420, 000 hectares of timber planted as well as significant state investment in industrial infrastructure for pulp and paper (Gomez and Echenique 1 9 88, 43-45). This is by way of suggesting that there are important continuities across the 1 9 73 rupture, that both the import substituting and the neoliberal states were attuned to certain world-market op portunities that any Chilean state must consider. STATE AND MARKET UNDER PINOCHET In his admittedly too''benign" account of economic changes in Chile between 1 9 73 and 1 9 80-a severe crisis rocked the economy in 1 9 81 - 1 9 83-the Chris tian Democratic economist Alejandro Foxley ( 1 9 83, chap. 3) discussed the in terplay of macroeconomic stabilization measures and structural transformations introduced by the military government. In the first phase, to March 1 9 75, deregula tion occurred through currency devaluation, eliminating price controls, public sector deficit reduction, raising taxes, and shifting those taxes from capital to workers and consumers. Expropriated properties were returned to former owners, import and foreign-investment rules were liberalized, tariff reduction began, and plans were formulated to privatize the public sector. Collective bargaining was suppressed. Unemployment quadrupled, recession set in, and with copper prices falling, the balance of payments was in crisis. Rather than retreating from their ambitious goals, the so-called Chicago boys, Pinochet's economic advisors, administered a fifteen-month " shock treatment." They drastically cut public expenditures, raised taxes further, reduced real wages by lowering the basis for cost-of-living adjustments, and put some of the poor to work sweeping streets and cleaning up parks for a pittance. Structurally, they accelerated privatization (especially in banking), freed interest rates, and step ped up the tariff-reduction program. The payments crisis eased thanks to copper price rises and to increased inflows of foreign capital, but the recession deepened, and official unemployment levels reached almost 20 percent. This led to a third phase, from June 1 9 76 to June 1 9 79, marked by more currency devaluations and tariff reductions, an increase in economic activity (unemployment fell to 1 3 per cent), and an increased influx of foreign capital. By mid- 1 9 79 Chile's economy had been fully opened to world-market forces, and the miracle was being State, Market, and Agriculture in Chile 73 - pro claimed. But little more than two years later, severe recession once again set - in . Banks and businesses were failing, the Chicago boys were finished, and the Chilean state was forced to resume its protective and developmentalist roles, albeit a far lesser degree than before the coup. Structural economic changes went beyond a privatization program that reduc ed the number of public enterprises from 507 to 15 and the amount of public employment by 20 percent, eliminated profit remittance restrictions, and through undervaluing sold-off assets and encouraging speculation transferred large amounts of ass ets to the largest firms. Trade, the structure of production, and distribu tional patterns changed as well. Chile became an open economy as tariffs fell from 94 percent to 1 0 percent, exports were exempted from the value-added tax (VAT) and from customs duties, and nontraditional exports mushroomed while in many branches of industry, import desubstitution occurred. As befits the ironic description ' 'newly underdeveloping country, " Chile saw manufacturing decline as agriculture and mining, commerce, and services grew. Distributionally, there was a tremendous concentration of productive assets in a small number of con glomerates, which were restructured with even greater concentration after the -198 1 - 1 983 crisis. Simultaneously, the rich got richer and the poor got poorer, with the consumption share of the top 20 percent rising from 43 percent in 1 969 to 51 percent by 1 978 as that of the bottom 60 percent fell from 36 percent to 28 percent. " This marked dualism in consumption seems to be an essential characteristic of the model" (Foxley 1 98 3 , 84) . What began a s technocratic monetarism evolved into a full-blown adaptation of U.S. neoconservatism as an ideological and institutional project for the military regime. Whereas classical liberalism typically accompanies the market mentality, here authoritarianism was justified on the grounds that the Chilean people had previously been educated to think in statist and socialist terms. They would therefore need a long period of exposure to and experience with the of the free market before they could be expected to make rational """"""'� . language curiously mimicking Maoist phraseology, the government emlbaJrke!:i' what it called "the seven modernizations" : labor, social security, health, regional decentralization, agriculture, and justice. The new labor gave birth to competitive union formation and to decentralized, atomized ' tive bargaining; privatization of social security led to monopolistic control of retire- 'f\ ment funds; private markets were encouraged for schooling, medical care, housing; -- and nutrition (Foxley 1 983, chap. 4). The night-watchman state was reinvented, but with a bigger stick than Bentham or Mill could ever have imagined. The agricultural sector under Pinochet has undergone some ironic twists to the modernization process that was set in motion when the Frei-era land reforms were first promulgated. The military government's initial thrust was to reverse with suddenness and finality the most visible tendencies of the previous decade: ex propriation and division or cooperativization of large holdings and formation of peasant associations and agricultural unions (about 80 percent of rural wage workers were unionized as of 1 973 [Garcia Elizalde 1 986, chap. 3]) . The land - _ 74 Semi peripheral Success Stories? situation was "regularized " as many properties were wholly or partially restored to their former owners, state cooperatives were disbanded, and plots were assigned to individual cultivators. Small farmers and the rural poor, principal beneficiaries of the land reform, were denied access to credit and technical assistance, partly from politics, partly from the free play of the market, and partly from the mistaken view that large is more efficient than small. Legalization of corporate farming 1985). 1975 to 1983 found the agrarian sector hit particularly hard gave a further boost to large growers (Jarvis The period from by the imposition of the neoliberal model. With the exception of a few enter prises that were highly capitalized and tightly linked to foreign markets or to specialized domestic ones, the entire sector suffered. With both the dollar and the tariff reduced, U.S. food poured into Chile, while large growers, small-scale peasants, and especially wage workers saw their economic conditions deteriorate. Owners contracted debts that high interest rates rendered unpayable, leading to forced sales. Many ref orm beneficiaries-perhaps as many as 40 percent-were 1988, 46, 96). required or induced to sell their parcels (Gomez and Echenique The pauperization of peasants and laborers led to growing rates of malnutrition, 58 per 1 ,000 in the most rural 1979 (Leyton 1 983, 137-38). When the rural troubles intensified under the pressure of the general crisis of 198 1 - 1 9 8 3 , grower protests and the failure illiteracy, and infant mortality, the latter reaching zones in of several prominent large firms led to a reorientation of state policy and a new dynamism in the countryside. If the new export sectors in fruit and forest products have advanced farthest in the processes of land concentration, transnationalization, and technical change, other subsectors of agriculture are already moving in those directions, including dairy, livestock, and hops. Four of the seven largest fruit exporters are multina tionals, foreign capital is heavily involved in the timber industry, and there are notable instances of joint ventures as well. Table grapes now follow only copper and fish meal in export earnings; the value of fruit exports, of which grapes con stitute a little more than half and apples another quarter, has grown at around 20 percent annually since 1 9 8 1 . But the big surprise has been the turnaround i n basic foodstuffs. Due i n large measure to the introduction of price supports in response to the crisis-generated protests of 1 983, a rapid increase in productivity has resulted in an astounding process of import substitution. In effect, the land reform and counterreform had prepared the terrain for commercially astute proprietors to apply advanced technology, but not until the state aided the market to give the appropriate signals. Whereas the first decade of military rule featured food imports equal to half the 1983 and 1 986, 34 percent to 9 1 percent in wheat, 3 percent to 6 0 percent i n vegetable oils, 5 1 percent to 9 7 per cent in sugar, 83 percent to 99 percent in dairy, 71 percent to 78 percent in rice, and 78 percent to 94 percent in corn. Were income distribution less skewed, so that demand f or food were to increase by the 20 percent necessary to restore the foreign debt built up during those years, in the few years between domestic production as a proportion of consumption rose from State, Market, and Agriculture in Chile 75 levels of 1 970, there is every reason to believe that domestic produc could grow further. Such are the contradictions of the free market that the and protein intakes of the population have been declining throughout the Pinochet period (Gomez and Echenique 1 988, 160-65, 272). Oddly enough, ,.'-'U.u.�.�. agriculture in the 1 980s has recapitulated the story of import-substituting induSlmUllzauon: between the limits of the internal market (highly unequal distribu of income), the high costs of imported inputs (machinery, fertilizers, pesticides, and in some cases seeds) , and increased competition from ever cheapening advanced-country exports, stagnation tends to set in. Meanwhile, only if there are successful efforts to diversify markets for fruit and vegetable exports, and only if Chile can avoid boycotts on the basis of the regime 's international unpopularity, will the recent dynamism of export production be sustainable. Nor can it be denied that the state has played a critical role, unintentionally as well as deliberately, in creating and perpetuating the current situation. We already touched upon the CORFO diversification plans of the 1 960s, the of the land reform and counterreform, the consequences of policies favoring growers over small, and the replacement of the neoliberal import splurge policies allowing the growth of domestic production. But the commercially au,'ru"�,,u sectors of Chilean agriculture have benefited from other state actions as well. Direct subsidies have gone to reforestation and to irrigation. Productive lands have been handed over at below-market value in exchange for bonds retiring portions of the external debt. Land taxes have been laughably low, and enter prises have taken advantage of the regime' s neglect of wage levels, working con ditions, and environmental effects. Via commission and omission, the Pinochet government has enriched the powerful and pauperized the weak, while its economy' s meager trickle-down has not begun to compensate'for what its institu tional restructuring dried up. STATE AND MARKET: THE CHILEAN PROSPECT The "double movement" is an axiom of Polanyi' s thought, that is, advance of the market is necessarily accompanied by the advance of protect society from the market' s effects. The state, typically, is expected to vide that protection; social welfare and socialism are names for alternative ways of organizing it. The Chilean case reminds us that the state can dedicate to advancing the cause of the market while rejecting protective responsibilities in principle. Just as in the early nineteenth century the British state made far reaching institutional and ideological changes to entrench the market system, so the Chilean state in the 1 970s and 1 980s reversed the usual fascist patterns with its embrace of both the world market and the market mentality. In the name of anticommunism, on the one hand, and efficient insertion in the world market, on the other, the Pinochet regime introduced an economic model that failed even to protect many members of the social classes from which it drew its original support. Yet the regime and its neoliberal model survived its disasters, its crises 76 Semiperipheral Success Stories? of 1 975- 1 976, and 1 98 1 - 1 983, its unpopularity, and its international opprobrium. This survival owed much to U.S. backing and to the international financial com munity, much to its partial successes in controlling inflation and in stimulating export expansion, and much, needless to say, to its effectively brutal repression. But as the military regime has embarked on an uncertain transition to democracy, what are the prospects for the continued viability of the neoliberal model and for the resurgence of protection? We can approach these questions in terms of the present conjuncture, the structural changes of the past fifteen years, and the likely effects of a more democratic polity on the relationship between state and market. Three con junctural phenomena have buoyed the Chilean economy since 1 983, accounting for much of the growth that induced the regime's leadership to think that it would win a fair and free plebiscite in October 1 988: cheap oil, a low dollar, and rising copper prices. Imported inputs have thus been relatively cheap, and exports relatively remunerative. A reversal of one or two of these trends, or a generalized world recession, would generate severe problems for an economy highly dependent on price fluctuations in the world market. There is little a small country (population 1 2 million) can do to protect itself from such fluctuations, although compared to the mid- 1 960's, Chile today has significantly diversified both its exports and its customers for those exports. While timber and pulp and paper appear poised to enjoy long-term security, opposite-season fruit may be reaching the limits of its Northern Hemisphere markets, in part because of the specter of European and U.S. protectionism. In case of recession or fall ing prices, contradictory demands for protection, on the one hand, versus renewed austerity, on the other, could well lead to a reversal of the trajectory toward democracy and quite possibly to abandonment of the neoliberal model, most pro bably in the direction of classical fascism, but perhaps toward socialism once again. Some structural changes of the past fifteen years are likely to remain in place while others are reversed. Export diversification will continue. Increased bureaucratic efficiency may prove the most important legacy of the military to the state apparatus. Continued wide scope for entrepreneurial initiative is prob able. Commercialization and even California-ization of agriculture will pick up speed. But the government will return to social provisioning in a major way. In fact, one of the notable features of Pinochet's preplebiscite maneuvering was his pork-barrel housing and public works spending in 1 98 7 and 1 988. One sensed a wide consensus, beyond even the remarkable grouping of the sixteen parties in the "No" campaign (and beyond it both to the left and to some sectors of the right who supported the "Yes"), that the distributional consequences of en forced neoliberalism are simply incompatible with the claim to be civilized. The state will resume a protective role in part, then, because society demands it. This brings us to the question of democracy, to which Chile is returning , albeit more slowly and less completely than the majority of Chileans clearly desire. To this point, the transition process has been propelled by pressure from below, by support from Europe and more recently the United States, and by the exercise of enlightened self-interest on the part of elite sectors that vastly prefer gradual, State, Market, and Agriculture in Chile 77 controlled democratization to the possibility of convulsive and violent struggle, whoever the victor (most probably the armed forces again). But democracy has proved through the last century and a half to be the harbinger of social protection and the enemy of liberalism, neo or otherwise. Democratic demands may well engender fiscal crisis by raising wages so that exports are less competitive or profitable, by channeling to social programs revenues that might otherwise be invested, and by attacking or threatening the conditions that have lured foreign investors. On the other hand, it is just possible-and certainly in keeping with the vibrantly hopeful spirit one found in the streets of Santiago in October 1988-that democracy will stimulate responsible participation, reduce the social and fiscal costs of repression, and allow the talents of the people to be expressed in construction rather than in defensive struggle. There may be a Spanish or perhaps even a Norwegian future for Chile, and however imperfect, that is sure ly preferable to the odd mixture of Franco and Quisling represented by Pinochet. At the least, sociology will return to the university curriculum, and the second half of the double movement will have its chance. REFERENCES Foxley , A. 198 3 . Latin American Experiments in Neo-Conservative Economics. Berkeley : University of California Press. Garcia Elizalde, P. 1986. "El desarrollo fruticola en Chile y sus derivaciones sociales . " In El desarollo fruticola y forestal en Chile y sus derivaciones sociales: 9-120. San tiago: CEPAUFAO . Goldfrank, W. 1 989. " Harvesting Counterrevolution: Agricultural Exports in Pinochet's Chile." In Revolution in the World-System; edited by T. Boswell, 1 89-98. Westport, Conn. : Greenwood Press. Gomez, S . , and J. Echenique, 1 9 8 8 . La agricultura chilena. Santiago: FLACSO. Jarvis, L. 1 985 . Chilean Agriculture under Military Rule. Berkeley: Institute of tional Studies . Leyton, 1. 1986 . " El fomento de la actividad forestal y su impacto sobre el desarollo on Chile. "in El desarollo fruticola y forestal en Chile y sus derivaciones 121-227. Santiago: CEP AUF AO. Loveman, B. 1 974. " Unidad Popular in the Countryside: Ni razon, ni fuerza. " American Perspectives 1 , 2 (Summer) : 147-55. Polanyi, K. 1944. 1he Great Transformation . Boston: Beacon Press . Triantis, S . 1967. Changes i n Trade Balances of Countries Exporting Primary Products, 1927-1933. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. ON A SEMIPERIPHERAL UCCESS STORY? STATE DEPENDENT EVELOPMENT AND THE PROSPECTS R SOUTH KOREAN OCRATIZATION A. Smith and Su-Hoon Lee developmentalist approach to social change dominant i n the 1 95 0s and 1 960s expected increasing political pluralism to develop as part of an ensemble of "modernization" (along with industrial growth, urbanization, and so on). But by the 1 970s it had become clear that empirical patterns contradicted this expec tation in many parts of the less developed world. Many of these societies not only had failed to develop Western-style democracy but had moved toward new forms of particularly repressive military-controlled ' ' bureaucratic-authoritarian" (O'Donnell 1 973) . Against this backdrop, it seemed unlikely that the 1 980s would be heralded as a decade of democratization, but that is the message of both academic and the popular press. The wave began in the late 1 970s in Spain and to Latin American countries like Brazil and Argentina. By 1 986 it was at Asian shores, first in the "people power" revolution in the a little later in the move to direct elections in the Republic of Korea Analysis of this phenomenon varies from careful scholarly work (for ,_.. O'Donnell, Schmitter, and Whitehead 1 986) to superficial mass-media tion about contagion and self-congratulatory tomes from the present U.S. ad ministration. The purpose of this chapter is to contribute to the former by establishing a framework for examining the South Korean case in detail and at tempting to develop a clearly specified political economy of the world-system explanation for the process and prospects for democratization in that nation. We hope to move beyond the tentative, suggestive nature of this chapter to more detailed empirically rich analyses in future work. Our perspective is a structural one that focuses on the linkages between the international and national political economy and adopts a historical stance. While we reject the view that either political change or economic development proceeds through a universal sequence of stages, we believe the two are inexorably linked. �... .... 80 Semi peripheral Success Stories? Our perspective should help illuminate the social forces and openings that can be used by the proponents of democratization, as well as map some of the con straints and difficulties they face. However, we are well aware of the critiques of approaches that overemphasize structure and ignore human agency (Giddens 1 979; Deyo 1 987c). Clearly, political organization, energy, and passion are crucial components in moves toward more participatory politics (0'Donnell and Schmitter 1 986). We also note that in laying out some potential obstacles to democratiza tion, our intention is not to suggest the futility of efforts to attain it. Quite the contrary, it is our contention that a better understanding of the structural con straints to political change could and should be useful to those who are struggling to attain democracy. At this late date, for readers of this volume, a general explication of the world systems perspective is hardly warranted. Two key advantages of the Wallerstein ian approach distinguish it from the " dependency" tradition from which it developed. First, there is the idea that the world-system is organized into distinct strata. Second, there is the possibility of mobility in the global system through "dependent development" (see Cardoso and Faletto 1 969, 1 979; Evans 1 979b). Furthermore, the perspective suggests the working hypothesis that countries play ing similar roles in the international system (i.e., at structurally isomorphic "levels") may exhibit similar patterns and mechanisms of development. The semiperipheral stratum is of particular interest. This level differs economically and politically from both the core and the periphery. The internal production activities are a mixture of ' 'core-like" industrial production and labor intensive "periphery-like" production (Chase-Dunn 1 980, 1 988). As Arrighi and Drangel ( 1 986) point out, the precise nature of activities and products that are either "core-like" or "periphery-like" is historically bounded and related to cur rent technology and product cycles (Schumpeter 1 964; see Cumings 1 984, relating this to contemporary Northeast Asia). Core activities are highly profitable and embody the latest technological innovation (Arrighi and DrangeI 1 986). In the eighteenth century, wooden shipbuilding might fit (Chase-Dunn 1 980) ; in the twen tieth century, automobiles or computers (Cumings 1 984). At any rate, semiperi pheral countries, with a developing mix of economic activities, are much more likely to attract foreign and/or local capital to manufacturing industries than the periphery. These societies are also usually starting to indigenously develop or (more likely) import technology to promote industrial growth. Yet development remains "dependent" in that it is severely constrained by the international economy, dominated in the most advanced sectors by the vastly superior technological, financial, and commercial resources of the core countries. This semiperipheral dependence is all the more evident in the majority of these coun tries in which ( 1 ) development efforts have been financed by large foreign debt and/or (2) the engine of economic growth has been export-led industrialization. Politically, the semiperiphery is also quite different from the periphery (or the core). The more even mix of core-periphery economic activities in semiperipheral nations changes the nature of the dominant class coalitions and means that state Prospects for South Korean Democratization 81 policies can more directly influence local capital accumulation. Indeed, Waller stein argues that " semiperipherality is important because it points to a concen trati on of state-oriented political activity by major internal (and external) actors" ( 1 985, 35) . While acknowledging a wide variance in political ideology (from "rightist" to "socialist") , Chase-Dunn and Rubinson claim that semiperipheral countries " tend to employ more state-directed and state-mobilizing development policies than do core countries" ( 1 977, 472). Obviously, this emphasis on " dependent development" in the semiperiphery moves the state into central focus in world-system analysis. This may seem ironic, since the most well known critiques of the world-system perspective focused on the economistic nature of exchange-based "neo-Smithian Marxism" and the lack of attention to political and class forces (Brenner 1 977; Skocpol 1 977). In the 1980s a major effort was under way to " bring the state back in" to theory building and to establish a more nuanced "new comparative political economy" dedicated to historical-structural analysis of classes, elites, and politics (Evans, Rueschemeyer, and Skocpol 1 98 5 ; Evans and Stephens 1988) . While this shift toward greater attention to " internal" factors and the articula tion between national and local political economies and the international system is one key theoretical shift, an equally important change has occurred in the con ceptualization of the world-system itself. Increasingly, international political economists are aclmowledging that a thorough understanding of the global system needs to account for both the world-economy and the international state system. While these two aspects of the world-system are intertwined, neither is reducible to the other (Chase-Dunn 1 98 1 ; Evans and Stephens 1 988). Here growing research interest in Northeast Asia has directly contributed to theoretical clarification. Studies of this world region, in particular, insist that geopolitics and military strategems played a major role in development and social change (Cumings 1 984; Lim 1 985 ; Nemeth and Smith 1985; Koo 1 987) . KOREA AND THE EAST ASIAN NICs: STRONG STATE AND DEPENDENT DEVELOPMENT The recent experiences of South Korea and the other East Asian . dustrialized countries (NICs) provide a crucial case challenging the m�errlaUOltal political economy perspective (and, indeed, other theoretical approaches that port to explain societal development) (Deyo 1 987a, Introduction) . A number of scholars argue that the experiences of these nations, and particularly Taiwan and South Korea, provide the evidence needed to "disprove" dependency/world system theory (Barrett and Whyte 1 982 ; Gold 1 985 ; Hamilton 1 986; Barrett and Chin 1 987) . At the risk of trivializing these arguments, their basic thrust is that the East Asian "little tigers' " achievement of rapid economic growth and a relatively modest level of income inequality, despite their reliance on external economic and political links, qualifies these countries as "deviant cases" that contradict basic assumptions of the international political economy approach. Semiperipheral Success Stories? 82 Unfortunately, some of these critiques have framed their arguments in particular ly unconstructive ways. For instance, Barrett and Whyte's ( 1 982) widely read article follows a rough qualitative''hypothesis-testing" strategy in which the work of various and sundry dependency/world-system writers is abstracted (often wildly out of context) into a series of propositions. The authors then, predictably, pro ceed to demolish the dependency/world-system "arguments" with data from Taiwan. Not surprisingly, their favorite target is the early polemical writings of A. G. Frank, which provide the lightest-weight materials with which to construct a straw man. Despite a f oment of debates at the time about''dependent develop , ment' and the status of semiperipheral nations, this article ignores this possibili ty, suggesting that dependency theory always equates dependency with underdevelopment, stagnation, and inequality. Further, it argues that the presence of a strong interventionist state in Taiwan runs contrary to world-system expec tations, when, in fact, it is precisely the political form we would anticipate in an upwardly mobile semiperiphery.1 Even a very recent evaluation of the East Asian NICs in the world-system retains a similar flavor (Barrett and Chin, 1 987). It steadfastly ignores the elaborations of the international political economy perspective in the last decade.2 Proponents of the international political economy perspective respond to the attacks by claiming that a sophisticated, flexible world-system perspective is useful, even for the seemingly difficult cases of the East Asian NICs (Cumings 1 984, 1 989; Evans 1 98 7; Koo 1 987). These countries must be understood as semiperi pheral states undergoing the process of "dependent development." To begin to explain trajectories of these countries, which are quite different from those of either advanced core nations or underdeveloped peripheral ones, we need first to look at historical patterns. Space precludes a full discussion of this argument here (see Lim 1 985 for the most complete analysis of the Korean case). But for both Korea and Taiwan, the timing and mode of their initial incor poration into the modern world-system through Japanese colonialism is crucial (Cumings 1 984; Lim 1 98 5; Nemeth and Smith 1 985). The Japanese were hardly benevolent imperialists, but because of their own relatively vulnerable global status, the contiguity of Korea and Japan, and the peninsula's perceived strategic value, the Japanese occupation had a number of "developmental " consequences that colonialism in other world regions did not. The Japanese invested in modern heavy industry, which prompts Cumings to claim that "by 1 945 Korea had an industrial infrastructure that, although skewed sharply to metropolitan interests, was among the most developed in the Third World" ( 1 984, 56). Partly with military strategy in mind, the Japanese also established a transportation network that quantitatively and qualitatively outstripped infrastructural development in other less developed countries (Nemeth and Smith 1 985, 200). After World War II the absence of a strong indigenous landed class and the infusion of massive U.S. military and economic aid promoted forces favoring the rise of "import substitution industrialization" in the early 1 950s (Nemeth and Smith 1 985; Cum ings 1 984; Koo 1 987). This development phase, in turn, set the political and Prospects far South Korean Democratization 83 context (particularly in the seeds of what Cumings calls the 'bureaucratic-authoritarian industrializing regimes" [BAIRs]) for the export-led manufacturing that emerged in the 1 970s (Cumings 1 984; Lima 1 985; Nemeth Smith 1 985) . In the contemporary period the key component to the international political economy arguments is their emphasis on the crucial role of the state as the in termediary between the nation and the world system. Deyo emphasizes this facet and argues that "state med iation of dependency involves the institutional chan neling of most external linkages through bureaucratic agencies that are thereby enabled to introduce strategic criteria into the construction of foreign market, technology, and capital relationships" ( 1 987c, 237). South Korea, like other semiperipheral nations, has a state with the capacity to "negotiate dependency" (see Evans 1 979b, 274-329). The South Korean state has done this in several ways. One is by limiting and regulating the extent and nature of foreign capital penetration. As Peter Evans (1987, 206-9) perceptively notes, the correlation between relatively low foreign direct investment and rapid economic growth in the East Asian NICs is a resound ing confirmation of a basic tenet of the world-system argument. State policy has, perhaps implicitly, followed what dependendistas would have prescribed. Despite strict limitations on multinational capital, South Korea has relied heavily on ex ternal capital flows. During the immediate postwar period these were largely in the form of direct development and military grants from the United States.3 Dur ing the early 1 960s the Park Chung Hee government increasingly turned toward foreign loans as a source of capital for industrialization (Lim 1 985; Haggard and Cheng 1 987; Evans, 1 987). While this created a degree of debt dependency significantly higher than in the other East Asian NICs and high enough to prompt some analysts to warn of potentially serious future economic difficulties (Cum ings 1 984; Lim 1 985), the most important aspect of the borrowing was the ner in which the state positioned itself between foreign lenders and local val""'LU".' The state, through central financial institutions, controlled and channeled of capital to businessmen and companies. This mechanism became a for state-directed economic planning (as well as a potential focus of Nn·nn"if, and payoffs) (Evans 1 987). Kim ( 1 988) argues that the absolute autonomy of the Korean state eroded in the 1 980s as the giant trading (chaebols) became increasingly influential. But this does not indicate that economy is more genuinely competitive. Instead, Kim ' s analysis documents the continuing monopolization of economic planning by an alliance of leading chaebols and the state . The final way in which the South Korean state has intervened in the economy to maintain or bolster its international market position and reduce the negative effects of dependency has involved its relations with labor. Clearly, this aspect of state policy has been as necessary a part of the ' 'economic miracle" as the government' s strategies for dealing with local and international capital. As Deyo rather bluntly states, the tremendous success of " export-oriented industrialization" 84 Semiperipheral Success Stories? (EO!) throughout East Asia has been built on the foundation of "disciplined and low cost labor" (1987b, 183). He argues that political demobilization and exclu sion are not accidental but an integral part of a wage policy for labor-intensive manufacturing-which has worked. This argument is reminiscent of O'Donnell's "bureaucratic-authoritarian (BA) state" model, which argued that the rise of military-dominated dictatorships in Latin America in the 1960s and 1970s was a necessary political precondition for the "deepening" of industrialization in semiperipheral Brazil and Argentina (O'Donnell 1973; see also Collier 1979). Some Korean scholars have argued that the constitutional crisis of the Yushin period in 1972 and the imposition of martial law mark the beginning of a true BA state and follow the O'Donnell model (Han 1985; 1m 1987). Others claim that authoritarianism had taken root long before the beginning of industrial "deepening" (Lim 1985; Deyo 1987a). Nevertheless, it does seem almost irrefut able that the existence of the BA state (or BAIR) provided political conditions that facilitated the success of the export-led manufacturing strategy (Cumings 1984). Regardless of the causal sequence, the functional requirement for repressed labor and deferred consumption was met by the Park regime. It is the consensus of researchers that the South Korean labor laws and policies were the most repressive among Asia's "little tigers" and, at least until recently, were "becoming ever more oppressive" (Koo, Haggard, and Deyo 1986, 66). Antiunion activities (often in the guise of "anticommunism'') and political demobilization have fulfilled an economic function that contributes to the country's competitiveness in the world economy. Mouzelis's argument suggesting an "elective affinity" between "the recent multinational phase of capitalist industrialization and the type of exclu sionist military dictatorships that have sprung up in several post-war semiperipheral societies" (1986, 193) seems to fit. Such a link would appear to exist between the BAIR and the South Korean model of development in the late 196 0s through the early 1980s. Today, to appropriate the title of a recent speech of the ROK's minister of plan ning to the foreign press, it may be accurate to see "the Korean economy at a crossroads" (Cho 1989). Both the demands of international economic com petitiveness and the national political climate are forcing the South Korean peo ple and leading economic and political actors to make strategic choices that may involve moving in new directions. A move to more capital-intensive, technological ly innovative production might m itigate the need to depress wage costs to maintain international competitiveness. This shift would have clear political ramifications, probably conducive to increasing democracy. But the costs of creating a research and development capability comparable to that of metropolitan core countries would be enormous. Lacking R&D competitiveness would mean that South Korea would remain reliant on imported technologies or "reverse engineering" (i. e., copying products developed elsewhere) and remain stuck in the middle (less pro fitable and rather unstable) position in industrial product cycles (Cumings 1984). This is the dreaded "sandwich effect" where semiperipheral NICs are unable to compete in innovative core-type production but also can no longer offer the Prospects for South Korean Democratization 85 advantages of very low wage labor comparable to that available in peripheral countries (Gereffi 1988). In a later section the emerging strategies to deal with this conundrum will be addre ssed. For now, the crucial point is that state planning and intervention are again likely to play a key role in negotiating Korea's ability to sustain economic growth in the face of a changing internal political situation and despite continued international commercial, financial, and technological constraints. Global eco nomic dependence involves much more than the relative presence or absence of multinational corporations in a developing country. The structurally constrained " maneuvering room" available, given the nation's niche in the international divi sion of labor, poses problems that are just as real for the indigenous bourgeoisie, military officers, and sta te bureaucrats as they would be for managers of transna tional firms. In the past twenty-five years the Korean state has played a pivotal role in solving these dilemmas. POLITICS AND THE STATE: DOMINATION AND DEMOCRACY While Korea must be understood in the context of its role in the global system and the economic constraints and opportunities present therein, political change cannot be explained simply in terms of the nation's international status or in purely economistic terms. Reductionist arguments, whether they seek the answer only with reference to international dependency or focus exclusively on the state as a facilitator of capital accumulation, will not provide very complete or useful accounts of the process or prospects of South Korean democratization. Instead, it is essential to emphasize more complex, contingent, and recursive relation ships between the world-economic context and the national political economy. The historical nuances of class dynamics, states as actors and organizations, and the relationships between classes, states, and the world-system all must be sidered consistent with the synthetic "new comparative political economy" proach (Evans and Stephens 1988). It would be extremely unwise to attempt to untangle this intricate theoretical connections here. Instead, we will develop two basic theoretical tions that move beyond world-system analysis and are particularly relevant an examination of the ROK state and the impetus toward democratization. One recognizes the dual function of any capitalist state to maintain both economic ac cumulation and political legitimacy. The other stresses the state as a " relatively autonomous" actor and organization in which the people who staff the state develop distinct interests in perpetuating the political-economic status quo. Recent research on transitions from authoritarianism to democracy emphasizes the accumulation/legitimation tension (O'Donnell, Schmitter, and Whitehead 1986). Authoritarian regimes usually are much better at promoting profitability and economic growth than in engendering political legitimation. Often military/ bureaucratic-authoritarian rulers came to power as the "solution" to perceived 86 Semiperipheral Success Stories? economic mismanagement and sluggish growth. In the short run, attaining rapid " economic development" in itself provides a measure of popular legitimacy (th is seems to have been the explicit strategy of Park Chung Hee in South Korea) . In the longer term, however, the success of the program for economic growth may lead to a serious''legitimation problem" as " those sectors of the popula tion which are excluded and victimjzed" demand "the removal of the authoritarian regime and its replacement by a democratic one" (O'Donnell and Schmitter 1986, 15). In the case of South Korea this type of pressure from below built up throughout the Chun regime, leading ultimately to a full-fledged ' 'legitimation crisis" in early 1987 and a sudden "loosening up" in June of that year. This does not imply an immediate political transformation : the transition to democracy is filled with uncertainty and contingencies involving various " accumulation and legitimation options" (Kaufman 1986, 100-107) and "negotiating (and renegotiating) pacts" between key class and interest groups (O'Donnell and Schmitter 1986, chap. 4). But empirically, it does appear that the South Korean state under Roh has lost a substantial amount of both "state capacity" (the ability to get its policies im plemented) and legitimation (the degree to which it can mobilize national con sensus around its goals). In the recent past Deyo has argued that the ability of East Asian authoritarian regimes to deal with "the effectiveness-legitimacy dilemma" has been enhanced by the weak and disorganized nature of "the popular sector" (i.e, peasants and workers) (1987c, 231-33). This distinguishes the East Asian NICs from bureau cratic-authoritarian regimes elsewhere (for example, Latin America' s Southern Cone) where the popular mobilization has been higher. But Deyo points out that South Korea is a little different from Taiwan or Singapore. In the ROK he cites " more repressive regimes . . . imposed in response to sometimes violent opposi tion from middle-class intellectuals, students, and workers" (1987c, 241), which have made the tension between accumulation and legitimacy more palpable than in other semiperipheral East Asian states. To understand the dynamics of this process, it is necessary to move to the sec ond theoretical issue: the nature of the state as both an actor and an organization made up of various interests. Students of the advanced core countries pioneered the move away from "instrumentalist" images of the state to models stressing "relative autonomy" (Poulantzas 1969; Block 1977). Block's observations that the state must often grant concession to workers and rationalize production in response to "class struggle" in order to maintain overall "business confidence" may offer particularly useful insights into recent pressures on the South Korean government (although the constraints of "dependent development" may limit the degree of rationalization and wage concessions possible in this case). Skocpol ( 1979) further develops the idea that the state has its own distinct material in terests. She points to the multiplicity of state personnel (bureaucrats, police and military officers, and politicians) who share the broad goal of maintaining social order, political peace, and business confidence, but whose specific interests often conflict. Critically, these competing interests are often most transparent in times of Prospects for South Korean Democratization 87 crisis and may play a crucial role in the reshuffling, or even demise, of a regime. In an attempt to directly wrestle with ' 'politics in the semiperiphery, " Mouzelis 986) also formulates a nonreductionist approach to the state. He also uses the (1 " relative autonomy " argument as a springboard to develop an alternative to O'Donnell' s BA state approach. While not abandoning "the tradition of Marxist ori ented approaches , " Mouzelis urges ' 'new concepts which give serious attention to the sp ecificity of political structures" ( 1 986, 203). He suggests an expanded terminology including "the mode of political domination" (similar to the " mode of production, '). The semiperipheral mode of domination is generally characterized by "incorporative relations of production" (205) that exclude the masses from meaningful political participation, and it often promotes the ' 'praetorian tenden cy" (toward military domination) in "late-late industrializing societies" (184). Echoing arguments made earlier by Evans ( 1 979a) , Mouzelis highlights the power of the state in the semiperiphery to guide economic development and to shape class interests and configurations (rather than acting as an " instrument" of the dominant classes). Like Block and Skocpol, Mouzelis is arguing for the key role of "a non-economistic conceptualisation of political institutions and actors, " but one that still operates under a general idea of a capitalist state. The emphasis on the role of strategic " state-based" interests in opening possibilities for political change may be crucial to understanding the Korean case. The fissures between the interests within the ROK state have become most clear ly visible in the past two years of political crisis and uncertainty. This has led to an increasing lack of coordination between different government agencies and ministries across a gamut of issues and policies. In turn, this further weakens state capacity vis-a-vis a civil society that is gaining political strength and losing confidence in its rulers. The result is a degree of stalemate within the state that makes popular demands difficult to resist. Nevertheless, still lurking in the background is the general imperative to maintain " business confidence. " The crucial issue in this period of flux is, at what point are interests in the South Korean . state likely to coalesce and reimpose a more repressive solution? TOWARD A NEW ECONOMIC MODEL? PROSPECTS AND PROBLEMS If the South Korean economy has reached a crossroads, there is a growing con sensus among planners and policymakers that the most promising highway to the future involves the development and application of increasingly sophisticated technology. Prominent government planner Lee Chong Ouk claims, " There are several predictions, including one from the World Bank, that the Republic of Korea will be ranked among the developed countries by the turn of this century. . . . Korean society has been making full-fledged efforts to make this prediction a reality through the development of science and technology capabilities" ( 1 988" 1 5). Realizing the key role that research and development may play in determin ing South Korea's role in the global division of labor in the future, he lists several 88 Semiperipheral Success Stories? high-priority areas (including ' ' micro-electronics, information and telecommunica tions technology" and "specialty chemicals, new materials, genetic engineering " ) . Other economic planning experts agree. "Developing independent technology " and moving toward "capital-intensive production" are the keys to keeping the South Korean economy ' ' truly internationally competitive" (interview with Dr. Kang Won Lee, Korean Institute for Economics and Technology [KIET] , July 14, 1 988). In a published review of industrial policy, another KIET research fellow notes various steps that have been taken to encourage the development of innovative technology (through direct government support and tax incentives). Between 1 980 and 1 986 the share of R&D investments to GNP rose from 0.9 percent to 2 percent ( "which is almost the OECD level") (Kang 1 988, 3 1 ), with plans to in crease it to 3 percent by the early 1 990s (37). This attitude is consistent with past efforts by genuinely development-oriented ROK elites and technocrats to develop national industrial strategies designed to enhance the country' s global competitiveness. The success of this R&D push, however, is itself contingent on international factors . As Lee ( 1 988) acknowledges, technological development in South Korea will necessitate "cooperation" with advanced nations like the United States . But this implies a degree of continued technological dependency that could become problematic. As Haggard and Cheng ( 1 987) point out, South Korea and the other East Asian NICs may be limited by the willingness of core firms to engage in " 'real ' technology transf er." Current dif ficulties with ob taining the latest productive innovations are seen in the prevalence of " backward engineering " in which major Korean firms engage-where overseas products (often from Japan, Europe, or the United States) are taken apart in order to deter mine how to copy the technology . Of necessity, this type of R&D relegates the economy to a lower swing of the product cycle than nations that are innovators (see Cumings 1 984 for a discussion). Haggard and Cheng claim that "the develop ment of an indigenous capacity for science and technology" will be critically i m portant. This suggests the urgent need for a major push toward science and engineering, which may be difficult in a country that up until now has had a relatively limited R&D infrastructure (using, for example, the physical plant of universities as an indicator). Of course, this is not the only strategy available for Korean capital. " Dein dustrialization" in the core countries (see Bluestone and Harrison 1 982 on the United States) is a basic component of the emerging ' 'new international division of labor" (Frobel, Heinrichs , and Kreye 1 980). One would expect that a similar process might occur in Korea as well, particularly in the declining, less com petitive, labor-intensive industries (e.g., textiles, light industries, simple assembly) . Such production might seek locales (like Southeast Asia) where labor is cheaper and more compliant. This is the downward side of the ' ' sandwich" dilemma (see Gereffi 1 988). Unless these types of industry are rapidly replaced by newer "high tech " forms, we would expect that aggregate industrial production will shrink. The beginnings of this process may be becoming visible in contemporary Seoul, where capital increasingly is attracted to nonproductive investments in urban Prospects for South Korean Democratization 89 buildings and real estate. Growing land speculation of this type creates housing shortages and rampant inflation and may present a long-term threat to the entire South Korean economy. Failure to move toward more sophisticated capital-intensive manufacturing will not only fetter continued economic growth, it will also endanger the process of democratization itself. This move is necessary because the " old" model of eco nomic growth was based on low wages and popular political exclusion. Once civil society increases the demands for more democratic participation, the viability of such a strategy becomes dubious. While the desire to maintain international competitiveness does seem to be an integral part of the impetus toward ' 'rationaliz ing " the economy by moving to more technologically sophisticated production tech niques, there is also a complementary "internal" motive. There is near consensus among South Korean development planners, academic researchers, and political ad visors that the "social costs" of the low-wage dependent export manufacturing had become intolerable. For example, a Korean Development Institute researcher told one of the authors that the political situa tion and labor unrest had resulted in a situation in which increased social spend ing and rising wages are almost inevitable.4 Maintaining economic growth becomes very problematic, and "one solution would be to move toward more capital-intensive production" (interview with Dr. Soon Won Kwon, KDI, July 16, 1 988). Dr. Lee at KIET also argued that "economic policies now must ex plicitly deal with their ' social costs' . . . in particular, labor disputes, income inequality, and regional disparity need to be addressed. " There is a growing perception that the current political climate has ended working-class acquiescence to "labor discipline" ; industrial workers seem no longer willing to accept low wages and restricted consumption in exchange for national economic goals. CONTENDING FORCES IN THE STRUGGLE FOR POWER To fully capture the shifting dynamics of contemporary South Korean would require an examination of a number of class and interest group military has dominated the ROK government for much of the postwar ... ... __' � continues to exert enormous clout; President Roh is a n ex-general. in various state agencies also play an important role in policy-making and sup port for the current regime. Students and intellectuals have historically been in the vanguard of the struggle for democracy. Their persistence in the face of relentless government repression throughout the past decade was the catalyst that sparked the national mobilization leading to the removal of President Chun (and provided a heroic model for the 1 989 Chinese student movement for democracy). The middle classes of professionals and small entrepreneurs are likely to be as critical for successful moves toward democracy in Korea as they have been historically in other nations. Emerging social groups may become more impor tant too. Although they are largely quiescent today, Seoul and other large Korean cities have significant and growing populations of urban poor. In 1 988 the _ 90 Semiperipheral Success Stories? opposition was beginning to make a political issues of the substandard living con ditions in urban shantytowns and "moon villages. " While other social f orces may be important, our analysis suggests that the strug gle between the workers and the uneasy alliance between big business and the state is particularly important. Historically, both the capitalist and working classes are of recent origin. Only with the success of export-oriented manufacturing and the institutionalization of giant chaebol trading companies as major economic forces in the late 1970s and early 1980s did a politically important bourgeoisie emerge (Koo 198 7; Kim 1988). As business becomes more powerful, some members of the capitalist class are calling for decreased intervention in the economy by technocrats and favor limiting the political prerogatives of the military. Thus in some instances parts of this emerging capitalist class actually are advocating economic liberalization and limited forms of political liberalization, although they are also quite aware of the potential problems that unions, strikes, increased demands for a social wage, and higher labor costs might bring if democracy pro ceeds too fast or too far. This fear is a realistic assessment of the emerging clout of a n urban industrial working class. This is occurring against a historical backdrop of forty years of efforts to marginalize the political left and disorganize and exclude urban working class groups from political participation (Cumings 1981; Haggard and Cheng 1987). Deyo identifies "disciplined low-cost labor" as the basic element of export oriented industrialization and points to increasing levels of labor repression under Park Chung Hee. He points out that after Park seized power in 1961, strikes declined from an average of 79 per year (1955-1960) to 15 per year (1963-1971) (1987b, 186). After Park's narrow presidential victory i n 1971 (and the "Yushin Constitution" in 1972), even more controls were placed on workers and unions. Labor repression actually intensified in the early 1980s (Deyo, 198 7b) as Presi dent Chun Doo Hwan "suspended all collective bargaining and banned organiz ed labor protests and the formation of independent labor unions" (Fineman 1987). In spite of this repression, the latent power of the South Korean working class was gradually growing as the success of export-oriented industrialization was dramatically transf orming the occupational structure. The result of the economic transformation is a proletarianized and urbanized South Korea. When "political cracks " began to appear in the mid -1980s (created by a legitimation crisis in the Chun dictatorship), the pent-up demands of the working class rapidly coalesced. In July 198 7 a foreign missionary noted "a tremendous surge in labor activity" and said that''the explosion is understandable when you consider the labor sec tor is the most suppressed of any in society today" (Fineman 1987). Workers unleashed a wave of strikes demanding wage increases, better working condi tions (in 1986, 1, 718 ROK workers were killed and 141,809 disabled by on-the j ob injuries [Fineman 198 7] ), and collective bargaining rights and guarantees. This appears to reflect a feeling among workers that they have deferred safety and consumption long enough. But beyond acting for their own narrow self-interest in work stoppages, workers have also joined in numerous demonstrations to Prospects for South Korean Democratization 91 support students' calls for more democratic reforms and Korean reunification. The developing class consciousness of Korean workers appears to transcend the narro w economism that appears to characterize the core proletariat. As interesting and important as growing working-class demands is the response from the ruling elites. While some businessmen and government officials insist that worker demands for wage increases, increased workplace safety, and institu tionaliza.on of collective bargaining are no threat to overall profitability (examples in Fineman 1 987), others are not so sure. A Hyundai manager complained in Iln August 1 988 story in the Ko rean Herald , that, " Our workers used to be highly disciplined and do whatever the company wanted them to do but since the govern ment announced democratic reforms in June last year, the workers' attitude changed completely" (Moon 1 988). In October 1988 the chairman of Daewoo, Kim Woo Chong, told a Los Angeles Times reporter, " If it hadn't been for labor trouble the GNP would have grown 20% last year instead of 12 % (Jameson 1988). Recently President Roh "said strikes have cost $2.4 billion in lost production and $600 million in reduced exports this year [ 1 989] " (Associated Press 1 989). Clearly, business and government leaders are acutely aware of the economic costs of democratic and labor reforms (although they may also feel that it is not feasi ble to "roll back" the reforms). As argued earlier, one of the imperatives that the state must fulfill is maintaining ' 'business confidence" ; at some point further reforms may come into sharp conflict with this function. WHITHER DEMOCRACY? South Korea in the 1 980s was undergoing a perilous time of change. It is, literal ly, at the economic and political crossroads. Many Koreans are buoyed by the modest political opening affected by Roh Tae Woo in the past four years. the structural analysis of this chapter suggests ample reasons for pessimism. constraints of ' 'dependent development" make political democratization ficult, even in a country that has been largely a " semiperipheral success It is not likely that South Korea's state and business elites would allow tional economic competitiveness to be sacrificed in exchange for greater I-'V>H"",' and economic participation for ordinary Koreans, but this is a choice that may face. Gereffi lays out the "three-dimensional challenge" to all East Asian NICs from below, by emerging NICs like the Philippines, Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand who were competing in many of the same low-wage manufacturing export industries that East Asia's "Gang of Four" (Taiwan, South Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore) so suc cessfully exploited during the previous decade; from above, creeping protectionism in the major markets for their industrial exports (the United States and the nations of Western Europe); and from within, the shrinking labor pool, and hence rising wage levels . . . coupled with growing political unrest in South Korea. (1988, 20) 92 Semi peripheral Success Stories? Some aspects of the South Korean reality, particularly the emergence of large , strong, politically savvy urban industrial classes, along with the state' s enhanced desire to attain national and intemational legitimacy, seem to bode well for gen uine lasting political change and democratization. On balance, however, there appear to be many constraints on the speed and extent of political liberalization. Perhaps Peter Evans 's speculation on the future trajectory of political change is worth noting. He wonders whether South Korea might follow Japan 's lead here. If so, rather than ending up in the ' 'tumultuous democracy" of the Latin American semiperipheral societies, the ROK might end up with a Japanese-style "controlled parliamentary system" characterized by "restricted" electoral competition "with a minimum or repression" ( 1 987, 223) . Events in the spring of 1989 suggest that the Roh government is beginning to become very worried about the burgeonin� and increasingly militant labor movement and demands for more radical elec toral opposition politics. The state response has been sometimes-violent repres sion and the cancellation of a scheduled referendum on the president. None of this bodes well for the prospect of further political liberalization. Perhaps even Evans has been too optimistic. On the other hand, predicting social change is a very perilous task. In the past the people of South Korea have taken on major challenges against very long odds and succeeded. It is quite possible that they may be able to steer their society toward a distinctly Korean form of democracy and overcome some of the con straints suggested in this chapter. We would only argue that constraints are more readily overcome if they are acknowledged, understood, and confronted head on, rather than denied, avoided or sidestepped. We end with a recent assessment from the Economist: South Korea has confounded pessimists before . . . . Korea's challenge will be to see whether democrats can run an economy as successfully as despots . ( 1989, 78) NOTES A substantial portion of this research was carried out while David Smith was a 1988 sum mer fellow at the Institute for Far Eastern Studies. We thank the institute for its generous support. 