Download GTAP Resource 5275

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup

Abenomics wikipedia , lookup

Uneven and combined development wikipedia , lookup

Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Production for use wikipedia , lookup

Đổi Mới wikipedia , lookup

Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Is Japanese economic growth possible under a decrease in population? :
Policy implication of dynamic spatial CGE model with endogenous
growth mechanism
Abstract
This paper tried to measure influences of population decline in matured economy like Japan
with consideration of mutual relations of technological progress and population growth. The
spatial dynamic computable general equilibrium model (SD-CGE model) was used to
concretely show the future situation of economy. The simulation results demonstrated that
(i)technological progress caused by knowledge capital stocks is critical for keeping the GDP
level as the present situation in Japan where population is decreasing, (ii) in urban area, such as
Kanto region, GDP can continue to increase, because inflow of fund and labor force occurs, but
other regions face serious decline in GDP, (iii) Japan cannot achieve 600 trillion yen ( 5.5 trillion
dollars) of GDP in the future under population decline, which is the policy target of Japan, even
if the past invested capital stocks in our society was taken into accounts, (iv) furthermore, the
more serious problem will happen after the 2030's, and GDP turns into decrease due to a
decrease in knowledge capital stocks. To avoid such decrease in GDP, the government should
keep demand for manufacturing products by enhancing children support program for an
increase in birth rate of young generations.
1.Introduction
Japanese government aims to achieve 6 trillion dollars of gross domestic production (GDP)
in 2020, which is 1.13 times higher than present GDP level. A growth in GDP is easy if
1
population increases in the future, but Japanese population is now decreasing and total
population will be 2/3 of present population in 2050. Hence, there are some big questions on
whether Japan can increase its GDP under population decline and whether such growth is
sustainable or not. To answer such questions is important and interesting for policy making.
In general, one of the most effective measures to increase GDP under population decline is
to increase in efficiency of industrial production (Solow, 1956; Swan, 1956; Yoshikawa, 2016).
Research and development (R&D) investment and public investment, such as road construction
and irrigation and farmland consolidation, can contribute to such purpose. However, such
prescription on decreasing population economy is based on an independency of population
change and technological progress. If these two factors relate each other, optimal policy for
matured economy would be completely different from common theory. There is no information
on how much effects can emerge in Japan. Furthermore, the R&D investments improve
different industries, and industries which are influenced by these investments are differently
located in each region. Hence, regional impacts of these investments are probably different in
regions, and hence there are two different influences of these investments regarding the regional
gaps in gross production. Based on such aspects of these measures for two kinds investments,
we also need to consider effects of both types investments simultaneously to evaluate regional
impacts.
To tackle these issues, this study aims to analyze future Japanese economic situation, when
research and development investment and public investment stay at the present level. We use
dynamic spatial computable general equilibrium model which endogenizes private R&D
investment and its influence on industrial production and considers effects of public facilities,
such as road, irrigation facilities and consolidated farmland, on total factor productivity of
agriculture, distribution industries and electricity and gas industry. We also simulate future
2
economic growth and gaps of regional production by such DS-CGE model.
2.Method
(1) CGE Model
The model used here is the recursive-dynamic spatial CGE model (SD-CGE model) with
multiple regions.
The structure of our model is based on the work of Bann (2007), which uses
GAMS (GAMS Development Corporation) and MPSGE (a modeling tool using the mixed
complementary problem), as developed by Rutherford (1999). The basic model structure is as
follows.
The cost functions derived from the production functions are defined as nested-type CES
(constant elasticity of substitution) forms. The structure of production part is shown in Figure
