Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain Hau Lee • Seungjin Whang Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, California 94305 [email protected] • [email protected] T his paper investigates the impacts of a secondary market where resellers can buy and sell excess inventories. We develop a two-period model with a single manufacturer and many resellers. At the beginning of the first period resellers order and receive products from the manufacturer, but at the beginning of the second period, they can trade inventories among themselves in the secondary market. We endogenously derive the optimal decisions for the resellers, along with the equilibrium market price of the secondary market. The secondary market creates two interdependent effects—a quantity effect (sales by the manufacturer) and an allocation effect (supply chain performance). The former is indeterminate; i.e., the total sales volume for the manufacturer may increase or decrease, depending on the critical fractile. The latter is always positive; i.e., the secondary market always improves allocative efficiency. The sum of the effects is also unclear—the welfare of the supply chain may or may not increase as a result of the secondary market. Lastly, we study potential strategies for the manufacturer to increase sales in the presence of the secondary market. (Supply Chain; Secondary Market; Exchanges; Market Equilibrium) 1. Introduction has the function of facilitating transactions of the secondary market. In fact, for many market exchanges, business transactions in the secondary market are the only transactions that occur today. Hence, the secondary market is an important element of general market exchanges. This paper is motivated by one such market exchange in the high-tech industry called TradingHubs.com, set up by Hewlett-Packard Company (HP). We start by describing the trajectory of TradingHubs.com. The high-tech industry is plagued with highly uncertain demands, as well as with continuously shrinking product life cycles and high risks of product obsolescence. The inability to accurately forecast demand for short-life-cycle products has resulted in resellers of computer products either having to write off excessive obsolete inventory or losing significant profits because of stockouts at the end of a product life cycle. It is also common that one reseller may have excess inventory while another has a shortage. 0025-1909/02/4806/0719$5.00 1526-5501 electronic ISSN Management Science © 2002 INFORMS Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 pp. 719–731 The Internet is becoming a dominant technology platform for the conduct of business. The advance of business-to-business commerce has resulted in the establishment of many “eMarketplaces.” eMarketplaces bring potential buyers and sellers together in an Internet-based exchange, whereby business transactions can take place. There are many types and characteristics of these market exchanges: They can be private or public, and one-to-many or many-to-many (i.e., involving multiple buyers and multiple sellers). They can be used to trade primary materials for production or indirect materials for business operations. They can serve as the primary market, as the secondary market (i.e., to dispose of or buy excess inventory), or both. This paper focuses on the impact of a market exchange as the “secondary market”—that is, for the disposal and acquisition of excess inventory. Almost every market exchange that we have come across in practice LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain Because the resellers have to absorb these operational costs, the existence of the channel results in higher product costs to the consumers. Companies that employ a direct channel, such as Dell and Gateway, therefore have a definite advantage over companies like HP and Compaq that rely on the reseller channel to move their products. The cost advantage enjoyed by consumer-direct manufacturers has translated to increasing loss of market share by the manufacturers using reseller channels (see Austin et al. 1997). Moreover, excess inventory in the channel at the end of the product life cycle is also a liability to HP, due to price protection (see Lee et al. 2000) and returns allowances paid by the manufacturer. This motivated HP to develop a strategy to help the channel reduce its inventory-related costs, with hopes of closing the cost gap between consumerdirect manufacturers and channel-based manufacturers. This was the genesis of a market exchange created by HP. In May 1999, HP launched an Internet-based exchange—TradingHubs.com. Among other things, it provided a secondary market for HP’s resellers to trade their computing and electronics products on the Internet. Hence, if HP or a reseller had excess inventory, it could use TradingHubs.com to seek other resellers to buy the excess inventory. Similarly, a reseller who needs certain products that cannot be provided by the manufacturer can seek resellers who have extra inventory to dispose of. Initially, products in the secondary market of TradingHubs.com included microprocessors, memory, drives, and storage devices. From July 1999 to April 2000, over $45 million of parts and products were traded in the secondary market of TradingHubs.com. The success of TradingHubs.com has prompted HP to work with other manufacturers to create a much bigger eMarketplace that would have an expanded scope of product offerings. On May 1, 2000, AMD, Compaq, Gateway, Hitachi, HP, Infineon, NEC, Quantum, Samsung, SCI Systems, Solectron, and Western Digital formed an independent company, named eHITEX, that will operate an open Internet-based exchange to serve the needs of the electronics and high-tech community (eHITEX 2000). The new venture will provide 720 online sales services to buyers and sellers involved in computing- and electronics-related industries, a market that is estimated to be about $600 billion over the next few years. A major part of eHITEX (later renamed Converge) is to provide a secondary market function allowing trade of excesses and surpluses. In 2001, Converge decided to scale back their market exchange offerings, and it is interesting to note that it is the secondary market function that it still keeps and that constitutes almost all the activities of this exchange today. Although the originators of TradingHubs.com were convinced that the creation of an online secondary market would help the resellers reduce their inventory-related costs, they were not as sure about the impact of it on HP itself (Billington 1999). One school of thought was that a reseller, expecting that the secondary market could make it effortless to dispose of excess inventory at a later stage of the product life cycle, would therefore purchase more from HP at the beginning of the product life cycle. This would benefit HP, as higher product sales at the beginning of the product life cycle would give rise to more revenues, as a result of both higher sales volumes and higher profit margins at the beginning of the product life cycle. On the other hand, a pessimistic view was that a reseller, knowing that the secondary market enables him to purchase more products, if needed, at a later stage of the product life cycle, would therefore purchase less from HP at the beginning of the product life cycle so as to avoid product overage. This would hurt HP’s bottom line. The impact of the online secondary market on HP and resellers is also complicated by the fact that the collective purchase decisions of the resellers affect the amount available to be traded in the secondary market, and ultimately the secondary market price. If most resellers aggressively purchase products from HP at the beginning of the product life cycle, then the potential excess inventory available in the secondary market will be larger, and the price in the secondary market will be depressed. This expectation will in turn make resellers reconsider buying so much from HP. The converse holds if most resellers underpurchase from HP. Thus, the market price has a dual role in the secondary market: to match supply Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain with demand, and to form an expectation for resellers to use in deciding the quantity to buy from HP and in the secondary market. Hence, although HP launched TradingHubs.com and later worked with other manufacturers to create eHITEX, the impact of the online secondary market remains a key question faced by HP executives. Would a reseller indeed purchase more at the beginning of a product life cycle with the existence of the online secondary market than without the market? Would the overall sales of HP products to consumers increase or decrease with the secondary market? Would we see more or fewer stockouts at the resellers as a result of the secondary market? Would there be less excess inventory at the resellers towards the end of the product life cycle, so that there would be fewer product returns for which HP is liable, due to the secondary market? This paper seeks to provide partial answers to these questions. There is a literature of research related to secondary markets. First, auctions have been used extensively as the mechanism for conducting trades in secondary markets, and there has been a tradition of research in economics on the theory of auctions (see, for example, Riley and Samuelson 1981 and Milgrom and Weber 1982). More recent research that deals with auctions in e-marketplaces can be found in Gallien and Wein (2000) and Vakrat (2000). Our current paper is not about the mechanics of online secondary markets, but rather on the impact of such markets on operational performance of manufacturers and resellers. A more relevant line of research is the literature on inventory pooling and component commonality in the operations management area. The existence of a secondary market has the effect of allowing the resellers to share inventory after initial purchases have been made. Hence, this is similar to inventory pooling (see Eppen and Schrage 1981 or Tagaras and Cohen 1992) or lateral transshipments in the multiechelon literature (see Lee 1987 or Axsaster 1990, for example). It is also similar to component commonality in manufacturing (see Baker et al. 1986 and Gerchak et al. 1988, for example). In both cases, the impacts of inventory pooling and commonality have been modeled. The differential impacts on the manufacturers and the resellers, however, were not Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 considered. More recently, the work by Anupindi and Bassok (1999) represents the first attempt to examine the impacts of inventory sharing at the retail level on the manufacturer, and shows that a manufacturer may be worse off with inventory pooling at the retail level; i.e., the resellers may sometimes purchase less from the manufacturer compared with the case of no inventory pooling. A similar result has been obtained by Dong and Lee (2000) in the case of parts commonality, and therefore special incentive systems have to be developed so that manufacturers would be willing to participate in designing commonality into their products. The past research on inventory pooling and commonality were, however, limited in their direct applicability to online secondary markets. As mentioned earlier, most of the past research has centered around the impacts only on the resellers or the system as a whole, and not the differential impacts on manufacturers, resellers, and the supply chain. Second, the number of resellers was often limited (generally to two), which presumably is not the case with online secondary markets. Third, the market price in the use of inventory pooling or commonality was assumed to be exogenously given and constant, which is not the case with online secondary markets where prices are dynamically determined endogenously according to supply and demand. Given the scarcity of research capturing “markets” in the inventory