1 . Evans writes : "If classic dependence was associated with weak states, dependent development is associated with the strengthening of strong states in the 'semi-periphery. ' The consolidation of state power may even be considered a prerequisite for dependent development" (1979b, 1 1) . 2. The ideological nature of this critique i s clearly revealed in the author' s admission of preference for ' 'neo-classical " economic theory as an explanation of East Asian NIC development. The view that these economies' successes depend on unfettered free enter prise, markets , and a lack of government intervention is so patently false (for a discussion of government intervention in the ROK, see Johnson 1987, 139) that it would almost be Prospects far South Korean Democratization 93 . comical but that this misperception enjoys such great influence in the planning and policy literature (see, for example, World Development 1 6 , I ) . 3 . "Since 1945 South Korea has received nearly 6 % of the total nonmilitary grants by the United States. This continued assistance from the United States reflects the pcJ.'�O" HJ.O strategic or geopolitical importance of South Korea. The extent of its strategic n{"\,rto,,{'p becomes clear when one considers that since 1970 South Korea also received nearly 3 . 5 billion dollars in United States military aid, over three times that of any other East Asian country except Vietnam (Ibid: 870)" (Nemeth and Smith 1985, 203). "It is no exaggeration to say thatthe American aid sustained the Korean and Taiwanese economies in the 1950s . " (Haggard and Cheng 1 987, 87). 4. Dr. K won's discussion of labor unrest took on a very concrete form. He related how KDI itself had been touched by it only a few weeks before the interview when lower-level researchers and assistants had gone on strike and succeeded in winning some concessions. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel . 1 986. "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone. " Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 10, 1 :9-74. Associated Press. 1989. " S . Korean Police Arrest Strikers in Factory Raids. " Los Angeles Times , April 1 9 . Barrett, Richard , and Soomi Chin. 1 987. " Export-oriented Industrializing States i n the Capitalist World System: Similarities and Differences. " In The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by F. Deyo, 23-43 . Ithaca, N . Y . : Cornell University Press. Barrett, Richard , and Martin Whyte. 1982. "Dependency Theory and Taiwan: Analysis of a Deviant Case. " American Journal of Sociology 87: 1064-89. Block, Fred. 1977. "The Ruling Class Does Not Rule: Notes on the Marxist Theory of the State. " Socialist Revolution 3 3:6-28 . Bluestone, B . , and B. Harrison. 1982. The Deindustrialization of America. New York: Basic Books. Brenner, Robert. 1 977. "The Origins of Capitalist Development Theory: A Neo-Smithian Marxism. " New Left Review 104:24-92. Cardoso, Fernando, and Enzo Faletto. [1969] 1979. Dependency and Development . America. Berkeley: University of California Press. Chase-Dunn, Christopher. 1980. " The Development of Core Capitalism in the States : Tariff Policies and Class Struggle in an Upwardly Mobile Semiperiphery. In Studies of the Modem World-System, edited by Albert Bergesen, 1 89-230. New York: Academic. . 198 1 . "Interstate System and Capitalist World Economy: One Logic or Two?" International Studies Quarterly 25 ( 1 ) : 1 9-42. . 1988. Global Formation: Structures of the World-Economy. New York: Basil Blackwell. __ __ Chase-Dunn, Christopher, and Richard Rubinson. 1977 . "Toward a Structural Perspec tive on the World-System. " Politics and Society 7, 4:453-76. , Cho, Soon. 1989. " Korean Economy at a Crossroads : Blueprint for Internationalization . ' Speech to Foreign Correspondents Club, Seoul, January 1 8 . (Reprinted in For Your Information bulletin, Korea Economic Institute, January 27 . 94 Semiperipheral Success Stories? Collier, David, ed. 1979. The New Authoritarianism in Latin America . Princeton, N .J. : Princeton University Press. Cumings, Bruce. 1 98 1 . Ihe Origins ofthe Korean War. Princeton, N.J. : Princton University Press. . 1984. "The Origins and Development of the Northeast Asian Political Economy: Industrial Sectors , Product Cycles , and Political Consequences. " International Organization 38: 1-40. . 1989. "The Abortive Agertura: South Korea in the Light of Latin American Experience. " New Left Review 1 7 3 : 5-32. Deyo, Frederic C . , ed. 1987a. Ihe Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism. Ithaca, N .Y . : Cornell University Press . . 1 987b. " State and Labor: Modes of Political Exclusion in East Asian Develop ment. " In The Political EcofWmy ofthe New Asian Industrialism, edited by F. Deyo, 1 82-202. Ithaca, N. Y . : Cornell University Press. . 1 9 87c. "Coalitions, Institutions , and Linkage Sequencing: Toward a Strategic Capacity Model of East Asian Development. " In 1he Political Economy ofthe New Asian Industrialism, edited by F. Deyo, 227-47 . Ithaca, N .Y. : Cornell University Press . Economist. 1989. "South Korea's Miracle. " May 4, 77-78. Evans, Peter. 1979a. "Beyond Center and Periphery. A Comment on the World-System Approach to the Study of Development. " Sociological Inquiry 49 , 4: 1 5-20 . . 1 979b. Dependent Development. Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press. . 1 987. "Class, State, and Dependence in �East Asia: Lessons for Latin Americanists . " In The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by F . Deyo, 203-26. Ithaca, N.Y. : Cornell University Press. Evans, Peter, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol. 1 985. Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press . Evans, Peter, and John Stephens . 1988 . "Development and the World-Economy. " In lhe Handbook of Sociology, edited by N. Smelser, 739-73. Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. Fineman, Mark. 1987. "Labor Movement Puts South Korea Democratic Reforms to the Test. " Los Angeles Times. Business section, July 1 . Frobel, F . , J . Heinrichs, and O . Kreye. 1 980. 1he New International Division of Labor. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gereffi, Gary. 1988 . "Industrial Restructuring in Latin America and East Asia. " Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, Atlanta , Georgia, August. Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure, and Con tradiction in Social Analysis. Berkeley: University of California Press. Gold, Thomas. 1986. State and Society in the Taiwan Miracle. Armonk, N.Y . : M. E. Sharpe. Haggard, Steven, and Tun-jen Cheng. 1987. " State and Foreign Capital in the East Asian NICs. " In The Political EcofWmy ofthe New Asian Industrialism, edited by F. Deyo, 84- 1 3 5 . Ithaca, N .Y . : Cornell University Press. Hamilton, Clive. 1986. Capitalist Industrialization in Korea. Boulder, Colo . : Westview Press. Han, Sang-jin. 1985. " Bureaucratic Authoritarianism and Economic Development in Korea during the Yushin Period. " In Dependency Issues in Korean Development, edited by K. Kim. Seoul: Seoul National University Press. ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ Prospects for South Korean Democratization 95 Hyug Baeg. 1987. " The Rise of Bureaucratic Authoritarianism in South Korea. " World Politics 39, 2 : 23 1-57. Sam. 1 9 8 8 . " Daewoo Chief Worries over Labor Strife, but is Bullish on South Korea. Los Angeles Times. Business Section, November 6 . Chalmers . 1 987. " Political Institutions and Economic Performance: the Govern ment-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan. " In 1he Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by Frederic Deyo, 1 36-64. Ithaca: Cornell University Press . Kang, Kyu . 1 9 8 8 . Industrial Policy in Korea: Review and Perspective. Seoul: Korea In stitute for Economics and Technology (KIET) . Kaufluan, Robert. 1986. "Liberalization and the Institutionalization of Military-dominated Polities in Latin American. " In Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Prospects for Democracy; edited by G. O'Donnell, P. Schmitter, and L. Whitehead , pt. 3 , 85-107 . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Eun Mee. 1 9 8 8 . "From Dominance to Symbiosis: State and Chaebol in Korea. " Pacific Focus 3 , 2 : 105:2 1 . Koo, Hagen . 1987. "The Interplay of State, Social Class, and World System in East Asian Development: The Cases of South Korea and Taiwan. " In 1he Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism; edited by F. Deyo, 1 65 -8 1 . Ithaca, N . Y . : Cornell University Press. Hagen, Steven Haggard, and Frederic Deyo. 1986. " Labor and Development Strategy in the East Asian NICs. " Itemf (Social Science Research Council Bulletin) 40:64-68. Lee, Chong Ouk. 1 9 8 8 . "Korea' s Science and Technology Policy . " Washington, D . C . : Korea Economic Institute. Lim, Hyun-Chin. 1 985. Dependent Development in Korea: 1 963-1979. Seoul: Seoul Na tional University Press. Moon, !hI-Wan. 1988. "Hyundai Aims at U.S. Car Market with 'Sonata. ' " Korea Herald, August 6 . Mouzelis, Nicos. 1 986. Politics in the Semi-Periphery. London: Macmillan. Nemeth, Roger, and David Smith. 1985. " The Political Economy of Contrasting Urban Hierarchies in South Korea and the Philippines . " In Urbanization in the Economy, edited by M . Timberlake, 1 83-206. New York: Academic. O'Donnell, Guillermo. 1973 . Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism. Institute of International Studies, University of California, Berkeley. O'Donnell, Guillermo, and Philippe Schmitter. 1 986. "Tentative Conclusions and Democracies . " Part 4 of Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Democracy; edited by G. O 'Donnell, P. Schmitter, and L. Whitehead. Johns Hopkins University Press. O'Donnell, Guillermo, Philippe Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead, eds. 1 986. from Authoritarian Rule: Prospects for Democracy. Baltimore: Johns University Press . Poulantzas, Nicos. 1 969. "Problems of the Capitalist State. " New Left Review 5 8 : 67-78. Schumpeter, Joseph. 1 964. Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process . New York: McGraw-Hill. Skocpol, Theda. 1 977. "Wallerstein' s World Capitalist System: A Theoretical and Historical Critique . " American Journal of Sociology 82: 1 075-90. . 1979. States and Social Revolutions. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1 985. ' 'The Relevance of the Concept of Semiperiphery to Southern Europe . " In Semiperipheral Development; edited by G . Arrighi, 3 1-54. Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. ___ HE LIMITS TO SEMIPERIPHERAL EVELOPMENT: ARGENTINA IN THE WENTIETH C ENTURY P. Korzeniewicz chapter argues that the concept of semiperiphery, as advanced by world theory, allows for a more accurate analysis of institutional arrangements social constraints upon development among individual nation-states. This step important because some authors continue to portray world-systems theory as essentially similar to the dependency approach, maintaining that in both theories "external factors determine the dynamics of domestic development" and Stephens 1 988, 740). Such a criticism distorts the character 0 f world theory, manipulating a superficial dichotomy between " internal" and vAlvl1J.al ' factors to portray the theory as a reductionist version of the dependency approach. In this chapter I will focus on the concept of semi periphery to the importance of world-systems theory in revealing social dynamics that define as being of an " internal" or " domestic" nature. This chapter centers on the institutional arrangements and economic tra j of Argentina. The endemic crisis of development in the case of Argentina often been held as a crucial paradox to be explained by theories of "p'llPlnnrn",nT� Waisman's concept of reversal of development ( 1 988) is a recent example of effort to explain Argentina' s apparent anomaly. The mediocre economic perfor- . mance of Argentina since World War II is often contrasted with other nations of recent European settlement such as Australia and Canada. There is also a con sensus that Argentina's steady deterioration in its standing within the world economy after World War II is in stark contrast to the trajectory of rapidly in dustrializing nations such as Brazil and South Korea. In short, on a comparative basis, the pattern of economic growth in Argentina for much of the twentieth century, and particularly during the postwar period, shows considerable stagna tion. This is illustrated by figure 6. 1 . The adoption of a world-systems approach eliminates many of the apparent paradoxes in Argentina ' s trajectory of development. Thus Arrighi has pointed 6.1 1929 . . . . . . . . •••••I• . . . . • • , . '" I.J • • •I • • •••• • • • 1965 •I• .• I••••••••• .. 19 5 7 . ','I'. ... • Source: Elaborated o n the basis of data i n Waisman (1988) . , 1937 = , . . .. .. .. . ••.• 1978 1982 .. .. .. .. , " 1 I" I , , ,.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . , 11 100) 1 II , 1/ , " " . , I ' •�' (Argentina .. ... 1913-1982 -'-', /////..r..r..r////-'-'/-'-'-' ..,.. ///..r..r..r../..r..//..r//..r..r/..r/ /// I I f 1!! !!� � J��:=;; . .....n' 1913 o 1 50 200· 250 3 00 350 400 450 500 Per C apita Product, Selected Countries, Figure Australia :///, Brazil ':,:,:,:,:,:':' Italy I... C(]JUJ[]a - A rgentina The Limits to Development: Argentina 99 out that from a world-systems approach, " what appears as development at the national level may be part and parcel of the reproduction of a core-periphery dichotomy at the global level" ( 1 985, 250). The same argument also applies to the opposite situation: namely, what appears as a case of world-economic stagna tion resulting from purely national characteristics in Argentina may in fact manifest constraints and obstacles that are inherent in the world-economy as a system. The premise of this chapter is that these constraints can be made analytically transparent only by identifying them as embedded in structural positions within the world-economy. Core, semiperiphery, and periphery refer to the position occupied by states in the world division of labor rather than to their position in the interstate system or their internal political characteristics. Utilizing GNP per capita as an " opera tional measurement of the various mixes of core-peripheral activities, " Arrighi and Drangel ( 1 986) have introduced greater precision in identifying both the distribution of nation-states among the three structural positions in the world economy and the extent and frequency of individual mobility by nation-states from one position to another. According to their research, core, semiperipheral, and peripheral positions within the world-economy have maintained a high degree of stability since the 1 930s, with relatively few transitions taking place from zone to zone. The use of this same operational measurement shows that since the late nineteenth century Australia and Canada have been firmly grounded in the core and Argentina in the semiperiphery, with the trajectories of nation-states such as Brazil and South Korea representing a transition from the periphery into the semiperiphery after the interwar period. The three sections of this chapter focus on these trajectories and their relation ship to institutional arrangements, state policies, and social constraints. The first section deals with the differences between Argentina and other nations of recent settlement and argues that the consolidation of Australia and Canada in the core was accompanied by the adoption of state policies conducive to mass consumption, and electoral democracy, while Argentina' s "".lill""UV'" development involved mbre limited advances in each of these spheres. The and section of the chapter deals with the interwar period and suggests that were strong parallels between institutional arrangements in Argentina and adopted among other semi peripheral nations during the 1 920s and 1 930s, and that many of the specificities of Peronism resulted from the strong character of semiperipheral development in Argentina prior to World War II. The third sec tion dra ws conceptual distinctions between the concept of semiperiphery and that of " dependent development. " This section discusses the postwar period to argue that social constraints upon state policies in Argentina are indicative of structural limits to semi peripheral development, and that the " success models" of Brazil and South Korea involve a different type of trajectory (from the periphery into the semiperiphery) that is likely to encounter similar limits in the near future. The major points made in each of the three sections are summarized in the conclusion. 1 00 Semiperipheral Success Stories? NATIONS OF RECENT SETTLEMENT (1890s-WORLD WAR I) There has been much debate over the trajectories followed by the nations of recent European settlement within the world-economy. In his early articles Wallerstein was somewhat ambivalent about their precise structural position, (1979, 85-86), other times placing them (1 979, 1 00). Resnick (1 989) argues that Canada should be sometimes placing these states in the core in the semi periphery considered as part of the semi periphery because of a weak national bourgeoisie and little influence in the arena of international politics. Giving greater emphasis to economic characteristics, Glenday has suggested that Canada belongs to the semiperiphery because "economic development has been constrained by the in fluence of both the trade in 'staples' and the nature and direction of the flows of capital from its metropolitan partner" (1989 , 216). Other authors have more accurately highlighted profound structural differences between Australia and Canada, on the one hand, and Argentina, on the other. Dyster, for example, indicated that differences between Australia and Argentina in terms of relative wage levels were already entrenched by the last quarter of the eighteenth century and the first half of the nineteenth century: "A decisive shift had occurred in Argentina ' s terms of trade toward landholding and produc tion for export, whereas the balance in Australia between import and export, be tween consumption and production, held firm throughout" (1 979 , 95). Similar ly, Diaz Alejandro argued that a great gap existed between Argentina and other countries of recent settlement already by 1 860, although the gap was consistently narrowed over the next seventy years, when national income grew faster in Argen tina than in Australia, Canada, and even the United States (1970, 55) . 1 Alex ander has also argued that by the turn of the century Argentina was firmly in the semiperiphery and Australia in the core of the world-economy, indicating that these divergent positions explain the consolidation of democratic institutions in Australia and the breakdown of democratic institutions and the adoption of "a path of state repression and counterrevolution" that prevented the "incor (1989, 32 1 , 328).2 Finally, Arrighi and Drangel (1 986) and Arrighi, Korzeniewicz, and Martin ( 1 985) confirm that Australia and Canada were already firmly grounded poration of the working class into a consumerist capitalism" in Argentina in the core and Argentina in the semiperiphery by the late nineteenth century, and that these structural differences persisted throughout the twentieth century. The fact that by the 1 920s Argentina remained in the semiperiphery, despite experiencing a rate of growth among the world 's fastest, emphasizes that rapid economic growth may be accompanied by no structural changes in the position occupied by particular nation-states within the world-economy. The world economic trajectories of Canada, Australia, and Argentina also show that the ag gregate rewards accruing to different nodes of economic activity are not inherent in the technical features of production or the type of commodities involved but are an outcome of changing processes of competition and innovation among economic actors in different areas of the world-economy (Wallerstein 1 979 , 71). The Limits to Development: Argentina 101 Hence i n all three nations state policies and entrepreneurial initiative had achieved formidable rates of economic growth by rapidly bringing together land, labor, and capital into the production of high-priced agricultural commodities.3 Further more, aggregate rewards differed even within a single commodity according to the forms of production that prevailed among different regions of the worldeconomy: after the 1 8 70s growing agricultural productivity in nations of recent settlement led to declining market shares in grains for Eastern Europe, where older methods of production prevailed (Alexander 1 989). Finally, in all the nations of recent settlement (including Argentina) the state played a very active role in providing conditions favorable to economic expan sion. In the case of Argentina, for example, state elites were a major force behind territorial expansion and the military elimination of native Americans, as well as in promoting labor migration from Europe and attracting foreign investments. It is important to emphasize the active role of the state in Argentina during the last half of the nineteenth century because some have interpreted the world-systems approach to argue that nations in the semiperiphery are characterized by weak states (Cumings 1 988, 269). This is not the argument put forth in world-systems theory. In fact, Wallerstein has indicated that among semiperipheral nations "the direct and immediate interest of the state as a political machinery in the control of the market (internal and international) is greater than in either the core or the peripheral states, since the semiperipheral states can never depend on the market to maximize, in the sho rt run, their profit margins" ( 1 979, 72). Contrasts in the trajectories of Australia, Argentina, and Canada after the 1 930s have long been acknowledged in comparative studies, where the debate has re volved around whether the postwar stagnation of Argentina should be attributed to Peronism or to the economic and political arrangements developed by land owners prior the the turn of the century. Most of these comparative studies have focused on differences in the structure of economic growth. In Canada wheat production was an important component of this growth, but ' ' exports of and of livestock products also grew rapidly. And as export income eXj)aTIldel:ii domestic market, manufacturing and the service trades also raced ahead" 1 978, 1 98). Manufacturing also played a more important role in Australia: ing the 1 920s the total annual output of steel grew from 1 4 , 000 to over �vv. ,,'vv. tons, and the motor vehicle industry became " one of the principal ways in which foreign capital and techniques of production were introduced into Australian manufacturing" (Forster 1 964, 57). In both Australia and Canada state economic policies played an active role in promoting industrialization and in raising pro ductivity within mining and agriculture by making major investments in technological innovations and scientific research. In Argentina, on the other hand, the process of industrial growth was largely saddled on the export structure that had been mounted in the 1 870s, and there was a " high propensity to import manufactures" (Diaz Ale jandro 1 970, 16). 4 Manufacturing prior to World War I grew more slowly, so that in 1 9 1 3 the out put of manufactures per capita in Argentina was roughly one-fourth of what it 1 02 Semiperipheral Success Stories' was in Australia (Lewis 1978, 163). As opposed to Canada and Australi a , manufac turing in Argentina grew ei ther in response to market opportunities or as an unintended consequence of state policies. However, "The Argentine growth rate did not suffer noticeably from this relative weakness of backward linkages. It may even have benefitted from greater specialization along the lines of comparative advantage, in contrast with Australia during the same period , " so that "a sus tained lag in Argentina's growth rate behind most of Western Europe and coun tries of recent settlement is difficult to find before 1930" (Diaz Alejandro 1970, 17, 54). Hence industrialization would only make a substantial difference in the interwar period, when manufacturing (in a world-economy characterized by a breakdown of hegemony and crisis of the world market) became a mechanism to overcome peripheralizing pressures within the world-economy . In fact, over the short run, the economic rewards of protectionist policies in Australia during the interwar period were meager when compared to the consi stently high rates of economic growth achi eved in Argentina between World War l and World WarIl . Unemploy ment and recession also hit Australia with much greater strength than Argentina during the 1930s. But by World War II it became clear that state policies in Australia had been instrumental in consolidating a core position within the world-economy.s State policies promoting i ndustrialization and increasing agricultural produc tivity in Australia and Canada were part of the creation of innovative institutional arrangements designed to respond to the social pressures generated by labor and/or family farmers . 6 This can be best illustrated by contrasting Australia and Argen tina. Mining in Australia served as the basis for a powerful labor movement that by the early 1900s effectively constrained the choice of strategies that the state could pursue. Having repeatedly lost major strikes throughout the 1890s , organized labor turned to the politi cal arena to seek there the concessions it could not wrest from employers through direct bargaining (see Turner 1965). The position of organized labor was further strengthened after 1901 by the formation of a powerful Labour Party. Thereafter, it was the presence of labor in politics, and the growing strength of the industrial organiza tions, which precipitated the wave of social legislation that for a time made Australia a model for the world. . . . the growth of government enterprise and the creation of institu tions, such as the Commonwealth Bank, to give effect to government economic policy; such nationalist policies as immigration restrictions and defense-all these, the better and the worse, owed their existence substantially to the labour parties (Turner 1 965 , 50). Over the long run, however, these changing state policies (and particularly the new restricti ons on immigration) could only be made compatible with further economic growth by promoting a model of development based on industrializa tion rather than exports. This did become the new direction adopted by state policies in Australia in the early twenti eth century. 7 The Limits to Development: Argentina 1 03 The political incorporation of labor also paved the road for industrialization in Australia by providing an early institutional system through which to mediate conflicts between workers and employers . The creation of these state institutions included the early consolidation of a state bureaucracy that subsequently under took an active role in promoting industrialization as a " natural " extension of its original functions (MacIntyre 1983, 1 08). Labor's strong political position also had a crucial impact upon the domestic market: wages and income in Australia rose through most of the 191 0s and 1920s, not only ensuring growing domestic demand for consumer durables but also acting as an incentive for both technological innovation and industrial protectionism. In Argentina the forms of action and organization adopted by labor were precise ly the opposite to those of Australia. To begin with, " In spite of some cyclical unemployment, for 1 860-1 930 as a whole Argentina can be characterized as a full-employment economy " (Diaz Alejandro 1970, 27) . Furthermore, internal labor reserves were lacking, and European immigrants had to be attracted through high wages. As a result, workers had considerable bargaining power within the labor market. This bargaining power was enforced through innovative forms of action and organization adopted by labor when unformalized craft controls over the workplace and the labor market were undermined after the 1880s. Workers in Argentina were able to effectively press demands upon employers with little need to strengthen the political power of their organizations. 8 This does not mean that semi peripheral nations are characterized by weak labor movements or poorly paid workers: it is precisely the strong market bargaining power of labor in Argentina that explains the absence of a highly politicized labor movement. This also does not mean that politics were absent from the develop ment of the labor movement: it underlines that politics did not constitute the cen tral arena in which workers pressed their demands upon employers. In short, the export-led model of growth continued to shape state policies without any jor political challenge from organized labor. The very success of the prevailing model of development allowed for and political challenges to be met by gradual institutional innovations and rewards, and this provided an overall stability to the political system-at while economic resources remained easily available. In the process, the structure of Argentina evolved in a manner similar to that which prevailed among core countries . This had social and political consequences that were to reveal the inherent limits of semiperipheral development. THE SEMIPERIPHERY IN THE INTERWAR PERIOD By the end of the interwar period, the social and political constraints of Argen tina's semiperipheral position in the world-economy began to become apparent. The interwar period as a whole was punctuated by increasingly pronounced economic and political discontinuities. Economically, state elites found growing difficulties in continuing to rely on exports as the main drive for the overall 104 Semi peripheral Success Stories? economy : this was manifested in growing unemployment and balance-of-trade deficits and declining rates of economic growth. Politically, there was a cris is of prevailing institutional arrangements, beginning with the military overthrow of the Yrigoyen administration in 1930, following with the widespread use of fraud in elections through the rest of the decade, and culminating in the military coup of 1943. These discontinuities resulted in two significant new trends : growing intervention of the state in protecting the export sector and manufacturing from competitive pressures and increasing mediation of the state in conflicts between capital and labor. In turn, social actors began turning to the state to seek to ad vance their positions primarily through the political arena. Both under the Radical administrations of the 1920s and the regimes of the 1930s, state policies in Argentina were intended to respond to the breakup of the world market and the intensification of interimperialist rivalry. Facing a deterioration of the terms of trade, growing protectionism in Europe, and a wither ing of capital flows from the United States, state policies were designed to avoid the impact of competitive pressures by closing ranks with England through bilateral trade agreements. Industrial growth did proceed forward in Argentina during the 1920s and 1930s, but it was bound by a model of growth that revolved around the undisputed primacy of agricultural and livestock exports, as well as by the rigidities of a political system in which ruling elites sought to keep institutional innovations at a minimum.9 This institutional response to world competitive pressures stood in contrast to the state policies pursued by the Vargas regime in Brazil during the same period. The Vargas regime saw regional competition among factions of capital as a political threat. In response, state policies in Brazil soon after the 1930 coup made in dustrial protectionism into the centerpiece of a broader effort to counter the im pact of the international crisis. For this purpose, domestic demand was stimulated and financed by the central government through fiscal deficits and the revenues generated by exports (Fishlow 1977, 26). Tariffs and exchange controls were introduced to reduce imports and improve the balance of trade, and state agen cies were created to provide easier channels of credit for industrial development (Villela and Suzigan 1975, 60). The state itself invested heavily in industry, par ticularly in large-scale and high-risk projects and enterprises that the military con sidered to be strategic to national security (Trebat 1981, 56). State policies in Brazil during the 1930s were highly successful. Economic recovery through the 1930s was led by manufacturing, which grew "at an [average annual] rate of 8.6 % . . . while agriculture rose at half this rate" (Fish low 1977, 26). In contrast, manufacturing in Argentina grew at an average annual rate of 3 percent between 1929 and 1939 (Diaz Ale jandro 1984, 39). State policies pro moting industrialization in Brazil evolved in a manner similar to the case of Mex ico where these policies emerged as "a reflection of the government's unifica ' tion policy, designed to counteract the centrifugal forces at work in the country" (Furtado 1970, 80). From this point of view, the main priority of the Vargas regime was to capture and centralize political power under the central national The Limits to Development: Argentina 1 05 go vernment; industrialization was pursued as a means to achieve this ulterior :political objective. , ( These policies shared important features with those of fascist regimes in Southern �urope during the interwar period, particularly in terms of the strategy adopted to deal with the new opportunities and constraints of the world-economy. : ' Ideologically, these regimes pushed for ' ' social harmony" -as opposed to " market {rule, liberal democracy and class conflict, [which] were seen as disruptive in fluences on the nation's internal cohesion and external power" (Arrighi 1 985, 251 ) . These regimes were also similar in their state policies, with protectionism and mercantilism being ' ' meant to sustain domestic production and employment in order to facilitate social harmony/control, and to strengthen the internal linkages between economic processes at the expense of external linkages " (Arrighi 1 985, 25 1). In other words, state policies were designed to strengthen national com over wealth by insulating domestic producers from peripheralizing tenden : cies in the world-economy. Argentina did come to share some similarities with these regimes after the emergence of Peronism following the 1 943 coup. As part of the new develop ment strategy implemented after 1 943, state policies pursued industrial growth by stimulating consumer demand through higher wages and public spending, pro tected industrial entrepreneurs from foreign competition through import tariffs, and redistributed income from the export sector to the urban sectors. 10 Once im plemented, protectionist policies were supported by industrial entrepreneurs and labor alike, for they allowed both wages and prices to rise. These policies coin cided with an effort by the Peronist administrations ( 1 946- 1 955) to consolidate an internal coalition of the urban and rural working class, industrial entrepreneurs, small farmers, and the middle class, while establishing Argentina' s hegemony within Latin America. But if one compares Peronism to other corporatist experiences in semiperiphery, there are salient differences. First, Peronism made its <""r\po,r"" l'P late in the interwar period rather than during the 1 920s (as in the case of or the 1 930s (as in the case of Brazil). This difference in timing had ,'Tnn(�rt,,,· consequences, for the same state policies that had effectively promoted . dustrialization among many semiperipheral nations during the 1 920s and would prove considerably less effective during the postwar period and the era of U.S. hegemony. The second difference involves the role of labor under the ,: Peronist regimes. In Italy labor-repressive legislation "was . . . a necessary com plement [of protectionism and mercantilism], since only direct state regulation and repression could simultaneously maintain industrial peace, full employment, and wages low enough to allow for accumulation in an inefficient economy" (Ar righi 1 985, 252) . In relation to the labor movement, fascism involved both en hanced competition within the labor force and a mobilization of other social groups in support of antilabor policies (with the fragmentation and heterogeneity of social groups providing a basis for the autonomy of state policies from particular economic interests). In Brazil under the Vargas regime, state policies began to � t\ 1 06 Semi peripheral Success Stories? regulate the actions of organized labor; this ensured labor discipline, while at II the same time it opened a new potential basis of social support. But in Argentina organized labor under Peronism considerably increased its political bargaining power and institutional strength. Despite efforts to subordinate trade unions to the state apparatus, they maintained a greater degree of autonomy (particularly at the grass roots level), and state institutions found it difficult to control the rising frequency of labor-capital conflicts. Furthermore , comisiones intemas and factory delegates contested management's control over the organiza tion of the workplace. Finally, the emergence of Peronism was accompanied by a massive growth in union membership, and trade unions played a key institu tional role within the new regime. In other words, organized labor under Peronism achieved considerable institutional strength, and this would allow the labor move ment to effectively challenge state policies for decades to come. How can these differences in timing and in the role played by labor under Peronism best be explained? Waisman argues that these policies resulted from an unrealistic fear of revolution among state elites. Structural changes in the world economy around the 1930s had challenged the economic and political status quo, leading to a fragmentation of established elites and making possible a greater autonomization of the state. But facing an unrealistic fear of revolution, new state elites developed antirevolutionary policies- "radical protectionism to manufac turing and a corporatist strategy toward labor" (Waisman 1987, 137)-that led to growing economic stagnation and political illegitimacy. According to Waisman, ' 'The new industrial and labor policies were initiated from above, and they were not a concession to the demands and mobilization for these policies in civil socie ty" (1987, 138). In short, political instability and economic stagnation were the outcome of misguided state policies: "The decline of Argentina was the result of policies with which sectors of the elite believed they were protecting their in terests. More specifically, they sacrificed economic growth for what they thought were their long-term political interests" (Waisman 1987, 11).12 But were Peronist policies merely ref orms ' 'from above " that did not respond to actual social demands? In fact, during the 1930s labor was very effective in adopting new forms of action and organization that enhanced its political bargaining power. Before the 1930s the adoption of industry wide forms of action and organization among workers had been rare, labor's bargaining power revolved primarily around tight labor-market conditions, and state mediation in labor-capital conflicts was irregular. But with the wave of strikes of the mid-1930s, semiskilled and unskilled workers engaged in industrywide actions, adopted unions organized on a nationwide basis, and pursued state mediation as a central mechanism for pressing demands upon employers. Communist organizers were particularly suc cessful within these new industrial unions. Their success challenged the older political leadership within the labor movement (such as Syndicalists, Socialists, and Anarchists) and was viewed as a threat by conservative leaders, business, and the armed forces. The state responded to labor unrest, particularly after a wave of strikes in the mid-1930s, by intervening more directly in regulating labor The Limits to Development: Argentina 1 07 cap ital. With these changes , labor' s political bargaining power began to the new centerpiece of institutional arrangements among labor, capital, the state. �; P'ef(ml:, m developed as a response to the new pressures generated by the labor ;';""PTneI1t upon prevailing institutional arrangements. After the 1 943 military the primary concern of Colonel Peron upon becoming secretary of labor to contain the growth of Communist influence within organized labor. Here broader context is important: as indicated in repeated memoirs and statements the military during this period, there were pronounced fears among the armed that organized labor-and with it, the Communist presence in Argentina grow substantially stronger upon the end of World War II. To counter Communist unions and strengthen state regulation of labor-capital relations, relied upon and further developed channels of institutional mediation that been initiated in response to labor unrest during the 1 93 0s. Peron found will allies among trade un ion leaders from other political tendencies and encouraged to adopt the same forms of action and organization that had previously been under Communist leadership in the industrial unions. Finally, Peronism the development of an alliance with other social sectors (such as ggricultural workers, industrial entrepreneurs, the commercial middle class, and farmers) through the use of a political discourse that actually shared many in common with the Communist discourse of the late 1 930s and early But the timing of Peronism and the role played by labor in support of these should also be understood in light of the relative success of Argentina the world-economy prior to World War n. Institutional arrangements among capital, and the state had come to share strong similarities to those that in core areas of the world-economy. In this sense the high revenues ,, ' g:ellierarea through the comparative advantages of agricultural and livestock pro-� . · yielded a larger volume of revenues that could be distributed among in Argentina to limit conflicts among them. As in core areas of the this allowed for the early prevalence of a convergence of mtprc·ctc tween labor and capital and for " a market economy sustained by the state," function of state policies "was . . . the reestablishment and "U.U�'JH'.la.'IU.JCl5";i" ",.f'r:;' rather than the suppression of market competition" (Arrighi 1 980, 1 1 - 12). some adjustments, these policies were maintained by state elites in Argentina in the midst of the Great Depression. Overall, particularly in the short term, state policies in Argentina during the interwar period were very successful in dealing the disruptions of the world-economy. 13 As indicated in the previous section, the labor movement in Argentina derived considerable bargaining power from the strong pattern of economic development that characterized the period prior to World War n. In contrast to other semiperi pheral areas of the world-economy (such as Italy and other Southern European nations), periods of economic expansion always confronted a relative shortage of workers and/or labor reserves. As a consequence, the labor market in Argentina 1 08 Semi peripheral Success Stories? was characterized by a tendency toward full employment, and this greatly strengthened the bargaining power of labor at all levels. This is where the issue of historical timing becomes important in relation to the formation of Peronism. Through the 1930s institu.onal arrangements in Argen tina began to channel social demands through the political sphere, and there was a rising mobilization not only of workers , but also of industrial entrepreneurs , farmers, exporters , and merchants. The coup of 1943 was designed to provide new leadership to these disparate social forces . But as opposed to other semiperipheral nations at the ti me, Argentina's privileged position in the world market during World War II as a producer of foodstuffs generated considerable wealth, providing a greater margin of resources for political negotiation and the incorporation of labor. In a context marked by a high degree of politicization, Peronist policies were designed to use this margin of negotiation to generate a rapid and broad basis of political support. Seeking to increase state control over economic resources to advance in dustrialization, Peronist state policies also used the distribution of wealth to en sure continued political support by labor . But as i ndicated in the next section of the chapter, this new strategy of development also entailed future constraints. The availability of revenues derived from a privileged position in the world market was of central importance to the ability of state elites to maintain political con sensus . These revenues quickly dwindled in the early 1950s , generating a marked recessi on. As agricultural and livestock producti on ceased to yield the same high level of revenues as before, and as the state failed in its bid to transform Argen tina into a core area of the world-economy, the margin of surplus available for internal distribution began to stagnate or even decline. At the same time, the in stitutional strength gained by labor under Peronism limited the ability of state policies to reverse their strategy and try to more effectively subordinate labor to accumulation. In a world context in which the unruli ness of labor acted as a constraint upon development, these pressures would lead to the continued crisis of the postwar peri od. THE CONSTRAINTS OF SEMIPERIPHERAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE POSTWAR PERIOD Argentina's trajectory within the world-economy during the postwar period sug gests that institutional arrangements in the semi periphery are characterized by social constraints that become an obstacle for subsequent transitions into the core. During this period, as elsewhere in the semi periphery , " it was the outbreak of social conflict and its unfolding that determined more than anything else the tim ing and direction of political-economic change" (Arrighi 1985, 2 64). Most im portantly, the labor movement in Argentina retained the strength that characterized organized labor in core areas of the world-economy, but it became increasingly dif ficult for the state to sustain the relative convergence of interests that had characterized previous phases (or the immediate postwar period under Peronism). The Limits to Development: Argentina 109 particular, state policies in Argentina during the postwar period found it in hard either to control social unrest or to extend mass consumption and H _�'nt.,," full employment. Hence labor unrest in Argentina in the postwar period more profound and sustained than in most core areas of the world and entrepreneurs responded with capital flight abroad. The explosive uu,' U "'�" of a strong labor movement with limited revenues illustrates some the key structural constraints that are characteristic of semi peripheral areas the world-economy. As indicated in the previous section, these constraints were not immediately ;'ilPlp arent after the end of World War II. At the end of the war favorable trade cond.ltlClDS and large reserves provided the Peronist regime elected in 1 946 with necessary resources to promote industrial expansion and economic growth improving wages . By the 1 95 0s, however, Peronist state policies ran against ' VUILU"U""-n.� that would constrain economic growth for decades to come. Thus, the favorable external conditions of 1 945-48 and the reserves accumulated 1946 had disappeared, and in spite of the brief Korean commodity boom, economy was not capable of sustaining a growth rate superior to that of the " .UJu'I'U"UU�'u (Diaz Alejandro 1 970, 1 1 0). new economic difficulties resulted in part from a deterioration in the balance trade. After the 1 95 0s, revenues from exports declined due to stagnant productivity, falling terms of trade, and growing domestic consump of agricultural and livestock products. At the same time, the process of import industrialization generated greater demand for capital goods and raw that could only be secured abroad. These two trends resulted in " stop, ' and-go" cycles (see Braun 1 973 ) . State authorities periodically responded to the ' , deterioration in the balance of trade by implementing devaluations designed to agricultural exports and raise the cost of imports. Eventually, imc ' orov,emlentS in the balance of trade generated foreign revenues and increased the: of the national currency, providing new opportunities for urban and entrepreneurs to press for more favorable state policies (O'Donnell These drastic fluctuations in economic growth and state policies prevented consolidation of a coherent institutional strategy for integrated economic U"V"J:uu'�, . ment. During the Peronist regimes, for example, there was growing competition , '.- among manufacturing firms in Argentina over their relative share of a stagnant I:; , : ' domestic market, but these firms found it difficult to gain a competitive edge � " throUgh the adoption of technological innovations due to the lack of capital im. , __ ports. From this perspective, protectionism and the closing of the economy to foreign competition resulted in more pronounced inefficiencies in the production i i and distribution of goods and service s . 14 �.