Download Coordinating Pricing and Ordering Decisions in a Multi

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts
no text concepts found
Transcript
Journal of Industrial and Systems Engineering
Vol. 9, No. 1, pp 35-56
Winter (January) 2016
Coordinating Pricing and Ordering Decisions in a Multi-Echelon
Pharmacological Supply Chain under Different Market Power
using Game Theory
Mahsa Noori-daryan1, Ata Allah Taleizadeh1*
School of Industrial Engineering, College of Engineering, University of Tehran, Tehran, Iran
[email protected], [email protected]
Abstract
The importance of supply chains in pharmacological industry is remarkable so that
nowadays many pharmacological supply chains have an effective and critical role for
supplying and distributing drugs in health area. So, this article studies a three-echelon
pharmacological supply chain containing multi-distributor of raw materials, a
pharmaceutical factory, and multi-drug distributors companies. The distributors of raw
material order raw materials of some drugs to own suppliers and sell them to the
pharmaceutical factory. The factory transmutes raw materials to the several finished
products and sells them to some drug distributors companies. There are several types of
raw materials and finished products. Here, it is supposed that the market powers of partners
are different. So, the Stackelberg game among the members of the chain is deemed to
analyze the coordination behavior of the members of the proposed chain. The aim of the
research is to maximize the total profit of supply chain by employing the optimal pricing
and ordering decision policies where the order quantities of the distributors and the selling
prices of pharmaceutical factory (manufacturer) and the distributors are the decision
variables. Besides, the closed form solutions of the decision variables are presented. At the
end, numerical example and some sensitivity analysis are presented.
Keywords: Pricing; Inventory; Production; Health Care; Game theory; Supply Chain.
1- Introduction and literature review
Many industries focus on pricing as a marketing tool to improve their profits. In addition, for production
industries, coordination of price decisions with other aspects of the supply chain such as manufacturing and
inventory, are useful and essential. The coordination of these decisions needs an integrated model to
optimize the integrated system rather than individual components of the supply chain. This integration
between manufacturing, pricing, and inventory decisions is still in its early stages in many firms. But
recently, many researchers have focused on this topic and even each component of mentioned integrated
system, separately. For instance, Lee and Rosenblatt (1986) introduced the problem of offering price
discount and pricing, at the same time. Boyaci and Gallego (2002) studied coordination cases under
deterministic demand which is price sensitive in a two echelons supply chain containing one wholesaler and
one or more retailers and they considered joint lot sizing and pricing decisions for optimizing their model.
Abad (2003) analyzed pricing and lot sizing policies for a perishable item when partial backordering
shortage is allowed. Dai et al. (2005) discussed the pricing policy for multi-competing firm supporting the
same service for the customers where each firm’s demand is price sensitive.
*Corresponding author.
ISSN: 1735-8272, Copyright c 2016 JISE. All rights reserved
35
Rosenthal (2008) evaluated the problem of setting prices in an integrated supply chain. Szmerekovsky
and Zhang (2009) investigated two tiers advertising levels and pricing decisions between one manufacturer
and one retailer. In their model end user’s demand depends on the retail price and manufacturer and retailer
advertisement costs.
Xiao et al. (2010) utilized wholesale pricing, ordering and lead time decisions in a three echelons supply
chain where the manufacturer produces deteriorating items. Cai et al. (2009) surveyed pricing and ordering
models with partial lost sales in a supply chain with one buyer and one seller. Soon (2011) reviewed multiple
products pricing models where pricing is combined with other decision policies like distribution of resources
or production. Seyed-Esfahani et al. (2011) studied vertical cooperative advertising with pricing decision
policy in a supply chain involving one manufacturer and one retailer. Hua et al. (2012) analyzed the optimal
pricing and ordering policies where the supplier suggests free shipping. Mutlu and Cetinkaya (2013)
designed a carrier-retailer channel under both centralized and decentralized structures with price-sensitive
demand to examine and also compare the profitability of chain under both structures. Giri and Sharma
(2014) employed a pricing strategy in a two-echelon supply chain involving a manufacturer and two
competing retailers where demand depends on advertising cost. Taleizadeh and Noori-daryan (2015a)
proposed an economic production quantity (EPQ) model in a three-echelon supply chain composed of a
supplier, a manufacturer and a group of retailers to study the reaction of the chain members. Their proposed
model determines the optimal pricing and inventory policies to promote the profit of the chain. Ekici et al.