literature, our objective is modest. We develop a simple mathematical model (i.e., the newsvendor model that is modified to capture the basic characteristics of the secondary market), and analyze the properties of the equilibrium and differential performance of the manufacturer, resellers, and the supply chain as a whole. We also give managerial insights and implications for industry that follow from our research. The paper is organized as follows. In §2 we describe the basic model that will be used throughout the paper. Section 3 characterizes the equilibrium of the model, while §4 and §5 investigate the quantity effect and allocation effect of the secondary market. Section 6 discusses potential strategies for the manufacturer. Additional comments, limitation of the model, 721 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain and future research directions are given in §7, thereby closing the paper. 2. The Standard Setting with No Secondary Market Consider n resellers who order a single product from the manufacturer and sell it over a short sales season. The short sales season setting is typical of the hightech industry. Product life cycles are short, so the resellers often do not have the opportunities to resupply stocks from the manufacturer after initial purchases at the beginning of the product life cycle. Each reseller buys each unit at p1 , sells at to end consumers, and the salvage value of the units left unsold by the end of the sales season is zero. The manufacturer has a constant unit production cost which is normalized at zero. The sequence of events is as follows. At the beginning of the season, reseller i orders Qi from the manufacturer, which is delivered immediately. Retail sales zi are realized over the sales season where zi is a random variable independently drawn from F ·. This means that the resellers’ respective retail markets are segregated from each other. We assume that F is twice differentiable over 0 , with a finite mean , and we assume its inverse function exists. Unfilled orders are lost forever. This is the standard setting for the newsvendor problem which can be formulated as Qi max zf z dz + Qi f z dz − p1 Qi Qi 0 Qi The optimal stock level is: o −1 − p1 Qi = F 3. The Model of the Secondary Market (2.1) Now suppose that a secondary market opens at some point during the sales season; based on this point the sales season is divided into Periods 1 and 2. The sequence of events is as follows. At the beginning of Period 1, reseller i orders Qi from the manufacturer 722 (or equivalently, in the primary market), which is delivered immediately. First-period retail sales xi are realized where xi is a random variable independently drawn from F1 · with a finite mean 1 . At the end of Period 1 the secondary market is opened, where resellers trade units at a uniform price. The price p2 is endogenously determined to clear the market, and resellers buy and sell at the same price (i.e., there are no transaction fees or transportation costs). Given the price p2 , each reseller chooses a stock level qi for the second period. Sales yi are realized in Period 2—drawn from an independent distribution function F2 · (with its mean 2 ), and the game ends. We assume that xi and yi are independent for each i. This independence assumption implicitly requires that the demand process over time has statistically independent increments, such as Brownian or Poisson demands. To be consistent with the model with no secondary market, F is the convolution of F1 and F2 (thus, = 1 + 2 ). We are interested in the case in which n is infinitely large (which mimics an Internet-based market), so each reseller is a price-taker in the secondary market: i.e., dp2 /dQi = 0. Reseller i’s strategy is captured by the pair Qi qi —the stock levels for Periods 1 and 2. Thus, the symmetric (subgame-perfect) equilibrium Q∗ q∗ is defined, 1 such that moving backwards in time, (1) given any Q x, and p2 , reseller i chooses the second-period stock level qi∗ to maximize his expected profit for Period 2; (2) given any Q and x, the market clears at a market-clearing price p2 so that demand equals supply; and (3) taking other resellers’ strategies Q∗−i = Q1∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ Q2 Qi−1 Qi+1 Qn∗ as given, reseller i chooses Qi , so that his expected profit over the two periods is maximized. We ignore the time cost of money in this paper mainly for the simplicity of the exposition, although the analysis will not materially change when a discount factor is used in the revenue and cost of Period 2. 1 A boldface letter denotes the n-vector of corresponding variables: e.g., Q = Q1 Q2 Qn . Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain 3.1. Second-Period Stock Level Given arbitrary p2 Q, and x, reseller i determines its stock level qi∗ , such that q i yf2 y dy + qi f2 y dy qi∗ = arg max qi 0 From this we have: Theorem 1. Given a positive Q, (a) (Law of Large Numbers) p̂2 = lim p2 = 1 − F2 1 Q n→ qi − p2 qi − Qi − xi + Note that the last term may be either negative or positive depending on whether reseller i buys or sells in the secondary market. The optimal solution is − p2 (3.1) qi∗ = F2−1 By symmetry, let qi∗ = q ∗ for each i. Note that q ∗ is the critical fractile solution to the newsvendor problem applied to the second period only. 3.2. Equilibrium Price in Period 2 Given any Q and x, total demand under p2 is given by nq = nF2−1 − p2 /, whereas total supply is n + i=1 Qi − xi . The market price p2 is determined by equating these two entities, so that in market equilibrium: n 1 + p2 = 1 − F 2 (3.2) Q − xi n i=1 i By symmetry, Qi = Q for all i. If n is infinitely large, then the law of large numbers yields: Q n 1 Q − xi + = EQ − x+ = Q − xf1 x dx n→ n 0 i=1 Q = F1 x dx = 1 Q lim 0 Q where i Q = 0 Fi x dx for i = 1 2 throughout the paper. From this and the Slutsky Theorem (Serfling 1980), we obtain the limiting price p̂2 as follows. p̂2 = lim p2 = 1 − F2 1 Q n→ Note that p2 and p̂2 are functions of a given Q, but to simplify notation, we suppress the argument Q. Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 (b) (Central Limit Theorem) p2 is asymptotically distributed according to N p̂2 2 f22 p̂2 n2 , where 1 Q n2 = 1 x dx − p̂2 2 2 n 0 Proof. (b) Let zi = Q − xi + . Then, from the cen tral limit theorem, ni=1 zi /n is asymptotically normal with mean 1 Q and variance n1 EQ − xi + 2 − p̂22 Q or n1 2 0 1 x dx − p̂2 2 . From Theorem A of Serfling (1980, p. 118), if x is AN n2 (meaning asymptotically normal), then a differentiable transformation hx is AN h h 2 n2 assuming h = 0. Hence follows the result. Note from Theorem 1(a) that due to the assumption of large n, the market price is independent of specific realizations of first-period demands x. The only determinant of the price is first-period order quantities Q. Part (b) shows the asymptotic behavior of the price when the number of resellers grows large. Clearly, as n approaches infinity, n2 approaches zero, and Part (b) collapses to Part (a)—the usual relationship between the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem. When the number (n) of resellers is on the order of hundreds, as is typically the case in an Internet-based market, the variance of the price is small enough to justify our analysis of the limiting case. For the rest of the paper, we will assume that n is large enough for us to take p̂2 as the market price, and all resellers are pricetakers. The following theorem offers sensitivity analysis showing the behavior of p2∗ and q ∗ for small changes in Q. Theorem 2. (a) The secondary market price decreases in Q. (b) The optimal stock level for the second period increases in Q. Proof. (a) d p̂2 /dQ = −f2 1 QF1 Q < 0 723 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain (b) From (3.1) and Theorem 1(a), ∗ −1 − p̂2 q = F2 = 1 Q so dq ∗ /dQ = F1 Q > 0. Both results are intuitively clear. As each reseller increases the initial purchase amount from the manufacturer, the secondary market price will go down, and this will encourage each reseller to carry more stock for the second period. 3.3. Optimal Order Quantity in Period 1 We now determine resellers’ optimal first-period purchase decisions Q as the symmetric equilibrium strategy. Let p2∗ Q and q ∗ Q, respectively, denote the equilibrium market price and the equilibrium secondperiod stock level, when resellers make the decisions Q in the first period. To derive the symmetric Nash equilibrium first-period stock levels Q∗ , we take other resellers’ decisions Q∗−i = Q∗ Q∗ Q∗ as given and derive reseller i’s optimal decision Qi . Letting for short p2∗ Qi = p2∗ Q∗−i Qi and q ∗ Qi = q ∗ Q∗−i Qi , reseller i’s decision problem is given by Q i max xf1 xdx +Qi f1 xdx −p1 Qi +V2 Qi Qi Qi 0 where V2 Qi = E q ∗ Qi 0 yf2 y dy + q ∗ Qi q ∗ Qi f2 y dy + p2∗ Qi Qi − xi + − q ∗ Qi In the above, V2 Qi represents the reseller’s expected profit for the second period when the first-period order quantity is Qi . As n approaches infinity, we have: dp2∗ Qi /dQi = dq2∗ Qi /dQi = 0, due to the price-taker assumption, and thus we can use the definition p2∗ = p2∗ Qi and q ∗ = q ∗ Qi . Therefore, we can show that d Qi lim V2 Qi = p2∗ Qi − xi f1 x dx = p2∗ F1 Qi n→ dQi 0 Using this, and by differentiating the objective with respect to Qi , the first-order condition for an optimal order quantity for Period 1 satisfies − p1 F1 Qi = (3.3) − p2∗ 724 The symmetric equilibrium for the first period is thus Q∗ = Q∗ Q∗ Q∗ , where Q∗ satisfies (3.3). From the above discussions, the equilibrium of the model is fully characterized by the first-period order level Q∗ , the secondary market price p2∗ , and the second-period stock level q ∗ as in the following theorem. Theorem 3. For n large enough, the first-period order quantity Q∗ , the second-period equilibrium price p2∗ , and the second-period stock level q ∗ satisfy the following simultaneous equations: F1 Q∗ = −p1 −p2∗ p2∗ = 1 − F2 1 Q∗ and ∗ q = F2−1 −p2∗ (3.4) (3.5) The equilibrium secondary price p2∗ has the following property. Theorem 4. In equilibrium, p2∗ < p1 . Proof. The theorem follows from (3.3): p2∗ = − − p1 < − − p1 = p1 F1 Q∗ The theorem demonstrates that the price in the secondary market is strictly lower than the original purchase price. The unit made available in the second market has already lost the chance of being sold in the first period, so that the expected revenue from the unit should be smaller than the unit available in the first period. 4. The Impact of the Secondary Market—The Quantity Effect Will a secondary market increase or decrease the sales of the manufacturer in the first period? Intuition can direct us either way: A reseller may increase the purchase quantity because she faces a smaller risk of getting stuck with unsold inventory. By purchasing more from the manufacturer, she can avoid stockouts in the first period. At the same time, a reseller may also have an incentive to buy less from the manufacturer because she can observe the sales of the first period, decide later how much more she needs for the next Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain period, and buy from the secondary market. This is exactly the question faced by HP with regard to TradingHubs.com. We term this effect of the secondary market the quantity effect. The answer is an outcome of a complex trade-off among multiple factors like inventory and stockout costs. In short, the secondary market may increase or decrease the manufacturer’s sales, depending on the critical fractile. Theorem 5. In equilibrium the secondary market increases the manufacturer’s sales (i.e., Qo ≤ Q∗ ) if and only if F1 F −1 # · F2 1 F −1 # ≤ # A where # is the critical fractile − p1 /. Proof. Combining (3.3) and (3.4) yields: − p1 − = p2∗ = − F2 1 Q∗ F1 Q∗ Theorem 6. If limx→0+ f x > 0, there exists a strictly positive # , for which if # ≤ # , the secondary market increases the manufacturer’s sales. This in turn gives F1 Q∗ F2 1 Q∗ = − p1 (4.1) In the case of the standard newsvendor setting, we have from (2.1) − p1 = # (4.2) F Qo = Let Hx = F1 xF2 1 x. It can be easily shown that Hx strictly increases in x. Therefore, if Qo ≤ Q∗ , then F1 Qo F2 1 Qo ≤ F1 Q∗ F2 1 Q∗ = # o Since Q = F −1 #, it holds that F1 F −1 # · F2 1 F −1 # ≤ # The reverse can be shown in a similar manner. To better understand Condition A, we investigate two special cases of the uniform and exponential distributions of demands. Example 1. Suppose that F1 and F2 are independent and identically distributed according to a uniform distribution over 0 1. We have: x2 /2 if 0 ≤ x ≤ 1 2 F x = F1 ∗ F2 x = x −1 + 2x − if 1 ≤ x ≤ 2 2 Applying Theorem 5, Qo ≤ Q∗ if and only if # ≤ 1/2. Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 Thus, for the uniform distribution case, Condition A translates to the critical fractile being less than one half. In this case, the reseller facing the secondary market increases the original purchase quantity if and only if the profit margin is small enough in percentage terms. Example 2. Next consider Fi x = 1 − exp−x, for i = 1 2; i.e., the demand in each period is exponential. Then, F x = 1−exp−x−x ·exp−x. The application of Theorem 5 gives: Qo ≤ Q∗ if and only if # ≤ #o , where #o = 1 − exp−xo − xo · exp−xo and xo is the unique positive solution to x − exp1 − exp−x · 1 − exp−x = 0. Again for the exponential distribution, Condition A is equivalent to a small critical fractile. For general distributions, a weaker form of this result holds as follows. Proof. Let R# = F1 F −1 # · F2 1 F −1 # − #. Then, Condition A can be rewritten as R# ≤ 0. Then, lim+ R # = lim+ #→0 #→0 f1 F −1 # F F −1 # f F −1 # 2 1 + F1 F −1 #f2 1 F −1 # F1 F −1 # −1 f F −1 # = −1 Hence, R# starts at zero with a negative slope and crosses first, if at all, the x axis from below. Denote the first crossing point by # . If it never crosses, choose any arbitrarily large number for # . Then follows the result. Note that both of the previous examples, as well as normal distributions, satisfy the condition of Theorem 6, while beta and gamma distributions do not. Theorems 5 and 6 show that the secondary market has the effect of “regression towards the mean” in the following sense. In the traditional newsvendor problem, the optimal order quantity is small or large depending on whether the critical fractile is small or large. On the other hand, however, the existence of the secondary market dilutes this logic, because the reseller orders more than the newsvendor solution if 725 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain the critical fractile is small, but less if the critical fractile is large. Figure 1 illustrates this result for normal demands. The phenomenon is attributed to the price effect of the secondary market—the opposing force to neutralize the individual optimization effect (i.e., the newsvendor logic). Consider a product with a small critical fractile. Using the single-period newsvendor solution will mean a smaller order quantity by the resellers and, stochastically, a lower leftover inventory at the end of the first period. As a result, the price in the secondary market will be relatively high, and this will invite resellers to buy more initially from the manufacturer than the newsvendor solution. Symmetrically, for a high-fractile product, using the singleperiod newsvendor solution will mean a higher order quantity and, stochastically, a higher leftover inventory at the end of the first period. Thus, the price in the secondary market will be low, and this encourages resellers to purchase less initially from the manufacturer. As a result, the secondary market serves both as a hedge against excess inventory for a small critical fractile case and a hedge against stockouts for a large critical fractile case. In other words, the secondary market makes wholesale demands less elastic to the critical factor. Now suppose Condition A is not met. Then, each reseller will buy less than the newsvendor solution, and the manufacturer will be worse off as a result of the secondary market. Even without the secondary market, the newsvendor solution is already smaller than the optimal order quantity for the supply chain due to “double marginalization” (Pasternack 1985). Thus, the secondary market aggravates double marginalization if Condition A is violated. 5. The Impact of the Secondary Market—The Allocation Effect We have seen in the previous section that the secondary market does not always increase the order quantity by resellers. By contrast, resellers always benefit from the secondary market. This is because a reseller can always achieve the same performance of the single-period newsvendor model by ignoring the secondary market. Hence, the secondary market gives an option that is of nonnegative value. How about the impact of the secondary market on the performance of the supply chain as a whole? We call this impact the allocation effect of the secondary market. The next theorem investigates three supply chain measures—consumer sales, stockouts, and leftover stock (at the end of the second period)—as a result of the secondary market. Theorem 7. For a given positive Qo , the following holds: (a) There exists &<0, such that the expected sales in the channel with a secondary market is larger than that without a secondary market if and only if Q∗ − Qo > &. (b) The expected number of stockouts in the channel with a secondary market is smaller than that without a secondary market if and only if Q∗ − Qo > &. (c) There exists &>0, such that the expected leftover inventory in the channel with a secondary market is smaller than that without a secondary market if and only if Q∗ − Qo < &. Proof. (a) Define T & = & + Qo − 2 1 Qo + & First, note that T 0 = Qo − 2 1 Qo ≥ 0 Figure 1 ∗ o Q Versus Q Under Normal Demands 1 Q*<Qo F1(Q)F2(Γ (Q)) F(Q) (5.1) (5.2) To show this, we have: Qo o Q = 2 Qo − x dF1 x 0 Qo o o 2 1 Q = 2 Q − x dF1 x 0 and 2 · is a convex function, so Jensen’s inequality holds. Also, we have: T & = 1−F2 