�{ . ': These institutional constraints were indicative of the limits to semi peripheral � : development within the world-economy. During the interwar period and immediate ,. postwar era, state action in the semiperiphery played a fundamental role in counter ing peripheralizing pressures within the world-economy by protecting domestic manufacturing from foreign competition. During this conjuncture state action was "U�'''b'J , ,'" " ,, f 110 Semi peripheral Success Stories? crucial in maintaining a semiperipheral position by reproducing an even mix of core and peripheral activities within national boundaries . But over time the very same strategy used to resist peripheralizing pressures within the world-economy became crystallized in institutional arrangements and entrenched economic in terests that would later prevent the adoption of the further innovations required for a successful transition into the core . During the immediate postwar years, for example, protectionist state policies had continued to promote the growth of manufacturing and to upgrade the mix of economic activities contained within Argentina. But later in the postwar period these same policies discouraged capital investments and/or the adoption of fur ther innovations in production. State efforts to dismantle these protectionist struc tures proved largely unsuccessful . This was because the restriction of foreign competition through protectionist policies developed into a crucial mechanism used by the state to reduce tensions between labor and capital, and both organized labor and manufacturing firms resisted any efforts to substantially alter these in stitutional arrangements . 15 In time, these arrangements fed strong inflationary tendencies, further undermining each of the different strategies of development pursued by both civilian and military governments during the postwar period. Thus, inherent in recurring balance-of-trade deficits, currency devaluations, pro tectionist structures, and inflationary pressures , there were escalating conflicts between and within labor, capital, and the state (Diaz Alejandro 1970, 122) . These conflicts were a major element explaining the institutional instability that followed the military overthrow of the Peronist administration in 1 955, as well as the economic stagnation and political violence that characterized Argentina for years to come. The postwar trajectory of Argentina has often been contrasted to that of Brazil (see figure 6. 1 ) . State policies in Brazil achieved high rates of economic growth through the rapid expansion of industrial activities : between 1 950 and 1 980 the share of manufacturing in gross domestic product (GDP) grew from 1 6 . 5 per cent to 30.2 percent (Economic Commission for Latin America 1 980, 1 09) . As an indication of the magnitude of industrial growth, " by 1976 the weight of steel products, machinery and equipment within the industrial sector was superior to 30. 0 % , the highest ratio in all Latin America and close to the existing ratio in Western Europe" (Serra 1983, 57) . Industrial growth was also accompanied by changes in the structure of exports, with the share of manufactured products grow ing from 1 0 . 5 percent in 1968 to 45 percent by 1 980 (Serra 1983, 59) . The success of the model of development pursued by federal state agencies in Brazil and the recurrent crises that characterized the trajectory of Argentina are indicative of significant differences in the type of social constraints encountered by the state. In Brazil federal elites since the 1 930s had diluted the direct pressures of economic interests by strengthening a centralized corporatist structure at the expense of the strength and autonomy of state governments . A myriad of federal state agencies were created to provide bureaucratic channels of participation, and their effectiveness served to solidify the new model of growth implemented after The Limits to Development: Argentina 111 mid-1 930s. These corporate channels of mediation were also effectively ex to the sphere 9f the organized labor movement. When these corporatist were challenged by labor militancy after the 1 950s, the military moved to replace them with more repressive forms of labor control. opposed to Brazil, institutional arrangements in postwar Argentina have constrained state efforts to consolidate any long-term development . The institutional political system has itself reflected ' 'a compromise be powerfully structured groups" (Furtado 1 970, 102). 16 In particular, in;tium oHru arrangements after the overthrow of the Peronist administration in 1 955 until the mid- 1 970s were characterized by the capacity of labor and com sectors of capital to successfully resist most attempts by state policies to ,,,�.,.t"" " "- them and ensure their political subordination. 17 Thus postwar Argen was characterized by "a state [that was] recurrently razed by changing co of civil society. . . . This resulted in a state apparatus [that was both] ex colonized by civil society and [hence] extraordinarily broken-up" LAJlIlI'v" 1 977, 552) . . These constraints were particularly evident in regard to the labor movement. political power developed by organized labor under Peronism made postwar ; 'lnlstil:utlon,U arrangements among labor, capital, and the state highly unstable and as a constraint upon capital accumulation. After the overthrow of Peron ""(;; . __ 1955, enterprises responded to the strength of trade unions by introducing L"'-"II"'''V/,'V'U innovations designed to improve the productivity of labor. These m",nV'UlCm s, however, had the unintended consequence of enhancing the ability ",r." Ir,�,.c to disrupt production through forms of action and organization centered the workplace. This workplace bargaining power of labor undermined ability of the official trade union leadership to discipline the rank and file, iiltlrod:uc:ing further instability into prevailing institutional arrangements. Final a succession of co-optive and coercive policies implemented by both " '."'-" J elected regimes proved unsuccessful in dampening labor unrest and/or the power of organized labor. This ' 'unruliness " of labor became the single most important constraint the process of accumulation in the 1 960s, particularly in light of the fact .' the military regimes in Argentina after 1 966 competed for the same flows of direct : foreign investment that military regimes attracted to Brazil after 1 964. For pot:enltIai . lm'esltors, the virtual explosion of labor conflicts in Argentina in 1 969 became " evidence that the Argentina Bureaucratic-Authoritarian [state] had failed as the - guarantor of social peace and economic stability. Consequently, the flow of foreign { investment halted and numerous indicators registered without delay the loss of �': ' confidence" (O 'Donnell 1 976, 1 9). In contrast, by 1 969 the military regime in . Brazil had shown " the will and the ability to impose a socially regressive policy over an extended period" (Skidmore 1 977, 28) , and this proved of great impor tance in effectively maintaining high rates of local and foreign investment. This does not mean, of course, that internal social constraints were the sole factor determining the relative success of state policies in generating high rates ___ . 1 12 Semi peripheral Success Stories? of economic growth . The stability of institutional arrangements in the postwar period hinged upon the ability of state policies to anticipate and effectively re spond to the new conditions of the world-economy. Foreign invesWnents, favorable trade agreements , and international financial confidence were of great importance in achieving high rates of economic growth, and they were pursued in Brazil through a variety of incentives . At the same time, state policies in Brazil had a long history of playing upon competitive pressures within the world-economy to gain leverage from which to increase and direct flows of foreign capital toward productive investments . Such a strategy was not effectively pursued by political elites in the case of Argentina. During the interwar period relations between Argentina and the United States were viewed as competitive. Already in 1 929 "many influential Argen tine leaders regarded their country as the logical counterpoise to the United States in the Americas, and dreamed of increasing Argentine influence in neighboring countries" (Diaz Alejandro 1970, 59). After the end of World War II, the Peronist administrations misjudged future developments in the world-economy and in terstate system (for example, by constructing trade policies based on expecta tions that an imminent World War III would increase demand for foodstuffs). Finally, after 1 955 successive efforts to attract international investments and finance were undermined by endemic institutional instability . From this perspec tive, Diaz Alejandro argues that ' 'nationalistic policies cost Argentina the direct foreign investment that stimulated industrialization in Australia, Brazil, and Canada during the postwar period" ( 1 970, 266) . But what was the character of postwar developments in Argentina and Brazil? The most significant attempt to conceptualize these trajectories of economic growth has been through the concept of dependent development. For Cardoso and Falet to, in dependent nations "the accumulation and expansion of capital cannot find its essential dynamic component inside the system" ( 1 979, xx). But postwar dependency is to be distinguished from ' 'classical dependency" (production of raw materials for the international economy prior to the Great Depression) (Evans 1 979, 58). After 1 929 populist regimes began to mobilize economic resources away from traditional export sectors to promote investments and expand urban consumption ; but the end of the export boom, combined with the growing strength of industrial entrepreneurs and the mobilization of wage earners , resulted in a political crisis of the populist regimes (Cardoso and Faletto 1 979, 1 50) . "When a political crisis in the system prevents an economic policy of public and private investment for development, the only alternatives are opening the market to foreign capital or making a radical move toward Socialism" (Cardoso and Faletto 1979, 1 55) . In the postwar period this gave rise to "dependent development" , which joined the public sector, the multinational corporation, and the modern capitalist sector of the national economy, and producers. "Producers become the most im portant 'consumers' in the economic expansion . . . . To raise the accumulation or savings capacity of those 'producer-consumers , ' the demands of the masses must be contained, and as a consequence, a policy of redistribution to broaden The Limits to Development: Argentina 1 13 consumption becomes ineffective and even contrary to this type of development b ased on the dynamism of big enterprises" (Cardoso and Faletto 1 979, 1 63) . From this perspective, the failure of state policies in Argentina to achieve high rates of economic growth would be attributed to the impact of social unrest in Argentina and the ability of organized labor and other social forces to resist the implementation of the authoritarian strategy. This theme is further developed by O'Donnell ( 1 978), who has focused on the political consequences of dependent development through the concept of the bureaucratic-authoritarian state. The dependent-development approach, particularly as used in Latin America itself, represented a significant advance over more simplistic dependency ap proaches. The new approach sought to uncover the ways in which state elites actively responded to the social constraints that had resulted from previous phases of accumulation. As a result, the dependent-development approach emphasized the processes of conflict and negotiation that confronted political actors and shaped state policies, and social unrest was brought into analysis as a significant variable shaping state policies. However, the dependent-development approach, particularly as used in the United States, had significant drawbacks. To begin with, the concept has involved a number of generalizations derived from a limited number of " case studies" (usually the most industrialized countries in Latin America) . Building on generali zations, the conclusions have often proved inadequate when dealing with other nations outside this particular region. Cumings ( 1 988), for example, suggests that the postwar trajectory of most Asian countries undermines the propositions that the state plays a relatively subordinate role to foreign capital or that the logic of the alliance between the state, foreign capital, and local elites will always re quire and reproduce greater social inequality and the political exclusion of the broad majority of the population. The problem arises in part because it is unclear whether the concept of dependent development applies to the relative standing of states within the world-economy (in other words, to the relative command wealth exercised by these states), or to the type of social and political that has promoted industrial growth in a restricted number of cases. The of semi periphery , on the other hand, allows for the two issues to be analytically distinct, so as to make their relationship an object of theoretical inquiry: This points to a further difference in the concepts of dependent development and semiperiphery. The concept of dependent development focuses almost ex clusively on the postwar period and the expansion of multinationals engaging in manufacturing in Third World countries . Patterns of development prior to the 1 930s are neglected as a phase of "classical dependency" that involved no signifi cant efforts by state elites to control interaction with the market. Within the world systems approach, on the other hand, the semi periphery is viewed as a constant feature in the development of the world-economy. By adopting a long-term historical perspective, it becomes easier to identify which are the features that have been constantly present in the semiperiphery and which are truly new phenomena of the postwar era. 1 14 Semiperipheral Success Stories? One of the consequences of this difference is that it allows for different historical questions to be raised . Although the notion of "active role of state" brings world systems theory close to the dependent-development approach in their emphasis on the active role of states in seeking to enhance the mix of economic activities contained within territorial boundaries, the world-systems approach maintains that this pattern of state action has always been a maj or feature of the semiperiphery, rather than being merely a postwar phenomenon. But the consequences go fur ther. Within the dependent-development approach, industrialization is generally viewed as a mechanism of upward mobility . In the world-systems approach, on the other hand, it is clear that the character of industrialization must be examined within its historical framework . From this perspective, manufacturing is not in itself a core activity . It may have been so at different times and places , and it may continue to be so in certain forms, but the degree to which it represents a core activity is a consequence not of the activity itself, but of the competitive relations it embodies within specific time-space coordinates . This point is par ticularly relevant insofar as developments in the past few decades have under lined that ' 'the industrialization of the semiperiphery and periphery has ultimate ly been a channel, not of subversion, but of reproduction of the hierarchy of the world-economy" (Arrighi and Drangel 1 986, 56) . Finally , within the dependent-development approach, global processes are nar rowly understood as mechanisms of dependency-the avenues through which ex ternal agencies condition the development of Third World states. Rather than adop ting a narrow focus on the vulnerability of Third World nations to decisions made in the core, the world-systems approach focuses on the dynamic process by which classes and states are engaged in conflict over their relative position. This also raises the issue of comparisons . Within the dependent-development approach, successful models of development are compared to broaden the generalizations that can be made about the dynamics and tensions of the social alliance that have served as the basis for industrialization . From a world-systems approach, what should be explored is the manner in which these developments were interrelated (e. g . , the successful movement of Brazil and South Korea into the semiperiphery , through competition for scarce foreign resources , became a constraint upon the development of Argentina) . CONCLUSION Argentina dramatizes the difficulties involved in breaking out from a semiperi pheral position to a core position. The institutional arrangements that accompanied the emergence of Peronism were designed to mediate and/or defuse potential social conflicts, and it was in these terms that the legitimacy of Peronism and postwar regimes can to be measured. But in the process, postwar regimes were shackled by the same social pressures they sought to defuse. This constraint became all the more evident after the late 1960s, when foreign investments avoided conflict ridden Argentina. Thus the weight that social pressures had exerted upon the The Limits to Development: Argentina 115 political system and the failure to overcome these pressures through political in novation have prevented the type of discontinuities and transformations that would have been required for Argentina to bid for a move into the core. Even the military coup of 1976, attempting to impose social discipline through corruption and repres sion, proved to be totally inept in creating legitimate and lasting changes in the existing institutional arrangements. The institutional responses adopted by labor, capital, and the state are likely to differ among various semiperipheral nations. Some states, although they constitute exceptional cases, may even succeed in generating innovative methods of institutional response that allow for movement into the core of the world economy, thereby becoming a model of development for other nations to follow. 18 Cumings argues that state policies in South Korea after the mid-1960s resemble those of the "bureaucratic-authoritarian" regimes in Argentina and Brazil, but that their " real model is . . . the 1930's Japanese state " (1988, 261). According to Cumings, this model involved a considerable degree of autonomy of the state from society; an active role of state elites as prime organizers of economic growth (planning, investments, and infrastructure) ; and a sustained effort to " suppress . . . all threats to the existing order" (1988, 261). In fact, this model seems to involve what constitutes a common pattern in all successful transitions from the periphery to the semiperiphery of the world-economy: state elites will generally break with dominant economic interests in promoting a new strategy of development designed to increase their legitimacy (internally and externally) and counter centrifugal forces within national boundaries (either across or among social forces). Once nations move into the semiperiphery, however, state elites are likely to encounter new social constraints that make it difficult to follow the path of suc cessful transition into the core without significant institutional innovations.19 To begin with, state elites must contend with either the appearance of new forces or shifts in the political balance among existing forces-the new of the labor movement in Brazil after the mid-1 970s or current de1{e14:)plneI involving students and the labor movement in South Korea are merely amples of this point. At the same time, as suggested by the trajectory of tina, institutional arrangements that prove functional to ensure a selnilpel:ip.llelral position at one point in time (such as protectionism) may also hinder further sit ion into the core. Finally, from this perspective, transition into the core the late nineteenth century has apparently required the adoption of qualitatively new institutional arrangements involving the effective economic and political in corporation of major social forces (as manifested during the postwar period, for example, in policies conducive to mass consumption and full employment) . But these changes are difficult to adopt in the semiperiphery, where the institutional arrangements of previous transitions or permanence in the zone tend to become crystallized in agencies and political channels of mediation that undermine the ability of state elites to generate innovative responses to social constraints and world -economic opportunities. 116 Semiperipheral Success Stories? The consolidation of Australia and Canada in the core, the relative stagnation of Argentina during the postwar period, and the character of successful transi tions from the periphery into the semiperiphery all serve to bring forth three im portant points. First, even when state elites do adopt innovative responses to social constraints , they must face competitive pressures from other peripheral and semiperipheral states within the world-economy . This is why the imitation of suc cessful models of development does not generally yield the expected results for other nations. As indicated in this chapter, generating innovative responses is difficult enough : in semiperipheral nations , as elsewhere in the world-economy, entrenched economic interests will systematically resist institutional changes that may expose them to greater competitive pressures . Furthermore, innovative responses may actually succeed in overcoming these social constraints but still fail to successfully exploit world-economic opportunities . Even states that are successful in each of these areas must still deal with the fact that they do not operate in a vacuum, but in a world-economy in which other states are also engaged in efforts to improve their control over world economic resources. For this reason, in order to understand the relative success or failure in the trajectory of individual nation-states, it is necessary to analyze these trajectories in their relation to each other . 20 Second, the trajectory of Argentina suggests that one of the most important constraints faced in further transitions into the core involves the nature of the labor movement in the semiperiphery. The unruliness of labor in the semiperiphery has a more explosive character than in the core, due to the fewer resources available to minimize conflicts between labor, capital, and the state. 21 Further more, the overall character of the labor movement is likely to undergo signifi cant changes on a periodical basis, generating further pressures that undermine the stability of prevailing institutional arrangements. This is due to the very character of the semiperiphery . Core production processes are characterized by innovations that are clustered in time (related to this, see Schumpeter 1 962 , 68) . These innovations result in cyclical transformations of the labor process and the labor market that alter the forms of action and organization of labor. To the ex tent that nations in the world-economy participate in these innovations, one should expect these changes to alter the nature and orientation of the labor movement on a periodical basis, often undermining the stability of prevailing institutional arrangements. However , in a semiperipheral context, labor movements " tend . . . to be strong enough to disrupt accumulation but not strong enough to resist retaliation in the workplace or in the political order" (Arrighi 1 985, 256). The consequences of these tensions are revealed by the explosive character of social and political conflict in the semiperiphery. For this reason, political strategies toward organized labor in the semiperiphery can be expected to be of central im portance in determining the outcome of democracy and economic growth in the immediate years to come. The third and final issue involves current political changes in the semiperiphery, and this final paragraph is designed to raise questions rather than provide answers. The Limits to Development: Argentina 117 From Moscow to Buenos Aires , and from Seoul to Rio de Janeiro, the 1980s have brought a clear trend toward greater democratization. In order to bring forth the importance of the concept of semiperiphery, the nature of these changes should be actively addressed within the world-systems approach. What will the semiperiphery look like in the 1 990s? Is the trend toward greater democracy in the semiperiphery likely to continue? Are political changes likely to be accom panied by structural economic transformations? From a world-systems ap proach,what are the limits that are likely to be encountered by these economic and political transformations? Does democratization provide an avenue for movement into the core? Alexander, for example, argues that ' ' democracy is not a social lUXury available only after industrialization has advanced a country to core status, it is an integral element in creating the flexibility that constitutes core politicS" ( 1 989, 329). But by its very nature, the concept of semi periphery would seem to preclude the possibility of a massive movement into the core by today' s democratizing nations . Does democracy hence share essential similarities with industrialization, in that both may have facilitated movement into the core prior to the postwar period but now function to reproduce a semiperipheral position? By addressing these problems, world-systems theory will begin to tackle the most relevant question in the contemporary semiperiphery : what will it be?22 NOTES 1 . Agricultural and livestock exports, which were at the core of economic growth in Argentina, grew at an average annual rate of 6 percent between 1 880 and 1 9 1 3, "making Argentina compete with Japan for the title of the fastest growing country in the world" (Lewis 1 978, 1 97) . But Diaz Alejandro points out that even by 1 929, GNP per capita in Argentina ($700) remained considerably lower than in both Australia ($1 ,000) and Canada ($1 ,300) (in 1 964 prices) ( 1 970, 55). 2 . Institutional differences between Argentina and Australia are clear; what be clarified is how these political differences were related to the different structural tions occupied by these nations within the world-economy. 3 . Fogarty ( 1985) has referred to these agricultural commodities as " �111n"T-�t>tnIF'�' and Di Tella ( 1 985) as a type of innovation yielding windfall profits . 4. This is not to say that industrial growth was insignificant in the early interwar The expansion of agricultural and livestock activities resulted in growing domestic de mand, while periodic deficits in the balance of trade slowly redirected the supply of con sumer goods from imports to domestic production. Villanueva ( 1 975, 69) has pointed out that industry grew rapidly in Argentina at the time: within the overa11 1900-1946 period, the 1920s witnessed the highest rates of growth of both industrial investments and imports of capital goods . Also, the deterioration of terms of trade for agricultural exports served as an incentive for import-substitution industrialization already prior to the crisis of 1 929 (O' Connell 1984, 196) . 5. This conclusion is similar to that of Dieguez (1969) , who argues that the industrializa tion policies pursued by the Australian state in the 1 9 1 0s anticipated by two decades the international developments that in the 1 930s forced the Argentine state to begin adopting 120 Semiperipheral Success Stories? the difficulties in generating appropriate responses to the social pressures of the interwar period. However, these constraints should not be seen as exclusively national in character, but as broadly characteristic of the semiperiphery . 20. Wallerstein indicates that "it is not possible theoretically for all states to ' develop' simultaneously . The so-called 'widening gap' is not an anomaly but a continuing basic mechanism of the world-economy. Of course, some countries can 'develop. ' But the some that rise are at the expense of others that decline" ( 1 979, 73) . 2 1 . Here I draw on the collective work of the World Labor Research Working Group at the Fernand Braudel Center at the State University of New York at Binghamton. 22. The methodological implications of this question are raised by Mukherjee (1979) . REFERENCES Alexander, Malcolm. 1989. "Conservatism, Counterrevolution, and Semiperipheral Politics: Argentina and Australia in the Interwar Period. " Review 12, 2 (Spring) : 299-333. Arrighi, Giovanni. 1980. "The Labor Movement in Twentieth Century Europe. " Paper presented at the Colloquium on World Labor and Social Change. Binghamton : State University of New York at Binghamton, August 21-23 . . 1 985. " Fascism to Democratic Socialism: Logic and Limits of a Transition . " In Semiperipheral Development: The Politics of Southern Europe in the Twentieth Century, edited by Giovanni Arrighi, 243-79. Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. � Arrighi, Giovanni , and Jessica DrangeL 1986. "The Stratification of the World Economy: :9-74. (Summer) 1 , An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone. " Review 1 0 Crises, "Three . 1985 Marlin. G. William and Arrighi, Giovanni, Roberto P. Korzeniewicz, Cahier " . Century Twentieth Long the in Relations y Core-Peripher Zones: Three du GIS Economie Mondiale, Tiers Monde, Developpement 6 (March) : 97-120. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Beverly Silver. 1984. "Labor Movements and Capital Migration: The United States and Western Europe in World Historical Perspective. " In Labor in ti.e Capitalist World-Economy, edited by C. Bergquist, 1 83-2 1 6 . Beverly Hills, ___ Calif. : Sage. Boehm, Ernest A. 1979. Twentieth Century Economic Development in Australia. Melbourne: Longman-Cheshire. Braun, Oscar. 1973. " Desarrollo del capital monopolista en la Argentina. " In El capitalismo argentino en crisis, edited by Oscar Braun, 1 1-44. Buenos Aires : Siglo XXI. Canitrot, Adolfo. 198 1 . " Teoria y pnlctica del liberalismo: Politica antiinflacionaria y apertura economica en la Argentina, 1 976- 1 98 1 . " Desarrollo Economico 1 5 , 59 (October-December) : 3 3 1 -52. Cardoso, Fernando H. 1 976, Ideologias de la burguesia industrial en sociedades depen dientes (Argentina y Brasil) . Mexico: Siglo XXI. Cardoso, Fernando. H . , and Enzo Faletto. 1979. Dependency and Development in Latin America. Berkeley : University of California Press. Cumings, Bruce. 1988. "World-System and Authoritarian Regimes in Korea, 1948-1984." In Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, edited by Edwin Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh, 249-69. Armonk, N. Y . : M. E. Sharpe. Del Barco, Ricardo. 1983. El regimenperonista, 1946-1955. Buenos Aires: Editorial de Belgrano. The Limits to Development: Argentina 121 D i Tella, Guido. 1985. "Rents, Quasi-Rents, Normal Profits, and Growth: Argentina and the Areas of Recent Settlement. " In Argentina, Australia, and Canada: Studies in Comparative Development 1876-1965, edited by D. C. M. Platt and Guido Di Tella, 37-52. New York: St. Martin's Press. Di Tella, Guido, and D . C . M . Platt. 1986. Ihe Political Economy ofArgentina, 1880-1914. London: Macmillan. Diaz Alejandro, Carlos. 1970. Essays on the Economic History ofthe Argentine Republic. New Haven: Yale University Press . . 1984. " Latin America in the 1 930's. " In Latin America in the 1930's: The Role of the Periphery in World Crisis, edited by Rosemary Thorp, 17-49. Oxford: St. Antony ' s/Macmillan Series. . 1985. "Argentina, Australia, and Brazil before 1 929 . " In Argentina, Australia, and Canada: Studies in Comparative Development, 1876-1965, edited by D . C . __ M . Platt and Guido D i Tella, 95-109. New York: St. Martin's Press. Dieguez, Hector. 1969 . "Argentina y Australia: Algunos aspectos de su desarrollo com parado . " Desarrollo Economico 8, 32 (January-March) :543-63 . Dyster, Barrie. 1979. " Argentine and Australian Development Compared. " Past and Pres ent 84: 9 1 - 1 10. Economic Commission for Latin America. 1980. Economic Survey ofLatin America . San tiago de Chile: U.N. Publications. Evans , Peter. 1979 . Dependent Development: The Alliance of Multinationals, State, and Local Capital in Brazil. Princeton, N.J . : Princeton University Press. Evans, Peter, and John D. Stephens. 1988. "Development and the World-Economy. " In Handbook of Sociology, edited by Neil Smelser, 739-73. Beverly HiJls, Calif. : Sage. Fishlow, Albert. 1977. "Origens e consequencias da substitui<;ao da importacoes no Brasil. " I n FOr7nafao economica do Brasil, a experiencia da industrialiZGI;ao, edited by Flavio R. Versiani and 1. R. Mendonca de Barros, 7-40. Sao Paulo: Sara iva. Fogarty, John. 1985. " Staples , Super-Staples, and the Limits of Staple Theory: The Ex periences of Argentina, Australia, and Canada Compared . " In Argentina, Australia, and Canada: Studies in Comparative Development, 1876-1965 , edited by D. M . Platt and Guido Di Tella, 19-36. New York: St. Martin's Press. Forster, Colin. 1964. Industrial Development in Australia, 1920-1 930. Canberra: National University. Furtado, Celso. 1 970. Economic Development ofLatin America. Cambridge: �a.1HU'U,! University Press. Glenday, DanieL 1989. "Rich But Semiperipheral : Canada's Ambiguous Position in World Economy . " Review 1 2 , 2 (Spring) :263-97. Korzeniewicz, Roberto P. 1989a. "Labor Unrest in Argentina, 1 887- 1907 . " American Research Review 24, 3 : 7 1-98 . . 1989b. "The Labour Movement and the State in Argentina, 1 887-1907 . " Bulletin of Latin American Research 8 , 1 : 25-45. Lewis, Arthur. 1 978 . Growth and Fluctuations, 1870-1913. London: George Allen and Unwin. __ Llorens de Azar, Carmen. 1 976. Argentina, evolucion economica, 1915-1976. Buenos Aires : Fundacion Banco de Boston. Macintyre, S. F. 1 9 8 3 . "Labour, Capital and Arbitration, 1 890-1920 . " In State and Economy in Australia, edited by Brian W. Head, 98-1 14. Melbourne: Oxford University Press. 1 22 Semiperipheral Success Stories? Mukherjee, Ramkrishna. 1979. What Will it Be? Explorations in Inductive Sociology. New Delhi: Allied Publishers . o 'Connell, Arturo. 1 984. "Argentina into the Depression: Problems of an Open Economy. " In Latin America in the 1930's: The Role of the Periphery in World Crisis, edited by Rosemary Thorp, 1 88-22 1 . Oxford: Macmillan Press. O'Donnell, Guillermo. 1973 . Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism. Berkeley, Calif. : , Institute of International Studies . . 1 976. " Reflections on the Patterns of Changes in the Bureaucratic-Authoritarian State . " Latin American Research Review 1 3 , 1 : 3-3 8 . . 1 977. "Estado y Alianzas e n la Argentina, 1956- 1976 . " Desarrollo Economico 64, 1 6 (January-March) : 523-54. Portantiero, Juan Carlos. 1963 . "Polltica y cIases sociales en la Argentina actual . " Pasado y Presente 1 (April-June): 1 8-23 . Resnick, Philip . 1989. "From Semiperiphery to Perimeter o f the Core: Canada' s Place in the Capitalist World-Economy . " Review 12, 2 (Spring) :263-97. Schum peter, Joseph A. 1 962. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper Torchbooks. Schurmann, Franz . 1 974 . the Logic of World Power. New York: Pantheon Books. Serra, Jose. 198 3 . "CicIos e mudancas estruturais na economia brasileira do pos-guerra. " In Carlos Lessa et al . , Desenvolvimento capitalista no Brasil: Ensaios sobre a crisis, 1 : 56- 1 2 1 . Sao Paulo: Editora Brasiliense . Skidmore, Thomas E. 1977. "The Politics of Economic Stabilization in Postwar Latin America. " In Authoritarianism and Corporatism in Latin America, edited by James Malloy, 149-90 . Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Solberg, Carl. 1985. " Land Tenure and Land Settlement: Policy and Patterns in the Cana dian Prairies and the Argentine Pampas , 1 880-1 930 . " In Argentina, Australia, and Canada: Studies in Comparative Development, 1876-1965, edited by D . C . M . Platt and Guido Di Tella, 53-75 . New York: .St. Martin' s Press. . 1987. the Prairies and the Pampas. Stanford, Calif. : Stanford University Press. Trebat, Thomas J. 1981 . " Public Enterprises in Brazil and Mexico . " In Authoritarian Capitalism: Brazil's Contemporary Economic and Political Development, edited by Thomas Bruneau and Phillipe Faucher, 41-58. Boulder, Colo . : Westview Press. Turner, Ian. 1965. Industrial Labour and Politics: the Dynamics of the Labour Move ment in Eastern Australia, 1900-1921 . Canberra: Australian National University . Villanueva, Javier. 1 975 . " Economic Development. " In Prologue to Peron: Argentina in Depression and War, 1930-1943, edited by Mark Falcoff and Ronald H. Dolkart, 57-82 . Berkeley : University of California Press. Villela, Annibal Villanova, and Wilson Suzigan. 1973. Polltica do governo e crescimento da economia brasileira, 1889-1945. Rio de Janeiro : IPEA/INPES . Waisman, Carlos H. 1 987. Reversal of Developl1Jent in Argentina. Princeton, N . J . : Princeton University Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel . 1 979. the Capitalist World-Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Wynia, Gary W. 1978. Argentina in the Postwar Era: Politics and Economic Policy-Making in a Divided Society. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press. ___ ___ ___ SEMIPERIPHERY OR CORE? 7 THE REPUBLIC OF IRELAND IN THE WORLD,ECONOMY : AN EXPLORATION OF DYNAMICS IN THE SEMIPERIPHERY Richard Grant and Donald Lyons World-system theorists argue that semiperipheral states occupy a critical struc tural position in the functioning of the world-economy. Semi peripheral states ex hibit a set of characteristics that combine core processes and peripheral processes . No semiperipheral processes have been identified. The semi periphery is a crucial middle zone in the three-tier hierarchy of states, providing stability to the world system by preventing a bipolar division of the world-economy into core and peripheral areas. This middle zone is one to which peripheral states can aspire, and it can insulate former core states from descending into periphery status. Classifications of the semi periphery include a diverse range of countries in terms of geographic locations, economic strength, political background, size of and levels of democracy. Despite recent attempts by Arrighi and Drangel (1986) to classify the imately 170 states of the world-economy into a trimodal structure semiperiphery, or periphery) , the concept of the semiperiphery has remained of the weakest and most ambiguous components of the Wallersteinian f'r,,","'Uli'lrl (Milkman 1979, 264) . Surprisingly, there have been few attempts i n the systems literature to trace in detail the development of semi peripheral states time, with the exceptions of Mingst's (1988) study of the Ivory Coast, Millcnan's (1979) work on South Africa, Martin's (1986) work on South Africa, and Ligthart and Reitsma' s (1988) historical analysis of Portugal in the seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries . The first aim of this chapter is to assess the Republic of Ireland' s position in the world-economy. We selected Ireland because it is an interesting case study of a recently independent country (1922) with a long history of colonialization. We decided to begin at 1959 since this was a key year in the development of Irish foreign and domestic economic policy. Prior to 1959 successive Irish govern ments pursued an exclusionary policy of economic autarky severely restricting 126 Semiperiphery or Core? foreign capital inputs and providing high tariff barriers for the protection of in digenous industry . This policy was deemed a failure in 1959 and was replaced with a " developmental " or " modernization " -style policy that actively encouraged foreign multinational investment. The second aim is to contribute further to a clarification of the concept of the semiperiphery, which is one of Wallerstein's most important and, at the same time, controversial concepts . In order to investigate Ireland' s position in the world-system, we selected two approaches from world-systems literature (Arrighi and Drangel 1 986; Mingst 1 988) and a method based on unequal exchange that we borrowed from international-relations research (Firebaugh and Bullock 1986) . The Arrighi and Drangel approach is based on the argument that the balance of core and peripheral activities in a particular country determines its share of the world' s resources or wealth and hence its structural position in the world-economy . They argue that this balance is reflected in differences in GNP per capita between countries, and this provides the basis for their classification. Mingst, drawing directly on Wallerstein ' s arguments about the semiperiphery , identifies three important at tributes of semiperipheral countries: economic complexity, strong state machinery, and a significant degree of cultural integrity. Firebaugh and Bullock attempt to operationalize the notion of unequal exchange by assigning a numeric value be tween 1 and 6 to exports on the basis of the degree of processing prior to export ing. Level 1 exports contain the least processing, while level 6 exports contain the highest degree of processing. This can then be used as an indicator to measure a state' s structural position in the world-economy. THE ARRIGHI AND D RANGEL METHOD Using the same procedure as Arrighi and Drangel, we have superimposed Ireland' s log of GNP per capita on the graph of core, semiperiphery, and periphery modes (figure 7 . 1) . The result is consistent with the hypothesis that Ireland is located in the semiperiphery. Unlike the semiperiphery as a whole, Ireland suc cessfully resisted peripheralization throughout the 1 960s and 1 970s . This was achieved in a number of ways. First, in an effort to gain access to the core, the previously unsuccessful economic autarkic policy was replaced by one that ac tively sought to attract foreign industry into the country to establish a viable in dustrial base. An aggressive industrial development policy was established that offered generous capital grants and tax incentives for export-based industry. Ireland ' s location on the rim of Western Europe, its inexpensive but relatively well educated work force, and the government' s favorable attitude to business made it an attractive location for branch-plant industry. Second, entry to the European Economic Community (EEC) enhanced its locational advantage enor mously. Final-stage or assembly branch-plant industry could now gain tariff-free access to the huge markets of Western Europe. Thus Ireland became an ideal internal periphery to the EEC (Perrons 1 986). Third, entry to the EEC brought about a large transfer of monies from core states through the Common Agricultural t -+------+--�-+1 950 1 965 Per i phera l Mode Se m i pe r i phe r a l M o d e Core Mode Source: G. Arrighi and J . 1.5 G 2.5 N P P C 2 L 0 G 3 3.5 '[ 1 970 I r e l and E175 -- -+-----1 980 1903 -- - - -- --- - - - - -- - - --- - - -- -� Figure 7.1 Trends in Modal GNP Per Capita of the Three Zones and Irish GNP Per Capita \ 1 28 Semiperiphery or Core? Policy (CAP) and to a lesser extent from the Regional Development Fund (Beck and Nierop 1986) . The boom experienced during the 1970s was short-lived, however, as rising inflation and indebtedness and increasing unemployment and labor turmoil caused a rapid downturn in the early 1 980s as the fragility of an industrial economy based on foreign multinational industry became evident. Real GNP per capital declined in the first half of the 1980s, unemployment rose to approximately 19 percent, and emigration reached 30,000 a year. Growth resumed during 1 987, and the trade balance reached a surplus, reflecting a fundamental improvement in Irish cost structures and the unexpected temporary strength of the international economy . While domestic demand remains weak, emigration continues , and unemployment remains high, GNP has begun to rise. The Arrighi and Drangel model is of limited use in locating any given country in the trimodal structure . Most importantly , Arrighi and Drangel do not present GNP per capita as a surrogate measure for classifying individual countries . Rather, it is used to identify the operation of broad structural processes within the world economy. As such, limited significance is attached to the exact GNP per capita values of any given country . Furthermore, while the Arrighi and Drangel model locates Ireland in the semiperiphery and suggests slow but steady growth throughout the 1 970s and early 1 980s, it hides the considerable variation within the Irish economy. While log of GNP per capita identifies the declining economic situation of the early 1 980s , it fails to capture the complexity of the economic situation in Ireland during the time period under study . Thus, while GNP per capita as a measure of command over a proportion of the world' s resources iden tifies important aspects (necessary features) of the underlying structure of the world-system, it does not isolate or identify how these patterns are worked out in specific locations (contingent features) . THE MINGST METHOD Wallerstein argues that specific characteristics of semiperipheral states involve their location between periphery and core on several dimensions: " the complex ity of economic activities, strength of state machinery, and cultural integrity " (Wallerstein 1974 , 349, quoted in Mingst 1988, 260) . Mingst uses this argument as the basis for her model . The complexity of economic activity may include a diversification of agricultural activity and movement from reliance on agriculture to growth in manufacturing and service sectors. Mingst begins her analysis by examining the sectoral com position of GDP. Even in 1960 the composition of Irish GDP was relatively diver sified, but a clear trend toward increasing complexity was evident (table 7 . 1 ) . Between 1 960 and 1 987 agriculture's share o f GDP declined from 22 . 2 percent to 8 percent, while manufacturing increased from 26.2 percent to 35 percent in the same period. This suggests considerable movement but again hides considerable variation in the internal structure of the economy. Furthermore, if we compare Irish GDP with that of the Ivory Coast (which Mingst has identified as a The Republic of Ireland 129 Table 7 . 1 Sectoral Origin o f Irish GDP Year Agriculture 1 960 22.2 26.2 51.6 1 965 1 8 .4 28.4 53. 1 1970 1 4. 4 30.5 55. 1 1 975 15.0 31 0 5 4. 0 1982 1 0. 0 33.0 57.0 1 9 87 8.0 35.0 57.0 Netherlands 4 .0 26.0 70. 0 Ivory Coast 2 7.4 1 8 .5 54. 1 (1 985) (1985) Manufacturing . Services Sources: World Bank, 1 976 ; Th e Economist, 1 982, 1 987. semiperipheral country) and the Netherlands (which is a classic core country), the composition of Irish GDP is closer to that of the Netherlands, suggesting that Ireland resembles a core country rather than a semiperipheral country. Aggregate output performance of Irish manufacturing industry between 1 973 and 1 983 outstripped that of all other OECD countries except Portugal (OECq 1985, 44). Total manufacturing output increased by 44. 9 percent, placing in a similar position to the NICs (table 7.2) . This growth was COilcentrate�l the capital-intensive, high-tech, and foreign-owned sectors such as (160.6 percent) and metals and engineering (88 .4 percent). Output in the tional Irish sectors fared badly in comparison. The largest indigenous food/drink and tobacco, experienced lower rates of increase, while output in other sectors declined. Sectoral change in employment during 1973- 1983 also reflects these changes (table 7.2). While total manufacturing employment decreased by 0.4 percent, this hides considerable variation. The labor-intensive manufacturing industry, with relatively low increases in labor productivity and a relatively high reliance on the slow-growing domestic market, has suffered large employment losses (e. g . , textiles, 48 .6 percent). These losses have been concentrated in the domestic-owned sectors. Employment in domestic textiles production, for example, decreased by 60. 8 percent, while employment in foreign-owned textile production decreased by 8.5 percent. Foreign-owned capital-intensive industry with lower overall labor 130 Table Semiperiphery or Core? 7.2 Structural Change in Irish Manufacturing Industry Ind. prod. % change % Total change Employment foreign-owned domestic-owne d % change % change 1973/83 1973/83 1 973/83 1 973/83 Total Manufacturing 44.9 -0.4 36.6 - 1 0.8 Chemicals, Metals, Engineering 1 60.6 88.4 20.9 52.8 50.2 90.4 - 1 1 .3 20.2 38.4 2 0.4 -2. 8 -5.2 9.8 ·9.5 -4.6 -2.5 - 1 5. 6 -48 . 6 -8.5 - 60. 8 -28.4 -23.9 '24.0 -36.8 Timber furniture - 1 4. 2 9. 1 -7.5 10.3 Paper and printing -7. 6 -2.8 ·7.7 -2. 1 Non-metallic production 1 1. 8 Miscellaneous 53. 1 Food Drink, Tobacco Textile Clothing footwear Source: OEDC, 47.7 1 .4 93.0 1 985. costs and high productivity growth has been less affected and recorded modest to large labor-force increases (chemicals, 20.9 percent; metals and engineering, 52. 8 percent) . The structure of the Irish economy is difficult to interpret within Mingst's semi periphery framework. On the one hand, sectoral diversity of GDP suggests, at a minimum, location in the semiperiphery and possibly the perimeter of the core. Ireland, like the core countries, has experienced changes from labor-intensive manufacturing to high-tech industry. On the other hand, the growth sectors of the Irish economy are almost exclusively foreign owned and controlled. These sectors have had little linkage into the domestic economy, and their significance to value added has been limited to wages and salaries and some services (Telesis 1982; OEeD 1985; Delaney 1987). What seems clear is that Ireland experienced rapid industrial development during the last twenty-five years, but this cannot be readily translated into real development. Rather, as Arrighi and Drangel argue, like other semiperipheral states, Ireland ran very fast in order to remain in the same place ( 1986, 60). The Republic of Ireland 131 One explanation of this outcome is offered b y Rothgeb (1986). As he has argued, multinational corporations (MNCs) during Kondratieff B phases may increase their flow of investments to the semiperiphery to gain further control of the semi periphery or reduce investment and thereby transfer the pain of recession to the semiperiphery. Both these processes are evident during the time period of the study. During the 1970s MNCs increased their investments, but the continued global recession and increased competitiveness of the 1980s warranted a different strategy, occasioning massive " shakeouts " and an overall reduction of invest ment. Together these two strategies had enormous impacts on Ireland's economy and thus suggest semiperipheral status. The second of Mingst's categories is state strength. Analyzing state strength is difficult since there is no consensus among researchers on how to measure it (Mingst 1988, 264). Mingst employs degree of political stability and state-nurtured capitalism, and we follow her definition. However, Mingst's analysis of state strength implies notions of a strong, corporatist, military-type government, which is probably more suitable for analyzing state strength in Third World countries. Except for a two-year civil war after the independence struggle, there have been no major political or economic cleavages within Irish politics. Irish politics operates under a system of representative democracy, a characteristic more evident in core states than in semiperipheral or peripheral states. Indeed, Gonick and Rosh (1988, 187) argue that Ireland has a high level of democracy and is more accurately classified as a core state. Evidence of state-nurtured capitalism provides another tool for analyzing state strength. Since the foundation of the state, Irish governments have been deeply involved with the development of industry. First, the development of an autarkic policy, embracing tariff protection to facilitate import substitution and restric tion of direct foreign investment, ensured state involvement in economic activi ty. Perhaps the strongest evidence of state support for capitalism comes from two referenda and the development of industrial policy after 1960. The two TPt".TP.11C da important in the development of state support for capitalism were on into the EEC in 1 9 73 and its further consolidation through the Single LJUJl VP"'.f Act in 1987. These two acts, which further strengthened Ireland's ties to pean core, were supported by both major parties (Fianna Fail and Fine and were passed by large majorities. The only opposition came from the Party and the small farmers' interest groups. Mingst's third criterion relates to cultural integrity. She argues that semiperi pheral states enjoy a semblance of cultural integrity more often found in the core and generally absent in the periphery. Since independence successive Irish govern ments have actively sought to maintain a distinctive Irish culture. Through the national education system and especially the national primary-school system, the state has attempted to keep alive the Irish language, history, heritage, and na tionalism. Until very recently, for example, five years of Irish-language instruc tion was mandatory for graduation from high school. Religion is usually regarded as a key cultural characteristic. Ninety-five per cent of those who live in the South are Roman Catholic, and while the influence 132 Semiperiphery or Core? of the Catholic hierarchy is declining, it is still very significant. On two major recent (1 983 and 1986) "religious/moral" referenda, concerning abortion and divorce, the official Catholic position was supported by the majority of the popula tion (O 'Loughlin and Parker, forthcoming) . There is little debate regarding the level of cultural integrity in Ireland. Ireland enjoys considerably more than a " semblance" of cultural integrity and is more closely associated with core coun tries in this respect. In summary, using the Mingst method for locating Ireland does not lead to any conclusive answer. In terms of economic complexity, Ireland has experienced rapid change since 1 960. Sectoral changes in GDP, output, and structure of manufacturing suggest a position somewhere between the semiperiphery and the rim of the core . On the other hand, the large foreign component in Irish economic diversity suggests that Ireland belongs in the semiperiphery . In relation to state strength and cultural integrity , Ireland appears more like a core country. These characteristics, however, may be more suitable for analysis of African countries than for semiperipheral countries in general. With the possible exception of the state-nurtured capitalism category, Ireland approximates the core more closely than the semiperiphery . THE FIREBAUGH AND BULLOCK METHOD The Firebaugh and Bullock method is based on an analysis of levels of pro cessing of exports (LPE) . The composition of semiperipheral countries would be reflected by a mix in the levels of processing of exports, with a smaller pro portion of exports in level l and level 2 (mainly agricultural exports) than in peripheral countries and less exports in levels 5 and 6 than in core countries. Wallerstein (1979) has argued that semiperipheral countries trade in both direc tions, in one mode with the periphery and in the opposite with the core. For ex ample, semiperipheral states have been viewed as exporting peripheral products to core states and core products to peripheral areas of the world-system (Waller stein 1 982 , 93) . Thus the semiperiphery exploits the periphery , while at the same time the semiperiphery itself suffers exploitation from the core. An examination of the direction of trade statistics indicates some diversifica tion of trade partners for Ireland over time, with less dependence on the United Kingdom, although the United Kingdom still represents Ireland 's largest trading partner (see tables 7 . 3 and 7 .4) . No dramatic changes have taken place in accor dance with changes in the world-economy. Ireland trades predominantly with the industrial countries, suggesting that the European Community (EC) has substituted for the United Kingdom and that the trading relation remains the same. Approx imately 93 percent of Ireland 's trade was with core countries for 1987. In the same year Ireland had a balance-of-trade surplus with the core for the first time in its history, but Ireland still has a trade deficit with the periphery. Ireland' s trade with the Third World i s less than 5 percent o f total trade for any year. As a result, we cannot describe Ireland as an exploiter of the periphery. There has Table 7.3 Ireland's Direction of Trade Exports (Values as a Percentage of Total) Area 1 960 1 965 1 970 1975 1 9 80 1987 Industrial 89.7 9 1 .0 84.5 9 1 .0 87.0 93.0 Britain 74.0 72.0 60. 