(2015) considered a supply chain with two rival suppliers and one retailer under asymmetric information to
evaluate the optimal pricing decisions where order consolidation strategy and order quantity constraint are
considered. Another aim of each supply chain is to control its inventory level; also the members of the chain
employ the optimal inventory decisions to satisfy the customers' demand. The authors considered different
decision policies in their researches. For example, Whitin (1955) considered an inventory and pricing
policies to optimize the objective function of an inventory system. Hill (1999) studied a problem in which
the vendor supplies a product to a buyer by employing the production and shipment policies. Jorgensen and
Kort (2002) proposed inventory replenishment and pricing policies in a system with serial inventories under
decentralized and centralized decision making. Khouja (2003) considered a three-echelon supply chain by
using three inventory decision policies. Ben-Daya et al. (2008) presented a comprehensive review of the
joint economic lot sizing problem. Yu and Huang (2010) investigated the optimal inventory policies in a
VMI supply chain containing a manufacturer and multi-retailers where a manufacturer receives raw material
from multiple suppliers to produce a family of product in order to sell to the retailers. Ru and Wang (2010)
studied a supply chain with a single period where a supplier contracts with a retailer. The demand is assumed
to be uncertain and price sensitive. In their article, they compared two consignment arrangements to manage
the inventory. Guan and Zhao (2011) developed an inventory-pricing model with multiple competing
retailers in which each retailer faces to stochastic demand in an infinite horizon. Arkan and Hejazi (2012)
offered a coordination mechanism in a two echelons supply chain containing one supplier and one buyer
under uncertain demand and positive lead time. Kovacs et al. (2013) studied the principal challenge of
inventory control, logistics and production under information asymmetry in supply chains. Cardenas-Barron
and Sana (2014) investigated the coordination problem for a single-manufacturer-single-retailer supply chain
where demand is sensitive to promotional sales teams’ initiative. Two researches subsequently analyzed EPQ
models in multi-echelon chains for deteriorating and reworkable items, respectively to determine optimal
pricing and inventory strategies of partners of the chains performed by Taleizadeh et al. (2015a, 2015b).
Game theory approaches have been employed to model the relation among the chains member’s in
many researches (Giri, B.C., Sharma, S., 2014), (Taleizadeh and Noori-daryan, 2015a), (Cardenas-Barron,
and Sana, 2014), (Taleizadeh, Noori-daryan and Cárdenas-Barrón, 2015a) and (Taleizadeh, Noori-daryan
and Tavakkoli-Moghaddam, 2015b). But, recently, due to different market power of the partners of the
chain, powerful partners do not agree to join a supply chain and collaborate with other ones as a whole
supply chain with equal market share and prefer to work separately in a supply chain under a decentralized
decision process. So, in these chains in which the members have different market power, non-cooperative
game theoretic approaches as Nash and Stackelberg game have been established to analyze the decisions of
the chains partners. To name a few, Cachon and Netessine (2004) studied a supply chain in which game
theory had been used. Yu et al. (2006) employed a Stackelberg game in a VMI system where the
manufacturer is leader and the multiple retailers are the followers. Nagarajan and Sosic (2008) presented
applications of cooperative game theory to manage supply chain. Cai et al. (2011) analyzed the influence of
pricing schemes and price discount contracts on the dual-channel supply chain competition from supplier and
36
retailer. Zhao and Atkins (2009) evaluated a transshipment game and a substitution game between competing
retailers. Huang et al. (2011) studied the coordination of enterprise decisions such as pricing and inventory in
a multi-echelon supply chain where multi-supplier, one manufacturer and multiple retailers are the members
of the chain and non-cooperative game between the members of the chain is used. Chen et al. (2012)
presented a review of the related issues to the manufacturer's pricing policies in a two-echelon supply chain
including one manufacturer and two competing retailers. They used the Stackelberg game approach such that
manufacturer who is leader, offers wholesale prices to two competing retailers. Pal et al. (2012) developed a
multi-product three echelons supply chain involving multi-supplier, one manufacturer and multi-retailer
where each supplier supplies one kind of required raw material of the manufacturer and the manufacturer
combines the fixed percentage of raw material to produce the products which should be sold to the retailers.
Zhao and Wang (2015) applied three different games study pricing and retail service decisions in a singlemanufacturer two-retailer supply chain under uncertainty, as manufacturer-leader Stackelberg, retailer-leader
Stackelberg, and vertical Nash. Qi et al. (2015) studied game theoretic models to evaluate the impact of
market search reaction of customer on the decisions of supply chain members where one manufacturer and
two retailers are considered as the chain partners with considering lost sale shortage at the retailers.
In this paper, an EPQ model is developed in a multi-echelon supply chain for pharmacological raw
material and products by applying optimal pricing and ordering policies. According to our review of
literature, the proposed model in this article has not been considered by any of the recent researches. The
novelty of the proposed model is that several raw materials distributors’, a pharmaceutical factory, and some
drug distributors are the members of the chain. It is assumed that demand is price-sensitive and shortage is
not allowed. Also thanks to different market power of the chain members, the Stackelberg game approach is
considered among the chain partners to survey and model the total profit of the chain. Moreover, the closed
form solutions of the optimal values of decision variables are presented so that the concavity of the total
profit functions is proven. The order quantities of the distributors and the selling prices of the pharmaceutical
factory and the drug distributors are the decision variables of the presented model. The rest of this paper is
arranged as follows. The problem is defined in section 2. The mathematical model is presented in section 3.
Section 4 shows the solution method. The numerical example and sensitivity analysis is provided in section 5
and section 6 presents conclusion.
2- Problem Definition: A Real Case Study
Consider a three-echelon supply chain of pharmacological industry including several non-competing
distributors of raw materials (distributors) of drugs such as Talk, Sodium Benzoate, Gelatin Capsule, Guar
Gum, Dibasic Calcium Phosphate, Flavor, Crystal Sugar, Color, and a pharmaceutical factory (manufacturer)
and some non-competing drug distributors companies (retailers). A configuration of this supply chain is
shown in Figure (1).