1. In this part, degrees of spatial dependence among regional products for intermediate inputs
are represented by spatial trade substitution elasticities (σr). The spatial substitution elasticities
on commodity flows were measured by empirical studies Koike et al. (2012) showed these
values were less than one, showing inelastic situation of spatial commodity flows and low
spatial dependence. On the other hand, Tsuchiya et al. (2005) showed that these values used in
previous SCGE models differed from 0.40 to 2.87 and were higher than substitution elasticities
between domestic goods and imported goods. There were big differences in these values
according to data, methods and kinds of commodities. Furthermore, spatial substitution
elasticities differ according to time span considered in the study. In the long run, these values
probably become higher than the case of short run. Considering these features of spatial
substitution elasticities, this study took adopted two scenarios in which Japanese economy
keeps inelastic spatial dependence and elastic spatial dependence for comparison of influences
of climate change.
3
Figure 1: Production Structure of Spatial Dynamic CGE Model
Total production
S=2
Total domestic
production
Imports
Exports
S=2
Total outputs
S=0
Value added
production
TFP
Intermediate
Goods 1
S=0.1
Goods 1
Region r1
Farm land
Intermediate
Intermediate
・・・・
Goods 2
Goods n
S=5.0
Goods 1
Regin r2
Goods 1
Region r9
Goods 2
Region r1
Goods n
・・・
Region r9
S=1
Capital stocks
Region r1
Capital stocks
Region r2
Capital stocks
Region r9
Labor
Region r1
Labor
Region r9
The elasticity of substitution of farmland to other input factors, which was not used in Bann
(2007), is assumed to be 0.2 for agriculture. Egaitsu (1985) concluded that the substitutability
of farmland for other input factors was low, but the substitutability between capital and labour
was high, according to empirical evidence on Japanese rice production from several studies.
Based on these findings, we assumed that farmland is a semi-fixed input for agricultural
production and cannot really be substituted by other factors.
Consumption is defined by the nested type function (Figure 2). The first nest is defined by
the linear expenditure system (LES) function derived from consumers’ maximization
4
assumption on utility with Stone-Geary form. The second nest shows spatial dependence among
commodities produced in different regions. As is the case of intermediate inputs in cost function,
the spatial substitution elasticities take two different values, i.e. 0.5 and 5.0, showing low and
high spatial dependence in economy. Other elasticity values of substitution in the consumption,
import, and export functions are set to be the same as those used by Bann (2007), which were
based on the GTAP database. The government consumption and government investment are
Leontief type fixed share function.
Figure 2: Consumers’ Utility Structure in the Model
Household
Consumption
Goods 1
S=5
Goods 1
Region r1
・・・・
Goods 2
S=5
Goods 1
Goods 1
Region
r
2
Region
・・ r9
S=1.0 , εY=0.4~1.0
Goods n
S=5
Goods・・・・・・・
2
Goods
2
Goods n ・・・・・・
Goods n ・
・・・・・
Region r1
Region r9
Region r1
Region r9
Figure 3 shows the government spending structure assuming Leontief substitution elasticity.
5
Figure 3: Government Spending
Government spendings
S=0
Government
consumption
Government
Investment
S=0
Goods 1
Region r1
Goods 1
Region r9
Goods n
・・・・・・
Region r9
S=0
Goods 1
Region r1
Goods 1
Goods n
・・・・・・
Region・・・・・・
r9
Region r9
(2) Modification of CGE model for consideration of endogenous growth
Technological progress of each industry measured by the total factor productivity (TFP) is,
in our model, assumed to occur based on knowledge capital stocks accumulated by the research
and development (R&D) investment. The level of R&D investment (IKP) is defined by the
production level of related industry as:
IK P j ,t  rik j  X
j ,t
(1)
Here, rik is the rate of R&D investment spent by total production of each industry classified
by j sector in year t. X is the total production of related industry. As shown by Eq. (), R&D
investment is endogenously defined by economic growth, and economic growth its self is
influenced by the R&D investment level via knowledge capital and TFP.
In real economy, more than 70 % of the R&D investment is done by the private company,
and the lest of them is invested by the public sector, such as government and university. These
public R&D investment is exogenously provided and allocated in public budget.
The knowledge capital stocks (KKP and KKG) are accumulated by the R&D investment as:
6
KK k (t )  IK k (t  Lag )  IK k (t  Lag  1)    IK k (t  Lag  N )