1 Qo +&F1 Qo + & > 0. Thus, Q*>Qo Q 726 T & > 0 ∀ & > 0 (5.3) Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain At & = −Qo (the minimum feasible value of &), we have: T −Qo = −Qo + Qo < 0 (5.4) From (5.3) and (5.4), therefore, T & is a strictly increasing function whose value is negative at & = −Qo , and positive at all & ≥ 0. Thus, there exists a unique & ∈ −Qo 0, such that T & = 0. Now, without a secondary market, the expected sales over the two periods (per reseller) are: S o = Qo − EQo − x+ = Qo − Qo (5.5) With the secondary market, the total expected sales in the two periods are: S ∗ = Q∗ − 1 Q∗ + q ∗ − 2 q ∗ = Q∗ − 2 1 Q∗ (5.6) where we used q ∗ = 1 Q∗ (by applying (3.4) to (3.5)). Hence, the difference is: S ∗ − S o = Q∗ − Qo + Qo − 2 1 Q∗ = T Q∗ − Qo Hence follows the desired result of Part (a). (b) The expected number N o of stockouts with out a secondary market is Qo x − Qo dF x dx = Fx dx = Qo , where Fx = 1 − F x. LikeQo wise, the expected number N ∗ of stockouts with a 2 q ∗ , where i Q = market is 1 Q∗ + secondary x dx. Noting that Q = −Q + + F i i i Q, for Q i i = 1 2 and the null case, the difference between the two cases is N o − N ∗ = Qo − 1 Q∗ − 2 q ∗ = Q∗ − o o ∗ ∗ o Q + Q − 2 1 Q = T Q − Q . From this point on, the proof parallels that of Part (a). Alternatively, note that under the lost-sales model, the sum of the expected channel sales and the expected stockouts are the mean demand, so Part (b) immediately follows from Part (a). (c) Without a secondary market, the expected second-period leftover inventory is EQo − x+ = Qo , while for the case of the secondary market, it is 2 1 Q∗ . Consider o o T1 & = Q − 2 1 Q + & Again as shown in the proof of (a), we have T1 0 = T 0 ≥ 0. Moreover, T1 & = −F2 1 Qo + &F1 Qo + & < 0. Also, note that T1 −Qo = Qo > 0 and Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 &>0, such that lim&→ T1 & < 0. Thus, there exists T1 & = 0. Hence, the desired result follows. The theorem reports a varying degree of performance depending on the value of Q∗ relative to Qo . = Qo + Let Q = Qo + & and Q &. Because Q < Qo , the implication of Theorem 7(a) and (b) is that when Qo ≤ Q∗ (i.e., when Condition A holds), we will always have Q < Q∗ , and the expected sales in the channel with a secondary market will be greater than that without a secondary market, while the expected stockouts are lower (see Figure 2). This is a situation in which both the manufacturer and the channel see higher sales. Also, the expected sales in the channel can be greater with a secondary market when Q∗ < Qo , as long as Q∗ > Q. Hence, it is possible that a secondary market will drive greater sales in the channel, even if the channel may actually buy less from the manufacturer. This would be of great concern to a manufacturer who is primarily interested in market share and consumer sales of its product. When Q ≤ we have the scenario in which the expected Q∗ ≤ Q, sales in the channel is higher with less expected stockouts, while the expected leftover inventory is lower with the secondary market. Further, if Qo ≤ Q∗ ≤ Q, all four measures improve due to the secondary market, creating a win-win situation for the manufacturer, resellers, and the supply chain as a whole. In particular, this includes the case of Qo = Q∗ . Thus, after controlling the quantity effect of the secondary market, the secondary market unambiguously improves the allocative efficiency of the supply chain by increasing Figure 2 Four Measures Depending on Q∗ 1. Higher Manufacturer sales Q Qo Q Newsvendor Solution 2. Higher Channel Sales 3. Lower Stockouts 4. Lower Leftover Inventory 727 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain sales to end consumers, and decreasing stockouts and leftover stock. 6. The Manufacturer’s Options What can the manufacturer do if sales are not guaranteed to be higher with the secondary market? Based on our results, if the manufacturer can control the types of products traded in the secondary market, he would choose only low-margin items to be traded in the market. Boeing, for example, is a major shareholder in an eMarketplace that includes the operation of a secondary market. In the secondary market, only commodity-type parts are exchanged among its airline customers. Specialized items (usually with high margins) would be purchased only direct from the manufacturer. If the manufacturer cannot control the secondary market, then the manufacturer has several options to offset or mitigate the secondary market impact using his market power. The first option is to enforce a minimum order quantity (MOQ) to each reseller. If the manufacturer has the market power, he may require the reseller to buy, for example, Qo at the minimum. Alternatively, the manufacturer may induce the same purchase quantity by offering a small quantity discount. Note that this arrangement of MOQ or quantity discount is not driven by logistics concerns as discussed by Lee and Rosenblatt (1986), or Corbett and deGroote (2000), but by the secondary market impact. In fact, the present model assumes away delivery costs, so the frequency of deliveries does not matter so long as the total purchase equals or exceeds the targeted quantity. If the required or induced purchase quantity is Qo , it would represent a weak Pareto-improvement to all supply chain members over the premarket equilibrium, as discussed in the previous section. The second option for the manufacturer is to complement the secondary market with a return policy. As Pasternack (1985) points out, a well-designed return policy can eliminate the quantity distortion driven by double marginalization. In other words, by offering a rebate on reseller’s unsold inventory, the manufacturer can induce the reseller to choose the order quantity that is optimal for the welfare of the supply chain as a whole, or for the maximal profit of the manufacturer. 