8 54.1 42. 6 34.2 Africa 0.003 0.003 0.008 0.02 0.0 1 0.0 1 Asia 0.008 0. 009 0.006 0.005 0.01 om Latin America 0.001 0. 008 0.007 0. 0 1 2 0. 0 1 2 0.003 USSR 0.00 1 0.008 0.007 0.0 1 2 0.0 1 2 0.003 Total a $425.8 $615 $ 1 ,1 20 $3, 1 9 3 $8,499 $15,999 Source: IMF. Various years. aMillions of US dollars. Table 7 . 4 Ireland's Direction of Trade Imports (Values as a Percentage of Total) Area 1 960 1 965 1 970 1 975 1 980 1 987 Industrial 77.0 8 1 .0 8 1 .2 84.4 88.5 91.6 Britain 49.7 5 1 .0 5 1 .7 48.6 50.8 42.0 Africa 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.0 1 Asia 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.02 0. 02 Latin America 0.02 0.02 0.009 0.0 1 om 0.0 1 USSR 0.0 1 0.0 1 0.02 0.0 1 0.01 0.003 -$ 1,041 -$ 1 ,622 Totala -$633.4 Source: IMF. Various years. <lMillions of US dollars. -$3,779 -$1 1 , 1 5 1 $ 1 3,628 134 Semiperiphery or Core? been an increase in the dependence on the core industrial countries in terms of imported goods, which lends some support to Wallerstein's assertion that semiperipheral countries are outlets for core products . Our estimates of LPE for Ireland are reported in table 7. 5 for the time period 1 960 to 1987. In 1 960 Ireland represented the classic peripheral distribution of LPE, with 43 percent of exports in level l , which is relatively close to the Third World average for 1 980. By 1975 the first signs of change are evident, with a decrease in the proportion of exports in level 1 by 26 percent and an increase of 1 3 percent for level 4. This coincided with a downturn of the global economy in the early 1 970s with Kondratieff 4 B (the decline phase of the fourth Kon dratieff cycle), Ireland' s membership in the EEC, and rapid increases in foreign investment. The pattern for 1980 represents a further decrease in the proportion of exports in levels 1 , 2 and 3 and an increase in levels 5 and 6, which is in dicative of a core economy. This trend continued through 1 986, and there was a dramatic increase of 23 percent in level 6. By 1 986 Ireland' s LPE resembled that of a core country , which is suggestive of a movement from the semiperiphery to the core. It is important to keep in mind, however, that most of this increase was due to foreign-owned rather than domestic industry . Ireland became integrated into the New International Division o f Labor (NIDL) in the 1 970s (Perrons 1 986). Firebaugh and Bullock ( 1 986) argue that a com parison of the mean LPE for a country over time can be employed as an indicator to assess the degree to which a NIDL is emerging. They demonstrate that LPE for the Third World as a whole increased from 1 . 58 in 1 970 to 1 . 69 in 1980, Table 7.5 Ireland: Levels of Processing o f Exports (LPE) Lev 3 Lev 4 Lev 5 Lev 6 Mean LPE Year Lev 1 Lev 2 1 960 43 24 4 15 11 1 965 43 24 8 14 8 1970 40 31 4 10 7 6 2.0 1 975 17 30 6 28 10 7 3.0 1 980 14 20 3 26 26 10 3.0 1986 10 17 3 16 19 33 3.0 Pr/AWl 64 16 10 6 2 Various years. aperipheral average for 1980 after Firebaugh and B ullock, 1986. Source: U.N. 2 2.0 1.9 1 . 69 The Republic of Ireland 135 suggesting the emergence of a NIDL, which was particularly evident for the NICs that moved from the periphery to the semiperiphery at this time . We should ex pect to find a similar pattern for Ireland (see table 7. 5). Ireland' s mean LPE in creased from 2 . 0 in 1 970 to 3 . 0 in 1 98 0, suggesting deeper incorporation into the Fordist world-economy (Perrons 1 986) . Ireland's mean LPE, also in com mon with the semiperipheral countries of the Third World, is situated midway on the continuum between level 1 and level 6 of the sophistication of exports. In comparison, Brazil, a semiperipheral country, scored 2. 7 for 1 980. By focusing on LPE for Ireland more closely and by examining where Ireland exports core products (level 6) and peripheral products (level 1), we are able to discern if this pattern correlates with the classic semiperipheral model where a semiperipheral country exports peripheral products to core states and core pro ducts to peripheral states (Wallerstein 1982). For the year 1 987 we have calculated that 80 percent of Ireland' s exports of peripheral products were exported to core states and 30 percent of core products were exported to peripheral states. The percentage of Ireland' s exports to core states declined with LPE, while exports to peripheral states increased with LPE. It can be argued, in relative terms, that Ireland exports peripheral products to core states and core products to peripheral states. Yet in absolute terms the evidence does not seem strong enough to locate Ireland as a semiperipheral state. When we inspect Ireland' s LPE with specific trade partners, the pattern is not any clearer (see table 7. 6). We selected the Netherlands as representative of a classic core EC state, Sweden as representing a classic core state outside the EC, and Mexico and Saudia Arabia as peripheral states. The configuration of Irish LPE to countries such as the Netherlands and Sweden does not correlate well with the semiperipheral model, as the largest concentration of exports is in the upper levels. (The 79 percent value for level S exports with Sweden appears ex aggerated for Sweden due to the low level of agricultural exports [levels one three] that Ireland trades with non-EC member states.) Ireland' s LPE to does not correspond to the peripheral mode either. We can conclude that Ireland's LPE does not resemble the semiperipheral norm. dominance of foreign-owned industry is crucial. CONCLUSIONS Three measures are potentially available for use in measuring the concept of the semiperiphery. The first focuses on attributes of states such as log of GNP per capita or economic, political, and cultural attributes (Arrighi and Drangel 1986; Mingst 1 988). The second category examines the interactive mode of states in the world-economy and the levels to which states are exploiters and exploited through such processes as unequal exchange (Firebaugh and Bullock 1 986). The third type focuses on the extent to which semiperipheral states function as stabilizers or as legitimators within the world-system and to our knowledge can not be empirically measured. 136 Table Semiperiphery o r Core? 7.6 Ireland's Trading Partners: A Breakdown of LPE for 1987 Lev 1 Lev 2 Lev 3 Lev 4 Lev 5 Lev 6 14 30 2 11 33 10 S weden 2 4 2 12 79 Mexico 4 43 14 23 16 15 7 32 14 33 Country Netherlands Saudi Arabia Source: Eurostat. 1 987. The use oflog of GNP per capita highlights a crucial necessary factor for iden tifying semiperipheral processes and individual countries. The position of states within the world-economy is generally determined by their position within the hierarchy of wealth. The more wealthy a country is, the better its chances of reap ing greater benefits from the world-economy. To stop here, however, ignores how the processes generating wealth are worked out)n specific places. GNP per capita locates Ireland within the semiperiphery but is unable to incorporate the complexity of the Irish economy. The Mingst method produces mixed results . On the one hand, it suggests that Ireland, in terms of its economic structure and diversity , is a strong member of the semiperiphery, but on the other two dimen sions, cultural integrity and state strength, Ireland resembles core states . The impact of MNCs and the degree of control over MNC activities are crucial here in understanding Ireland's role in the world-economy. What is clear here is that we can no longer identify development within countries on the simple basis of the degree of industrialization. More importantly, these results suggest that it may not be possible to identifY specific characteristics within the semiperiphery that operate similarly within all semiperipheral states . Taylor reaches a similar conclusion, arguing that causality is not a matter of simply observing ' 'cause and effect" but consists of identifying how key mechanisms inherent in the world economy are worked out in particular contexts ( 198 8 , 1 6) : The results from the Firebaugh and Bullock technique imply that Ireland' s LPE in recent years resembles a distribution generally found in core states. At the same time, we need to be aware that the contribution of a positive trade balance for 1988 does not seem to have led to real gains for its citizens . Again, what is important here is how these benefits from trade are played out within the country . These three measures can also be used to identify the timing of movement within the semi periphery , in the direction of the core or the periphery. Each measure may or may not produce different results on the nature of this timing, depending on the mix of processes that are reflected in each measure. However, this finding The Republic of Ireland 137 i s important as i t can highlight how processes are worked out i n different loca tions within the world-economy. These different results using three measures suggest that Ireland can not be termed simply a semiperipheral state; Ireland is superficially core-like in many resp ects, but it is not a core state. If we have to categorize Ireland on the dimen sion of core/semiperiphery, we clearly have problems. Ireland appears to resem ble core states in many of the attributes used in this study, but the small size of the Irish economy and its dependence on foreign MNCs suggest that it is dif ferent from the other core states. It also suggests that the characteristics of serniperipheral states cannot simply be read off a score chart. We should expect this result, however, since semiperipheral countries possess both core and peripheral processes, and there is no reason to suggest that such a mix would be easily identified by a simple set of characteristics evident in all or most semiperipheral countries. Semiperipheral states as constituent parts of the world system directly reflect the overall balance between the processes that produce them (Taylor 1 988, 3 6) . Rather, there is a need for further case studies to iden tify the complexity of the semi periphery and how the broader structural forces of the world-economy interact with the realities of concrete places to produce the complex mosiac that is the semiperiphery. In conclusion, Ireland is core-like but not core. It cannot be defined as a " classic" member of the semiperiphery because such classifications may not ex ist. Yet it is obvious that both core and peripheral processes operate within Ireland. Ireland perceives itself as a core state by being a member of the EC, and it is classified by the OECD as a core state. Ireland, " the poorest of the rich" (Economist 1 987) must be viewed as in the perimeter of the core, knocking on the door but not yet admitted. NOTE This paper was first presented to the Thirteenth Annual Conference on the Economy of the World-System, April 28-30, 1 989, at the University of lllinois at Champaign. Thanks are due to John Q'Loughlin (University of Colorado at Boulder), Taylor (University of Newcastle upon Tyne) , Herman Van der Wusten (University ' Amsterdam) , Neil Smith (Rutgers University), Jan Nijman (University of Miami), Denise Blanchard (University of Colorado at Boulder), who provided detailed COInrrlents on our work. Thanks are also due to Senator Michael Lanigan (Fianna Fail), who us in obtaining information on the Irish economy. Any remaining errors are our own. REFERENCES Arrighi, G . , and J. Drangel. 1986. "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Ex ploration of the Semiperipheral Zone . " Review 10: 9-74. Aymard, M. 1 985. "Nation-States and Interregional Disparities of Development. " In Semiperipheral Development: The Politics of Southem Europe in the Twentieth Cen tury, edited by G. Arrighi, 40-54. Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. 138 Semiperiphery or Core? Beck, J. , and T. Nierop. 1 9 8 6 . De EEG en de Mediterrane Landboun in het licht van de lberische toetreding. Instituut vour sociale geograafie, Universiteit van Amsterdam. Delaney , G. 1 9 8 7 . "Electronics Multinational Enterprises in the Cork Region and Limerick/Shannon. " Master 's thesis, University College, Cork, Ireland . Ihe Economist. 1982 and 1 9 87 . "A Survey of the Republic of Ireland . " January 1 6 . Eurostat. 1 9 87 . External Trade: Monthly Statistics. Luxembourg: Statistical Office of the European Community . Firebaugh, G. , and B. Bullock. 1 9 8 6 . " Levels of Processing of Exports: New Estimates for 73 Less-Developed Countries in 1970 and 1980. " International Studies Quarterly 3 0 : 3 33-50. Gonick, L . , and R. Rosh. 1 9 8 8 . "The Structural Constraints of the World-Economy on National Political Development . " Comparative Political Studies 2 1 : 1 7 1-99. International Monetary Fund. Various Years . Direction of Trade Statistics. Washington, D .C . : International Monetary Fund. Ligthart, H . , and H. Reitsma. 1 9 8 8 . "Portugal' s Semi-peripheral Middleman Role in Its Relations with England, 1640- 1 760 . " Political Geography Quarterly. 7 : 353-62. McAlleese, D. 1 9 8 9 . "Ireland . " Europe, January/February 1 9 8 9 . Martin, W. 1 9 8 6 . "Southern Africa and the World-Economy . " Review 1 0 : 9 9 - 1 1 9 . Milkman, R . 1 979 . "Contradictions o f SemiPeripheral Development: The South African Case. " In Ihe Modem World-System of Capitalism: Past and Present, edited by W. Goldfrank, 26 1-84 . Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. Mingst, K. 1 9 8 8 . "The Ivory Coast at the Semi-Periphery of the World-Economy . " International Studies Quarterly 32 :259-74 . OECD. 1962. Economic Surveys, Ireland. Paris: OECD . OECD. 1 9 8 3 . Economic Surveys, Ireland. Paris: OECD . OECD. 1 9 8 5 . Economic Surveys, Ireland. Paris: OECD . OECD. 1987a. Economic Surveys, Ireland. Paris: OEC D. OECD . 1987b. International Investment and Multinational Enterprises. Recent Trends in International Direct Investment. Paris: OECD. O 'Loughlin, J . , and A. J. Parker. Forthcoming. "Tradition contra Change: The Political Geography of Irish Referenda, 1937- 1987 . " In Developments in Electoral Geography, edited by R. 1. Johnston, F. Shelley, and P. 1. Taylor. London: Croom Helm. Perrons, D. 1 9 8 6 . "Unequal Integration in Global Fordism: The Case of Ireland. " In Production, Work, and Tern'tory, edited by A. Scott and M. Stopher, 246-64. Boston: Allen and Unwin. Regan, C. 1 980. "Economic Development in Ireland: The Historical Dimension. " An tipode 1 2 : 1 - 1 4 . Rothgeb, John M . , J r. 1 986. "Compensation o r Opportunity? The Effects of International Recessions upon Direct Foreign Investment and Growth in 3rd World States , 1970- 1 9 78 . " International Studies Quarterly 3 0 : 123-52. Taylor, P. 1988. "The Poverty ofIntemational Comparisons: Some Methodological Lessons from World-Systems Analysis. " Studies in Comparative International Development 22: 12-3 9 . Telesis Consultancy Group . 1 9 8 2 . A Review of Industrial Policy. National Economic and Social Council Report no. 64. Dublin: National Economic and Social Council. United Nations. Various years. International Trade Statistics Yearbook. New York: United Nations. United Nations. 1 986. National Legislation and Regulations Relating to Transnational Cor porations. New York: United Nations. The Republic of Ireland 139 Wallerstein, 1 . 1 974. Ihe Modem World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press. __ . 1979 . Ihe Capitalist World-Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press . __ . 1982. " World-Systems Analysis: Theoreiical and Interpretative Issues. " I n World Systems Analysis: Iheory and Methodology, edited by T. Hopkins, 1. Wallerstein, and associates, 9 1- 1 03 . Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. __ . 1 984. Ihe Politics of the World-Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. World Bank. 1 976. World Tables. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. 8 PERIPHERY IN THE CENTER: CANADA IN THE NORTH AMERICAN ECONOMY Jorge Niosi The analysis of the late-industrialized countries in the world-economy, their development, and the dynamics of their changing relationships with the large, core industrialized countries has spawned an abundant theoretical and empirical literature. This ranges from the most traditional and "mechanistic" models in the Rostowian current to the neo-Marxist approaches of dependent development in Cardoso and Faletto (1969) or Evans (1979). Canada (like Australia, Finland, or Norway) is a good case for the testing of these models, because it resists easy classifications, being sometimes labeled " dependent, " sometimes " industri , alized, ' sometimes " semi-industrialized. " In this chapter some of the most basic propositions of these theories are put to proof in the Canadian context. The starts with a rapid review of these theories and sets forth some original h",,,,,th,,, on the rise of Canada from the ranks of the semi-industrialized to those specialized industrial countries. The argument is that Canada has l1lCLHQ'b'"'' own original way to industrial development, based on both its natural (mainly in the case of energy-intensive industries) and state intervention in industrial niches. Canada is in fact the largest of a group of industrialized omies-together with Sweden, Norway, Finland, Denmark, the NetherlaJlds Belgium, Switzerland, and Austria-that cling to the core advanced capitalist tries (the United States in the Canadian case; Britain, France, Germany, and Italy in Europe) . These smaller countries are as industrialized as the larger ones but more specialized. Furthermore, they lack the political, military, and diplomatic power that characterizes the core nations, and in this sense they are ' 'peripheral" . The chapter argues that the core economies tend to create other, new industrialized countries as technological diffusion and learning effects spread to smaller neighbors. I call these countries "central-peripheral" to distinguish them from Wallerstein's semiperipheral states. Central-peripheral states are characterized by (1) high levels of industrialization, comparable to those of the most industrialized 1 42 Semiperiphery or Core? states on a per capita basis ; (2) industrial specialization due to market-size con straints ; (3) trade relationships with the most developed countries (both in terms of exports and imports) ; and (4) lack of any important military , political, or diplomatic power in the world-system. This definition clearly makes them dif ferent from Wallerstein's semiperipheral states but is compatible with Arrighi and Drangel's stratification categories (Arrighi and Drangel 1986) . Presently, the most successful newly industrialized countries (NICs) (Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore in Asia; Spain in Europe) spread around the core advanced countries . They are all "catchers-up" that may eventually join this " central periphery " in the years to come. In the second part of this chapter Canadian and international comparative data for the postwar period are presented to support the argument and test the previous hypothesis. A conclusion summarizes the evidence and compares it with some of the most important theories presented in the first part. THEORIES ON INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT Most of the received international trade theories are totally useless for understan ding both industrial development and the complex patterns of commerce, invest ment, and technological linkages between developed and developing countries . Assuming perfect competition, identical production functions, identical tastes across countries , and a passive and almost inexistent state, these theories do not explain the rapid growth and changing configurations of the world-economy that have taken place in the last forty-five years (see Soete and Dosi 1 990; Niosi and Faucher 1 990) . Among these major changes in the global industrial landscape, the postwar period has witnessed the catching up to the United States by Western Europe and Japan as well as the rise of a group of other smaller and more specialized in dustrial countries in Europe and North America. More recently, an array of newly industrialized countries in the Pacific Rim and Southern Europe have also made inroads in some industrial markets traditionally served by firms from advanced capitalist countries . How do received theories of development cope with these rapid changes? For some authors , both Marxists and non-Marxists , industrial development is a natural outcome of the diffusion of capital , technology, consumption patterns, and organization from the most advanced to the less advanced countries . Rostow ( 1 960) and Kuznets ( 1 965) were among the first to argue in this direction. Other authors emphasized the standardization of technology and labor-cost differentials as the main push factor explaining the inevitable industrialization of the develop ing countries. One recognizes here the product life-cycle theory of Vernon ( 1 966, 1 97 1 ) and Wells ( 1 972 , 1 983) , but also the Marxist version of these arguments in the works of Warren ( 1 980) , Frobel et al . ( 1 980) , or Michalet ( 1 976) . In these approaches semi-industrial countries are only transitional states in the general ized process of development. Canada in the North American Economy 1 43 At the other extremity of this first current, one finds Marxist theories of im and most neo-Marxist theories of dependency. Here industrial developremains locked in a few advanced nations. Industrial concentration and corporations from developed countries tend to create early or oligopolistic markets in developing countries; these market struc tur es are conducive to stagnation through the repatriation of monopoly profits (Baran 1 95 7; Frank 1 967) or through the barriers they impose to technological innovation (Merhav 1 969) . Technological dependence (Vaitsos 1 973) , combined with commercial and financial dependence (Helleiner 1 98 1 ) , prevents backward countries from following the same development path the now-advanced coun tries had taken in the eighteenth or nineteenth centuries. A variation of this thesis appears in Wallerstein ( 1 984), where development is described as a " game of chairs," with a few advanced countries at the top and some semiperipheral countries attached to them as satellites. Semiperipheral states (including Canada) are characterized by their intermediate situation in the world system, both in economic and in political terms. In the long term the players change through time, the number of winners and quasi-winners (semiperipheral) remains restricted. Development is a sort of zero-sum game in which some countries' gains equal other countries' losses. A much more blended picture emerges from some neodependency theories. Dependency is here a complex phenomenon with political as well as economic dimensions. In backward countries development can be attained through indigenous technological learning and adaptation, internal capital formation and inflows, and a mix of organizational borrowing and local innovations. In the works of several Latin American and American economists and sociologists like Cardoso and Falet to ( 1 969) , Evans ( 1 979) , Katz ( 1 976), or Perez and Soete ( 1 98 8) , the path to industrial development, though narrow, is not at all closed. This path is one in which dependency and development will coexist during the industrialization with increasing local control and the spreading of technological learning the developing country, and a mixture of home protection for infant and the export of industrial products to foreign markets from the start. authors not suspected of neodependency sympathies (Yoffie 1 983) have that some developing countries were not helpless in building commercial designed to penetrate the developed countries' markets with their industrial pro-. ducts. In this approach the number of developed countries is always increasing, but by small numbers. This chapter is closer to this latter theoretical approach. In our view, each period of long-term growth in the world-economy has created development opportunities for several backward countries. Some of them, either by design or by a fortuitous combination of circumstances, have seized those opportunities. Russia, Sweden, Italy, Canada, and Japan were among the candidates for development in the sec ond half of the nineteenth century, as Argentina and Australia were in the first half of the twentieth century, and a dozen NICs are in the postwar period. Some of the candidates succeeded in attaining a sustained level of industrialization; others 144 Semiperiphery or Corel failed. Similarly, some present-day NICs are knocking at the door of the developed world, while others are already failing. In other words, in the musical game the number of chairs is always increasing, but slowly so, and a few semiperipheral states are now attaining the level of the industrialized countries. The largest of them may pretend in the future to a position among the core coun tries (Spain today) , while the smaller (Korea or Taiwan) will remain central peripheral states . Our assumption, thus, is that development is possible-and is in fact taking place-in some countries of the peripheral capitalist world through a combina tion of indigenous learning and technological adaptation, organizational mimetism and local innovation, and scientific borrowings and new political craftsmanship, both in the domestic and in the international arenas. The last forty-five years have witnessed an array of capitalist industrialization paths, from the most "liberal" (Hong Kong) to the most planned and state-oriented (Brazil, Korea, Taiwan) . Similarly, Canada was the least interventionist among the late niIieteenth-century industrializing countries, if compared to Japan, Germany, Sweden, or Italy. Canada' s economic limitations and structural weaknesses may be traced back to the uneven state intervention implemented to promote catching-up industrialization. Capital, technology, and managerial know-how from developed countries on ly flow to those followers that have the best political, economic, and cultural con ditions to absorb them. Human migration from more advanced countries and geographic and cultural proximity are among the best preconditions for the suc cessful industrial growth of latecomers. Development is a cluster-like process that occurs among neighbors, inasmuch as the latecomer is able to understand and eventually copy and adapt at least part of the organization and technical know how of the most advanced country. CANADA AS AN INDUSTRIALIZED PERIPHERAL COUNTRY Canadian development has been interpreted in very different ways by social scientists. The most common approach has been in terms of dependency and trun cated industrialization. Starting with Innis 's theory of staple development ( 1 962a, 1 962b), many social scientists concluded that the export of basic commodities such as furs, wheat, timber, and minerals had not been conducive to industrial development. Foreign control of most of the basic resources created a primary economy with a few basic industrial transformation spin-offs. The neo-Marxist approach in Levitt ( 1 970) , Watkins ( 1 970, 1 973, 1 982) , Hutcheson ( 1 977) , Williams (1983), or Clement (Clement and Williams 1 989) contends that Canada's industrialization was arrested by the early foreign direct investment in the upstream activities of manufacturing. Foreign (mainly American) multinational corpora tions created branch plants in Canada for a captive protected market and not for export. These subsidiaries used foreign machinery and technology, thus block ing any further industrial development in Canada. This approach is c1eaxly coherent with Wallerstein's view, in which Canada appears as a semiperipheral state Canada in the North American Economy 1 45 together with Nigeria and Zaire in Africa, Brazil, Mexico, or Argentina in Latin America, and Saudi Arabia in Asia (Wallerstein 1 979) . A more optimistic approach was built on the basis of work by Mackintosh (1 939) and Dales ( 1 957). Staple production and export were accepted as the first stage in Canadian development, but their transformation was seen as a base for the development of Canadian industry, either foreign- or Canadian-controlled. Dales insisted on the particular importance of hydroelectricity as a basic resource in Canadian industrial development, attracting many energy-intensive manufactur ing activities such as pulp and paper, metal refining, and petrochemicals. This dynamic staple approach is much closer to Rostow' s or Kuznets' s theories, where development follows naturally from the economic linkage with more developed countries. More recently, Lower ( 1 964) and Spelt ( 1 972) argued in the same direc tion as Mackintosh had done half a century ago. Finally, some authors built a more nuanced perspective. While accepting dependency as a starting point in Canadian industrialization, they emphasized the gradual decline of foreign control in the Canadian economy since 1 970, the rise of local capital in the 1 960s and 1 970s with the help of both the provincial (Pratt and Richards 1 979) and federal Canadian state (Niosi 1 981), the rapid deploy ment of Canadian multinational corporations in the postwar period (Niosi 1 985), and the steady development of Canadian industry since World War II (Resnick 1 982 ; Carroll 1 986) . While Canada is not a "core" country or principal industrial power, its manufacturing base has certainly attained some level of maturity and is able to compete with foreign manufacturing enterprises of core developed coun tries in several niches. In this perspective Canada is one of those latecomer countries that for more than a century has managed its original way of industrialization. With a popula tion of only 26 million today it could hardly attain a very diversified industrial structure. But it i s, and can remain in the foreseeable future, very {Y\lnnf>htnlP in several manufacturing areas. In the past, the inflow of scientific, U'�U"'S"'.'� and technical knowledge was favored by its proximity both to England the United States and by massive migration from both countries, the " .."_""",,. hegemons in the world-economy since 1 8 1 5. Starting with a high level control in the late nineteenth century, some Canadian firms were already in the nineteenth century in traditional manufacturing industries, such as and beverages, wood products, shipbuilding, textiles, apparel, and shoes. World War II some of them entered pulp and paper, metal refining, or heavy equipment, and later (during or after the war) some entered high-technology in dustries such as the production of telecommunications and mass-transportation equipment, synthetic rubber, aircraft, and nuclear engineering. In services Canada conserved its traditional international stronghold in banking and insurance and added engineering and co�struction in the postwar period. Canada's industrial development was favored by macroeconomic state interven tion, such as the protectionist National Policy in 1 87 9, and by the unification of the domestic market through the construction of a national network of railways. 1 46 Semi periphery or Core? These policies were similar to those implemented in the nineteenth century by presently industrialized countries . State intervention was also crucial in the development of today ' s important in dustries. Pulp and paper migrated to the north in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries because of the imposition of provincial taxes or embargoes on the export of timber cut in the Crown lands (Guthrie 1 94 1 ) . Petrochemicals and synthetic rubber developed first during World War II under a giant Crown corporation, Polymer , using American technology and technical personnel for defense production (N iosi 1 985) . Nuclear energy developed also during and after World War II under the aegis of the federal government through another Crown corporation, Atomic Energy of Canada (Doern and Morrison 1980) . Telecom munications equipment was a favorite of the federal government' s industrial sub sidies policy in the postwar period (Conklin 1 988) . Engineering was developed in the 1960s and 1970s through the nationalistic procurement policies of the Quebec government, particularly those of Hydro-Quebec, the giant provincial Crown cor poration (Niosi and Faucher 1987a) . Tax incentives were key in the postwar development of the now-prosperous steel industry (Barnett and Schorsch 1983) . As these examples show, Canadian interventionism was not a tight package of measures closely implemented in a short span of time (as in Germany, Japan, or Italy) , but a much more chronologically scattered set of punctual policies de signed to develop one particular industry at a given moment. Besides, it was depen dent on the fluctuations of the political process: it was heightened between 1 966 and 1984 under the Liberal federal administration and has declined since with the Conservatives. Canadian interventionism was much less embracing than the French , the Ger man, or the Swedish, with their early emphasis on scientific, technical, and in dustrial education; in these countries the state created a large education system in order to insure a fast and adequate training of workers , technicians, and engineers for manufacturing (Landes 1972). Canada seldom relied on the straight creation of industrial enterprises by the state or on massive direct subsidies to infant private firms as Japan, Italy, or Germany did in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries (Blackford 1988; Landes 1 972) . In this sense Canada's path to industrialization was a " late liberal model, " more interventionist than the British, but less than the Japanese, the German , or the Italian. If late in dustrialization is often achieved under the auspices of the state, as Gerschenkron ( 1 965) has successfully argued, the degree and types of public intervention varied from one country to another, depending on many particular historical cir cumstances . Canada, for example, strongly counted on migration of a qualified labor force, mainly from Britain and the United States; many of thes� immigrants founded some of the largest and best-known Canadian industrial giants, such as Dofasco (steel) , Hiram Walker (distilleries), or Alcan (aluminum) (see Niosi 1 978). The result of these market and policy developments was a particular Canadian industrial structure showing two kinds of strongholds. Some of them were based Canada in the North American Economy \ 147 on static comparative advantages. This was the case in energy-intensive such as aluminum, copper, nickel, zinc, and lead refining, pulp and and steel minimills; it was also the case in modern natural-gas Vl"J.l"lun.·u." and agricultural machinery. The second group was based on state :,nt,orv,entlon, technology transfer from abroad, and indigenous R & D, including r.ell!l:U'UUUUILU\.-QUOJU<> equipment, integrated steel production, mass-transportation eOllllpme:nI, and synthetic rubber. nr11 1 �lTle., ADA'S INTERNATIONAL POSITION TODAY On some dimensions Canada can be compared with the largest core industrial (with which it sits, since 1 976, in the Group of Seven) , while on others compares with the smaller industrialized nations of Western Europe. Canada' s international position will be analyzed o n the basis of three related indicators: . direct investment, trade, and technological flows. But let us first start with some • basic indicators of industrial development Canada' s proportion of manufacturing in the gross domestic product is cer tainly much lower than the German or the Japanese proportion but is similar to ' that of the United States and the Netherlands, between 1 9 and 2 0 percent (table 8 . 1) . While Canada' s productivity in manufacturing is second only to that of the United States, all these core and central peripheral countries have very close pro , ductivity levels, considerably higher than those of even the most successful NICs (table 8 .2). The analysis of the international position shows, -first, that in terms of foreign direct investment, Canada is now the fifth-largest foreign direct investor in the world, after the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan, and West Germany, and preceding the Netherlands (see table 8. 3) . Like all the largest industrialized countries, its foreign investment takes place mostly in the developed countries (85 percent) , mainly the United States, and only marginally in the world (15 percent). The industrial distribution of its foreign direct " ,n " ""ot"..,,,, shows traditional sectors such as shoes and distilleries, capital-intensive areas as pulp and paper, metal refining, and agricultural machinery, and hlg;h-tectmologM industries such as telecommunications equipment, plastics, and synthetic rubber. In any event, this industrial distribution is much more like that of the United States than that of any other country. In per capita terms, of course, Canadian foreign direct investment (CFDI) is much higher than U. S . foreign direct investment abroad. One could show that the other central-peripheral countries are also in vesting in core countries and not in less developed countries (LDCs) , bringing another rebuttal to Wallerstein's inclusion of them in the semiperiphery . The Canadian economy is highly concentrated, and CFDI is the consequence of this high level of concentration. The theory of multinational corporations, as Hymer (1 970) has shown, is but a chapter of industrial organization theory. Also, Canadian firms are making intensive use of some static and dynamic advantages they have acquired in the management of specific Canadian resources (such as Semiperiphery or Core? 1 48 Table 8.1 GDP i n Manufacturing Industries a t Market Prices, Country 1986 GDP in manufacturing as % of GDP Germany, Federal Republic 33.1% Japan 29 . 3 % Austria 27 . 1 % France 25.0%* Italy 2 3 . 6% Belgium 22. 6 % * United Kingdom 22.6% * S weden 2 1 .5 % Finland 2 1 .0% Netherlands 19.8% United States 19.3 % CANADA 19.2% Norway 1 5. 3 % United Nations. December 1987. Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; United Nations. 1988a; OECD. 1988a; U.S. President. 1988; Bank of Canada. 1988. Sources: * Figures are for 1 985. Data are not available for other industrial countries in these sources. pulp and paper and nonferrous metals) or through industrial activities connected with them (such as agricultural machinery) . However, not all CFDI can be ex plained by experience gained through the intensive use of local natural resources, as the cases of telecommunications equipment, rubber, and plastics show. Foreign direct investment in Canada has been falling in relative terms. Foreign control of the Canadian economy peaked in 1 970, with nearly 36 �ercent of the assets of nonfinancial industries, then declined steadily , reaching a level of ap proximately 24 percent in 1986 (see table 8 .4) . In manufacturing foreign control declined from 58 percent in 1 970 to 44 percent in 1986, but the decline has been general and across the board. Under the favorable economic and political en vironment of federal and provincial nationalism, Canadian firms have been able Canada in the North American Economy 1 49 Table 8.2 Manufacturing Productivity (1984) in Current U.S. Dollars Country Producri vitya United States 55 1 3 6 CANADA 41 373 Germany, Federal Republic 39073 Japan 35542 Sweden 284 1 5 Australia 27938 Netherlands 25 1 1 9 (1 983) France 24725 Italy 24689 (1982) Finland 24286 Belgium 2 1 7 5 1 ( 1 983) Norway 2 1 704 United Kingdom 20340 Austria 1 8308 Spain 1 6 1 48 ( 19 83) South Korea 12939 Source: United Nations 1988c. aDefined a s manufacturing value added 0 n average number 0 f employees i n manufacturing for the year. to acquire ongoing foreign subsidiaries in Canada or to successfully compete with them in many of the same industries in which foreign subsidiaries were active. However, nearly 17 percent of Canadian assets still are under American control, and 30 percent of its manufacturing assets, a proportion not found in any other central-peripheral industrial country (United Nations 1 983) . In terms of trade, and thus of the international competitiveness of its industry, Canada is now the seventh-largest exporter of manufacturing products, ranking after West Germany, Japan, the United States, France, Italy, and Great Britain, Table 8.3 Foreign Direct Investment Stock, Main Countries, 1984 FDr Share (%) Amount (Bi llions of U. S . Dollars) Counrry 233.4 42.5 United Kingdom 85.3 15.5 Japan 37.9 6.9 Germany, Federal Republic 36.6 6.7 CANADA 31.3 5.7 Netherlands 3 1 .2 5. 7 Other 93.3 17.0 549.0 1 00 . 0 United S tates Total Source: Keizai Koho Center. 1 986. Table 8.4 Foreign Control o f Canadian Industry, Industry 1979 and 1986 A ssets under foreign control as a percentage of total assets Difference 1986 1 970 Agriculture, forests 13% 3'0'" · 1 0% Mining 69% 31% ·38'70 Manufacturing 58% 44% · ] 4% Construction 1 6% 70b ·9 % 8% 3�1c, ·5 % Wholesale trade 27% 24% ·3 % Retail trade 22% 13% ·9 % Services 22% 16% ·6% Total, non financial industries 36% 240/" · 1 2% Utilities Source: S tatistics Canada. 1 980, 1987. Cat. 6 1 ·2 1 0. Cil r; Canada in the North American Economy 151 but before Belgium-Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and Sweden (table 8 . 5) . Its share of the world market of manufactured goods has increased since 1975 . On this measure Japan and Italy have improved their performance, contrary to the United States, the United Kingdom, and even Germany and France. Again, in per capital manufactured exports Canada ranks eighth after Switzerland, Belgium Luxembourg, Sweden, West Germany, the Netherlands, Finland, and Austria, but before Norway, Japan, France, the United Kingdom, and the United States (table 8 . 6) . Table 8.5 Exports of Manufactured Good s, Selected Countries in Market Economies 1975 and 1986 (in billion US$ ) 1986 1986 Germany, Federal Republic 7 9 . 62 2 1 7.32 1 6. 9 % 16. 1 % Japan 53. 1 7 203.36 1 1 .3 % 15.1 % United S tates 70.97 1 48.87 15.1 % 1 1 .0 % France 3 9 .72 92. 1 9 8.4% 6.8% Italy 29. 1 4 86.09 6.2% 6.4% United Kingdom 36.44 80.09 7.8% 5.9% CANADA 1 6. 6 8 56. 1 9 3.5% 4.2% Belgi um-Luxembourg 22.84 52.29 4. 9 % 3.9% Netherlands 1 9. 3 2 46. 82 4. 1 % 3.5% Switzerland 1 2. 1 2 35.79 2.6% 2.7% Sweden 1 3 . 84 3 1 .49 2.9% 2.3 % Austria 6.52 20. 1 7 1 .4 % 1.5% Finland 4.40 1 3.57 0.9% 1.0% Norway 5 . 07 8.30 1.1% 0.6% S u btotal 409 . 85 1 092.54 87.2% 81 .0% Total (market economies) 470.06 1 349.30 1 00.0% 1 00.0% Source: United Nations. April 1 976. April 1 987. 1 975 (in %) 1975 Country/Year Monthly B ulletin a/Statistics. Semiperiphery or Core? 1 52 Table 8.6 Manufactured Exports Per Capita, 1975 and 1986 (in current U . S . dollars) Country 1975 1986 S witzerland 1 8 94 5506 Belgium-Luxembourg 2239 5077 S weden 1678 3749 Germany 1228 3557 Netherlands 1410 3207 Finland 936 2769 Ausoia 869 2654 CANADA 7 32 2 1 94 1268 1 976 Japan 476 1673 France 752 1 664 Italy 522 1505 United Kingdom 65 1 1410 United S tates 332 616 Norway Source: Calculated from United Nations. April 1 976. April 1987. Monthly Bulletin of Statistics. The arguments of the dependency school were also based on another dimen sion of Canada's international trade: its geographical concentration. As Hirschman and others have suggested, dependency emerges where country A represents a large percentage of trade of country B, but the latter takes a small part of country A's total trade (Hirschman 1945) . Canada conducts 72 percent of its foreign trade with only one country , the United States , while it represents only 20 percent of U . S . trade . We found several small European industrialized countries with high proportions of trade in only one area: Belgium, the Netherlands , and Switzerland are also "dependent" upon a single market, both for exports and for imports (table 8 . 7) . There are two important differences , however, between Canada and these countries. Some of these small industrial nations are inside the EEC and are thus exempted from eventual threats or retaliation from their larger trading partners ; second, no single country takes as high a part of the total trade of any small industrial nation, including the Southeast Asian NICs (Barrett and Chin Canada in the North American Economy 1 53 Table 8.7 Developed Countries, 1987: Main Foreign Market and Supplier Co untry Main foreign market (% of exports) Main supplier (% of imports) Belgium EEC (74.2%) EEC (72.4%) CANADA United S tates (75 .6%) United S tates (68. 1 % ) Netherlands EEC (74 .9%) EEC (64. 1 % ) S witzerland EEC (55 . 7 % ) EEC (72.2%) France EEC (5 8 . 3 % ) EEC (60.7 % ) Norway EEC (64.4%) EEC (49. 6 % ) Italy EEC (56. 1 %) EEC (56.6%) Sweden EEC (5 1 . 0%) EEC (57.3%) Germany, Federal Republic EEC (52. 7 % ) EEC (52. 7 % ) United Kingdom EEC (49.5%) EEC (52.8%) Finland EEC (42 . 1 % ) EEC (44.4%) Japan United S tates (36. 8 % ) United States (21.2%) Australia Japan (25 .6%) Japan ( 1 9. 7 % ) United S tates EEC (24.2%) Japan (20 . 2 % ) Source: United Nations. 1 9 8 8 b . 1987). A t another level, our tables show that small industrial countries, Canada, Finland, or Norway, trade with other developed countries, not with industrial and peripheral economies, as was suggested by Wallerstein' s aPlJroaCh This kind of trade dependency is not without consequences. In the case Canada, it was the main official reason given by the Canadian government for a free-trade agreement with the United States. Increasing U.S. protectionism and the vulnerability of Canadian exports to this threat were repeatedly cited as the crucial explanation of the urgent need for a Canada-U.S. treaty, both during the trade negotiations and the recent federal campaign. When it comes to technology, Canada has a lower ratio of gross expenditure on research and development (GERD) to GDP than the United States, Japan, West Germany, France, and the United Kingdom (among the largest economies) and Sweden, Switzerland, and the Netherlands (among the mid-sized economies). But Semi periphery or Core? 1 54 it has a larger GERD/GDP ratio than Austria, Australia, and Spain (among the mid-sized economies) and also almost all the small industrialized economies ex cept Norway and Finland. Furthermore, Canada has very low military expen ditures in R & D , while these account for a large proportion of total publicly financed GERD in the United States, the United Kingdom, France, and Sweden (table 8.8). When these military expenditures are subtracted, as Palda (1984) has already remarked, Canadian R & D expenditures become much closer to those of other developed countries. Also, the Canadian balance of technological payments , while negative, is close to that of the French and the Japanese, and it is far less negative than that of the Netherlands, Italy, or Spain. In sum, Canada exhibits many structural similarities with mid-sized and small industrialized economies: strong industrial specialization , high per capita manu factured exports, high per capita foreign direct investment, high geographical trade concentration, smaller R & D expenditures, and a negative technology transfer balance. These characteristics are those of industrialized countries , 'clustering " around larger core industrial nations . It would be easy to show the technological , cultural, and economic links of each of these " central-peripheral" states with one or two neighboring mother countries : Austria and Scandinavia with Germany; Belgium with France; Korea and Taiwan first with the United States and then with Japan; and Canada with Great Britain and then with the United States. Table 8.8 Government R & D Expenditures by Objective in 1987 Country Defence All other Total United S tates 68.6% 3 1 . 4% 100% United Kingdom 50.3% 49.7% 1 00% France 34. 1 % 65.9% 1 00% S weden 26.9% 73. 1 % 1 00 % Germany. Federal Republic 12.5% 87.5% 1 00% Australia 9.2% 90. 8 % 1 00% Italy 7.8% 92.2% 1 00% Norway 7.5% 92.5% 100% CANADA 7.4% 92.6% 1 00% Source: OECD. 1 9 8 8 b : 4. Canada in the North American Economy 1 55 CONCLUSION Our figures tend to refute the more radical versions of the dependentist analysis of Canadian economic development by Levitt, Watkins, Hutcheson, or Williams. Canada is neither underindustrialized nor deindustrializing. On the contrary, its industrial performance has been better than that of the United States and several other OECD countries since 1967. Foreign control has been declining for fifteen years. Canadian industrial and service multinational firms are increasingly play ing important roles in world markets, successfully competing in the United States and Western Europe. The figures also deny Canada' s inclusion in the semi peri pheral category, as in Wallerstein's analysis. On the basis of our data, Canada could even be included in the core, as Arrighi and Drangel suggested. However, if dependency is a continuous variable with many different values, Canada looks in some respects more dependent than any comparable country of similar size. Its commerce is more concentrated with a single industrialized na tion. Its industry has a higher degree of foreign control. Its manufacturing is also more reliant on the transformation of resources than on knowledge-intensive ac tivities. Manufacturing is a smaller part of its GDP than in any other large or medium-sized industrial nation. Canada shows an important and increasing deficit in high-technology products. Its scientific and technical base is lagging behind those not only of large developed countries but also of some small and medium sized industrial nations. Canadian industry and domestic multinationals are mostly on the low-intensive area of the technological spectrum. These weaknesses can be traced back to the less embracing and continuous state efforts to promote industrialization. In the future, too large a reliance on static comparative advantages may con tribute to a one-sided industrial structure and mortgage industrial development based on knowledge-intensive industries. Free markets and hands-off goveITIIl1erits may underproduce the scientific and technological resources necessary for development of the next generation of industrial goods. The more optimistic perspective was thus wrong in neglecting the role of the state in past development. More importantly, it could also prove wrong in the future, due the increasing competition in world markets and to the steady rise of new in dustrial countries using more sophisticated industrial and commercial policies than Canada. From a more theoretical perspective, a group of "central-peripheral" coun tries has to be neatly differentiated from the countries of the semiperiphery. These central nations trade with larger, core countries, both in terms of imports and exports. Their foreign direct investment also takes place in core countries. Their technology overwhelmingly comes from these larger partners. Their industry is as advanced as that of the core countries but more specialized, due to market size restrictions. They are not ' 'intermediary countries" in any meaningful sense but are most often close followers to early developed economies. 1 56 Semiperiphery or Core? REFERENCES Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel. 1986. "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone. " Review 10, 1 (Summer) :9-74. Bank of Canada. 1988. Bank of Canada Review. Ottawa: Bank of Canada. Baran, Paul. 1957. 1he Political Economy of Growth. New York: Monthly Review Press. Barnett, Donald F . , and Louis Schorsch. 1983. Steel: Upheaval in a Basic Industry. Cambridge, Mass. : Ballinger. Barrett, Richard S. , and Soomi Chin. 1987. "Export-oriented Industrializing States in the Capitalist World System: Similarities and Differences. " In 1he Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by Frederic C . Deyo, pp 23 1 -43 . Ithaca, N .Y . : Cornell University Press. Blackford, Mansel G. 1988 . The Rise of Modem Business in Great Britain, the United States, and Japan. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Cardoso, Fernando-H. , and Enzo Faletto. 1 969 . Dependencia y desarrollo en America Latina . Mexico: Siglo XXI. Carroll, William. 1986. Corporate Power and Canadian Capitalism. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press. Clement, Wallace, and Glen Williams, eds. 1989. The New Canadian Political Economy. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press. Conklin, David. 1988 . Canadian High-Tech i n a New World Economy: A Case Study of Information Technology. Vancouver: Institute for Research on Public Policy. Dales, John. 1957. Hydroelectricity and Industrial Development, Quebec, 1898-1940. Cam bridge, Mass . : Harvard University Press. Doern, G. Bruce, and Robert W. Morrison. 1980. Canadian Nuclear Policies. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy. Evans, Peter. 1979. Dependent Development. Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press. Frank, Andre G. 1967. Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. New York: Monthly Review Press. Frobel, Friedrich, et al. 1980. 1he New International Division ofLabor. New Yor k: Cam bridge University Press. Gerschenkron, Alexander . 1 965 . Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. New York: Praeger. Guthrie, John. 194 1 . 1he Newsprint Paper Industry. Cambridge, Mass . : Harvard University Press. Helleiner, Gary. 1980. International Economic Disorder. Toronto: University of Toron to Press. Hirschman, Albert. 1945 . National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Hutcheson, John. 1977. Dominance and Dependency. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart. Hymer, Stephen. 1970. 1he International Operations ofNational Firms. Cambridge, Mass. : MIT Press. Innis, Harold. 1962a. The Fur Trade in Canada. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. . 1962b. Essays in Canadian Economic History. Toronto: University of Toronto Press . Katz, Jorge. 1976. Importacilm de tecnologia, aprendizaje, e industrializacilm dependiente. Mexico: F . C . E . ___ Canada in the North American Economy 157 Keizai Koho Center. 1 986. Japan: A n International Comparison . Tokyo: Keizai Koho Center. Kuznets , Simon. 1965 . Modem Economic Growth. New Haven: Yale University Press. Landes, David. 1972. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1 750 to the Present. New York: Cambridge University Press. Levitt, Kari. 1 970. Silent Surrender. Toronto: Macmillan. Lower, Albert R.M. 1964. Colony to Nation: A History of Canada . Don Mills, Ontario : Longmans . Mackintosh, William A. 1939. The Economic Background ofDominion-Provincial Rela tions. Royal Commission on Dominion-Provincial Relations. Ottawa: King's Printer. Merhav, Meir. 1 969 . Technological Dependence, Monopoly, and Growth . London: Pergamon. Michalet, Charles-A. 1976. Le capitalisme mondial. Paris : Presses Universitaires de France. Niosi, Jorge. 1978. The Economy of Canada: A Study of Ownership and Control. Montreal: Black Rose Books . . 198 1 . Canadian Capitalism. Toronto: Lorimer. . 1985. Canadian Multinationals. Toronto: Between-the-Lines. Niosi, Jorge, and Philippe Faucher. 1987a. " Les marches publics comme instrument de ___ ___ developpement industriel: Le cas d'Hydro-Quebec. " Recherches sociographiques 2 8 , 1 : 9-28. . 1987b. "The Decline of North American Industry : The U . S . and Canada. " In Frontyard Backyard: The Americas in the Global Crisis, edited by J. Holmes and C . Leys. Toronto: Between the Lines . . 1990. "The State and National Competitiveness . " In Technology and National Competitiveness, edited by Jorge Niosi. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press. OECD. 1988a. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Economic Studies. Paris : OECD. . 1988b. STI Indicators Newsletter. No. 10. Paris: OECD. PaIda, Kristian. 1984. Industrial Innovation: Its Place in the Public Policy Agenda . couver: Fraser Institute. Perez, Carlota, and Luc Soete. 1988. "Catching Up Technology: Entry Barriers dows of Opportunity. In Technical Change and Economic 1heory, edited by ni Dosi et al. , pp. 458-79. London: Pinter. Pratt, Larry, and John Richards. 1 979. Prairie Capitalism. Toronto: McClelland Stewart. Resnick, Philippe. 