Lag  N

(2)
IK k (t  i)
i  Lag
Here, superscript k (k ∈ P and G) shows public or private knowledge capital stocks, Lag
is the gestation period of R&D investment, and N is the obsolescence period of knowledge. Lag
is assumed to be 3 years for private R&D investment and 7 years for public R&D investment,
and N is 12 years for private sector and 8 years for public sector. These periods are based on
the questionnaire research of Science and Technology Agency (1999).
TFP of each industry is defined by knowledge capitals stocks, public capital stocks of
infrastructure and management scale of agriculture farms as:
TFPj ,r (t ) / TFPj ,r (t 0 )  KK j ,r (t ) / KK j ,r (t 0 ) 
 Kj
  KG g , j ,r (t ) / KG g , j ,r (t 0 ) 
 gG, j
g
MA
(t ) / MA j ,r (t 0 ) 

(3)
M
j
j ,r
Here, g, j and r respectively show kinds of public infrastructure (roads and agricultural base
facilities), industry and region. KK, KG and MA are knowledge capital stocks, public
infrastructure stocks and average management scale of agriculture farms representing
economies of scale. The subscript t0 shows the initial year (2010) in our model.  K ,  G and
 M are respectively elasticities of knowledge capital, public infrastructure capital and average
scale of agricultural farms. These elasticities are measured by the econometric estimation and
statistic data and shown in Table 1.
7
Table 1
Elasticity values of TFP with respect to factors by industries.
Factors
Sectors
Knowledge
capital
Public
Agriculture farm
infrastructure
management scale
capital
Paddy rice
0.1067
0.1067
0.1067
Dry field production
0.0451
0.0451
0.0451
Livestocks
0.1784
0.1784
0.0330
Transportation and Communication
0.1992
0.1992
-
Electricity and gas
0.0750
0.0750
-
Chemical products
0.0888
-
-
M achine
0.0611
-
-
Electric equipments
0.4892
-
-
Other manufacturing
0.0543
-
-
To form the recursive dynamic path, the capital stock equation is defined by annual
investment (I) and depreciation rate (δ= 0.04), as follows.
K i , r ,t  (1 δ) K i , r ,t 1  I i , r ,t
(4)
In this model, Ki,r,t shows capital stocks in i-th industry of r-th region at year t, and is defined
for every year from I, which is endogenously defined by the CGE model as follows.
 PK j , r (t  1)  ror j
IPj , r (t )  IPj , r (t )
 PK r (t  1)  ror




0.5
IPT (t )
IPT (t  1)
(5)
Here, Ii,r,t0 is initial level of investment in i-th industry of r-th region, PK is service price of
capital stocks representing rate of return of capital stocks and PK is average service price
among industries. 0.5 represents the adjustment speed of investment.
Public infrastructure capital stocks, such as road facilities and agricultural base facilities
like irrigation and drainage canals, are defined as:
KGg ,r ,t  KGg ,r ,t 1  IG g ,r ,t  DG g ,r ,t
(6)
8
Here, g ∈ road facilities and agricultural base facilities, depreciation value of stocks is
derived from actual data on public facilities (Japanese Social Infrastructure Capital, Japanese
Cabinet Office, 2012). In our model, KGg,r,t=2010, IGg,r,t and DGg,r,t are assumed to be
exogenously defined.
Labor forces and investment, which forms capital stocks, are assumed to move among
regions, but farmland cannot move. Considering these features, regional allocation function on
these resources were formed. Labor supply which is one of exogenous variables was assumed
to decrease according to the changes in Japanese population, but regional labor supply was
considered labor force inter-regional immigration based on wage differences as follows.
LS r ,t
 PLr ,t 1 