728 Likewise, our manufacturer can choose an appropriate rebate to maximize the profit. To derive the optimal rebate, consider the manufacturer who offers a rebate of ) for each unit left unsold by the end of the second period. Then, the effect of the rebate propagates in the following sequence—first the inventory level q ) , then the limiting secondary ) market price p2 , and ultimately the order quantity Q) in the primary market. Thus, the counterpart of (3.3)–(3.5) for the rebate case can be obtained as follows: F1 Q) = −p1 ) −p2 (6.1) ) p2 = − − )F2 1 Q) and q ) = F2−1 ) − p2 −) (6.2) (6.3) From (6.1) and (6.2): F1 Q) · F2 1 Q) = − p1 −) (6.4) Because the function H x = F1 x · F2 1 x strictly increases in the range of 0 1, there is a one-to-one mapping between Q and ) in the appropriate range of values. Thus, ) can be set to induce a given quantity of Q. The manufacturer can then choose an appropriate ) that would optimize his profit. The third, rather intriguing, option available to the manufacturer is to intervene in the secondary market by releasing a prepared quantity. This way the manufacturer can sell more in the secondary market, but it may have other effects. To see this, suppose that the manufacturer prepares a quantity *n (i.e., * per reseller) and releases it in the secondary market. Omitting the straightforward details similar to those in §3, the counterpart of Theorem 3 for this case is F1 Q* = −p1 * −p2 * p2 = 1 − F2 1 Q* + * and q * = F2−1 * − p2 (6.5) (6.6) (6.7) Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain where the superscript * is used to highlight the dependence of the quantities on *. Using (6.5) and (6.6), we also derive the counterpart of (4.1): F1 Q* F2 1 Q* + * = − p1 (6.8) Comparing this with (4.2), we observe that Q* decreases in *, i.e., the more the manufacturer intervenes, the less resellers buy from the manufacturer. This is intuitively clear. If the manufacturer intervenes heavily, the market price will go down in the second period, so resellers will have less incentive to buy much initially from the manufacturer, and will rely more on the secondary market to augment their stock later. The problem of maximizing the total profit to the manufacturer is given by * max +* = n p2 * + p1 Q* * subject to Constraints (6.5)–(6.7). The solution is not straightforward due to complex * interactions among p2 Q* , and *, but marginal analysis at * = 0 shows that d+* dQ* ∗ = np + np (6.9) 1 2 d* *=0 d* *=0 and dQ* −F1 Q∗ f2 1 Q∗ = d* *=0 F12 Q∗ f2 1 Q∗ + f1 Q∗ F2 1 Q∗ Equation (6.9) shows the exact trade-off facing the manufacturer in deciding whether or not to intervene in the secondary market. With the market intervention, she gains in the secondary market at the rate of p2∗ per reseller, but loses in the primary market at the rate of p1 dQ* /d**=0 . The final result depends on the relative magnitude. An interesting observation is the case of the uniform distribution as shown in Example 1. In Appendix 1, we can show that dQ* /d**=0 > 0 if # > 05. This is a useful result, as we have shown that if # < 05, then Qo < Q∗ so the manufacturer is already better off with the secondary market. However, if # > 05, then Qo > Q∗ , and this Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 is the case when the manufacturer may see itself as worse off with the secondary market and be anxious to find a way to prevent profit reduction. Indeed, the result of Appendix 1 shows that the manufacturer can always improve its profitability by intervention in the “unfavorable” secondary market condition. 7. Conclusions This paper investigates the impacts of a secondary market where resellers can buy and sell excess inventories. We develop a two-period model with a single manufacturer and many resellers. At the beginning of the first period, resellers order and receive products from the manufacturer, but at the beginning of the second period, they can trade inventories among themselves in the secondary market. We endogenously derive the optimal decisions for the resellers, along with the equilibrium market price of the secondary market. The secondary market creates two interdependent effects—a quantity effect (sales by the manufacturer) and an allocation effect (supply chain performance). The former is indeterminate; i.e., the total sales volume for the manufacturer may increase or decrease, depending on the critical fractile. The latter is always positive; i.e., the secondary market always improves allocative efficiency. The sum of the effects is also unclear—the welfare of the supply chain may or may not increase as a result of the secondary market. Lastly, we study potential strategies for the manufacturer to increase sales in the presence of the secondary market. The model is built on several strong assumptions. One of them is the zero transactions-cost assumption. Although the Internet would clearly lower the cost of operating a marketplace, there remain nontrivial transactions costs such as logistics costs and transaction fees to the exchange. Suppose we relax this and assume that a transactions cost c per unit traded is paid by the seller. In the second period, not every reseller would choose the same inventory position. Because sellers pay the transaction fee, overstocked resellers will take an inventory position strictly larger than understocked resellers. In particular, the resellers slightly overstocked will not find it worthwhile to trade paying transaction fees. More 729 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain specifically, the resellers are divided into three groups: sellers, buyers, and no traders, and the analysis gets very complicated. Another restrictive assumption of the model is that demands over the two periods are independent and that their distributions are known to all parties at the beginning of the season. In reality, the demand information is revealed as the sales season progresses (Ananth and Fisher 1996). Particularly interesting is the case in which an unexpected demand is experienced in the first period, which alerts resellers of larger-than-expected demands