1982. "Canadian Capitalism Comes of Age. " Our Generation 3 : 1 1-25 . Rostow, Walt. 1960. The Stages ofEconomic Growth. New York: Cambridge University Press. Soete, Luc, and Giovanni Dosi. 1989. "Technological Innovation and International Com petitiveness . " In Technology and National Competitiveness, edited by Jorge Niosi. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press. Spelt, John. 1972. Urban Development i n South-Central Ontario. Toronto : McClelland and Stewart. Statistics Canada. 1980 and 1 987. Annual Report of the Treasury Board Under the Cor porations and Labour Unions Return Act. Ottawa: Statistics Canada. __ __ __ " 1 58 Semiperiphery or Core? United Nations . Various months . Monthly Bulletin ofStatistics. New York: United Nations. 1988a. National Accounts Statistics. New York: United Nations . . 1988b. International Trade Statistics Yearbook. New York: United Nations. . 1988c. Industrial Statistics Yearbook 1 985. New York: United Nations . United Nations. Centre for Transnational Corporations. 1983. Transnational Corporations in World Development. Ihird Study. New York: United Nations . United States. President. 1 988 . Economic Report of the President. Washington, D . C . : U . S . Govenunent Printing Office. Vaitsos, Constantino . 1973 . La comercializacion de tecnologla en el Pacto Andino. L ima: Instituto de estudios peruanos. Vernon, Raymond. 1 966. "International Investment and International Trade i n the Pro duct Cycle. " Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 1 90-207. . 1971 . Sovereignty at Bay. New York: Basic Books. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979. Ihe Capitalist World-Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press. . 1984. The Politics of the World-Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Warren, Bill. 1980. Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism. London: New Left Books. Watkins, Mel. 1 970. "The Dismal State of Economics in Canada. " In Close the 49th Parallel: Ihe Americanization of Canada, edited by Ian Lumsden, pp 1 97-208 . Toronto: University of Toronto Press. 1973 . " Resources and Underdevelopment. " I n Canada Ltd. : Ihe Political Economy of Dependency, edited by Robert M. Laxer, pp. 107-26. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart. . 1 982. "The Innis Tradition in Canadian Political Economy. " Canadian Jour nal of Political and Social Theory, no. 6 (Winter): 12-34. Wells, Louis T. , Jr. , ed. 1972. Ihe Product L(fe Cycle and International Trade . Boston: Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University. . 1 983 . Ihird World Multinationals. Cambridge, Mass . : MIT Press. Williams, Glen. 1 983. Notfor Export: Towards a Political Economy of Canada 's Arrested Industrialization. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart. Yoffie, David B. 1 983. Power and Protectionism: Strategies of the Newly Industrialized Countries. New York: Columbia University Press. ___ __ ___ __ __ ___ __ . PART IV ETHNICITY: PROPELLING OR CHECKING ADVANCE ? 9 THE CONTRADICTIONS OF SEMIPERIPHERAL "SUCCESS " : THE CASE OF ISRAEL Beverly Silver In a recently published volume Yoram Ben Porath notes the wildly shifting for tunes of the Israeli economy: "For twenty-five years after the establishment of the state in 1948, Israel was considered an economic miracle, with one of the highest rates of growth in the world . . . . During the 1970s, however . . . the economy almost stagnated and Israel has become synonymous with running in flation and balance of . payments crises" (1986, 1). Israel's transition from " economic miracle" to " economic disaster" can be fruitfully analyzed as part of the world-systemic processes that have continuously reproduced an intermediate (semiperipheral) zone of the world-economy. Israel's high growth rates in the 1950s and 1960s found parallels among many semiperipheral states of the era. The combined result was a narrowing of the wealth gap between semiperiphery during the postwar phase of world economic expansion. as the 1970s and 1980s progressed, one semiperipheral " economic another collapsed into economic disaster, leading to a widening of the tween core and semiperiphery during the current phase of world-economic traction (Arrighi and Drangel 1986; World Bank 1989). The first section of this chapter will analyze the social processes J .�.e Israel's rapid economic growth from the establishment of the state in 1948 the abrupt shift to stagflation in 1973. Many of the processes that will be em phasized will be familiar to students of other " successful" semiperipheral NICs. These are (1) the important role played by an activist state leadership with a strong developmentalist and nation-building ideology; (2) the fact that in comparison with the state, both dominant and subordinate classes and groups were weak, thus giving the state leadership a large degree of autonomy in channeling human and material resources in accordance with nation-building priorities; (3) the success of the state leadership in manipulating and/or bypassing world-market forces rather than becoming their passive victims, including the ability to stimulate or block �"'��•• 162 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? resource inflows and outflows through nonmarket mechanisms ; and (4) the abili ty to find a niche in the expanding world-market by exploiting their cost advan tage (lower wages) vis-a-vis core producers and their resource advantages (capital, skilled labor, and infrastructure) vis-a-vis peripheral producers . While some were trying to distill the secret of successful development out of an analysis of the NICs, the very success of the latter was changing the world economic and national class conditions on which their own rapid growth had been based. The second part of this chapter analyzes the processes through which Israel's success (and success throughout much of the semiperiphery) undermined the con ditions for continued rapid growth . Again, some of the processes that will be emphasized in the Israeli case are familiar to students of other semiperipheral states. First, on the national front, rapid growth itself tended to strengthen civil socie ty and weaken the relative autonomy of the state . The emergence of militant and effective movements of workers and other subordinate groups throughout the semiperiphery-from Spain and Brazil to South Africa and South Korea-signalled the end of "cheap labor. " In Israel the end of cheap labor has been loudly an nounced in numerous forms from "the Oriental (Jewish) Revolt" of the 1970s to the Palestinian intifadah in the late 1980s . Second, at the world-economic level, as more and more countries attempted to follow the NIC strategy of developing low-wage manufactured exports , com petitive pressures intensified, squeezing and/or eliminating profits. As more and more low-wage exporters targeted core markets, protectionist pressures inten sified, thus bringing the limits of the low-wage manufacture export strategy into clear vision. These trends support one of the key predictions of world-systems analysis: strategies that can make some states (or individuals) wealthy cannot simultaneously make all states (or individuals) wealthy (Arrighi and Drangel 1986; Wallerstein 1979 , 60-6 1 ) . Israel could not resolve the squeeze on profits in its old lines o f production by lowering wages . With the new balance of class forces , real wages have escalated beyond productivity increases virtually every year since the late 1 970s . The only alternative was to shift to new lines of production that would be subject to less competitive pressure (i . e . , core activities) . In fact , this has been the main em phasis of the Israeli state 's development strategy since the late 1 960s-that is, the promotion of skill-intensive, high-tech industries . While Israel has had some success in this area (most notably in the buildup of a military-industrial complex) , the difficulties Israel has faced in promoting an overall shift to core activities illustrates the general processes that keep semi peripheral states from catching up with the wealth levels of the core. Core countries (because of their wealth) are able to sustain the processes of innovation that allow them to continuously shift into new economic activities that are not subject to strong competitive pressures. To be sure, semiperipheral states have a resource advantage over peripheral states , and an activist state leadership can exploit this advantage to promote innovations and production in core activities The Case of Israel 1 63 (e. g . , Uzi submachine guns and Gabriel missiles) . However, they simply do not have the necessary resources (capital, labor, infrastructure, and markets) to move up overall into predominantly core activities. This inability was starkly demonstrated by Israel's recent forced abandonment of its multibillion-dollar pro ject to design, build, and market its own world-class fighter airplane (the Lavi) . Israel has thus very much followed the semiperipheral pattern of "running fast to stay in the same place. " However, the post-1973 Israeli experience also ex hib its a curious deviation. Since 1973 the Israeli domestic economy has been in virtually perpetual crisis. However, according to Arrighi and Drangel (1986) , during this same period Israel moved up into the "perimeter o f the core . " Moreover, the latest World Development Report (World Bank 1989) has reclassified Israel, promoting it into the group of "high income economies . " If from 1948 to 1973 Israel "ran fast to stay in the same place, " since 1973 Israel appears to have moved up by standing still. The key to this paradox lies in massive U.S. economic aid. This aid first became significant in 1973 and then escalated sharply in the 1980s. Thus, while the semiperiphery as a group sank, Israel was kept afloat. While it has not moved up much relative to the average GNP of the core in the 1970s and 1980s, it has been spared the fate of moving down with the bulk of the semiperiphery. While it is not clear whether this aid can be converted into a form that will allow Israel to firmly move up into the core, or if it will all be dissipated through warfare and financial speculation, the post-1973 Israeli experience provides a strik ing illustration of the most effective means by which positions in the world hierarchy of wealth can be affected. If we can judge from the Israeli case, massive redistribution from the core is the most effective route . However, redistribution as a strategy of upward mobility is the biggest fallacy of them all. Israel, with a population of only about 4 million, receives nearly 30 percent of total U.S. foreign aid (Abed 1986) . Thus such a strategy to upward mobility, like all sW'ategies of upward mobility, is by definition limited to exceptional cases. TIIE SOCIAL FOUNDATION OF RAPID ECONOMIC GROWTH, 1948-1973 Israel presents yet another clear case refuting the neoclassical myth high growth rates of the successful postwar NICs were the result of free prise in action, made possible by a state that passively accepted the verdict unencumbered market forces . 1 Instead, the key role was played by an activist state leadership with a deep-seated nation-building ideology and a strong distrust for private capital and market forces. Furthermore, the ability of this state leader ship to successfully implement its develop mentalist goals was predicated on a large inflow of both capital and labor-neither of which was responding to the pull of market forces. Indeed, if it had been left to the free play of the market and purely economic motivations, Israel would have been marginalized from the international flows of labor and capital . 1 64 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? Given the logic of postwar international capital and labor flows, Israel was not likely to attract large-scale resource inflows as a result of purely market mechanisms. In the first place, Israel has no natural resources of significance to attract capital interested in primary production for export. Second, during the first two postwar decades manufacturing capital was attracted either to countries with large protected domestic markets or to countries with access to even larger regional markets (e. g . , the EEC, Spain, Brazil, Mexico) . Israel had neither a large domestic market nor access to the regional market. By the 1 970s , with the intensification of world-market competition, low labor costs became an impor tant factor in attracting foreign investment in labor-intensive segments of the labor process. However, while Israel' s wage levels were low relative to those of the core, it could not compete with most of the rest of the semiperipheral zone (par ticularly East Asia) , not to mention the periphery . A final determination of large-scale international capital flows has been cold war politics . While this type of resource inflow has by now become the main source of outside funds for Israel, before 1 973 intergovernmental transfers represented an insignificant factor in Israel 's balance-of-payments situation. It was not until the outcome of the Six-Day War that the United States began to seriously consider Israel as a strategic asset, and it was not until after the Oc tober 1 973 war that the United States became a key source of financial assistance (Israel Central Bureau of Statistics, annual; Silver 1987; Safran 198 1 , 578) . Thus, if it had been left to market forces, Israel would have been subject to strong peripheralizing pressures . Instead, Israel was able to resist marginaliza tion through the development of strong (nonmarket) links with extraterritorial individuals and communities-diaspora Jewish communities around the world. The Israeli state was able to effectively mobilize the latter' s resources (capital, labor, expertise, and trade networks) and direct them toward the development of the nation-state. These ties gave the Israeli state the resources to effectively pursue an aggressive nation-building strategy-for example, sufficient capital to make large-scale investments in agriculture, industry, and infrastructure; sup plies of both skilled and unskilled labor through immigration and association; and the development of trade networks through integration into those of diaspora businessmen. The most striking success has been in the promotion of capital flows from the diaspora community. Annual appeals for donations were institutionalized in Jewish communities throughout the world, raising $ 1 . 7 billion from 1 950 to 1 967 . Dur ing the same period another $ 1 . 3 billion were raised through the sale of Israel State Bonds (at below-market interest rates) . Finally, a major component of the $ 1 billion in foreign private investment that reached Israel in this period was " philanthropic" in nature-private investments by diaspora Jews that would not have been made had the main criterion been profit (Lucas 1 975, 337-40) . The largest single source of capital inflow in the 1 950-1967 period was also premised on the existence of close ties between the Israeli state and world Jewry . The war reparations agreement concluded with West Germany in 1952 provided The Case of Israel 1 65 for the payment of some $820 million to the state of Israel over a twelve-year period (the first payments arriving in 1 953) and was followed by an agreement on personal restitution payments to individual victims of Nazism that by 1 967 brought another $ 1 . 2 billion into the hands ofIsraeli citizens (Lucas 1 975, 338-39). These large capital inflows played a key role in financing Israel' s rapid economic growth. From 1 95 0 to 1 973 Israel was able to maintain an average yearly invest ment rate of 3 0 percent of GNP while maintaining an import surplus equal to 8 1 percent of gross domestic capital formation, with accounts being balanced by the capital inflows (Israel Central Bureau of Statistics, annual). Israel' s rapid economic growth from 1 948 to 1 973 was also facilitated by the large-scale immigration of skilled and unskilled labor. Between May 1 5 , 1 948, and the end of 1 95 1 , 686,739 new Jewish imm igrants settled in the country; and by 1973 total imm igration equaled over 1 . 5 million. These massive labor inflows were not responding to market mechanisms. Many first-generation immigrants experienced a sharp downward mobility relative to their economic status in their country of origin. Moreover, unemployment rates were exceptionally high throughout the period of mass immigration in the 1 95 0s. Instead, immigrants were either ideologically or religiously motivated or pushed there by threats to their personal safety in the sites of emigration. These massive labor and capital inflows gave Israel important cost and resource advantages in the competitive struggle. Israel was able to acquire them at below market prices-that is, interest and wages paid were lower than those that would have been required to induce the same supply through market mechanisms. The Israeli state leadership had a strong nation-building/developmentalist ideology. Moreover, by the time of the establishment of the state, it had a degree of control over resources that allowed it to act on this ideology. By the end of the 1 948 war, ownership or control of capital, labor, and (especially) land was heavily concentrated in the hands of the state. In addition to this physical control over resources, the relative weakness of both the capitalist and working enhanced the state' s power to channel human and material resources. The 1 948 war and subsequent Israeli policy toward Palestinian r"t'n",p"" their property led to a dramatic concentration of land into the hands of the Briefly, the 650,000 Arabs who had left their ' 'usual place of residence" at time since the outbreak of the war (defined as November 29, 1 947, in the L"">.U'''''"LL'''' Property Law of 1 95 0) were classified as "absentees, " and their property subject to confiscation by the state. In addition, laws were put into effect (or car" ried over from the British Mandate) that allowed lands to be seized by the military "in the interests of public safety" and by the minister of agriculture in the in terests of ensuring that all lands were cultivated. The total amount of land involved was vast: the United Nations CCP Refugee Office "estimated that although only a little more than a quarter was considered cultivatable, more than 80 percent of Israel' s total land area of 2 0,850 square kilometers represented land abandoned by Arab refugees" (Peretz 1 958, 1 43). By the time all the nationalization processes had been completed at the beginning 166 t:thnicity: f-'ropelling o r Checking Ad� 'nC�) of the 1960s, over 90 percent of all land 'W 1958; Segev 1986; Kirnrnerling 1983a, 19 \lll.ct This sudden and nearly total control Ov b� t.. �t per t:z; e Sti(: etrunent control (S� 976) . a crucial asset for the political leadershi � 1 p . 1 9 80a , 1980 ; Jif)'l S and economic viability of the state . In til til It� b r was t ' the rapid development of a capital -inteh � fit� ql.t " y s agricul tural sect01iti al t � �t . c " Stv 1' redistributed (for use) m large tracts to e <t P IaI: t0 C onsolidate the 0 fo r i s b a . · � ' It · e a (coop �t 11:" S an overall government plan to achIev provided the g d w as �t · "1 . . . . tu ral all l Jewish polItical control withm the 1 949 ICll\t\J. atly e Th secto r. t <t . . a rt o f at tensive aid to these cooperatives m the fOr ilt·1St' l s � s and collectiveS aS I' dat e II: �l li and marketing . The mandatory channeliIlt 0f I: � i�f" SuffiIciency and COn so d e)(n d t Histadrut Trade Union Federation's lltat l. g af �().it � S .2 The state e)(teCl . �c e , . a e t "' ill� s} , g r �c 1 public control over the agnculturaI S\ltN an ts , technic al <"-' S S h the and reinvested according to the 1eade sh'lJ.s , \'�()lll.hl.l.ltural produce throOg ured r . a ' ) ll s The refugee properties were also mstrul 1):\' S 'V ClyIt'I I: �t' tlle s (e . g . , TnuVa e ol a ted ltel C Jll o tion of the state. O �e of the first �cts Of th lta) i �tQll Uld then be acco . to pass a law allowmg for unrestncted Je e. l) \ylJ. I: al} ().e velopment pi ' . 1'O S1\lv l � y a S new state's extremely precarious econolh: sh I' I \; olidating the strateg1 C was . ' ••().e ta et tion were promoted for a mIxture of "idII\: s·It\J.<tlhh e sh S ' nt e te th e t> ....tl.i g r P nde Jew i one hand, the ingathering of the exiles ft 1()tl. atio n to Israel . V�S 1'� ; raf ' -1",, ''''g . Ot>. t (:al ' I.l.", <lI ' t d' etre of the state. The speed at WhICh al trni ed flows 0 v'on the g"Cl1 1fl l of fears for the safety of some diaspot <t s e Cu rity reasOll S , r a i soll Holocaust survivors stuck in displaced � <t J \y . <ts p I sh diaspora waS th e t � r e sul large part the policy of rapid immigration. r S(jll.s , IS� l.lrsUed was in part th� e th g . . I: . . I U di ll . . shortage m a new state faced WIth a Iong �h\y �'<s � I:<tl" OIh� III p " .'-lIl UllltJes (JOc er ' l "t .. "'IQ eV w tight security situation. fJo \)l'I.) � S� S In Europe) . pOwer The extensive property of Arab refuge tat \V llse to the severe rP�Jl ous1y . at fOIl .-.uJlU J' on. " Of the 3 hi t' <t " of mass Imnllgrat absorptIOn o wed by a co,· y � between 1 948 and the beginning of 1 953 3 f() tl. \y a , for the more than one-third of Israel 's Jewish P S() \y � J �y role in allowillg d aP e blishe nearly a third of the new immigrants (250 ��ti�t� Cl \Vl sh settlements esta 954, 1 l) doned by Arabs . In addition to homes n.��\J\j p ll. ab sentee propertY . 111 and y a and stores were taken over by the custoQ fa��Pl � on absentee propert a i e a b ll s to new immigrants (Peretz 1958, 143)· lvt ll l:lf \\, t ll Settled in urban ar� � s ses , o r disputed border areas, thus giving l: h. Cl qbs�h thOU sand shops , bUS 1�e u d Q . b te rl . f . ·'tee . establIshment of new JeWIsh seUIemen.t ,, (). ItiCl 11. d 1' s tr1 " � p ty pe r d o r an l . s te tellSe tl.<tl fu gee property w as II) Land was not the only critical econolllil: ' e a st t th lized by the state. E�ually i��rt�nt was t�SSet tegic sign ificall C e ta t t ty of investment capItal arnvmg III the ca � l<t hat I: tt 110po in long-term capital inflows (62 percellt I.ttl.tty �t ' s '%.e to be virtuallY IJlo ori the state. Furthermore, during the sau e h()f tl' t;-tCl�antrol over the va st IJl�Ij . "'l � t <' . . b liOll " s t'� tlrw were III the form of umlateral transler 1 19 5 5 to 1 973 $3 6 1 o f CI ", t . . ' a . ' halld s were controlled by the state or publIc ag� ttq <t" the '<l) ll. �rnv ed into the . fl W O S tances by the Jewish National Fund, Ge l<lJ ority of resou rce 11) h se r f e . 0 t trJ.atl. · tCIt Il Iatger proportlOI) ,.,.,it. a1 re'" �l(Q . \)Qt r lt1p l e , institutlO!) lI Ql I srae e a n Pay ments to th � � () t�� {� � t'til() "til: this O\a�i �S " : � l�\V� �Q liv l tll:i�s� �v� t� The Case of Israel 167 state, and intergovernmental transfers (see Israeli Central Bureau of Statistics, annual, balance-of-payments tables). The concentration of investment funds in the hands of the state leadership was of great significance. Since the goal of the state leadership was to consolidate a nation-state rather than to turn a profit, it was willing and able to channel in vestment funds into areas and activities that were deemed a priority from the point of view of political and economic development rather than from the point of view of pure profit criteria. Consolidation of the new state required large-scale in vestments in areas and activities that were either not profitable or were too risky from the individual private entrepreneur's point of view. The state leadership, hOw ever, was able to encourage investments in all the priority areas through its decisions on how to dispense the capital it commanded: to whom, for what economic activity, and at what interest rate. The state's development budget became the major source of investment finan cing for both public and private enterprises (Pack 1 97 1 , 1 44). The Israeli capitalist class was relatively weak, composed of small entrepreneurs with little indepen dent access to capital. As a result, the state was able to control investments, not only through state-owned and Histadrut-affiliated enterprises, but also through disbursements to private entrepreneurs that were earmarked for use on a specific investment considered essential by the government. The weakness of the Israeli working class (Jewish and Palestinian) during the first decade or two after independence also gave the state leadership a great deal of power to channel human resources in accordance with the developmentalist and nation-building ideology of its leaders. During the first three and one-half y ear s of statehood the population of Israel more than doubled, increasing from 64 9 , 600 in May 1 948 to 1 , 404,400 at the end of 1 95 1 . This massive wave of immigration was composed almost entirely of destitute individuals: Jews fro.m Arab countries who were either impoverished in their countries of origin (e the M oroccan Jews) or whose possessions were expropriated by their ments (e. g. , the Iraqi Jews), and concentration-camp survivors and displaced persons ' camps in Europe. Unlike earlier waves of immigration, h a d no useful personal contacts (family who had arrived and settled o r political connections (with the Zionist parties, each of which controlled a of patronage in the form of access to jobs and other resources). Having dependent financial resources, they were totally dependent on the various ment agencies for their immediate subsistence and their " absorption" into economy and society (see Smooha 1 978, chap. 5 ; Segev 1 986, chap. 6) . While the absorption of destitute immigrants meant a commitment of vast sums of m oney in order to support the immigrants until they could be integrated into th e lab or force and become self-supporting, the immigrants ' dependence made it much easier for the state to direct new manpower resources into the economic branches and geographical areas required by the development goals. For exam pIe , the twin goals of population dispersal and import-substitution industrializa t ion were facilitated by the government's ability to send groups of immigrants 168 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? from the transit camps to newly built Development Towns in outlying areas . Here a newly built factory , designed for, say, textiles or food processing, would await their arrival and integration as the unskilled labor force. Certainly , if a large percentage of the new immigrants had had independent financial resources , it would have been far more difficult for the state to persuade the population (through ideological exhortations) to settle in the priority development zones: the border and desert areas and areas of the country where a Jewish majority had yet to materialize. It would also have been far more difficult for the state to persuade the large percentage of immigrants who had been involved in petty-bourgeois urban occupations in their country of origin to suddenly become farmers trying to squeeze a living out of marginally fertile land. The existence of an established trade union federation affiliated with the ruling party furthered the new immigrants' dependence on the state. Responsibility for negotiating wages and working conditions on a national and industrywide scale lay with the Histadrut's central Trade Union Department. The latter's leadership was drawn from the same strata and party from which the state leadership was drawn . (The first prime minister of the state of Israel, for example, was also the first secretary-general of the Histadrut in 1920-David Ben-Gurian. ) Moreover, the ruling party also dominated the majority of Workers' Committees at the fac tory level-shop-floor committees that would have been a natural vehicle for spon taneous trade union activity (Shalev 1984, 37 1 ) . The Histadrut leadership, in turn, trod a fine line between defending th e rights of its members and promoting economic development. The following quote from Pinchas Lavon, a secretary-general of the Histadrut in the 1950s , highlights the Histadrut's policy of cooperating with the government leadership and subordinating the pecuniary interests of its members (e.g . , rising real wages) to the broader goals of full employment, economic growth, immigration absorption, price stabili ty, and national defense: We are a movement which recognizes no fundamental differences between itself and the State, but seeks to shape its policy and its actions on a basis of faithful service to the labour community and the State alike. Such a movement cannot be guided by rule of thumb, nor isolate itself from the outside world, but must consider itself always in the service of the community and from time to time, true to its character, consider how to circumscribe its organizational efforts in its field of activity. (quoted in Preuss 1965 , 1 48) Whether as a result of state-Histadrut cooperation and hegemony over the labor force or due to the high unemployment rates registered throughout most of the 1 950s , a degree of labor tranquility was achieved during the first decade of statehood. Between 1 948 and 1 957 only 7 percent of all strike days were due to strikes and lockouts not authorized by the Histadrut Trade Union Department (Preuss 1 965, 1 68). During the same period strike activity declined almost year ly . Real wages rose yearly, but they did so at both a decelerating rate and at levels consistently below increases in productivity (Silver 1 987). The Case of Israel 169 Finally, there was n o serious challenge from the Arab national minority dur ing the first decades of statehood. The political and economic weakness of the Palestinians allowed the Israeli state to extract important resources from the " Arab sector" and direct these toward the consolidation of the nation-state. Furthermore, it meant that the effective maintenance of control over a discontented and hostile national minority could be achieved at a very low cost to the state (see Lustick 1980a, 1 980b). While the force of Arab nationalism was an unsuccessful but costly and palpable threat to the Zionist movement before 1 948 (Porath 1 977; Silver 1 987), after 1 948 the remnant of the Palestinian Arab community left within the borders of the new Jewish state was far too small, weak, and disorganized to present a serious security threat to the state. For the Arabs remaining within the boundaries of the new state of Israel, the outcome of the 1 948 war meant a sudden and dramatic reversal of status from majority to minority: only 150,000 Arabs remained within the armistice lines, where there had been 800,000 before the conflict (Touma 1985, 74); at the same time their percentage of the total population dropped from 68 percent in 1 947 to 1 4 percent in 1 949 (Smooha 1 978, 68). Among those who left the country were the vast majority of the urban population (Lustick 1 980b, 66), including the economic, political, intellectual, and religious leadership. There were no longer any Arab newspapers, publishing houses, political parties, or labor unions. "The ' center' had fled; the Arabs who stayed were, in effect, the remnants of what had been the 'periphery' of the Arab community " (Lustick 1 980a, 48). The structural weakness of the Arab national minority combined with the state policies of repression, segmentation, and co-optation (see Lustick 1 980a, 1980b) succeeded in keeping discontent under control. During at least the first two decades of statehood the Israeli state did not have to confront mobilized mass-based na tionalist groups or political parties. The Arab national minority hardly ' into the consciousness of most Israelis or constrained the overall actions state, even as their resources were channeled to the development of the Finally, the autonomy of the state vis-a-vis all social forces was "u .�u�,un. by the chronic state of war. The establishment of military rule over Arab was justified by the tense security situation. However, the perceived national security was also an important factor in increasing the state's over the Jewish population. The nature of Israeli borders prior to 1 967 that in a war Israel could not afford to make any mistakes: along the coastal plain where most of Israel's population, economic life, and industry were concentrated, the country was only nine to fifteen miles wide, and thus a slight enemy advance from the West Bank could splitthe country in half, cutting off the Haifa and Galilee regions from the Tel Aviv region and the Negev. In this situation those who pur sued group- or class-based interests risked being accused of endangering national security. This sentiment was made explicit by Moshe Dayan when he commented that ' ' it is impossible to carry two flags at the same time" (quoted in Kimmerling 1 983a, 89-90). 1 70 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? In sum, a strong and motivated state leadership, faced with a weak civil socie ty and control over substantial resources , including non-market-induced capital and labor inflows , was able to promote over two decades of rapid economic growth .3 Yet, as will be argued below, "success" slowly eroded the social basis of further " success. " THE LIMITS OF "SUCCESS, " 1973-1989 In the previous section the integration of the immigrant labor force into an already-existing trade union structure with close links to the ruling party was iden tified as an important factor underlying the relative insulation of the state from class forces . The national trade union bureaucracy 's willingness to cooperate with government economic policy by restraining real wage increases to levels below productivity increases was a key factor allowing for the rapid economic growth of the first two decades of statehood. However, rapid economic growth culminated in long periods of full employment during which continued efforts by the na tional trade union bureaucracy to restrain real wage increases led to explosions in unauthorized strikes and open rank-and-file defiance of the national trade union leadership . The two periods in which the trade union bureaucracy successfully restrained real wage increases to levels significantly below productivity increases ( 1 957- 1962 and 1 97 1 - 1 976) both culminated in a period of rank-and-file revolt. The first rank-and-file revolt led the government to induce an economic reces sion in 1 966- 1 967 . The second and larger revolt, mounted after the October 1973 war, culminated in the ouster of the Labor Party from government and the vic tory of the Likud in 1977 (Shalev 1 984 ; also Friedman 1 976; Wolkinson and Cohen 1 982; Fischer and Jacobson 1 982) . The inability of Mapai/Labor Alignment, while still in power, to induce the working class to join in a social contract with the state through socialist or na tional appeals to sacrifice for the common good was not only, or even mainly, the result of cyclical processes (i . e . , a tight labor market) . Rather, important struc tural changes had taken place in the labor force that made it less likely to accept the subordinate conditions under which it was initially incorporated and that simultaneously gave it increased power to challenge those conditions. As we saw earlier, one of the reasons for the relative freedom to maneuver of the state in the early postindependence years was the total dependence of most of the immigrants on the state for everything from jobs to housing to Hebrew lessons . An elaborate system of patronage was developed through party machines in which resources were exchanged for votes and cooperation with state policies (Aronoff 1 982, 77; Meyer 1982) . The patronage system functioned as long as the immigrants were dependent on the state and felt powerless on their own. However, machine politics entered a crisis as the second-generation immigrants came to numerical dominance in the labor force; educated in the Israeli school system, speaking Hebrew fluently , they were far less dependent and vulnerable than their parents ' generation. 4 The Case of Israel 1 71 The revolt of the working class was sharpened by the strong overlap between class and ethnicity. Mass immigration in the 1 950s "created the preconditions for the mobility of an entire stratum of the [predominantly European/Ashkenazi] veteran population. Ever increasing numbers of the veteran members of society abandoned any positions which required physical labor (in agriculture, industry and construction) and instead moved into 'white collar' occupations which were created as a result of the growth of the government bureaucracy, the building of a professional army, and the growing demand by both the government and the private market for professionals. . . . The places of the veterans who had abandoned physical labor were taken by the new immigrants, primarily those who had immigrated from Asia and North Africa" (Kimmerling 1 983a, 1 1 1 ; also see Bernstein and Swirsky 1 982). Oriental resentment burst into organized protest in the late 1 960s. One ofthe first strong manifestations of discontent was the emergence of the Israeli Black Panther movement in 1 968, a militant organization of Oriental youth formed to protest the inferior social and economic conditions and discriminatory treatment faced by Oriental Jews (Peretz and Smooha 1 98 1 , 5 12 ) . " The Oriental revolt" mushroomed in the 1 970s, its most striking manifestation being in the clear shift ing of votes to the Likud, the right-wing but antiestablishment party. Of those voters born in Asia or Africa, 5 1 percent voted for Labor in 1 969, while only 39 percent did so in 1 973 , 32 percent in 1 977, and 25 percent in 1 98 1 . At the same time, the support for Likud from this group increased from 32 percent in 1 969 to 43 percent in 1 973 , 46 percent in 1 977, and 60 percent in 1 98 1 . Significantly, the percentage of votes going to the Likud was even greater among the second generation. Of voters whose fathers were born in Asia or Africa, the Likud increased its share from 37 percent in 1 969 to 47 percent in 1 973 and over 65 percent in 1977 and 198 1 (Peretz and Smooha 1 98 1 , 5 12 ; also see Cohen The Oriental revolt became a dominant political issue in the 1 970s, Ashkenazi political elite on the defensive. Manifestations of this shifting votes and organized protest movements to urban riots and rising levels-together with the growing strike movement of Ashkenazi and labor, were forceful signals that the state autonomy that had underlain the of rapid economic development had come to an end, and that a new social would have to be forged for sustained growth to reemerge. The Likud's response to this new balance of class forces was decidedly populist. Government spending increased in practically all spheres from export and in vestment subsidies to low-income housing (Project Renewal), basic commodity subsidies, public-sector wages, and increased defense spending and support for settlement activity in the occupied territories. The shekel was allowed to become and remain overvalued, thus stimulating a sharp surge in imports, expecially con sumer durables such as cars and color televisions, and an even sharper deteriora tion of the balance-of-payments situation. These economic policies got the Likud reelected in 1 98 1 , but they also exacerbated the domestic economic crisis, pushing the economy from stagflation to hyperinflation and collapse by 1 98 3 . 1 72 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? The crisis of state autonomy was further fueled by the changing relationship of forces between state and capital as the dependence of private entrepreneurs on the state also declined. The government's policy of providing investment funds and other incentives to all three sectors (private, public, and Histadrut) , while not in creasing the relative weight of the private sector (60 percent of GNP) , has increased its absolute size and strength. Much of the government development budget was permanently transferred to the private sector through grants, subsidies, and tax credits and through unindexed loans and mortgages that effectively turned into grants with inflation (Rosenfeld and Carmi 1976, 138-42; Kimmerling 1983a, 101). This privatization of public wealth gradually increased the sources of capital available to the private sector outside disbursements from the state development budget. As a result, the private sector became increasingly powerful in its ability to determine the overall pattern of economic evolution and to influence state policies to be more in line with its immediate interests (Rosenfeld and Carmi 1976, 142) . Thus, while the undisputed Israeli elite in the first decade of statehood con sisted of those individuals in the commanding heights of the public sector, by the late 1960s and 1970s a new elite was emerging . According to Jon Kimche, the post- 1967 economic boom and the accompanying surge in foreign direct in vestment led to the creation of "a new Israeli elite, a new establishment that to a considerable extent displaced the old, or embraced part of it into its amply financed New Deal . This resulted in a new parallel power-structure to that which had dominated Israel for the previous 30 years . . . . Thus, alongside the old establishment -the political parties, the Jewish Agency , the Histadrut, the Kib butz organizations and the armed forces-there grew up the new elite, which was no longer dependent on the restrictive patronage of the old establishment but was strong enough and had the fmancial resources to exercise its own form of patronage and influence" (quoted in Peretz 1 983, 72-73) . When the Likud came to power, it responded to the increased strength of capitalists by making expensive concessions . Among the economic measures im plemented by the Likud 's first finance minister, Simha Erlich , were ones that had long been desired by Israeli and foreign entrepreneurs-most notably the com plete liberalization of foreign exchange. Israeli nationals were allowed to hold foreign-denominated currency accounts forthe first time. Those with savings were able to (legally) protect themselves against the devaluation of the shekel by holding other currencies. This option was so popular that it created a vicious circle of devaluation and further flight from the shekel. In the context of a stagnating economy (characterized by rising real wages and declining productivity) , quicker and easier profits were to be made by investing capital in speculation against the national currency rather than in productive activities . The house of cards came crashing down along with the Tel Aviv stock exchange in October 1983 . The period of rapid economic development also culminated in the strengthen ing of the weakest social force in Israel, the Arab national minority . Israel 's rapid economic development led to the emergence of (1) a modem industrial proletariat; (2) a class of self-employed artisans and small businessmen; and (3) a large number The Case of Israel 1 73 of young educated professionals. With the growth of these groups, the base of the traditional leadership declined and the basis of a less vulnerable and less depen dent modern nationalist leadership was born. By the mid-1 970s vocal nationalist was widespread both within Israel's pre-1967 borders among Arab citizens . of Israel and among the West Bank and Gaza Palestinians . A stable Arab industrial proletariat emerged in Israel in the second half of the 1960s. With the post-1967-war boom and the incorporation of Palestinian labor from the occupied territories into the lowest rungs of the Israeli work force (e. g. , agriculture, construction, and services), the Palestinian citizens of Israel began to shift rapidly from employment in agriculture and construction to jobs in manu facturing-including the advanced military-related industries. By 1980 manufac turing was their leading category of employment. At the same time, the ratio of Palestinian Arab citizens in skilled proletarian occupations increased steadily, from 2 to 1 in 1974 to 3 . 2 to 1 in 1977 (Makhoul 1982, 78-79, 95). The growing presence of Palestinian Arab citizens in strategic positions in the national divi sion of labor increases their bargaining power. Likewise, the strong demand for . their labor power and the consequently larger numbers with stable employment and income indicate a move away from the unilateral economic dependence that was a key process underlying their social and political weakness.5 The expansion of the self-employed is also indicative of a decline in economic dependence and the emergence of a pool of independent resources in the Arab community that could help sustain political protest. For example, in a mixed Moslem-Christian village studied by Rosenfeld (1964, 1978) , more than one-third of the gainfully employed were self-employed in 1976, compared to less than 15 percent in 1963. For Rosenfeld, "The rise of the number of self-employed, the increased numbers of those with fixed and full-time employment points to inroads into the middle class" and a generally strengthened class position. The result, he concludes, is " that the Arabs have arrived at the point where they to conform, and are capable of resisting (along lines of legitimate political gle according to the democratic procedures of Israel itself) the role allotted by those who administer them" (Rosenfeld 1978, 396-97, 404; see also 1980b, 76-78). Simultaneously with the impact of economic development, political have contributed to the revival of Palestinian national consciousness. The whelming defeat of the armies of the Arab states in the 1967 war provoked a crisis of pan-Arabism and the rise and radicalization of Palestinian particularism (Ajami 1981) . The futility of the Palestinian movement 's strategy of relying on the Arab states to eliminate Israel was dramatically laid bare. A more dynamic Palestine Liberation Organization (PLO) under new and more militant leader ship emerged from the crisis (see Cobban 1984). At the same time, the occupa tion of the West Bank and Gaza by Israel unified the majority of the Palestinian people under one state' s rule, where they had previously been isolated from each other under the rule of three distinct states (Israel, Jordan, and Egypt) , each with vastly different policies toward them (Peretz 1977). Israel's bad performance in 1 74 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? the 1 973 war and the rise of the PLO and the Palestinian issue to prominence in the international arena further encouraged the militancy of Palestinians living under Israeli rule. The combined result of these socioeconomic and political changes has been the growing salience of protest: a shifting of votes from the Labor Party to the Communist Party (Rakkah) , the rise of an independent Arab student organiza tion on university campuses, and mass protest actions such as the "Land Day" general strike called on March 30, 1976 , to protest land expropriations. The Israeli Arab vote for Rakkah increased steadily from 2 3 . 6 percent in the 1965 Knesset election to 37 percent in 1 973 and about half the Arab votes in the 1 977 election . In the 1973 municipal elections the voters in Nazareth, Israel's largest Arab town, chose a Rakkah mayor and a leftist municipal council for the first time. But the greatest challenge to the Israeli state came from the West Bank. In the April 1 976 West Bank mayoral elections , PLO supporters were elected to govern in ten municipalities, including the three principal West Bank towns of Nablus, Hebron, and Ramallah (Peretz 1983, 67 , 72) . The shock of growing Palestinian militancy was among the factors leading to . the defeat of the Labor Party and the right-wing Likud's victory in 1977. High government officials (especially Ariel Sharon as the new minister of defense in 1 9 8 1 and Menachem Milson, the military governor of the territories) set out to destroy the PLO's influence in the occupied territories . They believed that this re quired not only the banning of the pro-PLO nationalist organizations that had developed in the territories (such as the National Guidance Committee) , but also the elimination of the PLO protostate in Lebanon (Sandler and Frisch 1 984, chap. 7). The war against the PLO began after the Likud's reelection victory in 1981 and was carried out in two phases . The first began i n March 1982 with a crackdown on the nationalist institutions and activities in the occupied territories . The sec ond began in June 1 982 when Lebanon was invaded and the war was carried for ward to Beirut with the goal of expelling the PLO entirely from Lebanon. The long-term results, however, were not those anticipated by the architects of the war against the PLO. Israeli forces became bogged down in a quagmire that eventually led to the unilateral withdrawal of Israeli ground forces. Support for the war on the home front wore thin, and conscientious objection among Israeli soldiers became a significant factor for the first time. Israel 's " solution" began to look like the U . S . " solution" in Vietnam-a capital-intensive role for its own troops (i .e . , bombing) , and the organization and support of a surrogate army (the Southern Lebanese Army) for the labor-intensive fighting . Meanwhile, in the occupied territories the outbreak of the largest and most sus tained Palestinian rebellion in December 1988 (the intifadah) made it abundantly clear that a military solution to the Israeli-Palestinian conflict was not being and could not be achieved. Thus the Israelis had poured an estimated $5 billion (Barkai 19 86) down the drain in a war all of whose aims were defeated. The expense of the Lebanese war was yet another phase in the growing economic dependence of Israel on the United States . By the time the Likud relinquished The Case of Israel 1 75 the premiership, approximately 65 percent of total net long-term capital flows and 50 percent of net unilateral transfers were in the form of U. S. aid; another big subsidy arrived as the National Unity government formed in 1984 asked for help in stepping back from the brink of bankruptcy. These funds helped finance a chronic import surplus amounting to more than 100 percent of total gross domestic capital formation (or around 30 percent of GNP) from 1973 on. Finally, the rise of Palestinian militancy, together with the combined outcomes of the 1967, 1973 , and Lebanon wars, led to a precipitous decline in the freedom to maneuver that the state had enjoyed due to the tense security situation and the public's faith that the governing elite could best handle security affairs without interference. Israel's quick and unambiguous victory in the 1967 war and the apparently far more defendable borders created by the absorption of the West Bank, Sinai, Gaza, and the Golan Heights reduced the barriers to the emergence of social movements based on fears of endangering national security. Pent-up demands, especially for increased consumption, burst out in the post -1 967 years. More significantly, " Unification of the ancient Land of Israel led to the shat tering of the political consensus that had precluded exhausting controversy over security issues. Disposition of the territories occupied in 1967 became a major and divisive-issue in Israel" (Meyer 1982, 32). The issue divided and immobi lized the LaborAlignment, which attempted to dodge the issue through vague policy formulations designed to maintain party unity-or at least contain disunity (Yaniv and Yishai 1981, 1117-18). The failure of the governing elite to anticipate the attack by Egypt and Syria in October 1973 (despite repeated warnings in intelligence reports) , and the heavy casualties suffered by Israel as a result, marked a major turning point. Confidence in the government was shattered. The shock of growing Palestinian militancy within Israeli-controlled territory and the international arena further contributed to the crisis of confidence in the government. After the 1973 war groups had previously abstained from interference in security affairs formed vocal forceful pressure groups and social movements. For example, the N Religious Party (NRP) began to express strong interest in security affairs, ly the disposition of the West Bank (the biblical Judea and Samaria). I n leaders of the National Religious Party youth faction became founding 'U','1UJ"'� of the extraparliamentary settlement movement Gush Emunim. The rise of extraparliamentary social movements on the settlement divided and paralyzed the Labor Party government. The Likud government came to power with a strong commitment to these movements' goal of the ' ' unification of the Biblical Land of Israel. " This goal drove the Likud into the Lebanon debacle in an effort to destroy PLO influence in the territories. It also led them into a policy of intensive Israeli settlement in the occupied territories in an effort to achieve de facto annexation (Benvenisti 1984). The National Unity governments since 1984 have again been divided and immobilized. With the governments pressed between effective Palestinian resistance, on the one hand, and heavily armed and committed settlement movements (with which key members of the 176 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? government have strong sympathy), on the other hand, the courage to provide the political leadership necessary to resolve the Israeli-Palestinian conflict has been tragically absent. CONCLUSIONS: THE CONTRADICTIONS OF NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE MODERN WORLD-SYSTEM The"development of underdevelopment" is the norm for noncore states within the world-economy. In part this is because "real development" (i.e., the attain ment and retainment of core status) requires the capacity to concentrate on the most lucrative economic activities within the world division of labor at any given point in time; and this in tum requires a capacity for constant innovation. However, the catch is that core states (and only core states) have the institutional arrangements and accumulated resources (capital, labor, expertise, and infrastructure) necessary to sustain the required stream of innovation in products and production processes. Thus the operation of market mechanisms on a world-scale serves to reproduce the unequal distribution of wealth produced in the world-economy (Arrighi and Drangel 1986). Israel, however, was able in large measure to overcome the limitations im posed by the paucity of market-determined resource inflows because Israel was able to mobilize sizable inflows of capital, labor, and expertise via noneconomic means-most notably via appeals to the religious and nationalist sentiment of diaspora Jewish communities. As was argued earlier, these resources gave Israel the means with which to sustain a period of rapid growth and a process of in novation that made Israel strikingly competitive in certain skill-intensive products. Ironically, the same processes that have allowed Israel to mobilize the resources necessary to achieve two decades of rapid economic growth have unleashed pro cesses that vitiate further attempts at progress. Here I am referring to the mobiliza tion of human and material resources through appeals to nationalist and religious sentiment. The drive to establish a nation-state in a hostile environment called forth the sacrificial energies necessary to establish and consolidate the state and to achieve two decades of rapid economic development. Thus, for example, far from suffering a "brain drain" during the first decades of statehood, Israel was able to attract skilled workers from the diaspora communities. However, na tionalism does not operate as a positive force in a vacuum, but instead comes into conflict with (and indeed provokes) the nationalist responses of others. As Israel became more and more successful in mobilizing human and material resources through nationalist appeals, more and more of those resources had to be directed toward military expenditures to counteract the reaction from com peting nationalist forces. Thus, while the nationalist and religious appeal pulled hundreds of thousands of Jewish immigrants to Israel in the 1950s who contributed to the rapid economic development of the state with their labor and other resources, it necessarily in flamed the conflict with Palestinian and Arab nationalism by creating a large The Case of Israel 1 77 refugee population along Israel's borders.6 Likewise, the combination of na tionalist and religious pride inspired by the successes in the 1967 war, including the occupation of the biblical lands of Judea and Samaria, initially called forth a tremendous surge in immigration and financial support from the diaspora com munities. However, the nationalist and religious upsurge in Israel (and the oc cupation of new territories) intensified the nationalist and religious opposition of the Arab states and the Palestinians. The route to Israel's successful mobiliza tion of human and material resources was also the route to an intensification and growing militarization of the conflict with Arab nationalism. While the available human and material resources grew, they were increasingly channeled into military expenditures. This contradiction brought Israel's economic miracle to an abrupt end. The Likud experience showed that Israel does not have the level of wealth necessary for the simultaneous maintenance of a warfare state and the establishment of a populist social contract that takes into account the strengthened bargaining power of the Jewish capitalist and working classes. The National Unity governments' experience has shown that the working class has become too strong for a strategy of prolonged recession to effectively restore labor discipline and productivity. Like many countries in the semiperipheral zone in the 1970s and 1980s, the work ing class in Israel is as least as strong as its counterparts in core countries, but the state and capital do not have the resources that exist in the core for forging a social contract that simultaneously takes into account this strength and allows for continued economic growth. Meanwhile, the economic crisis, combined with the growing militarization of Israeli society and its continued illegitimacy in the region, was contributing by the mid-1970s to the breakdown of the processes through which Israel had been able to mobilize large-scale, non-profit-oriented inflows of resources from the Jewish diaspora communities. With the combined impact of the intifadah and domestic economic collapse, Israel has begun fer from large-scale emigration and the classic "brain-drain" syndrome. while, diaspora communities are showing signs of growing alienation from (see, e.g., Sheffer 1984). An alternative source of funding has been available, and indeed since 1973 has been a shift to this new and mushrooming source-the U.S. government. Israel strengthened its warfare capabilities in response to the regional conflict; the United States became increasingly willing to [mance Israel-but as a surrogate, warfare state enmeshed in theU. S. global political strategy of East-West conflict and containment. While militarization in response to the regional conflict simultaneously has led Israel to seek additional (''non-J ewish'') sources of funds and has led the United States to see Israel as an attractive ally deserving lavish funding, the growing Israeli dependence on U.S. funds makes it increasingly dif ficult for Israel to resolve the regional conflict or exl£icate itself from the militariza tion that created the need for U.S. funding in the first place. On the one hand, military capacity is precisely the specialty that Israel has to sell to the United States in exchange for economic aid. On the other hand, the expansion of military 178 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? industries in response to the regional conflict has created an Israeli military industrial complex under pressure to export as a result of "economies of scale," which in turn requires a close collaboration with U.S. global strategic interests (see, e.g., Klieman 1985; Mintz 1985). This analysis suggests that the current crisis can only be resolved if Israel can disengage itself from the military conflict. It also suggests that such a disengage ment would not be easy: the two main transnational links on which the Israeli economy has depended are both links that (in very different ways) have promoted the process of militarization. However, without demilitarization, Pa'il's ( 1983, 30-31) grim prediction of an Israel that combines the worst aspects of Northern Ireland and South Africa-" a cruel non-democratic state structure with constant fighting and bloodshed" -becomes more true daily. Most of the "solutions" to the Israeli-Palestinian conflict currently on the political agenda would require massive inflows of resources from core countries. Unfortunately, however, it still remains to be seen whether "peace" can be as strong as a motivation as "war" (hot and cold) for eliciting massive international redistributions of wealth. NOTES This is a substantially revised and shortened version of a paper prepared for the Research Working Group on Semiperipheral States at the Fernand Braudel Center. Many of the assertions made in this paper are more fully documented in the longer version (Silver 1987), available on request from the author. For their comments and criticisms on this and/or earlier drafts, I thank Giovanni Arrighi,Baruch Kimmerling,Art Liebman,William Martin, Don Peretz,Allen Silver,and the members of the Research Working Group on Semiperi pheral States. 