 LS r ,t 1 
 PL t 1 
0.5
POPt
POPt 1
(7).
Here, LS is labor supply, PL is wage rate, PL is whole country average wage rate, and
POPt / POPt 1 is the growth rate of population. The future population is exogenously provided
according to the prediction of National Institute of Population and Social Security Research
(http://www.ipss.go.jp/).
Total farmland supply, FS, is assumed to decrease by gr which is set as -0.4 % with
consideration of actual decreasing tendency of farmland area in Japan and is almost the same
as population growth rate.
FS r ,t  (1  gr ) FS r ,t 1
(8).
Government savings, international trade balance and inter-regional money transfer were
assumed to be fixed as the present level. Although TFP in paddy sector changed as Eq. (1), TFP
growth rate of other sectors is assumed to be zero in order to make comparison simple.
9
(3) Data
Farm management area per farm organization, MA, were also collected from Cost Research
for Rice Production (Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fishery; MAFF). Knowledge capital
stocks, KK, were calculated based on Kunimitsu et al. (2015) by using annual expenditure of
R&D investment published in Investigation Report on R&D Expenditures for Scientific
Technology (Statistics Bureau of Ministry of Public Management, Home Affairs, Posts and
Telecommunications, every year). Public infrastructure capital stocks, KG, and public
investment, IG, were obtained from Japanese Social Infrastructure Capital (Cabinet Office,
2012) and Kunimitsu and Nakata (2015c).
To calibrate the parameters of the CGE model, the social accounting matrix (SAM) was
estimated based on Japan’s 2005 inter-regional input-output table published by the Ministry of
Economy, Trade and Industry (http://www. meti.go.jp/statistics/ tyo/entyoio/ result/result_13.
html). In order to analyze sectoral production more precisely, the rice sector, transportation
sector and research and development sector were separated from the aggregated sectors in the
IO table by using regional tables (404 × 350 sectors). Subsequently, the sectors were
reassembled into 16 sectors: (1) paddy (pady); (2) other agriculture, forestry and fishery (oaff);
(2) mining and fuel (minf); (4) food processing (food); (5) chemical products (chem); (6)
general machinery (mach); (7) electrical equipment and machinery (elem); (8) other
manufacturing (omfg); (9) construction (cnst); (10) electricity and gas (elga); (11) water (watr);
(12) transportation (tpts); (13) research and development(rese); (14) wholesale and retail sales
(trad); (15) financial services (fina); and (16) other services (serv). Regions consisted of 9
regions: Hokkaido; Tohoku; Kanto including Niigata prefecture; Chubu; Kinki; Chugoku;
Shikoku; Kyushu; and Okinawa.
The factor input value of farmland, not shown in the Japanese I/O table, was estimated using
10
farmland cultivation areas (Farmland statistics, Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishery,
and every year) and multiplying the areas by farmland rents. The factor input value of farmland
was subtracted from the operation surplus in the original IO table. The value of capital input
was subsequently composed of the remaining operational surplus and the depreciation value of
capital.
Most elasticity values of substitution in the production, consumption, import and export
functions were set at the same values as Bann (2007), which were based on the GTAP database.
The substitution elasticity of farmland and other input factors in agriculture was assumed to be
0.2. This elasticity value is based on empirical studies on Japanese agriculture, indicating that
farmland, as an input factor, is less substitutable to labor and capital stocks in agricultural
production (Egaitsu, 1986).
Spatial substitution elasticity values on Japanese economy were estimated by Koike et al.
(2012) and Tsuchiya et al.(2005), showing that those values differed from 0.3 to 8.0, but were
about 2 times higher than substitution elasticity values on foreign trade. Hence, the spatial
substitution elasticity value for intermediate and consumption demand was set as 4.0.