in the next period. The secondary market may serve as a rationing device and mitigate the bullwhip effect (Lee et al. 1997). This “market intelligence” model requires a significantly different setup (including the primary market operating in both periods), and thus we leave it for future research. We have also assumed that demands of the retailers are independent. In reality, demands across retailers are likely to be positively correlated. When that is the case, we expect that the value of the secondary market to the retailers will be smaller than in the current model. A more elaborate model incorporating both demand correlation and market intelligence will be a viable direction of further research. The current model assumes one production and one selling opportunity by the manufacturer. While this assumption may be reasonable for very-shortlife products like fashion apparel, they are not generally valid. Future research can also involve multiple production and selling opportunities by the manufacturer, as well as multiple periods in which transactions in the secondary market can take place. Finally, our model is still a partial equilibrium model because the retail price is exogenously given. A true equilibrium model would endogenize the formation of the retail price so that retail demand distributions may be affected by the existence of the secondary market. To do so, one needs a richer model than our newsvendor model to capture the retail demand function with uncertainty. Clearly, this is well beyond the scope of this paper, and we hope more future research will follow to enrich our understanding of the impacts of the secondary markets and the Internet on the supply chain. 730 Acknowledgments The authors thank the associate editor and two referees for numerous constructive comments and encouragement. They also thank the participants at the Second Thought Leaders Roundtable on Supply Chain Management sponsored by Eindhoven University in 1999, and seminars at the University of Washington, University of Dayton, and Purdue University for useful comments. Special thanks go to Thomas Schmitt, Ted Klastorin, Prabudha Dee, Lee Schwartz and Corey Billington. In addition, the authors thank Mr. Tunay Tunca for the computation of numerical examples and refinement of Theorem 5. The authors gratefully acknowledge the partial financial support from Global Supply Chain Forum at Stanford University. Appendix 1 We prove that under the uniform distribution of Example 1, dQ* /d**=0 > 0 if # > 05. Note that under the uniform distribution of Example 1, 1 Q = Q2 /2 Fi x = x, and fi x = 1 for appropriate ranges of x. Hence, (4.1) becomes Q∗ 3 /2 = #, and so 05 < # < 1 is equivalent to 1 < Q∗ 3 < 2. Now dQ* −2 = d* *=0 3Q∗ Thus, d+* n n = 6Q∗ − 4 − Q∗ 3 > ∗ Q∗ − 1 > 0 d* *=0 6Q∗ Q since Q∗ 3 < 2 and Q∗ > 1. References Ananth, R., M. Fisher. 1996. Reducing the cost of demand uncertainty through accurate response to early sales. Oper. Res. 44 87–99. Anupindi, R., Y. Bassok. 1999. Centralization of stocks: Resellers vs. manufacturers. Management Sci. 45(2) 178–191. Austin, T., H. L. Lee, L. Kopczak. 1997. Unlocking Hidden Value in the Personal Computer Supply Chain. Andersen Consulting. Axsaster, S. 1990. Modelling emergency lateral transshipments in inventory systems. Management Sci. 36 1329–1338. Baker, K. R., M. J. Magazine, H. L. W. Nuttle. 1986. The effect of commonality on safety stocks in a simple inventory model. Management Sci. 32(8) 982–988. Billington, C. 1999. Private communication, Hewlett-Packard Company. Corbett, C. J., X. deGroote. 2000. A supplier’s optimal quantity discount policy under asymmetric information. Management Sci. 46(3) 444–450. Dong, L., H. L. Lee. 2000. Aligning supply chain incentives for channel assembly with component commonality. Working paper, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 LEE AND WHANG The Impact of the Secondary Market on the Supply Chain eHITEX 2000. High-tech industry leaders announce open internet exchange for computer and electronics marketplace. Press Release (May 1). New York. Eppen, G., L. Schrage. 1981. Centralized ordering policies in a multi-warehouse system with lead times and random demand. L. B. Schwarz, ed. Multi-Level Production/Inventory Control Systems: Theory and Practice. TIMS Studies in the Management Sciences, Vol. 16. North-Holland, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 51–68. Gallien, J., L. Wein. 2000. Design and analysis of a smart market for industrial procurement. Working paper, Sloan School of Management, MIT, Cambridge, MA. Gerchak, Y., M. J. Magazine, A. B. Gamble. 1988. Component commonality with service level requirements. Management Sci. 34(6) 753–760. Lee, H. L. 1987. A multi-echelon inventory model for repairable items with emergency laterial transshipments. Management Sci. 33 1302–1316. , M. J. Rosenblatt. 1986. A generalized quantity discount pricing model to increase supplier’s profits. Management Sci. 32 1179–1187. , V. Padmanabhan, S. Whang. 1997. Information distortion in a supply chain: The bullwhip effect. Management Sci. 43(4) 546–558. , P. Padmanabhan, T. Taylor, S. Whang. 2000. Price protection in the PC industry. Management Sci. 46(4) 467–482. Milgrom P., R. J. Weber. 1982. A theory of auctions and competitive bidding. Econometrica 50(5) 1089–1122. Pasternack, B. A. 1985. Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Marketing Sci. 4(2) 166–176. Riley, J., W. Samuelson. 1981. Optimal auctions. Amer. Econom. Rev. 71 381–392. Serfling, R. J. 1980. Approximation Theorems of Mathematical Statistics. Wiley, New York. Tagaras, G., M. A. Cohen. 1992. Pooling in two-location inventory systems with non-negligible replenishment lead times. Management Sci. 38 1067–1083. Vakrat, Y. 2000. Online auctions. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY. Accepted by Fangruo Chen; received February 1, 2001. This paper was with the authors 3 months for 2 revisions. Management Science/Vol. 48, No. 6, June 2002 731