1. See,for example,Amsden (1985) on Taiwan,Evans (1979) on Brazil,and Deyo (1987) on the Southeast Asian NICs. 2. The degree of state control over the process should not be exaggerated. Much of the refugee property was seized by homeless new immigrants and returning war veterans who squatted in the empty properties (see,e. g. ,Segev 1986,75-76). In fact,the spon taneous "expropriations" created a situation that encouraged the government to move toward official expropriation. 3. It should be noted that the state's control over resources did not mean that it was free to pursue economic policy without regard for world-market conditions. Rather,the state's success in promoting rapid growth was largely linked to its ability to find niches that is, to channel resources into economic activities that were not subject to sharp com petitive pressures in the world-economy at any given point in time. Israel switched from a primary emphasis on import-substitution industrialization to export-oriented industrial expansion in the late 1950s and early 1960s,while world-market demand was still expand ing rapidly and before competition in industrial exports from low-wage countries became intense. After 1967 the state began to promote advanced technology exports,again a shift in step with world-market conditions as the terms of trade declined for low-technology industrial exports,much as they had for primary products in the previous period. The Case of Israel 179 Israel's unviable textile industry provides an example of the "wrong policy at the wrong time. " Although the Israeli textile industry has been targeted as a development budget priority and has undergone extensive state-subsidized modernization, it has never become a profitable export branch. The main reason for failure appears to be in the nature of the international competition. While Israeli wages for textile workers are significantly lower than those in core countries, the low-wage international competition has been fierce, with a large and growing number of competitors. By contrast, most of Israel's successful ex ports are in products with few or no other low-wage competitors in the international sphere (Silver 1987). 4. Beginning in 1975, for the first time in the life of the collectivity, the majority of Jewish residents in Israel were born in the country (Kimmerling 1983a, 143). 5. Kimmerling (1983a, 72-73) notes what amounts to the "workplace bargaining power" of the Arab strikers, that is, their concentration in the transport industry and their ability thus to paralyze movement in the country. Interestingly enough, it was this kind of power that came from being concentrated in the key sectors of the economy that the theorists and practitioners of Labor Zionism sought to achieve by the creation of a Jewish working class and the "normalization" of the Jewish class structure through the establishment of a self-sufficient Jewish nation-state in Palestine. See especially Ber Borochov ([1906] 1984). On the concept of workplace bargaining power, see Arrighi and Silver (1984). 6. Refugees with their fields near the border became the primary infrltrators during the early years of statehood, often attempting to return to their land permanently or to harvest crops or to get possessions left behind (Peretz 1958, 59). As the refugee problem remained unsettled, both the scale and violence of refugee infrltration and Israeli retalia tion across the border escalated until these tensions spilled over into the 1956 Israel-Egypt war (see Schiff 1985 on escalation of infiltration and retaliation). REFERENCES Abed, George T. 1986. "Israel in the Orbit of America: The Political Economy Dependency Relationship." Journal of Palestine Studies 16, 1:38-55. Ajami, Fouad. 1981. the Arab Predicament: Arab Political 7hought and Practice 1967. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Amsden, Alice. 1985. "The State and Taiwan's Economic Development." In the State Back In, edited by Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda pol, pp. 78-106. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Aronoff, Myron J. 1982. "The Labor Party in Opposition." In Israel in the Begin edited by R. o. Freedman. New York: Praeger. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel. 1986. "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone." Review 10, 1 (Summer):9-74. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Beverly Silver. 1984. "Labor Movements and Capital Migration: The United States and Western Europe in World Historical Perspective." In wbor in the Capitalist World-Economy, edited by Charles Bergquist, pp. 183-216. Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage. Barkai, Haim. 1986. "Reflections on the Economic Cost of the Lebanon War." Jerusalem Quarterly 37:95-106. Ben-Porath, Yoram. 1986. The Israeli Economy: Maturing through Crises. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. 180 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? Benvenisti,Meron. 1984. The West Bank Data Project: A Survey of Israel's Policies. Washington and London: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. Bernstein,Deborah,and Shlomo Swirsky. 1982. "The Rapid Economic Development of Israel and the Emergence of the Ethnic Division of Labour. " British Journal of Sociology 33,1:64-85. Borochov,Ber. [1906] 1984. "Our Platform. " In Class Struggle and the Jewish Nation, pp. 75-103. New Brunswick,N. J. : Transaction Books. Cobban,Helena. 1984. Ihe Palestinian Liberation Organization: People, Power, and Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cohen,Percy. 1983. "Ethnicity,Class,and Political Alignment in Israel. " Jewish Jour nal of Sociology 25, 2:119-30. Deyo,Frederic C.,ed. 1987. The Political Economy ofthe New Asian Industrialism. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press. Evans,Peter. 1979. Dependent Development: Ihe Alliance ofMultinational, State, and Local Capital in Brazil. Princeton,N. J. : Princeton University Press. Fischer,H. ,and C. Jacobsen. 1982. "Unauthorized Strikes and Slowdowns in Israel: An Institutional Evasion of Union Rules." British Journal of Industrial Relations 20,3:342-48. Friedman,Abraham. 1976. "Union Structure and Rank and File Revolt: The Israeli Experience. " Industrial Relations Industrielles 31,2:261-83. Israel Central Bureau of Statistics. Annual. Statistical Abstract of Israel. Jerusalem. Jiryis,Sabri. 1976. The Arabs in Israel. New York: Monthly Review Press. Kimmerling,Baruch. 1983a. Zionism and Economy. Cambridge,Mass. : Schenkman. . 1983b. Zionism and Territory. Berkeley: University of California International Studies Institute. Klieman,AaronS. 1985. Israel's Global Reach: Anns Sales as Diplomacy. Washington, D.C. : Pergamon-Brassey. Lucas,Noah. 1975. The Modern History of Israel. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson. Lustick,Ian. 1980a. Arabs in the Jewish State: Israel's Control of a National Minority. Austin: University of Texas Press. . 1980b. "The Quiescent Palestinians: The System of Control over Arabs in Israel. " In Ihe Sociology of the Palestinians, edited by Khalil Nakhleh and Elia Zureik, pp. 64-83. New York: St. Martin's Press. Makhoul,Najwa. 1982. "Employment Structure of Arabs in Israel." Journal ofPalestine Studies 11,3:77-102. Meyer,Lawrence. 1982. Israel Now: Portrait ofa Troubled Land. New York: Delacorte Press. Mintz,Alex. 1985. "Military-Industrial Linkages in Israel. " Anned Forces and Society 12,1:9-27. Pack, Howard. 1971. Structural Change and Economic Policy in Israel. New Haven: Yale University Press. Pail,Meir. 1983/4. "Zionism in Danger of Cancer. " Parts 1,2. New Outlook (October December:29-34,January: 27-29. Peretz,Don. 1958. Israel and the Palestine Arabs. Washington,D.C. : Middle East Institute. . 1977. "Palestinian Social Stratification: The Political Implications. " Journal of Palestine Studies 7,1:48-74. . 1983. The Government and Politics ofIsrael. Boulder,Colo. : Westview Press. . ___ ___ ___ ___ The Case of Israel 181 Peretz, Don, and Sammy Smooha. 1981. "Israel's Tenth Knesset Elections: Ethnic Up surgence and Decline of Ideology." Middle East Journal 35 :506-26. Porath, Yehoshua. 1977. The Palestinian Arab National Movement, 1929-1939: From Riots to Rebellion. London: Frank Casso Preuss, Walter. 1965. Ihe Labor Movement in Israel. Jerusalem: Rubin Mass. Rosenfeld, Henry. 1964. "From Peasantry to Wage Labor and Residual Peasantry: The Transformation of an Arab Village. " In Process and Pattern in Culture, edited by R. A. Manners, pp. 131-59. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company. ___ . 1978. "The Class Situation of the Arab National Minority in Israel. " Comparative Studies in Society and History 20, 3:374-407. Rosenfeld, Henry, and Shulamit Carmi. 1976. "The Privatization of Public Means: The State-made Middle Class and the Realization of Family Values in Israel." In Kin ship and Modernization in Mediterranean Society, edited by 1. G. Peristiany, pp. 211-34. Rome: Center for Mediterranean Studies, American Universi.es Field Staff. Safran, Nadav. 1981. Israel: The Embattled Ally. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Sandler, Shmuel, and Hillel Frisch. 1984. Israel, the Palestinians, and the West Bank. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books. Schiff, Ze'ev. 1985. A History of the Israeli Army, 1874 to the Present. New York: . Macmillan. Segev, Tom. 1986. 1949: The First Israelis. New York: Free Press. Shalev, Michael. 1984. "Labor, State, and Crisis: An Israeli Case Study." Industrial Rela tions (Berkeley) 23, 3:362-86. Sheffer, Gabriel. 1984. "The Uncertain Future of American Jewry-Israel Relations." Jerusalem Quarterly 32:66-80. Silver, Beverly. 1987. " Class and Nation in the Making of the Israeli State. " Paper prepared for the Research Working Group on Semiperipheral States, Femand Braudel Center. Smooha, Sammy. 1978. Israel: Pluralism and Conflict. Berkeley: University of Califor nia Press. Touma, Emile. 1985. "The Political Coming of Age of the 'National Minority.' " Jour nal of Palestine Studies 14, 2:74-83. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979. The Capitalist World-Economy. New York: University Press. r'�_1.._'.l Wolkinson, B. W., and A. Cohen. 1982. "Use of Work Sanctions in Israeli Disputes." British Journal of Industrial Relations 20, 2:231-46. World Bank. 1989. World Development Report. New York: Oxford University Yaniv, A. , and Y. Yishai. 1981. "Israeli Settlements in the West Bank: The Intransigence." Journal of Politics 43, 4:1105-28. 10 ETHNIC DIVISIONS AND STATE�CENTERED DEVELOPMENT: MALAYSIA AND NIGERIA COMPARED Paul M. Lubeck and Donna Rae Palmer WHAT IS THE COST OF ETHNIC DIVERSITY? In world-systems theory it is a truism that all successful semiperipheral states must mobilize nationalism as a social force to construct cultural integration and to discipline bureaucratic and social organizations. Indeed, history suggests that state-directed nationalism is necessary and determinant because it is critical for local capital accumulation, for the forging of alliances between capitalists and state technocrats, and, ultimately, for achieving upward mobility within the global division of labor-the capitalist world-economy (Evans 1979; Wallerstein 1979). In an ideal world ethnonational cultural identities overlap perfectly with the ter ritorial boundaries of the nation-state. Commonly, however, this ideal is lized. Oftentimes a state elite must "socially construct" a national' redefining existing ethnic boundaries through manipulation of religious, and cultural symbols or reconstruct one from diverse ethnic sources or The Mexican postrevolutionary political elite, for example, mobilized . port for state-centered industrialization by creating a new ethnonational that glorified Mexico's pre-Columbian past (Hamilton 1982, 138). Today this symbolic construction of''pastness" is personified by the appellation of opposi tion leader "Cuauhtemoc" Cardenas, son of the great populist president. 1 Since nationalism is an invaluable resource for mobilizing cultural and material resources for state-centered industrialization, multiethnic states are handicapped before bolting from the starting gate. To be sure, Malaysia and Nigeria are not alone, for ethnic diversity is widespread among aspiring semiperipheries. 2 If one examines today's most celebrated semiperiphery, South Korea, the contribution and power of ethnonational homogeneity are readily apparent. Let us examine this ideal case from a comparative perspective so as to highlight the cost of ethnic diversity borne by multiethnic states. 184 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? SOUTH KOREA: THE ORIGIN AND ADVANTAGE OF ETHNIC HOMOGENEITY Though lacking rich natural resources, South Korea owes no small part of its unrivaled success to a common language and national culture that were institu tionalized early by a Confucian-bureaucratic state that resisted waves of foreign invaders. The premodern Korean identity, in turn, was reinforced by the process of' 'reactive ethnonationlism" under the Japanese colonial occupation (1910-1945) (Hechter 1975). Unlike the British colonial states in Malaya and Nigeria, the im perialism of the Japanese was not indirect; rather, the Japanese colonial state in nded profoundly into the social and economic relations of both Korea and Taiwan. Interestingly, modern Korean nationalism was strengthened by the dialectical in terplay between the myth of premodern cultural unity and postwar reactive na tionalist resentment directed against Japanese imperialism. After the 1961 coup military-led strategists articulated a reconstructed interpretation of Korean na tionalism that was cohesive, disciplining, and "developmentalist," thus enabling them to harmonize the strategic objectives of indigenous capitalists and state technocratic elites. No relationship has more explanatory power for Korea's suc cess than the tightly articulated relationship between local capital and state technocrats.3 A widely shared nationalist consciousness, directed and institu tionalized by state planners, supplied the cultural mortar for this alliance in Korea as well as in other success stories such as Brazil and Taiwan. This contrasts sharply with the colonial experience of Nigeria and Malaysia, where, for reasons we shall explore, the colonial encounter with the world economy redefined ethnic groups and intensified communal antagonisms. Not only did colonial rule stimulate mutually antagonistic, reactive ethnonationalisms within Malaya and Nigeria, but the combined interaction of the colonial export economy and the administrative policy of the colonial state created an invidious ethnic division of labor in both colonies. Moreover, in Nigeria, more than in Malaya, semiautonomous regions were constructed, each possessing a distinct export-commodity relationship to the world economy and virtually no transethnic integrative institutions. Most significantly for our study, ethnic divisions in Malaysia and Nigeria overlapped with the social division of labor. In both cases the most economically backward but most politically cohesive groups controlled the postindependence state apparatus, while the more economically advanced groups dominated the higher niches of the indigenous economy. Instead of har mony in an alliance of accumulation, ethnic competition between state elites and economic elites undermined the thrust of nationalist cohesion, producing a stag nant state sector, a rentier bourgeoisie, and a disarticulated economy (Jesudason 1989; Lubeck 1986; Horowitz 1985). Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 185 ETHNONATIONALISM: CULTURAL AND STRUCTURAL EXPLANATlONS Accordingly, the central thesis of this chapter is that in order to evaluate the cost of ethnic diversity for semiperipheral development in our two case studies, one must first grasp the social reconstruction of ethnicity during the colonial en counter, a period when the ideologies and practices of "indirect rule" dictated a particular ethnic division of labor and relative regional autonomy. Only after understanding how colonial rule reconstructed ethnic identities in Nigeria and Malaysia can one suggest a structural explanation for ethnic antagonisms that have frustrated their achievement of a semi-industrial and semiperipheral role in the global division of labor. Throughout, we argue that ethnic groups or "peoples" are not primordial, natural, unchanging, or essential identities. Instead, any identity expressed as a "people" is the product of the dialectical interplay among several structural forces and an inherited or invented cultural system that must be repro duced socially in households at a particular moment in the evolution of the capitalist world-economy (Wallerstein 1987; Brass 1985).4 Obviously, we intend to avoid the essentialist reasoning employed by our historical-political subjects, that is, their understandable tendency to reifY the essence of their''Imagined Communities," to quote Benedict Anderson's felicitous phrase (Anderson 1983). Thus we must define the structural forces that, we theorize, best explain the affirmation of politically significant ethnic identities from a vast array of overlapping, contradictory cultural possibilities and social boundaries. Following Marx, we agree that identities are socially created but''not as they please." Such identities are formed under structural constraints''transmit ted from the past" (Marx 1963, 15). Accordingly, we argue that three structural forces interact with cultural legacies derived from kinship, religion, language, and custom to form the dominant ethnic groups in contemporary Malaysia Nigeria. These are (1) the historical relationship of groups to the cycles, cesses, and institutions of the capitalist world-economy, including exchange· tions, export-commodity production, and the diffusion of global cultural· tions such as language, religion, and print literacy; (2) the positive and impact of the colonial state on the boundaries, political organization, income op portunities, and cultural practices of subjected groups; and (3) the relationship between the ethnic and the social division of labor (i. e., class relations) within the colony, especially how each group's access to market opportunities was ad vanced or retarded by the state and the world division of labor. STRUCTURES, CULTURES, AND ETHNIC OUTCOMES: MALAYSIA AND NIGERIA COMPARED Given the space limits constraining this study, only the most salient ethnic groups, structural processes, and historical phases can be analyzed in the detail 186 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? they deserve. For Nigeria, where hU:1dreds of possible ethnic affiliations exist among more than 100 million citizens, the pivotal actors are the Muslims, Hausa speakers, who tend to control the military and the state, and the Yoruba , who are the most economically and educationally advanced group, but who are nearly evenly divided between Christian and Muslim affiliations. The latter dominate the southwestern states and the former the northern states. In Malaysia, where a population of about 16 million enjoys a higher per capita income, the Muslim Malays control the state apparatus, while the Chinese control indigenous capital. 5 The peoples from both countries participated in transnational trading empires during several distinct phases since the sixteenth century before incorporation into the capitalist world-economy. Coastal enclaves gave way to formal British imperial control during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Interac tion with the world-economy and the colonial policy of "indirect rule" advanced the economic and technical advantages of the Chinese and the coastal Yoruba, while protecting the aristocratic (prebendal) privileges of the Malay and Hausa rulers over their respective peasantries. Islam was promoted as a cultural mode of social control and a buttress for noncapitalist ruling groups in both cases. Despite the greater size of Nigeria and the greater wealth and presence of com mercial rubber plantations in Malaya, both exported tropical commodities as well as tin. Later both became dependent upon petroleum and natural-gas exports. Post-World War II politics generated a similar portrait: Nigerian southerners (e.g., Yoruba and Igbo) and Malay Chinese and Indians who were radical nationalists demanded independence in a unitary state, only to be confronted by unified but reluctant Hausa and Malay elites who feared being overwhelmed by the former rivals in the economy, in the civil service, and in the proposed unitary state con stitution. Predictably, the British opted for a federation as the "compromise of independence," an arrangement that soon degenerated into extensive communal rioting in 1966 in Nigeria and in 1969 in Malaysia. In each case resentment by the more economically backward, preponderantly Muslim groups ignited attacks on the more advanced Chinese and southern Nigerians, especially Igbos. The Nigerian civil war soon erupted, and civilian rule was suspended temporarily in Malaysia. State centralization, greater power for security forces, and greater state involvement in the economy characterized the policies of the 1970s. In terestingly, the political cohesion of the more backward groups, not unlike the . Afrikaners of South Africa, enabled them to exert greater authoritarian control over the state apparatus. High commodity prices, especially for petroleum, buoyed the economy through the inefficiencies wrought by redistribution and indigeniza tion of industry, policies implemented by both governments during the high tide of economic nationalism. Hence there are obvious and consistent similarities in these cases. Key dif ferences are important also. The Yoruba are indigenous and not "defined" as immigrants like the Chinese and Indians. The level of social development is more balanced and the economy more advanced in Malaysia than in Nigeria. Fiscal responsibility and economic nationalism are more restrained in Malaysia. The Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 187 number of ethnic groups in Nigeria requires greater pluralism; there are some cross-cutting social linkages in Nigeria such as the Islamic affiliation of at least half the Yoruba and the affirmation of a common racial (i.e., physical) identity. Most importantly, there is a long-standing and significant merchant-industrial bourgeoisie among the Hausa, centered in the Kano-Kaduna region. In Malaysia race, religion, language, and ethnicity overlap almost totally and thus reinforce the social division of labor to a degree not found in Nigeria. With this overview in mind, let us explore how these three structural factors interacted within distinct culturally defined groups during the colonial conjunc ture. We emphasize that these structural factors produced a remarkably similar ethnic separation of indigenous political and economic power. BEFORE COLONIALISM: THE CONSTRUCTION OF ETHNICITY Nigeria Contact with the Muslim world via long-distance trade and the Atlantic trade helped define ethnic identities. In the Hausa-speaking cities of northern Nigeria, the Muslims formed distinct communities with specialized occupational groups much valued by indigenous rulers for their trade, wealth, literacy, and lclowledge. Unified by a reform movement, the Fulanijihad, a vast number of communities and walled city-states were unified in the early nineteenth century into a largely Rausa-speaking empire that remained external to the capitalist world-economy (Ajayi and Crowder 1976). It was this ethnic identity that the British confronted when the caliphate was conquered in 1903-1904. Nonetheless, the divisions between Muslim and non-Muslim and aristocrats and commoners, as well as peting elite lineage affiliations, were more important sources of political tion and social cleavage than the subsequent''tribal" ethnic identities that "constructed" by a new colonial discourse when Nigeria became a feder ony (Lubeck 1986). If the northern Muslim groups remained external to the capitalist economy, thus allowing the Muslim state and belief systems to incorporate integrate diverse ethnic groups into the Muslim Hausa, southern Nigerians ed a different path. The two major ethnic groups of southern Nigeria, the Y and the Igbo, existed as language groups but not as ethnonational or unified political groups under a single authority. Town and clan rather than emirate and Muslim empire were the widest political affiliations in the south. Caught between the pressure from the Muslim expansion in the north and the changes in economic power arising from the slave trade, the confederation of Yoruba towns known as the Oyo Empire collapsed early in the nineteenth cen tury. Hence civilwar, fed by the slave and firearms trade with the world-economy, shattered the previous confederation and created new lineage-organized towns but did not create a common ethnonational (political) identity among the Yoruba 188 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? speakers. The effective political identity was, and still remains to a significant degree, the Yoruba city-state and not the language group as a nation. Customs, land-tenure practices, and dialect differences distinguished the separate towns. That the British conquerers played a role as peacemakers from 1886 until the declaration of a protectorate underscores the destructive impact of nineteenth century intra-Yoruba warfare (Lloyd 1968, 1971). Formal colonialism began when the coastal Yoruba town of Lagos was annexed as a crown colony in 1861, functioning as a commercial center for the palm-oil trade and a base for missionaries among the Yoruba. The origins of the educa tional advantage enjoyed by the Yoruba began when the missionaries translated the Bible into Yoruba and thereby provided an intra-Yoruba medium upon which "print nationalism" made its contribution to the colonial construction of the Yoruba (Wallerstein 1984). Christianity spread via Yoruba written in roman script. Emancipated slaves (i.e., the Saro) formed a protobourgeoisie, integrating rival Yoruba towns through evangelization and communicating their "peopleness" in the new script. Thus biblical Christianity provided a written medium of com munication and a symbolic form to express an emerging trans-Yoruba identity. The word "Yoruba" is not a Yoruba word; it is originally of Hausa extraction. The myth of descent from Oduduwa never enjoyed priority as a political identity above the Yoruba town. Finally, proximity to the Atlantic trade, together with missionary-sponsored educational investments, laid the foundation for Yoruba preeminence in state technocratic roles, commercial and industrial leadership, and dominance over the modern economy in general. Prior to colonial rule, therefore, the modem ethnic identities-Hausa, Yoruba, and Igbo-were not operative political identities. Intraethnic conflict was more significant, especially among the southern groups, than conflict between these groups. Only with the colonial export economy, migration to new urban centers, and the definitions asserted by the colonial state did "modern" ethnic identities emerge, taking on the new political meanings and new assertions of''peoplehood." Malaysia As in the case of Nigeria prior to incorporation and formal colonial rule, in stitutional borrowing from the great traditions (Hinduism and Islam) enabled cen tralized states to form in Malaysia from autochthonous groups. Yet neither large scale migration nor transformation of production systems arose from their in volvement in administered long-distance trade. Without a strict ethnic division of labor so characteristic of the colonial economy, both Malaysia and Nigeria witnessed the gradual assimilation of now-hostile groups into tribute-paying but legitimate local communities distinguished by possessing a unique origin. Observe how similar ethnic relations were in both cases prior to incorporation into the world-economy as a commodity exporter. Prior to formal incorporation as a British colony, the Malayan Peninsula was not divided into Malay and Chinese communities. Because it was situated midway Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 189 on the India-China trade route, the proliferation of trading ports and the conse quent influence of traders originating from the great empires of India and the Muslim world generated diverse cultural communities. Only later, under different structural conditions, do we discover the Malays, Chinese, and Indians who were to be consolidated into more or less strict ethnic identities during the colonial era. Believers in primordial ethnicity should examine the origins of the groups who became the contemporary "Malays": that is, those groups who inhabited the riverine villages (kampongs) that proliferated during the period of Asian trade. The inhabitants of these villages were by no means homogeneous. They were, in the early periods of settlement, immigrants from various regions within the Indonesian archipelago who displaced the aboriginal groups, the Orang Asli, forc ing them inward. They included among their ranks Minangkabau (Sumatrans), Bugis (Celebesians), Korincha, Rawa, Mandiling, Batak, Javanese, and Achehnese (Hua Wu Yin 1983). Generally, each of these groups settled in different areas, maintaining separate Hindu-style political kingdoms, local dialects, and sociopolitical identities. Although originally descended from the southern provinces of China, the various Malay groups of the archipelago and the Malayan Peninsula were more influenced culturally by the missionary-minded Indians than the Chinese, who were content to collect tribute from the Malays rather than to convert them. The commonality of Hinduism and a shared Malay language of trade is indicative of the social con struction of ethnic identity among the Malay peoples via contact with the world system of the Asian trade. Later, quite consistently, the Malay ethnic identity became inextricably linked with Islam rather than East Asian ethical systems (Gullick 1958). Attempts by Persian, Arabian, and Egyptians traders and missionaries to con vert the rulers of Sumatran kingdoms to Islam were generally unsuccessful, but the Muslim Indians from Gujerat, perhaps because of closer cultural affinity, were successful. Intermarriage between ruling families and proselytizing by a of Islamic religious scholars-originally Sayyids from Mecca, Persia, and and later indigenous Malay or Jawi pupils-spread the Muslim faith Sumatra and Malaya (Nagata 1984). The conversion of the sultan of Malacca to Islam in the sixteenth century coin". cided closely with the beginnings of contact with the European trading This coincidence had a universalizing effect, on the one hand, but promoted ethnic particularism, on the other. Ensuing political and economic antagonism between the Muslim rulers and the Europeans helped create an oppositional identity (believer/infidel) that stimulated a tightening of bonds between the sultans of the various states of the peninSUla as they vied for control of trade and tribute against the Portuguese and Dutch invaders. The intersection of the two processes Islamization and European mercantilism-helped to solidify a Malay state system and a political identity among the ruling classes throughout the peninSUla. In a process of reactive ethnonationalism these forces gradually socialized subordinated groups into the Muslim Malay identity. 190 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? Besides contributing to the social construction of the Malay identity, British incorporation of Malaya promoted a distinct economic role for Chinese traders as intermediaries between the hinterland and the Straits Settlements of the em pire. Even before formal colonialism, the global economy was structuring the ethnic division of labor (Lim Mah Hui 1980). Yet the Chinese traders in no way constituted a single ethnic group. They were spatially segregated and socially organized in communities distinguished according to affiliations derived from clan, dialect, and region of origin in China. Trade specialization followed dialect groups: Hokkiens with rubber, Teochews with rice importing, Cantonese with restaurants, import-export trade, and tin mining, and the Hakkas with tin mining and medicine (Jesudason 1989, 24). For European capitalists, the initial economic advantages arising from their fostering a competitive system for obtaining local products proved to be quite costly during the mid-nineteenth century. The demand for tin in the European capitalist world-economy stimulated intraethnic conflict among the rapidly increasing population of Chinese mining communities, conflict that necessitated the imposition of formal colonialism by the British in 1874. THE COLONIAL CONSTRUCTION OF ETHNICITY The Division of Labor in Nigeria If the conquest of Yorubaland was gradual and accompanied by missionaries, the incorporation of the northern Muslim and non-Muslim areas was swift and met with Islamic resistance (Mahdism) that reduced the influence of missionary education for Hausa speakers. From the very beginning, the northern, prebendal feudal states and their ruling classes were supported by colonial administrators who identified quite romantically with the noble life-styles of the Muslim aristocracy. Indirect rule blocked the progressive aspects of the market economy, constrained access to capital, reduced incentives for indigenous capital accumula tion, and increased the tax burden of the commoner classes, the talakawa. Guided by the doctrine of indirect rule, the colonial state institutionalized a distorted but functionally necessary vision of aristocratic privilege that was wedded to an authoritarian "Native Authority" system. Abuses by the latter bureaucracy were sanctioned by the colonial interpretation of Islam. Further, the Anglo- Muslim aristocratic alliance extended the printing and use of the Hausa language, especially in the colonial army. Hausa was the language of administration even among non Muslim, eventually Christian, groups in the so-called Middle Belt of the Nor thern Region. Quite unintentionally, modern rail and motor roads aided Muslim mercantile capital and facilitated urban forms of Islamic affiliation. "Ruling along native lines," as Lord Lugard instructed his residents, meant, in practice, sup porting the authoritarian and corrupt rule of a rentier ruling class, accepting its definitions of Islamic prerogative, and encouraging ethnic tensions by segregating southern ethnic groups in cities and discriminating against them in myriad ways in the interest of stability (Lubeck 1986; Paden 1974). Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 191 At least one-third of the northern provinces were non-Muslim, and even though the majority of colonial army recruits came from the Middle Belt, the ad ministrative language was Hausa. Most importantly, indirect rule created a con servative, romantic alliance between colonial administrators and Muslim aristocrats that institutionalized backwardness by undermining innovation in education, health, and industry. By increasing ethnic segregation of southern groups in cities, by exacerbating regional imbalances, by discriminating against the talakawa in op portunities for modern education, and by failing to prepare the region for postwar self-government, indirect rule was an immediate cause of the Nigerian civil war. At the same time, the colonial state unified the Muslim groups from Borno and the emirates of the Sokoto caliphate, thus creating a northern Muslim ethnic identity together with other Muslim groups such as the Nupe and the Yoruba of Ilorin. Virtually all spoke Hausa as well as indigenous languages. Given the hun dreds of ethnic groups in the less developed areas of the northern provinces and the limited utility of these identities in new urban situations, new communal iden tities were defined by conversion to Islam or Christianity, while individuals acknowledged an original or even a subtribal lineage identity in other contexts. United by a common governor of Nigeria, but in practice administered separately as the northern and southern provinces, each with different legal systems and "native" representative councils, the colonial state literally constructed regionally based ethnic identities. By 1939 export-oriented marketing boards mediating pro ducers with the world-economy also corresponded to what would become distinct regions-Northern, Western, and Eastern-dominated by the Hausa, Yoruba, and Igbo, respectively. Export commodities corresponded to the respective regions: peanuts and cotton in the north, cocoa in the west, and palm products in the east. Even prior to the time nationalist sentiments were activated as social movements, therefore, new ethnic identities had emerged that did not exist in the precolonial period. Such identities were the constructs of colonial state policy, ditfer'en1tial access to Western education and hence to civil-service employment, and, ly, distinct export-commodity relationships to the world-economy . .uLlHU',", " sions were quite literally overdetermined. The postwar nationalist emerged in the Southern Region, led by the Western-educated professional dIe classes who were now identified as Yoruba or Igbo (Coleman 1958). trary to the south, the members of the Muslim aristocracy were latecomers nationalism, preferring instead to maintain their alliance with the British The Division of Labor in Malaysia By developing an export-oriented plantation economy and by allowing the Chinese to organize tin mining, colonial Malaya departed from the experience of Nigeria. On the other hand, the colonial state institutionalized indirect rule, reinterpreted Islamic prerogatives for the benefit of the ruling aristocracy, and encouraged ethnic segregation by increasingly ossified definitions of community. For the majority of peasants, indirect rule institutionalized economic backwardness 192 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? in the interest of short-term stability. Hence the differences did not prevent an invidious ethnic division of labor from forming since it was perceived as natural, not to mention advantageous, for political control in the mind of the colonial administrator. The imposition of colonial rule proceeded swiftly in the heavily Chinese populated tin-mining states that were combined to form the Federated Malay States (FMS) under a centralized administration by the end of the nineteenth century. The twin objectives of formal British colonial policy, to "preserve" Malay society via indirect rule and to expand the colonial export economy, dictated the develop ment of an ethnic division of labor between the Chinese and Malay populations. The wealthy Chinese congregated in the FMS. Here they were entrenched in plantation agriculture and tin mining, largely because of their virtual control of immigrant labor and culturally organized institutional forms of capital accumula tion. Hence they were positioned to benefit immediately from the colonial state's financing of infrastructural development and subsequent economic expansion. Though the majority of Chinese immigrants had been recruited under strong com munal arrangements for the tin mines, in many cases they gained some oppor tunity for mobility to higher occupations. Indeed, the centralizing tendency of the colonial state gradually reduced the power of communal control over workers. Such economic benefits were not forthcoming for the Malays, however. Hav ing lost their major source of revenue from the enterprising Chinese, Malay aristocrats (and later some commoners) were placated through co-optation into the newly created Malay civil service or were given pensions for holding tradi tional offices within the state (Gullick and Gale 1986, 84). The Malay peasantry was placed in the precarious position of having lost traditional forms of support for land development through feudal arrangements while, at the same time, hav ing their physical mobility constrained by the introduction of backward land policies that discouraged investment or capitalist relations of production (Hing Ai Yun 1986). Take, for example, the rubber boom beginning in 1910: the oc cupational segregation of the Malays within the subsistence agricultural sphere was sealed by the passage of the Malay Land Reservation Act (1913). Designed ostensibly to protect the Malay peasant from alienating subsistence farmland for quick profits, especially to potential non-Malay landlords, this state colonial policy prohibited the planting of rubber on Malay lands and thus left the majority of Malays with no choice but to remain subsistence rice producers (Lim Teck Ghee 1977, 1984). Hence the ethnic specialization of Malay rice producers resulted not from natural choice but from state policy. The political compromise between the British and the Malay aristocracy in cluded a promise by the former not to interfere in matters of Malay custom (adat) and religion; thus the elite Malays maintained some traditional forms of social control. No such political appeasement was deemed necessary for the Chinese population, as they were perceived by the British to be temporary residents who would eventually return to China. By the time it became clear to the British that local-born Chinese had no intention of emigrating to the political and economic Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 193 uncertainty of China during the depression decade, the colonial state response of restricted immigration was useless. Attempts by the British to grant citizen ship rights to the disenfranchised Chinese were thwarted by the politically en trenched Malay elite. This was especially true of upper-class Malays involved in the administration of states outside of the FMS, where the political elite was more closely associated with the Islamic tradition and had been less directly bound by British administrative control. Isolated as a backward, subsistence region in a colonial situation marked by a strict division of labor even in the more economically advanced FMS, this area provided the political leadership for the early phases of the Malay nationalist movement (Gullick and Gale 1986). As in Nigeria, where the regions possessed even wider powers, the combination of uneven socioeconomic development across regions, the institutionalization of backwardness as a prop for aristocratic clients, and ethnic segregation policies generated an ethnic division of labor. 6 NATIONALISM AND THE COMPROMISE OF INDEPENDENCE Thus far we have argued that involvement in the world division of labor is associated with regional and hence ethnic specialization. In the cases of Nigeria and Malaysia, the colonial state allied itself with prebendal feudal classes via in direct rule and retarded the development of market forces in productive relations. Colonialism, therefore, was the historical moment when, through the interaction of agency, structure, and culture, ethnic boundaries expanded to include former ly remote, even hostile or rival communities. Moreover, colonial state and economic processes introduced new concepts that, once melded and applied locally, created new ethnonational loyalties. In turn, elites and their propagandists sought to assert the primordial nature of the new bonds. Often constructing boundaries around religion, language, and region, they went beyond the clan, town, and local linguistic group and defined a new ethnonational identity. Once colonial" ministrators began discussing the terms of political independence, elites ized these new loyalties into political parties, thus sealing the fate of ethnic daries indefinitely. Mobilizing their new nationalist identities, political then demanded that the transition serve their respective political and material in;' terests. Those who played an inferior role in the colonial division of labor or who became relatively more backward due to indirect rule sought exclusions from normal liberal democratic practice in order to guard authoritarian prerogatives. Of course, those who dominated the market and superior roles. in the colonial division of labor draped their demands in competitive values. To transfer power, therefore, required asserting constitutional compromises to protect key interests of the Anglo-Muslim aristocratic alliances. In retrospect, these compromises not only set the stage for communal violence but weakened the central state and any chance for a modern nationalist movement so necessary for a transition to semiperiphery. 194 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? Nigeria Both Igbo and Yoruba politicians spearheaded the demand for independence after World War II. Interestingly, the Yoruba movement originated from the founding of a pan-Yoruba cultural society, Egbe Omo Oduduwa (the descendants of Oduduwa, the mythical progenitor of the Yoruba peoples). The Igbos under Azikiwe attempted a genuine nationalist political party, the National Council of Nigerian Citizens (NCNC) , but they failed to overcome British hostility, their rival's distrust, regional power brokers, and the lack of integration from the col onial period. Pressure for independence produced a bevy of constitutions with varying degrees of decentralized power for the three regions. Not surprisingly, northern Muslim elites rejected rapid independence, fearing the domination from more advanced southern groups and the effect of radical democracy on their hold over the talakawa and minority groups in the northern provinces. The compromise of independence created a weak federation with three semiautonomous regions; each, in turn, was dominated by a major ethnic group that discriminated against its respective regional minorities. The relationship to the world-economy also figured importantly because with self-government each region's marketing-board surplus, now fat from the Korean War boom, fell under the control and patronage of each region's dominant ethnic elite. By the time of independence in 1960, the Northern Region was recognized as the most populous only because of the inclu sion of non-Muslim, non-Hausa peoples who resented aristocratic Muslim domina tion. This solution reflected the support of the British for their conservative allies and enabled the Muslim elites from the north to form an alliance with the Igbo against the Yoruba at the federal level while strengthening their autocratic con trol over the Northern Region (Coleman 1958; Diamond 1988). A weak federal government, strong regions that discriminated against outsiders, electoral fraud, and a disputed census set the stage for a military coup in January 1966 in which the northern Muslim leadership and its southern allies were assassinated. Since the coup leaders were perceived as Igbo, two pogroms were launched against Igbo living in northern towns. The Nigerian civil war followed when the Eastern Region declared independence as the nation of Biafra. With the demise of Biafra, the Igbos retreated after their loss, and the Yoruba became the unrivaled economic and technocratic elite during the postwar period. Hindsight confirms that British colonial administrative policy, the educational imbalance, the invidious ethnic division of labor, and the regional enclave linkages to the world-economy created the structural basis for new and antagonistic ethnona tionalist identities. Worse still, the constitutional arrangements for independence literally overdetermined ethnic conflict by supporting the antidemocratic domina tion of the northern, Hausa-speaking ruling class over the federation. The col onial compromise created a state apparatus that only exacerbated ethnic division and dissipated the potential creative energy of Nigerian nationalism. Rather than integrating diverse ethnic groups, the colonial state and export economy actually isolated them by creating separate dependent relationships to the world market. Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 195 In retrospect, while indirect rule redefmed the boundaries of ethnonations within regions, it also increased the antagonism between groups in the modern urban sector as well as fostering a technically backward peasantry. To some degree, the centralization of the federal state after the civil war reduced ethnic tension and brought class tensions to the fore. But the traditional ethnic blocs reasserted themselves in the elections for the Second Republic (1979) and again in 1983. Malaysia In Malaya the boundaries of the ethnic division of labor constructed by col onialism were strained during the global economic depression of the 1930s. The bust in the tin-export economy produced significant squatting on Malay agricultural land by displaced Chinese, who subsequently demanded political rights (Lim Teck Ghee 1984). The squatting also created a structural base for Chinese guerilla ac tivity. In response to heightened Malay fears, the colonial government enacted the Aliens Ordinance, which discontinued immigration by 1938, but by this time, a permanent non-Malay settlement existed that demanded economic and political rights. Political parties of various ideologies burgeoned among the local-born Chinese, and labor militancy increased. Among the Malays a small professional and commercial trading class appealed to Islamic notions of anti-imperialism and protested the economic domination of the Chinese and foreign capital. Still another group, a radical nationalist Malay faction, allied itself with the Indonesian in dependence movement, opting for a pan-Islamic identity. But the members of the elite chose to renegotiate their alliance with the British. English�educated Malays and the aristocracy, frustrated by their slow incorporation into the civil service, which was compounded by retrenchment in public expenditure, decried "special rights for the Malays" rather than anticolonialism ( Roff 1967). As was the case with their Muslim aristocratic counterparts in Nigeria, bureaucratic o f< . . fice and state revenue were the niches from which they were to reproduce ethnonationalist movement. During the Japanese occupation of World War II, the Japanese army ethnic cleavages and adopted separate policies for each ethnic community. the Chinese community the legitimacy of traditional leadership by Chinese was eroded by the latter's compromise with the Japanese. Their leadership replaced by that of the militant Malayan Communist Party. The Malay aristocracy was de legitimized due to its accommodation to the Japanese. However, cleavages between the radical Malay nationalists and the Malay aristocracy and administrators were arrested as ethnonationalist sentiments overshadowed class contradictions. When one reflects upon the critical differences between our case studies, the emergence of the Cold War in the post war period explains to a significant degree the pattern of ethnic conflict in Malaysia. After the defeat of the Japanese the resistance forces under the leadership of the Chinese dominated, but nonetheless multi-ethnic Malayan People's Anti-Japanese Army, unleashed a revenge cam paign against collaborators. Since the leadership was Marxist, the conjuncture 196 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? of the Cold War allowed British security forces, supported by their clients among the Malay aristocracy, to construe the insurgency as a purely Chinese phenomenon during the counter-insurgent "Emergency" of 1948-60. Significantly, the Anglo aristocratic alliance thwarted the Labour government's reform efforts toward a multi-ethnic democratic union as the vehicle for the transfer of political power to the indigenes. The Malayan Union would have abolished the position of the Malay rulers and granted citizenship and equal rights to all communities domiciled in Malaya. However, Malay aristocrats would not agree to the democratic pro posal which reverted the colonial "pro-Malay" stance, and the Malayan Union was dissolved (Gullick and Gale, 1986, pp. 86). This contrasts sharply with the post-war situation in Nigeria. While the British tended to support the Muslim aristocracy in the Northern Region, in the absence of an emergency, the security apparatus was unable to suppress radical nationalism in the south and transfer a national security state apparatus to their conservative clients upon independence. The nature of the compromise of independence embodied the British pro-Malay stance as well as the Malay aristocratic call for "special privileges" for the Malays. When the radical factions of each ethnic group had been crushed and the cleavages between the aristocratic and working classes of Malays had been repaired, a coali tion government was formed that incorporated the three elite-interested ethnic political parties into an alliance government. This tense''ethnic-accommodating" alliance firmly established the Malay ruling party (UMNO) as the dominant arm. Leaders were drawn from the ranks of the aristocracy, and most early leaders had gained experience within the colonial administration. The compromise in herent in the alliance allocated to the Chinese relatively free opportunity to develop and control the economy. Hence political events leading to the expression of ethnonationalism, which were themselves precipitated by the interaction of world-systemic factors and the colonially constructed ethnic division of labor, resulted in a postcolonial an tagonistic system in which the Malay elites were firmly in control of the state, while the Chinese bourgeoisie dominated the economic sphere. Imperial policy, Anglo-aristocratic alliances around security issues, and the division of labor in the colonial economy provided the structures of ethnic diversity, a division that continues today but was constructed during the colonial era. ETHNICALL Y DIVIDED SEMIPERIPHERIES Lessons from Malaysia and Nigeria The evidence supports the argument that colonial state policies-indirect rule, blocking capitalist land tenure, bolstering Muslim aristocratic privileges, and protecting British trading interests by limiting indigenous capital-constructed a division of labor that corresponded to, and thus reinforced, ethnic stratification in both states. The events of the postindependence period have not altered Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 197 significantly the correlation of ethnicity and state officeholding or membership in the most advanced sectors of indigenous capital. In Nigeria's civilian election of 1979, even when communal political parties were banned, the ethnic voting patterns were nearly identical to those registered at the time of independence. Economic nationalist intervention by the Nigerian state disproportionately benefited Yoruba businessmen who, by their education and concentration at Lagos, were ideally situated to take advantage of the decrees on indigenization of industry of 1972 and 1977 (Biersteker 1987). This windfall merely reinforced the Yoruba's domination of the more advanced technical and economic positions both in the public and private sectors. Yet the revival of Igbo entrepreneurship and the close relationship between state and capitalist elites among the Hausa-speaking nor therners allow for greater cross-cutting alliances than in the Malaysian case. In Malaysia the Malay domination of the state remains unchallenged. Indeed, it is illegal even to suggest altering their privileged preeminence. Efforts to create a Malay entrepreneurial class and an efficient industrial state sector have foundered, according to recent reports (Jomo 1988; Malaysian Business 1989). The Chinese, though hesitant to invest in fixed capital assets, remain dominant in the indigenous capitalist sector. Despite enormous expenditure of Malaysia's national wealth, the distribution of equity ownership may have changed, accord ing to the formulae established by the New Economic Policy, but a dynamic, innovative Malay bourgeoisie has not been produced. As in Nigeria, the separa tion of economic and political power hinders state-centered industrial policy; na tionalism remains a potential rather than an actual force, because in order to forestall Chinese domination of the economy, the state elites have relied on transna tional capital. Hence state-foreign joint ventures in heavy industry are costs rather than assets; electronic investments possess negligible forward or backward linkages; and the potential for linkages by medium-scale Chinese industry re mains unrealized, largely because of distrust between industrial policymakers and Chinese industrial entrepreneurs. Hence, though no condition is permanent a dynamic world-economy, the fusion of structural and cultural forces the colonial era has blocked, for now at least, the business-state alliances have been so effective elsewhere in the Pacific Rim . What has changed ethnonational affiliations with respect to the dynamic processes? Since independence the Islamic revival has figured into relationship between ethnic groups and state policy in both case studies. Of course, the rivival is inseparable from OPEC oil surpluses, and Islamization has always has been a transnational social movement. For the Hausa and Malay elites, "fun damentalism" represents a populist challenge to their leadership from within their respective groups. Although Islam is already enshrined as the state religion in Malaysia, Nigerian Muslim demands for the extension of Islamic law and con tinued membership in the Organization of Islamic Conference have raised new communal tensions, even riots in 1987, defined by religions rather than the col onial era's''tribal" definition of ethnicity. Islam is the route of assimilation into the Malay nation for Indonesians, Arabs, and South Asians and thus plays some 198 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? integrative role among the non-Chinese population. In the Nigerian case Islam is much more complex because it represents a cross-cutting cleavage between the Muslim Yoruba and the Hausa. Hence the construction of new, religiously defined, ethnonational identities is possible for Muslim Nigerians, especially among Hausa and Yoruba. Potentially, class factors could play a role in realign ment, for there tends to be a positive correlation between Christianity and high socioeconomic status among Yoruba. At the same time, Muslim fundamentalist demands for Islamic law and Islamic politics put additional pressure on the Hausa and Malay elites, who must construct compromises, arrange alliances, and main tain national unity in order to dominate their polity. Population growth, fed by higher natural increase and the capacity to assimilate Muslims, favors the continued growth of the Muslim Malays over the Chinese and Indians. Unlike the situation in Nigeria, there are no cross-cutting cleavages between the Chinese and the Malays. Race, religion, language, and culture separate them. The existing ethnic division of labor has been assaulted by state "affir mative action" interventions on behalf of the Malays but without encouraging results. Only a new model of accumulation that would allow the Chinese to exer cise their entrepreneurial talent more freely could stimulate the dynamic growth that the state planners aspire to achieve. Here the need to employ, and to redistribute income to, a rapidly urbanizing Malay population could serve as the basis of a new compromise, that is, a model that would require economic in tegration between the two groups and more freedom from state intervention for Chinese family businesses. One awaits the details of the Sixth Economic Plan (1991-1995). Prospects for Ethnically Divided Semiperipherai States In the face of ethnically supported social movements stretching from Sri Lanka to South Africa and even to Peru, the contradictions faced by Malaysia and Nigeria are unlikely to remain unique. It is important to investigate the origins of the groups in question with special attention to the ethnic division of labor and the policies, if relevant, of the colonial state. Clearly, when ethnic divisions separate indigenous political and economic elites, the arena for state intervention and state mobilization of nationalism is severely constrained, and the accumulating alliance is attenuated. If the internationalization of society, economy, and polity continue at the rapid rate registered over the past three decades, then very nationalist sentiments granted to the modern nation-state may come under increasing pressure from regional, ethnic, and local allegiances. Of course, such an outcome assumes a highly in tegrated world-economy that is probably beyond the regulative capacity of the nation-state as we now define it. Transformations of the world-economy have always altered the definition of ethnic groups, so the current trend toward in tense competition between blocs, reduced regulatory power of nation-states, and high technology integration and communication will surely impact on and generate Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 199 reactions from ethnic groups in the semiperiphery. Just as Nigeria's and Malaysia's ethnic identities and roles in the division of labor were shaped by the era of formal colonialism, so too one can expect the next wave of global expansion to construct new ethnic identities and problems for elites who direct semiperipheral policy. NOTES The authors would like to thank the Academic Senate Committee on Research, the Pacific Rim Program, the Social Sciences Division, the Graduate Student Patent Funds, and the Center for Cultural Studies, all of the University of California, Santa Cruz, for financial assistance in the preparation of this chapter. 1. Wallerstein observes that social categories-races, peoples, ethnic groups, and na tions-"are used with incredible inconsistency" (1987, 380). He sees the changing use of social identities as an attempt to construct a "pastness," which "is a tool persons use against each other . . . the content of pastness constantly changes" (381). Hence "it makes little difference whether we define pastness in terms of genetically continuous groups (races), historical socio-political groups (nations), or cultural groups (ethnic groups). They all are peoplehood constructs, all inventions of past ness, all contemporary political phenomena" (381). 2. Examples include India, Indonesia, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, South Africa, Iran, Kenya, Zaire, Peru, Yugoslavia, and Zimbabwe. 3. See C. Johnson (1987). 4. As Wallerstein explains: The "peoples" that exist today have come into existence as a result of the development of the capitalist world-economy, through which some groups (names) that were in existence before have become molded into peoples, other groups (names) have disappeared from our vocabulary, and some entirely new groups (names) have been invented.Furthermore, this creation of "peoples" is not a once-and-for all happening.It is a matter of constant, if slow-moving, flux ....The assertion of people-hood is a major political act.... Creating a people, or remolding its definition of boundaries, is portant mechanism in shaping the world market, and in the "assignment" of different' as specific work forces in the production processes that are integrated through that market. To and recreate peoples is to mold and remold class boundaries, and to strengthen or weaken processes of accumulation of capital (appropriation of surplus value).People formation is an part of class-formation. (1981, 50) 5. For purposes of brevity, we are eliminating from our discussion the Igbos of and the Indians of Malaysia. 6. Interestingly, in the unfederated Malay States such as the Malay padi-cultivating regions of the southern peninsula or the Siamese-controlled states of the north, such ethnic segmentation was much less pronounced. In fact, in the northern states of Kelantan and Trengganu there was assimilation and acculturation among Chinese artisans and merchants with local Malay and Thai cultural influences. They form a subethnic category (Peranakan Chinese) similar to the Malay-speaking Baba Chinese whose identity was congealed dur ing the period of the Malacca sultanate (see Tan Chee Beng 1986). It is noteworthy that in this instance ethnic segregation is correlated with the ethnic division of labor deter mined by exports to the world-economy, while the more isolated and least urbanized areas experienced greater interethnic assimilation during the colonial period. Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? 200 REFERENCES Ajayi, 1., and Crowder, M. 1976. History of West Africa. New York: Columbia Univer sity Press. Anderson, Benedict. 1983.Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origins and Spread of Nationalism. London: Verso. Biersteker, T. 1987. "Indigenization and the Nigerian Bourgeoisie." In 1he African Bourgeoisie: Capitalist Development in Nigeria, Kenya, and the Ivory Coast, edited by P. Lubeck, pp. 249-79. Boulder, Colo.: Lynn Rienner Publishers. Brass, Paul. 1985. Ethnic Groups and the State. Totowa, N.J.: Barnes and Noble. Coleman, James S. 1958. Nigeria: Background to Nationalism. Berkeley: University of California Press. Diamond, Larry. 1988. Class, Ethnicity, and Democracy in Nigeria: The Failure of the First Republic. Syracuse, N.Y.: Syracuse University Press. Evans, Peter. 1979. Dependent Development: The Alliance of Multinational, State, and Local Capital in Brazil. Princeton, N.1.: Princeton University Press. Gullick, John. 1958. Indigenous Political Systems of Western Malaya. London: Athlone Press. Gullick, John, and Bruce Gale. 1986.Malaysia: Its Political and Economic Development. Selangor, Malaysia: Pelanduk Publications. Hamilton, Nora. 1982. 1he Limits of State Autonomy: Post-Revolutionary Mexico. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Hechter, M. 1975. Internal Colonialism. Berkeley: University of California Press. Hing Ai Yun. 1984. "Capitalist Development, Class, and Race." In Ethnicity, Class, and Development, edited by S. Husin Ali, pp. 297-328. Kuala Lumpur: Persatuan Sains Social Malaysia, Universiti Malaysia. Horowitz, Donald. 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley: University of California Press. Hua Wu Yin. 1983.Class and Communalism in Malaysia: Politics in a Dependent Capitalist State. London: Zed Press. Jesudason, James V. 1989.Ethnicity and the Economy: 1he State, Chinese Business, and Multinationals in Malaysia. Singapore: Oxford University Press. Johnson, C. 1987. "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Govemment Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan." In 1he Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by Frederic C. Deyo, pp. 136-64. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press. Lim Mah Hui. 1980. "Ethnic and Class Relations in Malaysia." Journal of Contemporary Asia 19, 112:130-54. Lim Teck Ghee. 1984. "British Colonial Administration and the 'Ethnic Division of Labor' in Malaya." Kajian Malaysia: Journal ofMalaysian Studies 3, No.2 (December). ___ .1977. Peasants and 1heir Agricultural Economy in Colonial Malaya, 1874-1941. Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press. Lloyd, Peter. 1968. Africa in Social Change: West African Societies in Transition. New York: Praeger. ___ .1971. The Political Development of Yoruba Kingdoms in the Eighteenth and Nine teenth Centuries. London: Royal Anthropological Institute. Lubeck, Paul M. 1986. Islam and Urban Labor in Northern Nigeria: TIle Making of a Muslim Working Class. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Malaysia and Nigeria Compared 201 1989. "The New Economic Policy: Where Now? (On Equity and Equitability)." August 1-15, 17. Marx, Karl. 1963. 1he Eighteenth Brumaire ofLouis Bonaparte. New York: International Publishers. Nagata, Judith. 1984. 1he Flowering ofMalaysian Islam. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press. Paden, J. 1974. Religion and Political Culture in Kano. Berkeley: University of Califor nia Press. Roff, William. 1967. 1he Origins of Malay Nationalism. New Raven: Yale University Press. Sundaram, Jomo Kwame. 1988. A Question of Class: Capital, the State, and Uneven Development in Malaya. New York: Monthly Review Press. ---. 1988. Mahathir's Economic Policies. Kuala Lumpur: Insan. Tan Chee Beng. 1984. "Acculturation, Assimilation, and Integration: The Case of the Chinese." In Ethnicity, Class, and Development, edited by S. Rusin Ali, pp. 189-211. Kuala Lumpur: Persatuan Sains Social Malaysia, Universiti Malaysia. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979. 1he Capitalist World-Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ---. 1981. "Race Is Class? Some Reflections on South Africa Inspired by Mugubane." Monthly Review 32, 10 (March):47-52. ---. 1984. 1he Politics of the World-Economy: 1he States, the Movements, and the Civilizations. Studies in Modem Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ---. 1987. "The Construction of Peoplehood: Racism, Nationalism, and Ethnicity. " Sociological Forum 2, 2:373-87. Malaysian Business. 11 FROM NrC TO NUC : SOUTH AFRICA'S SEMIPERIPHERAL REGIMES William G. Martin IS SOUTH AFRICA OUTSIDE THE WORLD-SYSTEM? Few would contest South Africa' s semiperipheral status in the capitalist world economy. The country contains a well-established industrial complex yet falls far short of the advanced levels of core areas. GNP per capita squarely places South Africa in the middle of the global hierarchy of wealth. The South African state commands an extensive military, ideological, and economic infrastructure, yet despite its dominating regional position and nuclear capabilities, no one would rank it as a core power. Neither core nor peripheral, South Africa has never theless attained worldwide notoriety , captured best in one word: apartheid. Indeed, if there is one semiperipheral area where ethnicity would appear have made a decisive difference, it would surely be South Africa. Yet with divisions and oppression so obvious and pertinent, it has become almost ll ' Uf'\J''''.lU�' to approach any aspect of South Africa except through race. The result is the institutions and ideology of apartheid have provided the focus and point departure for almost all studies of South Africa. This is a most dangerous cedure. It has confounded our understanding not only of the historical trajectory of this region of the world, but even of the character and contradictions of racial oppression. Race and Deveiopmentalism It is impossible, of course, to ignore the salience of race. From its origins over three hundreds years ago as a shipping outpost en route to the Far East, to the present realities of apartheid, modern South Africa has been forged on the bedrock of white supremacy. For most of this period, however, the characteristics of set tler and colonial domination were shared with many other areas of the world. 204 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? South Africa's divergence from such patterns, and indeed its worldwide notorie ty, arose only after World War II . Here two related developments were central. First, the South African election of 1948 ushered in the terminology and prac tices of apartheid. Second, at the very moment when apartheid was being con structed, the world as a whole moved in the opposite direction-decolonization proceeded apace, and legalized racial domination was formally rejected elsewhere. Set against the self-congratulatory liberalism of U . S . hegemony, South Africa steadily became the exception, a pariah among the world of nations . Lending even further distinctiveness to South Africa' s path was the apparent success of modernization under white domination. Once resistance to the im plementation of apartheid was contained, the economy boomed; during the golden years of apartheid from the early 1960s to the mid- 1970s , few countries experi enced faster growth rates . Far from an atavistic phenomenon, racial domination in its most heightened form proved fully compatible with accelerated industrial accumulation. For the West and East, North and South, South Africa had become an isolated subject, all too much an affront to postwar sensibilities. This widely proclaimed uniqueness had immediate, long-lasting, and quite deleterious effects on our understanding of modern South Africa. As a racially structured and driven society , South Africa became a world apart: none of the comparative, much less world-historical , conceptual and theoretical advances com mon to the study of noncore areas of the world-economy were utilized to ex amine South Africa. Few of the debates or lessons drawn from African studies , for example, ever appear in the vast literature on the development of modern South Africa: for all intents and purposes South Africa has floated off the conti nent. There is not a single book written in the last two decades , moreover, that seriously treats the country from a dependency, dependent-development, or world systems perspective. How, then, do we explain the emergence and flourishing of a racially structured, industrializing area? Here the procedures have been quite straightforward: racial uniqueness underpinned the study of South Africa in isolation from world networks, and industrialization provided the perception of national development. The end result was the deployment of concepts and theories appropriate to the ongoing evolution of a national, industrial economy. For liberals and conservatives alike, modernization theory reigned supreme, while Marxists and neo-Marxists cast South Africa's historical development within the mold of the advance of national monopoly capital. For both parties , the history of South Africa became largely the history of the crea tion of a racially structured national society , nation-state, and national economy. While fierce debate continues to circulate around who instigated and benefited from apartheid (Lipton 1985 , 2- 1 3 ; Freund 1987) , agreement confirms a steady march forward from an agrarian to an industrial economy, from segregation to apartheid. In short, the racial distinctiveness of South Africa reinforces the exclusive character of the country's developmental trajectory. To step beyond the boundaries of these developmentalist premises places such a seemingly natural progression on its head. If we examine other noncore areas South Africa's Semi peripheral Regimes 2 05 of the world, ethnic and racial divisions are commonplace in the twentieth cen tury, and the achievement of an industrializing economy is the exception. But this is not all. To place South Africa within a world-historical perspective is to upset widely accepted conclusions regarding apartheid and indeed the whole course of the country's place in the twentieth-century world. As we argue later, far from advancing South Africa's place in the industrial world, apartheid has diminished it. Far from drawing upon tribalism and tradition, apartheid has created and remolded such social divisions. Above all, the apartheid state in the post-World War II period has, by openly allying itself with local and multinational enter prises, opened the door to an ever-lower position in the global division of labor. To grasp these insights is of importance not only to students of South and southern Africa, but to those seeking an understanding of the semiperipheral zone itself. Far from being unique, South Africa demonstrates the very contradictory posi tion of all semiperipheral states within the changing course of the twentieth-century world-system. Semiperipheral South Africa: Apartheid South Africa? To chart the course toward these conclusions, let us begin with the most cen tral issue framed by the debate over apartheid: what has been the relationship between phases of segregation and apartheid and accumulation? From the existing literature the answer is clear: it has been during the apar theid epoch that Soudi Africa has moved decisively toward a modern industrial status. If South Africa is investigated from a world-economic perspective, the conclusions could not be more different. Here we take the simplest measure utilized to indicate position within the polarizing core-periphery division of labor, GNP per capita. Unfortunately, reliable GNP data for South Africa and the world preclude any full analysis of South Africa within the global hierarchy of wealth during this century. Figure 1 1. 1 illustrates a less desirable procedure: Africa's relative distance from core status as measured by South GNP/capita as a percentage of that of four "organic" members (Britain, Germany, United States) of the core zone (data prior to 1 95 0 are approxima tions). One could readily extend such data with figures on wage rates and the mix of core-like and peripheral production processes over time. What even data here suggest, however, is startling in key aspects. Sharply evident is the current "organic crisis" of apartheid (Saul and Gelb 1 986, 63-98), only momentarily broken by rises in the price of gold. More strik ing are longer-term trends. Where recent analyses depict South Africa's develop ment as the outcome of apartheid, the data suggest otherwise: far from accelerating South Africa' s position in the global division of labor, apartheid has at best merely served to maintain the country in a steady middle position in the world-economy through most of the post-World War II period. If one compares South Africa with other semiperipheral areas, this observation is further confirmed. Figure 1 1. 2 illustrates other well-known semiperipheral states ' GNP per capita 206 Ethnicity; Propelling or Checking Advance? Figure 11.1 South African GNP Per Capita a s a Percentage o f Organic Core GNP Per Capita � . <IS s.. U 40 .... " Q.. Z 0 � 0 U Q.. 30 d) 00 '" ... " > -< .... 0 d) 00 '" 20 ;: " � " Q.. 10 4---�-.--�--r-�--�-.--�-4 1930 1 940 1 950 1 9 60 1 970 1 9 80 1 920 1 990 Sources: 1 929- 1948: United Nations. Various Years. 1 950-1987: World Bank. Various Years. and World Tables. Statistical Yearbook. World Development Repor t as a percentage of South Africa' s GNP per capita. The data sharply reveal South Africa's strong semiperipheral position in the early postwar period and the clos ing of the gap between South Africa and other semiperipheral areas in the 1960s and 1 970s . Even during the best years of the apartheid economy, other semiperi pheral states were overtaking South Africa. Indeed, one could be much harsher: if in 1 948 South Africa was a newly industrializing country (NIC) , in the last three decades it is more appropriately captured under the rubric of a newly under developing country (NUC) . While debates rage over the meaning of industrializa tion for Latin American and East Asian NICs, South Africa's postwar history indicates that steady industrialization hardly equals "development" or a move ment toward core status in the world-economy. Simply stated, the much-heralded and generalized boom of the apartheid era is a myth . Semiperipheral South Africa is not a product of apartheid, but rather apartheid' s starting point. Indeed, one might rather ask: is apartheid the result of semiperipheral development? South Africa's Semi peripheral Regimes 2 07 Figure 1 1 .2 GNP Per Capita of Selected Semiperipheral States as a Percentage of South African GNP Per Capita � '5.. '" 1 50 p... 1 25 u ... .., . I. I ) 1/ � v g() 1 00 J3 � "§ 0 t/J '- 0 d} co '" i:: OJ () ... ., 75 Brazil 50 - . ... . ... _ p... 25 0 1 950 Sources: . ... . ..... . , ;. " . ' 1 960 World Bank. World Tables. 0 ° ' " - ./ '. I ' \.. . .". ,. " r S o uth Korea _0'" 1 970 1 980 1 990 Various years. World Development R eport and FROM A PRIMARY-PRODUCING TO AN INDUSTRIALIZING SEMIPERIPHERAL REGIME Such conclusions , like the data, only tell us of raw, empirical outcomes: approximate location over time of South Africa in the global hierarchy of wealth. Here the data indicate that South Africa has been a steady member of the semi peripheral zone since at least the 1 930s. In light of the most common information regarding South African economic history, this generates two central periods of semiperipherality : (1) the country's movement from a simple, if rich, primary producing area of the world-economy in the opening decades of this century to a newly industrializing member of the semiperipheral zone during the interwar period, and (2) the failure to advance toward core status in the world-economy in the post-World War II period. It remains to be seen how such a position straddling core-peripheral relation ships was first captured, and subsequently, how South Africa' s semiperipheral position was maintained in the face of the transformations and cyclical rhythms 208 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? of the world-economy over the course of the last half century . The pursuit of answers to these questions, given South Africa's relatively long membership in the semiperiphery, has considerable advantages for the study of the semiperipheral zone. The study of South Africa illustrates , for example, that neither the transi tion to semiperipheral status nor the maintenance of it flowed naturally out of preceding phases of accumulation and conflict within South Africa. Each phase arose from violent confrontations with the contradictions of success of previous patterns of participation in the world-economy, and each of these key periods entailed the abandonment of past patterns of participation in core-peripheral net works, the local social and ethnonational alliances and practices that sustained such participation, and the political structures and policies that were essential to the continual reproduction of these relationships. It is to these quite clearly demar cated regimes of accumulation and political rule, and to their lessons for semiperipheral development generally, that we now turn . The Creation and Contradictions of Primary Production Nineteenth-century South Africa was the product of the extension of the world economy under British hegemony. Having seized the coastal shipping outpost of Cape Town from the Dutch in 1 806 , Britain steadily developed a set of col onial territories in southern Africa. To these areas flowed labor, capital, and the manufactured goods of Britain and other core areas ; from them flowed primary products such as wool and sugar. The exploitation of fabulous mineral deposits in the interior of southern Africa radically advanced this pattern as great mineral complexes developed around the mining first of diamonds in the 1 860s and then of gold in the 1 880s . By the end of the century the battle for control over these resources resulted in Great Britain's greatest colonial war, the Anglo-Boer con flict of 1 899-1902. Out of the war came the Union of South Africa ( 1 91 0) , designed to ensure what squabbling between colonial territories and Afrikaner republics had obstructed: the free flow of labor, commodities, and capital to , from, and across southern Africa. By this time both mining and agricultural production has emerged as classic instances of primary production, selling their products in markets deter mined by world prices and export opportunities and drawing their capital and most wage goods from overseas producers . As mining capital prospered, settler farmers struggled to commercialize their marginal lands in a world market well served by the extraordinarily fertile lands of Argentina, Australia, and even the Punjab . Two factors favored commercializing settler farmers , however: favorable world prices in the opening decades of the twentieth century and the South African state's intervention through direct financial assistance and the suppression of African competition. Part and parcel of this deepening peripheralization of accumulation processes was the constant exertion of political force in order to ensure the conditions for the reproduction of mining and agricultural capital. Overtly dominated by mining South Africa's Semiperipheral Regimes 2 09 interests, state policy followed the dictates of a free-trade policy designed to guarantee continued access to overseas financial and commodity markets and the lowest-priced commodity imports for the mines and settler agriculture. An open alliance with Britain sustained these relationships and even provided the levers to dominate Portuguese colonial territories from which the mines drew a signifi cant proportion of their labor force and through which critical railways passed. While at the turn of the century the stability and prosperity of South Africa seemed uncertain, the following decades witnessed the creation of a stable and prosperous peripheral regime of accumulation and political rule. Sheltered by British hegemony, feeding Europe's financial and commodity markets in return, and buoyed by an expanding world-economy, white South Africa appeared to have found its place in the modern world. By the end of World War II all such illusions would be rudely shattered. The Crisis of the Free-Trade, Low-Grade Regime The first signs of deep structural problems were transmitted directly through the commodity networks upon which South African prosperity had been based. This was most evident in the mining sector, where the long-term price inflation of the early twentieth-century A (expansionary) phase raised input costs for the mines while the price of gold remained fixed to sustain the British-led interna tional monetary system. By the end of World War I this " scissors crisis" was so severe that many mines were running at a loss and in danger of shutting down operations. Near panic ensued as the state and capital struggled to deal with the crisis of " low-grade" mines. At the same time, producer prices for South Africa's agricultural products suffered a sharp fall on the world market, while the cost of overseas imports remained at high levels. South African primary producers were hardly alone in facing these chill blowing across the world market. Across Africa, and indeed across most of periphery, the whole interwar period would be one of falling terms of increasing hardship. The very depth and scale of primary production in Africa had, however, created forces capable of a vigorous response. The was not simply a crisis of profitability, but the eruption of conflict as the social and political props that had underpinned fifty years of primary production collapsed. Central here was an outbreak of class struggle so extensive that it under mined not only the cohesion of minority rule and the social basis of the state, but the very stability of the relationship between the state and capital. At the heart of this process were developments in the mining sector. The rapid expansion of mining capital in the late nineteenth century had rested upon an equal ly rapid growth in the immigration of skilled white miners and an army of black labor drawn from surrounding colonial territories. World-record wages for white miners and the generalized benefits of mining had served to secure a common commitment amongst the white electorate to minority rule and mining produc tion. Mining capital's response to its profit squeeze was to squeeze in turn the 210 E thnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? only cost fully under its control , the price of labor. This first entailed extending the reach of black labor recruiting throughout southern Africa and undercutting the viability of African agriculture wherever possible. With the full support of the South African state and Great Britain, such designs were largely successful: black wage rates were' considerably reduced between the late nineteenth century and World War I. Reducing the larger wage bill for white miners (despite a ratio of ten black miners to every white miner) was tackled on a broad front: through the partial dilution of artisanal skills, the replacement of foreign artisans with locally trained and largely Afrikaner miners , and, contingent upon labor recruiting, raising the black/white labor ratio on the mines (Johnstone 1 976). Such moves against both black and white labor depended upon undercutting the marketplace bargaining power of labor: for black workers by withdrawing agricultural alternatives to part-lifetime wage employment, and for white workers by reducing skills monopolies, the scarcity of white labor, and the high (overseas) cost of its recruit ment and reproduction. Such tactics of class restructuring were made considerably more volatile by ongoing developments in settler agriculture. As commercial production expanded in the interior, ever-larger numbers of black and even white tenants and sharecrop pers were thrown off the veld. While displaced blacks could be forced into reserves, the growing urban army of "poor whites" posed mounting problems for the state. Together these factors led to a growing struggle between capital and labor, with a long strike wave in the mines by both black and white miners coming to a head just as the crisis of profitability peaked in the early post-World War I years . Both mining capital and the government remained stubbornly com mitted to a shared defense of primary production and a British-centered free-trade system. By 1922 pitched battles were being fought in the streets of Johannesburg. To those who had championed and benefited from the primary-producing role, the world seemed turned upside down. Not only had the world-economy turned against its golden outpost, but the very development of peripheral accumulation had fostered forces now contesting the political program that had sustained the social and economic relationships of primary production and the coherence of white domination. Such a conjuncture opened opportunities for opposition political parties, particularly the Afrikaner National Party, which sought to tap long standing anti-imperialist, anticapitalist sentiments. In 1924 global cycles and local political upheavals intersected: the ruling alliance of mining capital and the free trade, pro-British government was overthrown in national elections by a coali tion of the parties of Afrikaner nationalism and white labor. The South African state under this "Pact" government proved to be neither less capitalist nor less interventionist than preceding governments . What it per ceived more sharply and acted upon, however, was the evident failure of the coun try 's model of accumulation, class structure, and state policy. Central here was the implementation of two interwoven and interdependent aims : ( 1 ) the promo tion of industrialization as a solution to the poor white problem, white worker South Africa's Semi peripheral Regimes 211 militancy , and the decline of the mines , and (2) the reorientation of the state policy such that it was possible to counter the underdeveloping processes emanating from core areas. In quick order the government transformed the direction of state policy, turning away from a slavish fealty to mining capital and toward the creation of an industrial sector: South Africa's first protectionist tariff was passed, preferential duties for British manufactures were eliminated, state enterprises such as transport and energy production were revamped in the service of industrial production, and new state enterprises were established. Most notable among the latter was the establishment of a state iron and steel works (ISCOR), one of only two in tegrated steel plants outside core areas during this period. Such initiatives signaled far greater transformations than simply changes in state policy or, as is more commonly argued, the simple recomposition of white racism in the service of capital and the building of a national economy. What was at stake was nothing less than reorganizing and reintegrating the country ' s position in the global division of labor and the interstate system. At the interstate level this was most visible in the creation of a Department of Foreign Affairs and in the South African government's leading role in the successful struggle to achieve independent status in the interstate system for the dominions. Protectionist measures further disrupted the long-entrenched dependence of South Africa upon industrial sourcing from core areas. Essential to this effort was an attack upon British control over the country' s trading networks (Martin 1 990b). New multilateral relationships were established with Britain's competitors, particular ly those able to supply, on the most favorable terms, new technologies and capital goods for state and private industry . Britain's share of merchandise exports and imports accordingly fell throughout the interwar period. Less successful, it must be noted, was the attempt to sever the City of London's hold on the local capital market; it proved extraordinarily hard to undermine well-established personal and institutional ties between the semi-independent South African Reserve Bank and the Bank of England. The contribution of these measures to the localization of industrial was critical . Equally essential, however, was resolving the seemingly unruliness of labor and the threatened defection of segments of the white com munity. This was tackled on two fronts. First, the repression and control of black labor were greatly extended. Second, the militancy of employed and unemployed whites was undercut by the ideology of a " civilized labor" policy and the cor responding institutionalization of white labor-capital relations through Industrial Conciliation Councils. The success of these measures was indicated by the emergence of a period of labor peace and the rapid expansion of South Africa's nascent industrial sector. If the pursuit of the localization of industrial production demanded immediate action vis-a-vis core areas and new institutions of labor control, it soon became evident that it also required a division of labor between South Africa and sur rounding peripheral areas (Martin 1 990a). Under British hegemony the whole of southern Africa had become a common peripheral zone, open to transterritorial 212 Ethnicity; Propelling o r Checking Advance? flows of capital , labor, and commodities. If South Africa's program of manufac turing expansion were successful, local primary producers would supply inputs to an expanding urban-industrial complex, replacing a dependence on shrinking overseas markets . Manufacturing would in turn replace goods previously pur chased from overseas areas. Yet existing regional trade arrangements confounded such a development because they allowed regional producers to compete in ser vicing the South African market, yet privileged in many instances manufactured imports from Britain and Portugal . Here the actions of the South African government were quite clear. Any gains from increased local industrial consumption of primary products were to be awarded to South African producers alone. Toward this end, protectionist bar riers were erected not only against manufactured imports from core areas but against imports of raw materials and foodstuffs from surrounding territories. Gone were the days of the free importation of Rhodesian tobacco, Mozambican sugar and cement, and cattle from the High Commission territories of Bechuanaland (Botswana) , Swaziland, and Basutoland (Lesotho). At the same time, effective bargaining in the midst of the collapse of the world demand ensured South African access to surrounding markets for South African manufacturers. Southern Africa as a coherent region of center-hinterland relationships was being forged for the first time . In a similar vein the government moved to reorganize the pattern and fruits of labor migration. Local training of whites had already eliminated any appreciable skilled labor inflows from core areas. The supply of unskilled black labor, however, had long been based upon the recruitment of migrant labor from across southern Africa. While moving carefully in light of the mines' extreme suscep tibility to cost pressures, the Pact government slowIy redirected the reach of labor flows. This had the desired effect of ensuring not only that South Africa' s homelands became tied to the mining industry, but that migrants ' wages were spent on the products of South African manufacturers and not on British or Por tuguese goods in neighboring colonial territories . The impact of such measures became apparent when the international price of gold leapt upward after 1933 and employment increased: for the first time the majority o f black miners were recruited from within South Africa itself (Martin 1984) , while gold production boomed, stimulating ever-further industrial advance. During the 1 930s many countries-given the great crash , the breakup of the world market, and increased interimperialist rivalry-would attempt to reconstruct their position in core-periphery networks. By moving forward in the 1920s, the South African state was ideally situated to take advantage of the chaotic world conditions of the mid- 1930s. Yet precocity and the pursuit of farsighted state policies alone cannot explain South Africa's remarkable transition to a newly in dustrializing member of the semiperiphery. Nothing less than a radical rupture of prevailing social, economic, and political relationships was required. Major class and ethnic struggles in a hostile world climate set the stage. The resultiL6 Pact government, despite the screams of protest by mining capital, was, however, South Africa's Semi peripheral Regimes 213 hardly a " white workers' state, " much less an anticapitalist political movement. Yet a major transition had indeed taken place. Having broken the power of min ing capital and free trade, the state laid the foundations for industrialization, a corporative institutionalization of white labor movement, and a more assertive and momentarily autonomous-state. Interwar advancement would have been im possible without each of these ruptures. None of these features are encompassed, much less explained, within the restricted ambit of either black-white conflict or even national boundaries. Indeed, the resolution of the crisis of the primary producing, free-trade regime was only possible by shifting the country' s position in core-peripheral networks and the interstate system. This endeavor was, nevertheless, a movement down an uncharted path. It de pended to a very great degree upon world conditions of hegemonic crisis and great depression. Few paused to contemplate what would occur when these con ditions changed, and even fewer considered what new class and ethnonational forces this semiperipheral transformation would itself unleash. The end of World War IT would reveal just how volatile both these dimensions were. THE POST-WORLD WAR II SEMIPERIPHERAL REGIME As World War IT came to an end, South African officials faced the future full of the accomplishments of the past. As one government report noted, " The Union is not just entering the industrial stage. On the contrary the industrial develop ment of the country is well-advanced" (South Africa. Board of Trade and In dustries 1 945, 1 9) . In 1 91 8 industry' s contribution to GDP was but 29 percent of that of agriculture and 39 percent of that of mining; by 1 945 industry had sur passed both, with the industrial group of metal products, machinery, and transport bypassing food and beverages as the largest single group in the industrial sector (South Africa 1 982, 2 1. 5 , 2 1. 6) . Ever cognizant of South Africa' s position in the world-economy, government reports noted with approval that industry and national income had grown more rapidly than in many countries, including Australia, Canada, and New Zealand (South Africa. Board of Trade and Industries 1945, 1 9) . South Africa, it appeared, had entered the select ranks of the industrial world and was seemingly en route toward an advanced equality with overseas powers. What such assessments failed to anticipate, however, were the contradic tions due to the very success of the state ' s promotion of a semiperipheral posi tion and the emerging new world order of U.S. hegemony. Together these fac tors would make a continuation of the interwar trajectory impossible. Crisis and Transition As we have seen, one of the cornerstones of interwar semiperipheral develop ment was the application of corporative policies toward white labor in industry 'lAnd the deepening of black proletarianization within the country. As industrial production proceeded apace in the 1920s and 1 930s, these developments unleashed 214 Ethnicity: Propelling ar Checking Advance? serious challenges to further industrial accumulation . First of all , rapid industrial advance carried forward the replacement of a labor process based upon the ar tisan/unskilled division of labor with a division of labor utilizing semiskilled operatives. Unforeseen in the 1920s, and considerably accelerated during the 1930s and war years, this development stripped many white workers of their skill monopolies and thus bargaining power vis-a-vis capital . This in turn challenged the white worker' s very place in industrial production, as capital found newly urbanized black workers increasingly suitable for expanding operative positions. 