(4) Simulation cases
In order to predict future situation, the simulation is conducted for 40 years from 2010 to
2050. The four simulation scenarios are considered. Among them, Case 1 to 3 except for Case
0 are all business as usual with different perspectives and model settings.
Case 0 (reference case):
This is for the reference of other simulation and KKt / KKt0 in Eq. (3) is set as 1.0, which
shows no consideration of changes in knowledge capital stocks.
Case 1 (pessimistic exogenous growth of R&D investment)
11
This case takes no change in the level of R&D investment. The R&D investment for
knowledge capital stocks is assumed to continue at the same level as year 2010 level for 40
years (see Case 1 in Fig. 1).
Case 2 (optimistic exogenous growth of R&D investment)
This case increases R&D investment in accordance with past chronological trend of
investment level (see Case 2 in Fig. 1).
Case 3 (endogenous growth of R&D investment)
This case sets R&D investment as endogenously defined by the SD-CGE model based on
Eqs. (1) to (3).
Figure 4 Chronological settings of exogenous R&D investment
IKP_actual
Case 1 (IKP_fix)
2050
2047
2044
2041
2038
2035
2032
2029
2026
2023
2020
2017
2014
2011
2008
2005
2002
1999
1996
1993
18000
17000
16000
15000
14000
13000
12000
11000
10000
9000
8000
1990
(billion yen)
R&D investment (Exogenous cases)
Case 2 (IKP_trend)
3.Results
(1) Prediction of knowledge capital stocks
Figure 5 shows the prediction path of knowledge capital stocks in each case, and figure 6 is
12
the prediction path of TFP in each case. Case 3 is the only case which was calculated by the
SD-CGE model. Other cases were set as exogenous variables.
The knowledge capital stocks of the endogenous growth of R&D investment (Case 3) was
lower than even Case 1 which shows pessimistic settings. Therefore, there is great possibility
of which economy cannot achieve enough technological progress as shown by Fig. 6.
Figure 5 Chronological change in private knowledge capital stocks by cases
Private knowledge capital stocks (All industries)
200000
billion yen
190000
180000
170000
160000
150000
140000
Case 0
reference
Case 1
pessimistic
Case 2
Optimistic
2050
2048
2046
2044
2042
2040
2038
2036
2034
2032
2030
2028
2026
2024
2022
2020
2018
2016
2014
2012
2010
130000
Case 3
Endogenous
Big differences were found in TFP change among industries due to the different level of
knowledge capital stocks and chronological change of them. Manufacturing industries, such as
chemical products, general machinery, electrical equipment and machinery, and other
manufacturing, hold greater level of knowledge capital stocks, but changes in knowledge capital
stocks by cases were also greater than other industries. Especially, differences between Case 2
(optimistic view) and Case 3 (endogenous growth) are huge.
13
Figure 6 Private knowledge capital stocks in 2050 by industries and cases
Private knowledge capital stocks in 2050
70000
60000
billion yen
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
pady oaff minf food chem mach elem omfg cnst elga watr tpts rese trad fina serv
Case 0
reference
Case 1
pessimistic
Case 2
Optimistic
Case 3
Endogenous
(2) Prediction of GDP
Figure 7 shows prediction results of GDP by regions and cases. Only 5 regions and whole
country case were chosen because of a limitation of the space.
Case 0 which shows no technological progress marked the lowest GDP growth and the top
level GDP was almost the same as present level. In this sense, technological progress is the
must for Japanese economy where population is decreasing.
Among Case 1 to Case 3, Case 3 marked the lowest level of GDP in the future. This is of
course due to the lower level of R&D investment in Case 3. Population was decreasing in all
cases, but only Case 3 changes R&D investment according to the future economic situation in
Japan. Most of manufacturing industries as well as the first and third industries can increase
their production until 2030, but these industries decrease their production level after that. This
happened due to a decrease in demand based on population and a decrease in R&D investment
adjusting to their own production level.
The GDP growth path among regions were completely different. Only Kanto region which
14
includes Tokyo and Yokohama could avoid serious decrease in GDP level, but other regions
could not. This is because of different population change among regions and transfer of labor
force to Kanto region in accordance with GDP growth level.
Figure 7. Chronological change in GDP by regions and cases.
Whole country
Hokkaido
600000
20000
18000
550000
16000
14000
500000
12000
CASE0
CASE1
CASE2
2010
2013
2016
2019
2022
2025
2028
2031
2034
2037
2040
2043
2046
2049
10000
2010
2013
2016
2019
2022
2025
2028
2031
2034
2037
2040
2043
2046
2049
450000
CASE3
CASE0
Kanto
CASE1
CASE2
CASE3
Chubu
270000
60000
250000
55000
230000
50000
210000
170000
40000
CASE0
CASE1
CASE2
2010
2013
2016
2019
2022
2025
2028
2031
2034
2037
2040
2043
2046
2049
45000
2010
2013
2016
2019
2022
2025
2028
2031
2034
2037
2040
2043
2046
2049
190000
CASE3
CASE0
Sikoku
CASE1
CASE2
CASE3
Kyushu
13000
42000
40000
38000
36000
34000
32000
30000
12000
11000
10000
9000
2010
2013
2016
2019
2022
2025
2028
2031
2034
2037
2040
2043
2046
2049
2010
2013
2016
2019
2022
2025
2028
2031
2034
2037
2040
2043
2046
2049
8000
CASE0
CASE0
CASE1
CASE2
CASE3
CASE1
CASE2
CASE3
Even so, GDP level of Kanto region in Case 3 decreased a bit, although such decrease was
15
lower than other regions. Therefore, influence of population decline was serious in Japanese
economy.
4. Summary and conclusion
This paper tried to measure influences of population decline in matured economy like Japan
with consideration of mutual relations of technological progress and population growth. We
used spatial dynamic computable general equilibrium model (SD-CGE model) to concretely
show the future situation of economy.
The simulation results demonstrated the following points. First, technological progress
caused by knowledge capital stocks is critical for keeping the GDP level as the present situation
in Japan where population is decreasing. If technological progress does not occur, a decrease in
gross domestic production is unavoidable.
Second, in urban area, such as Kanto region, GDP can continue to increase, because inflow
of fund and labor force occurs, but other regions face serious decline in GDP. These opposite
effects bring about an expansion of regional gaps in gross production. In order to ease such
opposite situations, revitalization policy, such as public investment for agricultural base which
is mostly located in the local areas, is useful and effective.
Third, Japan cannot achieve 600 trillion yen ( 5.5 trillion dollars) of GDP in the future under
population decline, which is the policy target of Japan, even if the past invested capital stocks
in our society was taken into accounts.
Fourth, the more serious problem will happen after the 2030's, and GDP turns into decrease
due to a decrease in knowledge capital stocks. This happens because of a decrease in supply
and demand for manufacturing products under decreasing population and a decrease in R&D
investment in accordance with production.
16
Therefore, the government should keep demand for manufacturing products by enhancing
children support program for an increase in birth rate of young generations in order to avoid
such decrease in GDP. This is not only Japanese problem but also OECD countries where their
population will not increase or decrease.
<Reference>
Solow, R. M. (1956). "A contribution to the theory of economic growth". Quarterly Journal of
Economics. Oxford Journals. 70 (1): 65–94. doi:10.2307/1884513.
Swan, T. W. (1956). "Economic growth and capital accumulation". Economic Record. Wiley.
32 (2): 334–361. doi:10.1111/j.1475-4932.
Yoshikawa, H. (2016) Population and Japanese Economy, Chyuou Koron shya.
National Institute of Science and Technology Policy (1999) Investigation on the
quantitative evaluation technique for the economic effect of research and
development
policies
(Interim
report),
NISTEP
REPORT
64 ,
http://data.nistep.go.jp/dspace/handle /11035/611.
17