1 Although industrialization had opened avenues for white employment, the future of the white worker at the hands of capital looked bleak. Second, this undermining of white workers ' marketplace bargaining power rested upon increasing the supply of suitable black labor drawn from the more intensive exploitation of rural areas within South Africa. Success in this effort during the 1 930s and 1 940s, however, created an impoverished countryside and an urban black proletariat. For the increasing number of Africans without substan tial income from deteriorating rural agriculture, the attraction of urban employ ment was clear: average manufacturing wages were two and one-half times those of mining by 1945 , a significant increase over the one and one-half ratio at the beginning of the interwar period (South Africa 1 960, G4, G6 , G20) . Such increasing disparities within the labor market reflected the growing contradictions-for this world-historical period-between core-like industrial pro duction processes and peripheral mining and agricultural production processes. These contradictions involved not merely the formal wage disparities of a split labor market, but the very social structures that underpinned such inequalities. Mining and settler agriculture were well aware that urban-industrial labor-force formation was undercutting cheap migrant labor and the rural household struc tures that mixed income from part-lifetime waged work and rural subsistence pro duction. As these processes proceeded apace, tensions slowly emerged within the camp of capital over the direction of state policy . These contradictions arising from the very success of interwar industrializa tion came to a head in the early post-World War II years as tension among dif ferent sectors of capital was overlaid with growing struggles between capital and labor. White workers again resisted capital's move to employ ever-larger numbers of black workers at lower wage rates, while divisions among white workers erupted as trade unions representing artisans battled those representing semiskilled white workers (Lewis 1 984, chap. 9). Meanwhile, black workers became increasingly militant as urban living costs soared, conditions in unplanned and increasingly overcrowded urban locations worsened, and returns from deteriorating rural areas fell. Throughout the 1 940s workers ' struggles in response to these differing yet related processes rose in intensity; the period from 1 946 to 1 948 saw an un precedented number of strikes in comparison to the preceding two decades . The state's response to the challenges of escalating labor unrest and disunity among capital was one of uncertainty and vacillation. Only in the repression of black labor was the state capable of decisive intervention. When corporative labor South Africa's Semi peripheral Regimes 215 institutions became unworkable, for example, the state refused to offer legisla tion to secure the position of white workers in the new industrial order. The state similarly offered no solution to capital' s concerns over the competitive costs of black labor. With a disintegrating social base and an increasingly incoherent response to capital' s difficult and divergent situation, the government fell in the 1948 election . The era of apartheid had arrived. Changing Semiperipheral Regimes: The Apartheid-Industrial Complex The Nationalist Party (NP) victory in 1948 was based upon an explicit social alliance. Driven by bourgeois and petty-bourgeois Afrikaner elites based in fman cial and commercial organizations-but largely excluded from the expansion of industrial capital-the NP combined Afrikaner strata from within agriculture, labor, and nascent financial groups (O'Meara 1 983). Common explanations chart this development as either the economically irrational shoring up of white domina tion or the refurbishing, through repression, of a split labor market and cheap labor. Yet as we have indicated, underneath such surface manifestations of racial domination stood intractable contradictions arising from the very success of in terwar semiperipheral advance. While apartheid did indeed reconsolidate white solidarity, the inner secret of its success was not simply the reconstruction of white domination, but its ability to address the contradictory requirements of both peripheral and core production processes within the boundaries of a single state. Apartheid operated equally upon accumulation processes and upon the imposition of tribal and racial divisions. No better example of this exists than in the labor market. Here apartheid not merely ensured " cheap" black labor and an aristocracy of white workers-as is most commonly and crudely described-but most critically split black workers on sectoral and regional scale. In essence the policies and institutions of ap�lrtblel channeled the black labor force into three distinguishable segments: (1) creasingly foreign, semiproletarian labor force for the mines, (2) an tn{>rp"�li proletarian, yet coerced labor force for white commercial farmers, and (3) trolled, supposedly temporary, yet recognizably permanent urban South black working class. These new divisions corresponded to the conflicting aelmanal, « of, and particularly wage and labor-process differentials between, mining, agricultural, and industrial production. No longer, for example, could foreign black workers migrate to higher-paying industrial jobs. Low-wage labor for farms and mines was thus assured, as were the conditions for the continued expansion of urban industry. .. By moving in this direction, apartheid also served to recast South Mrica' s rela tionship with surrounding peripheral areas, particularly as foreign labor once again came to be the predominant source of labor for the mining sector (Stahl 1 98 1 , 1 4). Such changes reflected the density and connectedness of the regional rela tionships forged across southern Africa during the 1930s and the war years. It 216 Ethnicity: Propelling ar Checking Advance? also represented, however, a response to postwar alterations in the global divi sion of labor and the transition to a period of global expansion . The passing of classical imperialism-in the sense of the formal expansion of core powers , the dominance of finance capital, and intercapitalist rivalry leading to war-funda mentally altered the prospects of any continuation of interwar semiperipheral strategies. Under U . S . hegemony the world market was recomposed, decoloniza tion proceeded apace, and direct investment by multinationals displaced the in direct investment that allowed the development of locally controlled industries in the semiperiphery during the interwar years . South Africa's acceptance of this new world order was immediate: South Africa was a founding member of the United Nations, a signatory of the Bretton Woods agreements, and a full partner to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GAIT) treaties . This was a dramatic reversal of the pattern of interstate relations during the interwar period. In part this expressed the South African state's bid for a leading role in African-if not world-affairs; South African poJicymakers expected to secure their domination over central and southern Africa (Barber 1973 , 8 1 - 1 18). Considerable benefits were bestowed by such willing integration into the boom ing world order organized under U. S . hegemony, leading to what Wallerstein (1 979) has called economic advance by "seizing the chance. " After lagging economic growth in the late 1 940s and 1950s , the economy flourished as invest ment funds flowed in, the world market boomed, and local industrial production expanded to consumer durables . Such conditions facilitated the merger of South African firms into a handful of mining , financial, and industrial conglomerates. For foreign investors , South Africa offered not only high profit rates , but also a seemingly secure and stable base for penetration of southern and central Africa as a whole. In many ways this was a zero-sum game for countries in the region: multinational industrial investments would be located in only one country, and that was to be South Africa. Meanwhile, South African firms expanded into the region as well, although their investments were largely concentrated in the subor dinate spheres of finance and mineral exploitation. From the mid- 1960s to the mid-1970s there thus appeared a felicitous correspon dence of apartheid, economic boom, and support by the political and economic power of the West. Yet acceptance of U . S . hegemony significantly constrained any further movement toward core status in the world-economy. Unlike the in terwar policy of protection, participation in bodies such as GATT foreclosed any further protectionist policies . As befit an industrial power, concessions in respect of South Africa's own manufacturing exports were neither sought nor granted. In relation to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), as well as to the GATT, South Africa sought to be treated as an industrial power, thereby sacrificing ac cess to funds on terms offered to developing countries. By the early 1970s govern ment commissions and private-sector economists began to note that such agree ments constituted a major obstacle to further accumulation, particularly in the development of an export trade (South Africa 1972, 2 19 ; Nedbank Economic Unit 1983 , 20-2 1 ). South Africa's Semiperipheral Regimes 217 Much the same could be said \lbout the open embrace of foreign capital. This runs directly counter to the common thesis that overseas direct investment made possible the unbridled expansion of the apartheid-industrial regime. Indeed, it is quite curious that proponents of this view have failed to address studies elsewhere that stress the negative effects of unregulated multinational investment. Certainly these were in evidence: foreign capital came to control the commanding heights of the local economy, technological innovation was stifled at the national level, manufactured exports were blocked by overseas headquarters' directives to local branch plants, transfer pricing undoubtedly occurred, and so on. As the economy faltered, private and public analyses linked the failure to the advance beyond im port substitution to the multinational penetration of the economy (South Africa 1 972 , 21 9; Nedbank Economic Unit 1983 : 20-2 1 ) . Continued industrial expan sion by sectors with a high propensity to import, at the same time as gold pro duction was waning due to adverse input/output price ratios (as at the end of the previous A phase in the 1920s), threatened a structural balance-of-payments problem. Amidst such constraints South Africa' s domination of surrounding peripheral areas became increasingly strategic. As already noted, apartheid was truly a regional construct, solidifying a regional hierarchy of labor and production pro cesses linked by flows of labor, capital, and commodities. In this process a new pattern of center-hinterland linkages was constructed between South Africa and her surrounding neighbors. As argued earlier, influx controls prevented foreign labor from flowing toward higher-paying industrial jobs, an expansion of the ex change of South African industrial goods for regional primary products took place, and South African capital was invested in mineral and primary production in the surrounding periphery. To a degree rare among members of the semiperipheral zone, South Africa's position in core-peripheral networks was founded upon the emergence of a distinctive region of the world-economy. THE LIMITS OF THE APARTHEID REGIME By the early 1970s southern Africa was poised at a crossroads. Flushed the national and regional successes of the apartheid-industrial complex, African capital and the South African state moved to consolidate and center-hinterland links and thus their domination of the region. Even the effects of the outbreak of global crisis seemed to support such efforts: the shat tering of the international monetary system resulted in an unprecedented rise in the price of gold, which in tum alleviated balance-of-payments problems and spur red a speculative expansion of the local economy . Yet at the same time, the ligaments of the apartheid model came under severe attack. This assault struck from two quite different directions, although both derived, as we shall see, from common roots . The first challenge to apartheid came from the final completion of the interstate system in southern Africa. Portugal's defeats in its African colonial wars brought 218 Ethnicity: Propelling ar Checking Advance? to power in 1975 the MPLA and FRELIMO governments in Mozambique and Angola. FRELIMO's support for the armed struggle in Zimbabwe culminated in Zimbabwean independence (1980). The basis of South Africa's regional expansion, a common alliance with Portuguese colonialism and Rhodesian settlers, was in ruins. Over the same time period a second challenge emerged to South African hegemony from within the heartland of apartheid itself. Like revolts against the extension of South African power in the region, these arose out of the very develop ment of apartheid power. In this area, however, the critical effects resulted from the working out of the economic changes that had followed upon the successful suppression of labor and political unrest in the late 1950s and early 1960s . In dustrial expansion in subsequent years drastically revised the class and ethnic basis of South African society . As white workers were displaced upward into super visory and managerial positions, the factory floor became the province of an almost wholly black labor force. More importantly , postwar industrial advance under the aegis of multinationals widely introduced continuous-flow production pro cesses , which considerably strengthened the workplace bargaining power of a growing urban (black) working class . Despite apartheid' s best attempts to divide black South Africans into tribes , accumulation processes had created the basis for more united urban resistance. From 1976 onward, urban South Africa emerged as the central battlefront of a rising tide of resistance that claimed a common black identity. To make matters worse, the global depression, after the first flush of the speculative rise in the gold price passed, hit South Africa very hard. The triple hammer blows of regional challenge, internal resistance, and con traction in the world-economy shattered all pretenses of the peaceful evolution of apartheid. Although repressive measures escalated by the late 1 970s , the state and capital also recognized the need for a formative political response. The death of apartheid and the age of reform were thus proclaimed: the mixed-marriages act was repealed, signs of petty apartheid were removed, black trade unions were recognized, and attempts to co-opt Indian and " coloured" representatives into a new tricameral Parliament were advanced. None of this met the demand for majority rule. Apartheid had as well even dissolved its central supports within the white community : white workers had almost completely disappeared, while " Afrikaner" capital had become as monopolized as "English" capital. Those who had originally formed the central social supports for the apartheid project were nowhere to be found. CONCLUSION: SEMIPERIPHERAL REGIMES AND PROSPECTS We began this chapter by noting that far from underwriting South African pros perity , apartheid has barely maintained South Africa's semiperipheral position in the world-economy. Since the outbreak of the global crisis in the mid- 1970s, moreover, the crumbling of the national and regional pillars of apartheid has driven · South Africa even lower in the hierarchy of wealth and power on a world scale. South Africa's Semiperipheral Regimes 219 It is tempting to contain South Africa's current crisis within its dramatic political dimensions. Certainly any resolution of the crisis now requires meeting the de mand for majority rule. Yet majority rule alone will directly supply neither the means nor the measures to overcome the country' s seriously declining position in the modem world-economy. Indeed, the current crisis contains a far more substan tive problem shared with many other long-term members of the semi peripheral zone: the inability of postwar political and economic relationships to address the challenges of a changing global division of labor in the current B phase. To place twentieth-century South Africa within a world-economic perspective indicates this quite sharply . As argued earlier, the transformation of South Africa during the interwar period was induced and made possible by the conjunctural features of a great depression and rivalry in the interstate system. Under new political leadership the state was able to institutionalize white labor-capital rela tionships, reorganize linkages with core and peripheral areas, and thereby establish South Africa as a center for expanded industrial production. The distinctiveness of this path can be starkly revealed through comparisons to other states similarly situated in the international division of labor, but miss ing one or another of the elements of the South African configuration. In many instances outbreaks of labor and civil unrest similar in origin and timing to South Africa ' s occurred. Yet few resulted in a transition to new patterns of industrializa tion and state power. In many instances the very lure of continued wealth by staple production and the strength of dominant classes in agrarian or mineral produc tion foreclosed such a radical rupture as occurred in South Africa. Such, for ex ample, was the case in neighboring Zimbabwe, where settler farmers and export oriented mineral producers curtailed industrial initiatives; elsewhere, such as in Portugal, new political regimes emerged, yet proved antidevelopmentalist in their orientation. For much of Latin America, the search for new forms of accumula tion and state power emerged only in the mid- 1 930s, or even later, when and national conditions were far less favorable. As argued earlier, the very success of the interwar semiperipheral undermined its continuation in the early post-World War II period. In the instance this was a political challenge, as unfettered industrial simultaneously created a new, militant labor force and widened between the core-like industrial production and peripheral production in mining and agriculture. Apartheid resolved these difficulties by forging com plex new relationships between divergent production processes and their labor forces, the social and ideological basis of white rule, and the segregation and repression of black urban resistance. In key aspects such a configuration paralleled similar developments elsewhere in the world-economy that melded bureaucratic repression, industrialization, the expansion of a middle-class market, and the solicitation of foreign capital. Equally important to apartheid's stability, however, was the remolding of South Africa' s relationship with core powers and the now-stable and expanding world economy. In the world order established by Great Britain, accelerated industrialization 220 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? expanded national productive and technological capabilities. In this climate in novative and precocious state policies such as those pursued by South Africa made upward movement within the global division of labor possible. Such successes would later provide the evidence for dependency analysts' promotion of withdrawal from the world market. These semi peripheral strategies became increasingly in applicable, however, under postwar conditions of global expansion and the asser tion of U. S . hegemony . No longer could tariff barriers circumscribe polarizing forces emanating from core areas : multinationals, for example, simply leapt over tariff barriers . The relationship between industrialization and national power and wealth thus changed dramatically: in South Africa, as in many other semiperipheral areas , the commanding heights of the industrial sector came to depend upon and be limited by decisions , technology, capital goods, and trade coursing through the channels of multinational enterprises. In a similar fashion independent action by noncore states became less and less possible as U. S . hegemony was asserted throughout the nooks and crannies of the interstate system. For states such as South Africa, prosperity thus came to rest upon economic expansion in core areas that could sustain continued investment inflows and favorable terms of exchange with core areas . The 1 960s and early 1970s reaf firmed the apparent wisdom of a semiperipheral model based upon acceptance of the new world order. By the mid- 1 970s , however, the full effects of the world depression struck South Africa, and the inability to sustain and reproduce even the economic assumptions of the apartheid regime became fully apparent. Similar effects soon became evident all across the semiperiphery where "development by invitation" or "dependent development" had been relatively successful dur ing the postwar boom. Many have postulated that full-blown " peripheral Fordism, " seizing upon ongoing changes and opportunities in the global division of labor, now offers such states the best opportunity of advance toward core status in the world-economy. Indeed, apartheid has itself been termed a limited form of " racial Fordism, " sustaining industrial advance by expanding the high income of white consumers (Gelb 1 987). The implication for South Africa and other similarly situated states is that a redistri bution of wealth could push this process by stimulating greater mass production. Neither the expansion of demand nor higher levels of industrial output, however, are likely to be as possible or successful as is often suggested. A " Fordist" solu tion would require-as occurred during South Africa's interwar and postwar transitions-a radical reorganization of relationships between capital, labor, and the state. Here the limits imposed by changes in core-periphery networks im pinge severely . In core areas Fordism resolved labor-capital-state relationships by melding high wages , high productivity , and mass consumption. These were not simply elements of advanced industrial production but were based upon at tributes of accumulation in core areas: oligopolistic profits derived from highly innovative products and (continuous-flow) labor processes . As core areas have deindustrialized and semiperipheral areas industrialized, semiperipheral areas have inherited continuous-flow labor processes but not the South Africa's Semiperipheral Regimes 221 oligopolistic profits and high wages sustained by innovation. The result i s Ford ism in its labor-process aspect, but the blockage of the high-wage/mass-consump tion relationship as automobiles, steel, simple electronic goods, and so on have become standardized products subject to increasingly competitive production. Simply stated, the production of such commodities no longer generates oligopolistic profits, high wages, and thus mass consumption. For areas such as South Africa that have captured part of this ongoing process, the contradictory effects of these global developments are all too apparent. On the one hand, the workplace bargaining power of labor has been considerably enhanced, as is evident in the increasing unruliness of labor on the factory floor and in the political arena. On the other hand, capital and the state remain unable to strike the bargains reached in the United States during the 1930s and in Europe during the 1960s because the global rewards associated with such production pro cesses and a world-expansionary climate are absent. It should hardly surprise us, therefore, that labor and social unrest, and a desperate search for a means of politically containing them, have accelerated all across the industrializing semiperiphery. Such conclusions seem as equally applicable to South Africa as they are to the South Koreas, Brazils, Mexicos, and Polands of the semiperiphery. To be sure, in each state the handling of the contradictory aspects of semiperipherality in this late twentieth-century depression will surely be distinctive. In the instance of South Africa, majority rule will reforge, on the principles of a democratic and unitary state, a more stable political consensus. A postapartheid state would inherit, moreover, several critical features that may advantage the task of accelerated accumulation: a strong and in several areas a technologically advanced state sec tor; a defensive and yet highly concentrated and centralized ("monopoly" ) sec tor of national capital; and the weakened presence of foreign capital due to capital flight, disinvestment, and the forced repayment of debt. Whether and to what extent such elements could coalesce and form the for expanded accumulation and movement upwards in the international of labor remains to be seen. To be sure, some level of redistribution would pand the domestic market, and the political alliances across southern Africa cruing from over two decades of anticolonial and anti settler struggles could translated into a broader regional market and more sustained efforts to contain polarizing forces emanating from core zones of the world-economy. More prob lematical will be meeting the demands for equality and social justice. As is evi dent throughout much of the semiperiphery, these demands now speak with the powerful voice of a burgeoning labor movement. The forging of a new institu tional relationship between capital, labor, and the state-as was done in both the 1920s and the early apartheid period-will be an exceedingly difficult task. Pros pects here are especially clouded given world conditions, the legacy of decades of foreign investment, and the historical aversion of South Africa' s largest enter prises to the pursuit of innovative production processes. The legacy of the apar theid epoch will weigh heavily indeed upon any majority-rule government. 222 Ethnicity: Propelling or Checking Advance? How these elements might be combined and fashioned even in a period of global expansion remains open for further analysis .2 What is evident, however, is that no national solution to South Africa's, and even the semiperiphery 's, current crisis can arise simply from a rise in export revenues , new inflows of foreign capital, or even increased demand for basic consumer goods. Advance within the world economy cannot be fashioned simply by correct policies toward the external market but will depend upon a new social and political order corresponding to radical changes in the regional and global arena. If the semiperipheral regime denoted by apartheid has failed, it remains most uncertain what will replace it. South Africa, like the rest of the semiperiphery , faces a turbulent future. NOTES 1 . For a detailed example of this process in the metals industry, see Webster 1985, 45- 122. In sectors less dominated by artisans, such as beverage and food processing and textiles, the challenge was greater still. 2. This question is currently being addressed by the Fernand Braudel Center's Research Working Group on Southern Africa and the World-Economy; see Martin 1986. REFERENCES Barber, James. 1973 . South Africa 's Foreign Policy, 1945-1970. London: Oxford University Press. Freund, Bill. 1 987. "Defending South African Capitalism. " Transformation 3 : 84-97. Gelb, Steve. 1 987. "Making Sense of the Crisis. " Transformation 5 : 33-50. Johnstone, Frederick. 1976. Class, Race, and Gold. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Lewis, John. 1984. Industrialisation and Trade Union Organisation in South Africa, 1924-1955. London: Cambridge University Press. Lipton, Merle. 1 985 . Capitalism and Apartheid. Totowa: Rowman and Allanheld. Martin, William G. 1984. " Cycles, Trends , or Transformation? Black Labor Migration to the South African Gold Mines. " In Labor in the Capitalist World-Economy, edited by C . Bergquist, 157-79. Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. . 1986. " Southern Africa and the World-Economy: Cyclical Rhythms and Struc tural Constraints on Transformation. " Review 10, 3 : 99- 1 1 9 . . 1 990a. " Region Formation under Crisis Conditions : South v s . Southern Africa in the Interwar Period. " Journal of Southern African Studies 16, 1 , March. . 1 990b. " The Making of an Industrial South Africa: Trade and Tariffs in the Interwar Period . " International Journal ofAfrican Historical Studies 23, 2: 59-85 . Nedbank Economic Unit. 1983. South Africa: An Appraisal. Johannesburg: Nedbank Group Economic Unit. O'Meara, Dan. 1983. Volkskapitalisme. Johannesburg: Ravan Press. Saul, John, and Steve Gelb. 1986. The Crisis in South Africa, New York: Monthly Review Press. South Africa. 1960. Union Statistics for Fifty Years. Pretoria: Government Printer. ___ ___ ___ South Africa's Semiperipheral Regimes 223 . 1972 . Report of the Commission ofEnquiry into the Export Trade of the Republic of South Africa. Pretoria: Govenunent Printer. . 1982. South African Statistics 1982 . Pretoria: Govenunent Printer, 1982. . Board of Trade and Industries. 1945. Report No. 282: Investigation into Manufac turing Industries. Cape Town: Cape Times. Stahl, C. W. 1 98 1 . "Migrant Labour Supplies, Past, Present, and Future: With Special Reference to the Gold Mining Industry. " In Black Migration to South Africa, edited by W. R. Bohning, 7-44. Geneva: International Labour Office. United Nations . Various years . Statistical Yearbook. Geneva: United Nations. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979 . "Dependence in an Interdependent World: The Limited Possibilities of Transformation within the Capitalist World-Economy. " In Immanuel Wallerstein, The Capitalist World-Economy, 66-94. London: Cambridge Univer ___ ___ sity Press. Webster, Eddie. 198 5 . Cast i n a Racial Mould: Labour Process and Trade Unionism in the Foundries . Johannesburg: Ravan Press. World Bank. 1970, 1976, 1989. World Tables. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. World Bank. 1978-1989. World Development Report. New York: Oxford University Press. BIBLIOGRAPHY Amin, Samir, Giovanni Arrighi, Andre Gunder Frank, and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1 982. Dynamics of Global Crisis. New York: Monthly Review Press. Arrighi, Giovanni, ed. 1 985 . Semiperipheral Development: Th e Politics of Southern Europe in the Twentieth Century . Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel. 1986. "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone. " Review 10, 1 :9-74. Arrighi, Giovanni, Terence K . Hopkins, and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1989. Antisystemic Movements . London: Verso. Arrighi, Giovanni, Roberto P. Korzeniewicz, and William G. Martin . 1985 . " Three Crises, Three Zones : Core-Periphery Relations in the Long Twentieth Century. " Cahier du GIS Economie Mondiale, Tiers Monde, Developpement 6 (March) : 97- 1 20. Chase-Dunn, Christopher. 1988. "Comparing World-Systems: Toward a Theory of peripheral Development. " Comparative Civilizations Review 1 9 : 29-66. Cumings, Bruce. 1984. "The Origins and Development of the Northeast Asian Economy: Industrial Sectors, Product Cycles, and Political Consequences. national Organization 3 8 , 1 : 1 -40. Deyo, Frederic C . , ed. 1987. The Political Economy ofthe New Asian Indnstrialis m. N. Y . : Cornell University Press. Emmanuel, Arghiri. 1972. Unequal Exchange. New York: Monthly Review Press. Evans, Peter. 1979 . Dependent Development: Ihe Alliance of Multinational, State, and Local Capital in Brazil. Princeton, N . J . : Princeton University Press. Evans, Peter, and John D. Stephens. 1988. "Development and the World-Economy. " In Handbook of Sociology, edited by Neil Smelser, 739-73. Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. Frobel, F . , J. Heinrichs, and O. Kreye. 1 980. The New International Division ofLabour. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gordon, David M. 1988. "The Global Economy: New Edifice o r Crumbling Founda tions? " New Left Review 1 6 8 : 24-64. Harris, Nigel. 1986. Ihe End of the Ihird World: Newly Industrializing Countries and the Decline of an Ideology. Harmondsworth: Penguin. 226 Bibliography Lipietz, Alain. 1 987. Mirages and Miracles. London: Verso. Mouzelis, Nicos. 1986. Politics in the Semi-periphery: Early Parliamentarism and Late Industrialisation in the Balkans and Latin America. London: Macmillan. O'Donnell, Guillermo. 1973 . Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Taylor, Peter. 1988. " Alternative Geography: A Supportive Note on Arrighi and Drangel. " Review I I , 4:567-79. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1984. Ihe Politics of the World-Economy: The States, the Movements, and the Civilizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. . 1 985. "The Relevance of the Concept of Semiperiphery to Southern Europe. " In Semiperipheral Development: The Politics of Southern Europe in the Twentieth Century, edited by Giovanni Arrighi, 3 1-39 . Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage. Warren, Bill. 1980. Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism. London: New Left Books. __ INDEX Agriculture: capital intensive, in Israel, 166; European Economic Commun ity, 126-28; import substitution of foodstuffs , 74-75 , in Israel, 1 66-68; land policies in colonial Malaysia, 192; large landowners , 71 ; machinery, 147; modernization of, in Chile, 70-75; South African settler, 208 , 2 1 0 ; state assistance to, 72-73 . See also Primary products Allende, Salvador, 7 1 Alliance for Progress, 7 1 Anderson, Benedict, 1 85 Angola, 2 1 8 Apartheid: and industrialization, 205, 2 15- 17; limits of, 2 1 7- 1 8 ; "organic crisis " of, 205; reform of, 2 1 8 . See also South Africa A-phase. See Kondratieff waves Argentina: exports, 101 ; labor in, 103-9; as model, 33-34; versus NICs after World War II, 97-98. See also Peronism Arrighi, Giovanni, 5 , 97 Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel, 1 9 , 22, 48-49, 80, 99 , 1 00 , 125 , 142, 163; critique of, 128. Australia, 100 Authoritarian regimes: Chile, 73; crises of, 28-29, 3 1-32; economic growth, 85 ; "popular democracies" in Eastern Europe, 26; in Latin America, South ern Europe, and USSR, 26. See also Bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes; Military regimes Balance of payments : Israel, 159, 1 64, 171 Balance o f trade: crises i n Argentina 104, 109; Chile, 72 Banking and finance: Canada, 145; Chile, 7 1 ; City of London, 2 1 1 ; change rate in Israel, 1 7 1 ; tional community, 76; South Reserve Bank, 2 1 l . See also tional monetary system Biafra, 1 94 Bourgeoisie: and antisystemic regimes, 29; merchant-industrial in Nigeria, 187; South Korea, 85, 90. See also Capital; Class B-phases . See Great Depression; Kon dratieff waves Brazil: labor movement, 1 15 ; state policies, I I O- l l ; Vargas regime, 104-5 Bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes, 26, 79, 83; Argentina, I l l ; Latin 228 Index America and South Korea compared, 84; models, 3 ; South America, 69; state, 1 1 3 . See also Authoritarian regimes; Military regimes Canada: position in world division of labor, 147-55; hydroelectricity, 145; industrial late-comer, 145; a s member of semiperiphery, 100; theories of development of, 142-44 Capital: Afrikaner and English, 2 1 8 ; Muslim mercantile, 1 90 Capital concentration, 147. See also Monopoly capital Capital flight, 1 3 Capital flows: t o Chile, 72; forcible and voluntary 1 3 ; to Israel, 1 63-64; within world-economy, 12. See also Debt; Foreign direct investment Cardoso and Faletto, 1 12, 143 Center-periphery : polarization, 12; rela tional structure, 47. See also World division of labor Central-peripheral states , 141-42, 154 Chaebol, 83, 90 Chase-Dunn, Christopher, 3 1-32, 37 Cheap labor: in footwear industry, 5 8 ; South Africa, 215; South Korea, 84. See also Wages Chicago Boys, 72-73 Chile: CORFO (state development cor poration) , 72; economic changes under Pinochet, 73-75; import substitution, 70-7 1 , 75; populist developmentalism in, 70; repression, 70; state and market, 70-77; struc tural economic reforms under Eduardo Frei government, 7 1 Chinese: i n Malaysia, 1 86-87, 190, 1 92; traders, 1 90 Chun Doo Hwan, President, 89 Classes: Arab, 172-73; dominant and state, 7, 1 15 ; feudal , 193 ; Muslim aristocracy, 190-9 1 ; overlap with ethnicity, 1 7 1 ; popular in South Korea versus Latin America, 86; rentier, 190; ruling, 29; South Africa, 2 1 8 ; South Korea, 88-89 . See also Proletarianization; Working class . Cold War, 1 95-96 Colonialism: British policy in Malaysia, 192; and ethnic stratification, 196; in direct rule, 1 86, 190-9 1 ; Japanese, 82, 1 84; political parties under, 193; Portuguese, 209, 217- 1 8 Commodity chain: concept, 47-48, 50; footwear, 5 1 -55 Communist Party : coercive rule, 30; "democratization" of national wealth, 30; Malaysia, 195 Comparative advantage: Argentina, 107; Canada, 1 47 ; and industrial develop ment, 1 5 5 ; and semiperipheral state, 17 Core: Canada as member, 147; countries' ascent to, 14; definition by wealth, 15; expansion of, to areas of new settlement, 1 3 ; Ireland along perimeter of, 130; measured by · GNP per capita, 19-22; oligarchic wealth of, 17- 1 8 , 22; organic members of, 22, 205; perimeter of, 19-2 1 ; production processes and innovation, 84, 1 16; states, 12, 30. See also Central peripheral states; World division of labor Core enterprises: competition between, 3 3 ; concessions to labor, 27; move ment to semiperiphery, 27-28. See also Multinational corporations Corporatism, 26; Peronism compared to other, 105-6; South Africa, 2 1 3 Costa Rica, 2 6 , 32 C6te d'lvoire, 128 Crisis of dictatorships, 26 . See also Authoritarian regimes; Bureaucratic authoritarian regimes; Legitimacy ; Semipheriphery, contradictions of Cumings, Bruce, 83, 1 1 3 , 1 15 Currency devaluation, 72 Debt: dependency of South Korea, 8 3 ; financing development, 8 0 ; world crisis, 24 Index Deindustrialization: of core, 6, 1 1- 1 2 , 8 8 , 220; as defense of core status, 7 . See also New international division of labor; World division of labor Democracy: new forms in semipheri phery, 35; Japanese mode, 92 ; parliamentary , 26, 32; prosystemic , 32-33 ; semiperipheral , linked to North America and Western Europe, 3 3 ; South Africa, 2 1 9 Democratization, 7 9 , 1 17 ; Chile, 76-77; and crisis of semiperipheral regimes , 9; South Korea, 9 1 Dependence: commercial and financial, 1 43 ; technological, 88, 1 43 , 154 Dependency theory : and Canada, 1 52-55; classical form, 1 12 ; and in dustrialization, I I , 143; interwar ap plication, 220; neo-dependency theories, 1 43 Dependent development, 80-82, 1 12- 14, 141 , 220 Deregulation: Chile, 72 Deutscher, Isaac, 30 Development. See Dependent develop ment; Industrialization; Semiperiphery; World division of labor Developmentalism, 79; illusion of, 22; and industrialization, 24; populist, in Chile, 70; and progress, 9; and race, 203-5; stages of growth, 6 Development of underdevelopment, 176. See also Dependency theory Deyo, Frederic, 83-84, 86, 90 Dominions: South African growth com pared to, 2 1 3 Eastern Europe: political regimes, 26; proletarianization in, 29 ; redistribu tion of wealth, 27; ruling elites, 29 "Economic miracles " : Israel, 159; South Korea, 3 3 , 8 3 ; Taiwan, 3 3 Education: Canada, 1 4 6 ; imbalances in Nigeria, 1 94; Ireland, 1 3 1 ; Israel, 1 70; missionary in Nigeria, 1 8 8 Emmanuel, Arghiri, 5 , 1 2 229 Empires: Indian, 1 89; Muslim, 1 87, 189; Oyo, 1 87 Ethnic groups: Ashkenazi (Israel) , 1 7 1 ; concept, 1 8 5 ; origins of Malay, 1 89 Ethnicity: colonial construction of, 1 84, 190-93 ; cost of diversity, 1 83 ; and division of labor, 8 , 1 84, 1 93-94; and formation of political parties, 193 ; Nigeria and Malaysia compared, 1 85-90; repression of Arab minority in Israel , 1 69; South Korean homogeneity , 1 84; state intervention blocked by , 198; state and nation building in Israel, 1 64 Ethnonationalism, cultural and structural theories of, 1 85 European Economic Community (EEC): Common Agricultural Policy, 126-28; and Ireland, 126, 1 3 1 Evans, Peter, 92. See also Dependent development Exclusion, processes of, 1 6- 1 8 Exploitation, processes of, 1 6 - 1 8 Exports : agricultural, from Chile, 72, 74; Canada, 1 5 1 ; competition in footwear, 58-59; distribution and marketing networks, 60-61 ; diver sification, Chile, 75; level of pro cessing, 1 34-35; low-waged, 162; networks, 59-60; niches , footwear, 61-65 (figure 62) ; primary product, 1 9 1 ; South Korea, 64; structure in Argentina, 1 0 1 ; Taiwan, 64-65. also Export-oriented Tariff protection; Trade Export-oriented industrialization (EOI) , 80; Ireland, 126; models, 3 ; South Korea, 7, 83-84 Fascism: Chile, 76; Europe, 69; regimes, 26; southern Europe, interwar, 105 Federated Malay States, 192-93 Firebaugh and Bullock method, 126, 1 32-36 Fordism, 1 3 5 ; peripheral, 220; racial, 220; relations between labor, capital, state, 10; semiperipheral, 221 230 Index Foreign direct investment: attraction of semiperiphery for, 80; Canada, 144; of Canadian firms, 149-50; com parisons with Canada, 147; Ireland, 130; in South Africa, 2 1 6- 1 7 ; of South African firms, 2 1 6 ; United States, in Canada, 149. See also Multinational corporation Foreign exchange: deficits, 2 8 ; liberalization, 1 7 2 ; surpluses, 28 Foreign investment codes: Chile, 72 Footwear production: commodity chain of, 5 1 -5 5 ; distribution and marketing networks , 60-61 ; domestic capital, 54; exports to United States, 5 1 -5 3 ; firm size, 57-59; geographical shift in production, 54; peripheral produc tion, 6 5 ; product specialization, 59-60; profits from, 54, 66; raw materials in production, 56-57; upgrading of industry, 63-64 Foxley, Alejandro, 72 Free trade: policy, 209; system, British, 2 1 0 ; United States-Canada, 1 5 3 Fulani jihad, 1 8 7 General Agreement of Tariffs and Trade (GATT) , 2 1 6 Gerschenkron, Alexander, 1 46 Ghana, 2 1 -22, 49 Gold prices , 209, 2 1 7 Great Depression, 102; Argentina, 103-4; creative destruction during, 6; interwar, and semipheriphery, 103-8; state policies during, 212 Greece, prosystemic democracy, 32 Group o f Seven, 147 Gush, Emunim, 175 Harrod, Roy, 1 5 - 1 6 Hausa, 1 8 6-8 8 , 190 Hegemony : British in southern Africa, 209, 2 1 1 ; crisis of, 3 3 , 102; Canada in relation to United States and British, 145; rivalry, 27; United States, 9, 3 3 , 2 1 6 Hirsch, Fred, 1 5 - 1 6 Hirschman, Albert, 152 Histadrut, 1 66-68 Hobsbawm, Eric, 26 Holland, 1 4 Igbo, 1 86- 8 8 , 1 9 1 Imperialism: passing of, 2 1 6 ; theories of, and industrialization, 143 Import Substitution Industrialization (lSI) : Arg�ntina, 109; Chile, 70-7 1 , 75; Israel, 1 67 ; South America, 69-70; South Korea, 82 Income inequality : Chile, 27, 7 3 ; egalitarian, in East Asia, 45 ; in semiperiphery, 27. See also Inequal ity, world Income redistribution: necessity in Malaysia, 1 9 8 ; prospects of, in South Africa, 221 Incorporation into capitalist world economy: Korea, 82; Malaysia, 1 86-90; Nigeria, 1 86-87; South Africa, 208 ; Taiwan, 82 Independence movements : and Anglo Muslim aristocratic alliances, 1 93 ; Malaysia, 1 85 ; Nigeria, 1 8 6 , 194-95 Indians, in Malaysia, 1 86-87 Industrialization: contradictions of, in South Africa, 2 1 4 ; as measure of development, 46, 130, 204; paths of, 1 44; state promotion of, 144-45. See also Bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes ; Export -oriented industrial ization; World division of labor Industry: capital intensive, 89; domestic, in Ireland, 129; energy intensive, in Canada, 147; foreign-owned, capital intensive, 129; global system of, 45; international competitiveness of, South Korea, 8 9 ; late-comers to, 142; labor intensive, 88, 129; peripheralization of, 24; skill intensive in Israel, 176; by zone, 25 . See also Deindustrialization; World division of labor Inequality . See Income inequality ; In come redistribution; Inequality, world Index Inequality , world: gap between core semipheriphery-periphery , 1 2 , 1 9-20; long-term stability of, 22-24; and in dustrialization, 24 Institutional innovation, 1 14- 15 International division of labor: See World division of labor International Monetary Fund, 2 1 6 International monetary system, 209; and gold, 2 1 7 . See also Banking and finance Interstate system, 6 , 9 Intifadah, 162, 174, 177 Ireland: democracy , 26; and European Economic Community , 126, 1 3 1 ; migration from, 128; prosystemic democracy, 32; trade of, 126-34; and world division of labor, 130, 1 36-37 Islam: law, 1 97-98; and non-capitalist ruling groups, 1 86 ; religion, 1 89; revival, 1 97; scholars, 1 89 Israel : analogy with Eastern Europe and Soviet Union, 34; geo-strategic posi tion, 164; Histadrut, 1 66-68; invest ment rate in, 165; limits of success of, 170-76; as model for semiperi phery, 34-35; occupied territories, 1 75 ; strengthening of Arab minority in, 172 Ivory Coast. See C6te d'lvoire Japan: ascent to core, 1 8 , 2 1 -22; as model for semipheriphery, 1 15 ; sogoshosha, 60 Japanese occupation of Malaysia, 195 Jamaica, prosystemic democracy, 32 Kondratieff waves : expansion (A phrase), 1 59, 209, 2 1 6 ; contraction (B-phase) , 1 3 1 , 2 1 9 . See also Great Depression 231 Australia, 103 ; split markets under apartheid, 2 1 5 ; non-waged reserves of, 28 Labor militancy : Argentina, 1 1 1 ; Malaysia, 195; across semiperiphery , 22 1 , South Africa, 209- 10; South Korea, 89. See also Labor movements ; Strikes; Trade unions Labor movements: Argentina, 106, 109 ; Australia, 102 ; i n core, 27; in semiperiphery , 1 16 ; South Korean, 92. See also Labor militancy; Strikes ; Trade unions Labor parties: Israel, 1 7 1 , 175; South Africa, 2 1 0 Labor process : continuous flow, 2 1 8 ; semi-skilled operative, 2 1 4 Labor repression, 84, 90 Land: Arab, in Israel, 1 66 ; concentration of, in Chile, 74, nationalization and concentration of, in Israel, 165-66 Land reform: Chile, 7 1 , 72 Landowners, Argentina, 101 Late industrialization, 142 , 146; develop ment opportunities of, 143 Latin America. See under specific countries Legitimacy : and state, 85; crisis, in South Korea, 85-86, 90. See also Crisis of dictatorships ; Semiperiphery, crisis of legitimacy Liberalism, in Chile, 73 Libya, 2 1 , 26-27 Likud party , 170-75 Mahdism, 190 Malay : elites and state, 196 Malaysia: Chinese guerrillas, 1 95 ; " Emergency" o f 1 948-1960, 196; ethnic division of labor under colonialism, 1 95 ; ethnic groups, 186; nationalism, 195; UMNO party, 196 Labor, bargaining power: Argentina, 103 , 107 ; of South African miners , 210; workplace, 1 1 1 , 2 1 4 , 2 1 8 , 221 Labor, cheap. See Cheap labor; Wages Mapai/Labor Alignment, 1 70 Marketing boards , Nigeria, 1 9 1 Marx, Karl: o n identities, 1 85 ; and world-system perspective, 15 Labor : institutionalization of, in Mercantilism, European, 1 89 232 Index Middle class: South Korea, 8 9 ; market in South Africa, 2 1 9 Migration: to Canada, 146; China to Malaysia, 1 92 ; from Ireland, 128; to Israel, 163-66; from semiperiphery to core, 27-28 ; skilled labor from Israel, 177; South Africa and cheap labor, 212, 2 1 4 ; southern African, 2 1 5 ; and state manpower policies in Israel, 1 67 Militarization, of Israeli society, 177-78 Military coup : Argentina, 1 1 5 ; Chile, 7 1 ; Nigeria, 194 Military expenditures, 3 1 ; Canada, 154; Israel, 176 Military-industrial-complex, 29; in core, 30; Israeli, 34, 162-63, 1 7 8 ; South Africa, 3 4 Military regimes : 2 6 , 8 5 - 8 6 ; Argentina, I l l ; Chile, 73 ; promotion of economic development, 87 ; South America, 69; South Korea, 8 9 . See also Authoritarian regimes; Bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes Mining: Australia, 10 I; Canada, 10 I ; South Africa, 208 -10; tin, in Malaysia, 1 9 1 Modernization theory, 79, 142; applied to South Africa, 204; and in dustrialization, I I Monetarism, in Chile, 72-73 Monopoly capital , in South Africa, 204 Moslem. See Muslim; Islam Mouzelis, Nicos, 87 Mozambique, 2 1 8 Multinational corporation (MNC): in Canada, 1 44 ; in Chile, 74; in distri bution and marketing networks, 54; and industrialization, 136, 220; in Ireland, 1 2 8 ; nationalization, of, in Chile, 7 1 ; in semiperiphery and de pressions, 1 3 1 ; in South Africa, 2 1 6 Muslim: aristocracy, 190-9 1 ; faith, 1 89 ; rulers , 1 89 ; Nigeria, 1 86 . See also Islam Nationalism: Afrikaner, 2 1 0 , 2 1 5 ; Arab, 169, 1 7 3 , 176; Korean, 1 8 4 ; Malay, 1 9 3 ; Malaysian, 1 95-96; Nigerian 193-95; Palestinian, 1 69 , 173-76 National liberation movements, 27 Nationalist Party (South Africa) , 2 1 5 Neo-liberalism, 72 , 7 4 Netherlands, 129 New comparative political economy , 85 New International Division of Labor, 88, 134. See also World division of labor New International Economic Order, 1 0 Newly Industrializing Countries (NICs): and commodity chains, 50; competi tion between, 49; East Asia, 46, 8 1 ; export-oriented, 49; models and literature, 3-4; Pacific Rim and Southern Europe, 1 42 ; position in world hierarchy , 46. See also Bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes; Industrialization; World division of labor; under specific countries Newly Underdeveloping Country (NUC): Chile, 73 ; South Africa, 206 Nigeria: civil war, 1 94; coup, 194; Rausa, 1 87-8 8 , 190-9 1 ; regions, 1 86 , 1 9 1 , 1 94; Yoruba, 1 86-87, 1 9 1 O 'Donnell, Guillermo, 1 1 3 Oil prices, 1 8 6 Oligopoly profits, 220 Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), 1 97 Organization of Islamic Conference, 1 97 Oriental (Jewish) Revolt, 1 62, 1 7 1 Pact govenment (South Africa), 2 1 0- 1 1 , 2 1 3- 1 4 Palestinian Liberation Organization (PLO), 173-75 Park Chung-hee, President, 90 Patronage, 170 Peasants, Malaysia, 1 9 1 -92 Periphery : competition within, 7; decline due to semiperipheral success, 1 8 ; defined by wealth, 1 5 ; measured by GNP per capita, 19-22; organic members of, 22; perimeter of, 1 9-2 1 ; poverty of, 1 8 , 22; southern African Index zone, 2 1 1 - 1 2 . See also World divi sion of labor Peronism, 10 1 , 105-8 Pinochet, Augusto, 69, 70, 77 Plantations, rubber, in Malaysia, 1 86 Polanyi, Karl, 69-70 Population: distribution by zones of world-economy, 19-20 Populism: Israel, 1 7 1 , 177 Portugal, 32 Primary products: Malaysian exports of, 1 86; Nigerian exports of, 1 86; prices, 209; South African, 208-1 1 ; state promotion of, 101 Proletarianization : Arab, 172-7 3 ; East ern Europe, 29; and power of lower classes, 28; in semiperiphery , 26; of world, 26. See also Working class Protectionism: Argentina, 104, 1 09-10; Chile, 76; interwar, 1 0 2 ; Ireland, 125-26; Southern Europe, 105 ; United States, 1 5 3 . See also State economic policies; Tariff protection Privatization, in Chile, 72 Product life cycle theory, 142 Productivity in manufacturing, comparisons of, 147 , 1 49 Race: South Africa, 203-5; Nigeria, 187 Refugees : Arab , 165-66 Religion: Catholic Church, in Chile, 70; Christian, in Nigeria, 1 8 8 ; and ethnonational identities, 1 9 8 ; Hin duism, 1 89 ; Ireland, 1 3 1 -32; Malay, 192; movement in Israel, 175 Research and development: in Canada, 1 5 3 ; and international competitiveness 84; in South Korean economic growth, 87-88. See also Technological dependency Roh Tae Woo, 89, 91 Rostow, W. W., 1 4 1 -42 Rothgeb, John M. , 1 3 1 Schumpeter, Joseph, 1 5 Semiperipheral states : competition: com petition between , 2 8 , 1 62 ; democratic 233 wealth of, 17, 22; encouraging relocation of industry, 27-28; redistribution 0 f wealth by , 27; See also Semiperiphery Semiperiphery : antisystemic character of, 10, 29 , 3 1 -3 2 ; and cultural integrity , 1 3 1 ; contradictions of, 8-10, 9 1 , 176, 2 1 8-22; crises 0 f prosystemic, 28; crisis of legitimacy in, 35; defini tion of, 5, 1 1 , 1 1 3 , 125; ethnic diversity of, 196-9 8; and global pro cesses, 1 14; institutionalization and development of, 108-14; as measured by Firebaugh and Bullock method, 132-35; as measured by GNP per capita, debate over, 5 , 19-22, 126-28 , 1 3 6 ; as measured by Mingst method, 1 28-32; membership of, 4-5 , 47 ; mobility of, Ireland, 1 36-37; organic members of, 22; prospects of, 1 98-99; prosystemic role of, 10, 3 1 ; South Africa com pared to other semiperipheries, 207; stability of, 4; as stabilizer of world economy, 10, 3 1 , 1 3 5 ; and world division of labor, 27-28 . See also World division of labor Skocpol, Theda, 86 Slave trade, 13, 1 87 Social movements, 9-10; ethnic support for, 198; in Israel, 1 75-76. See also Labor; Nationalism Socialism, in Chile, 7 1 , 76 Sogo-shosha , as model for South 60 South Africa: analogy with Eastern Europe and Soviet Union, 34; com pared to other semiperipheries, 2 1 9 ; as model for semiperiphery, 34-3 5 ; position i n world division o f labor, 205. See also Apartheid Southern Africa: as region of world economy, 2 1 7 South Korea: ascent t o semiperiphery , 3 3 ; bureaucracy in, 85, chaebol, 8 3 , 90; democracy in, 9 1 -92; ethnic homogeneity of, 1 84; politics in, 234 Index 85-87 ; prospects of, 87-89; social forces and classes in, 89-9 1; state and development, 8 1 -85; student movement in, 89; upward mobility in world-economy, 21-22; urban poor of, 89 Spain: post-Franco model, 33, prosystemic democracy in, 32 Stabilization policies in Chile, 72 Staple theory, 144-45 State: aid to small urban producers, in Chile, 7 1 ; alliance with indigenous capital , 90, 1 97 (see also Dependent development) ; bureaucracy and ethnicity , 197; warfare, in Israel, 177. See also Authoritarian regimes ; Bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes; Military regimes State and foreign investment, 83, 1 13 , 126; Brazil compared to Argentina, I I I - 1 2 ; Israel, 166-67; State and market: Argentina, 107 ; Chile, 70-77; Israel , 163. See also Protec tionism; State economic policies State autonomy , 85; as organization of interests, 86; Israel, 160, 169, 17 1-72; South Korea, 83, 86-87; and successful development, 8 "State-centered development, " 7, 8, 8 1 State economic policies : Argentina, 103-4, 109- 10; Australia, 1 0 1 -2; autarchic, i n Ireland, 1 2 5 , 1 3 1 ; Canada, 101-2; Chile, 72; footwear production, 5 5 ; Israel, 162-65 , 167; Malaysia, 186, 198; on manpower, Israel, 167; and mobility between zones of world-economy, 7, 48; Nigeria, 188, 193-94, 197; Pinochet model, 72, 75 . See also Bureau cratic-authoritarian regimes ; Export oriented industrialization; Protectionism State enterprises: Canada, 146; Chile, 73; South Africa, 2 1 1 State labor policy: in Argentina, 106-9 (see also Peronism); "civilized labor" in South Africa; in Israel (see also Histadrut) , 168; in South Korea, 83, 90 Stock exchange crisis, in Israel, 172 Strikes: Argentina, 106; Australia, 1 02; Israel, 1 7 1 ; South Africa, 214; South Korea, 90-91 . See also Labor militancy; Trade unions Taiwan: ascent within world division of labor, 2 1 , 33 Tariff protection, 1 3 1 ; Chile, 70-7 1 , 73; South Africa, 2 1 1 -12 Tariff reductions, in Chile, 72 Technological dependency, 143 ; Canada, 154; South Korea, 88 Terms of trade: Argentina, 100 Textile production: Ireland, 129 Trade: Asian world-system, 189; Atlan tic, 1 87 ; collapse in 1 930s, 70; India-China route, 189; Ireland' s partners , 1 32-34; level of pro cessing, 132-35; of primary pro ducts in Argentina, 101 ; semiperipheral pattern of, 1 3 2 ; theories of, and industrial develop ment, 1 42 . See also Protectionism; Tariff protection Traders: Chinese, 190, 192; large trading companies, 59, 60; small ex port, 60 Trade unions: Argentina, 106, I l l ; Chile, 69, 73; Histadrut (Israel) , 1 66-68; rise of, in semiperiphery, 9 ; South Africa, 2 1 8 ; South Korea, 90-9 1 . See also Labor militancy; Labor movement Trading empires, 1 86 Trinidad and Tobago, 26 Unequal exchange: active engagement in, 17; and defining zones of world economy , l l-14; and high wages, 13; and labor flows, 12; method of measurement of, 126; and semiperiphery-core relations, 1 7 ; and world inequality, l l -14. See also Emmanuel, Arghiri Index Union of Soviet Socialist Republics: pro letarianization in, 29; and redistribu tion of wealth, 27; ruling elites, 29-30 United Nations , and South Africa, 2 1 6 United States, 1 3 ; aid to Israel, 1 63 , 1 75 , 1 77 ; aid to South Korea, 83; global strategy of, 1 77 . See also Hegemony Wages: female, 5 8 ; low, and competi tion, 85, 1 64; and productivity in Israel, 162 ; South Korea, 89; world levels, 1 2 . See also Cheap labor Waisman, Carlos H. , 97, 106 Wallerstein, Immanuel, 3 1 , 8 1 , 100- 1 0 1 , 143; o n semiperipheral trade, 1 32 , 134 War: Anglo-Boer, 208; intra-Yoruba, 1 8 8 ; Israel, 165, 169, 173-75 , 178; Nigerian civil, 185; reparations to Israel, 1 64-65 Warren, Bill, 1 4 Wealth: oligarchic and democratic, 15-17 Working class: Israel, 1 67 , 1 77 ; power of, 69; South Africa, 2 1 8 ; South 235 Korea, 90; Soviet, 30. See also Labor militancy; Labor movement; Proletarianization World division of labor: classic pattern, 45 ; competition within, 1 7 - 1 8 , 84, 1 00; and ethnicity, 1 8 3 , 1 97-99; footwear production, 66; in dustrialization of semiperiphery, 220; membership of zones, 19-2 1 ; move ment across zones, 6, 7, 48 ; redivi sion, 4, 7, 9; short-term mobility, 22; specialized niches within, 1 5 , 85; stability of zones of, 1 9 ; upward mobility, 2 1 ; zones, definition of, 99. See also Inequality , world; New In ternational Division of Labor World-system perspective: critiques of, 8 1 ; compared to dependency theory, 80, 97, 1 1 3-14; definition of core periphery, 14, 1 8 ; and ethnicity , 1 83 , 197-99; extending, 85; and na tionalism, 1 8 3 ; and semiperiphery, 4; and state, 101, 1 1 4; and South Africa, 205; unit of analysis , 6 Yoruba, 1 86-87, 1 9 1 Yugoslavia, 27 ABOUT THE CONTRIBUTORS GIOVANNI ARRIGHI is professor of sociology at the State University of New York at Binghamton and a board member of the Fernand Braudel Center. He is author of the Geometry of Imperialism and coauthor of Dynamics of Global Crisis, Antisytemic Mo vements, and Transforming the Revolutio n: Social Move ments and the World-System. GARY GEREFFI is associate professor of sociology at Duke University. He is the author of The Pharmaceutical Ind ustry and Depend ency in the Third Wo rld and coeditor of Manufactured Miracles: Paths ofIndustrialization in Latin America and East Asia. H e has served as a consultant to the United Nations Centre Transnational Corporations and organizations concerned with essential drugs grams in developing nations. His current research focuses on organizations port networks, and global competitiveness and on their implications for ment theory. WALTER GOLDFRANK is professor of sociology at the University of California, Santa Cruz . He edited Ihe Wo rld-System of Capitalism: Past and Present and has published on semiperipheral processes in Mexico, the USSR, Japan, and Italy. RICHARD GRANT is a Ph.D. candidate in political geography at the Universi ty of Colorado at Boulder. MIGUEL KORZENIEWICZ is an assistant professor in the Department of Sociology at the University of New Mexico. ROBERTO P. KORZENIEWICZ teaches sociology at Skidmore College and is a research associate at the Fernand Braudel Center at the State University of New 238 About the Contributors York at Binghamton. He has published several articles on the labor movement in Argentina. His current work centers on labor unrest, democracy, and develop ment in the semiperiphery. SU-HOON LEE is assistant professor of sociology and director of planning at the Institute for Far Eastern Studies at Kyungnam University in South Korea. He is the author of State Building in the Contemporary Third World (1988) . His current research interests include global militarization, world inequality, and the linkage between local modes of production and the dynamics of the world-economy. PAUL M. LUBECK is professor of sociology and history at the University of California, Santa Cruz, where he teaches political economy and development studies. He has published extensively on Nigeria, Islamic social movements , and capitalist development in Africa. His book, Islam and Urban Labor in Northern Nigeria, received the Herskovits Prize in 1987. His current research explores accumula tion, social movements , and state industrial policy in the Pacific Rim . DONALD LYONS is a Ph . D . candidate in political geography at the University of Colorado at Boulder. WILLIAM G. MARTIN teaches sociology and Africap studies at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. His research and publications have focused on southern Africa as a "region" of the world-economy and on antisystemic movements ; several large-scale studies, the result of individual and collaborative work, are presently being completed. Current research extends this work to similar semiperipheral areas , regions , and movements . JORGE NIOSI is professor at the Universiie du Quebec in Montreal (UQAM) , Canada, and director of its Centre for Research on the Development of Industry and Technology. He studied sociology in Argentina and economics in Paris, where he received his Ph .D. ( 1 973) . He is the author of six books and nearly thirty ar ticles , most on Canadian economy and society . DONNA RAE PALMER is a doctoral candidate in the Board of Studies in Sociol ogy at the University of California at Santa Cruz. She is currently writing a disser tation on the social consequences of industrial development policy in Malaysia. BEVERLY SILVER is a research associate of the Fernand Braudel Center and author of several articles on labor unrest in the world-economy. She is currently completing a long-term, large-scale analysis of the world labor movement. DAVID A. SMITH is assistant professor of sociology at the University of Califor nia, Irvine. His recent research focuses on comparative urbanization and socioeconomic development, Third World political change, and network analysis of the structure and dynamics of the world-economy. Studies in the Political Economy of the World-System (Formerly published as Political Economy of the World-System Annuals) - 1 . Social Change in the Capitalist World-Economy edited by Barbara Hockey Kaplan 2 . The World-System of Capitalism: Past and Present edited by Walter L. Goldfrank 3 . Processes of the World-System � I O! r;; V edited by Terence K. Hopkins and Immanuel Wallerstein 4. Dynamics of World Development edited by Richard Rubinson 5. Ascent and Decline in the World-System edited by Edward Friedman 6. Crises in the World-System edited by Albert Bergesen 7. Labor in the Capitalist World-Economy edited by Charles Bergquist 8 . States versus Markets in the World-System edited by Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Evelyne Huber Stephens 9. Crises in the Caribbean Basin: Past and Present edited by Richard Tardanico 1 0 . Rethinking the Nineteenth Century: Contradictions and Movements edited by Francisco O. Ramirez 1 1 . Racism, Sexism, and the World-System edited by Joan Smith, Jane Collins, Terence K. Hopkins, and Akbar Mu:hal'l1m'ad 12. Revolution in the World-System edited by Terry Boswell 1 3 . War in the World-System edited by Robert K. Schaeffer Numbers 1-9 published by Sage Publications