37
R1
D1
Pr1
R2
D2
Pr2
R3
D3
Dm
Dj is jth
distributor
Prn
Rh
Manufacturer
Ri is ith retailer
Prk is kth product
Figure1. Configuration of supply chain
In this chain, the distributors sell raw materials to the pharmaceutical factory and pharmaceutical
factory transfers them to the multi-finished products such as Cefexime, Cephalexine Sodium, Amoxiclov
156, Amoxiclov 228, Amoxiclov 312 , Amoxiclov 457, Co-Amoxiclov, etc., and then sends them to the drug
distributors companies and they satisfy their customers' demand. We assume that each distributor supplies
one kind of raw material and pharmaceutical factory needs to the combination of different kinds of raw
material in a defined percentage for each product. According to customers' demand, the distributors
companies’ demand are different and the ordering lot size of raw material and the selling price of
pharmaceutical factory and the selling price of drug distributors companies are decision variables.
The aim of this paper is to determine the optimal values of order quantity of distributors to their
supplier, the selling price of pharmaceutical factory and the selling price of drug distributors companies in a
three echelons supply chain such that the total profit of supply chain network is maximized.
In order to model the problem following notations are used. The number of distributors is assumed to be
m and its index is j = 1, 2, , m , the number of products is n and its index is k = 1, 2, , n , and there are h
retailers and its index is h = 1, 2, , k .
The inventory level of jth distributor,
d
The demand of jth raw material from the manufacture to the jth distributors,
D𝐼𝐼𝑗𝑗𝑑𝑑j
The ordering lot size of jth distributor of raw material to his supplier,
Qj
h dj
The holding cost of jth distributor of raw material,
A dj
The ordering cost of jth distributor of raw material,
HC dj
The total holding cost of jth distributor of raw material,
OC dj
The total ordering cost of jth distributor of raw material,
C dj
The purchasing price of jth distributor of raw material,
w dj
The selling price of jth distributor of raw material,
T jd
θ kj
The cycle time of jth distributor of raw material,
𝐼𝐼𝑘𝑘𝑚𝑚
The percentage of jth raw material for producing kth product,
38
Pk
The inventory level of manufacturer for kth finished product,
The demand of hth retailer for kth product, D hmk = a − bw km
The production rate of kth product,
hkm
The holding cost of manufacturer for kth finished product,
A km
The ordering cost of manufacturer for kth finished product,
HC km
The total holding cost of manufacturer for kth finished product,
OC km
The total ordering cost of manufacturer for kth finished product,
C (Pk )
The production cost of manufacturer for kth finished product,
Lk
ϕk
The fixed cost of production for kth finished product,
w km
The selling price of manufacturer for kth finished product,
T Pk
The cycle time of production for kth finished product,
T km
The cycle time of manufacturer,
µik
The percentage of demand of kth product for satisfying the demand of ith retailer,
D ikr
hikr
The end user’s demand of kth product to which the ith retailer is faced, D ikr = a − bw ikr
The holding cost of ith retailer for kth product,
A ikr
The ordering cost of ith retailer for kth product,
HC ikr
The total holding cost of ith retailer for kth product,
OC ikr
The total ordering cost of ith retailer for kth product,
w ikr
The selling price of ith retailer for kth product,
T ik
The required time of ith retailer for collecting kth product,
T ikr
The cycle time of ith retailer for selling kth product,
TPjd
The total profit of jth distributor,
TP m
The total profit of manufacturer,
The total profit of ith retailer,
D km
The variable cost of production for kth finished product,
r
TPi
The proposed model is developed under following assumptions:
1. Demands are constant and retailers and customers' demands are price-sensitive.
2. This model is extended to multi finished products and multi raw materials.
3. Holding costs, ordering costs and selling prices of raw material and products for members of each
echelon are different.
4. Shortage is not permitted.
5. Each distributor supplies one kind of raw material for the single manufacturer meaning the number
of supplier is equal to the kinds of raw materials.
6. For producing each product, manufacturer uses a certain percentage of different kinds of raw
materials.
7. Production rate of manufacturer is bigger than the retailers’ demand.
8. Replenishment rates of retailers are bigger than the market demand.
9. Lead time is negligible.
10. Demand of each retailer is different due to essence of various demands of customers.
11. All the parameters of the model are constant.
3- Mathematical Model
Here, we formulate a multi-product production and inventory model of three echelons supply chain
where the members of chain are multiple distributors, one manufacturer and multiple retailers.
39
3-1- Distributors model
Since we assume that the number of distributors is equal to the kind of raw materials, so jth distributor
d
delivers jth raw material at a rate of D j to the manufacturer. The differential equation of the inventory level
of jth distributor over the time is:
dI dj (t )
dt
d
= −D dj , 0 ≤ t ≤ T j , j = 1, 2,..., m
(1)
d
d
d
According to Figure (2), for the jth distributor I j (0) = Q j and I j (T j ) = 0 . Then, the inventory level of
jth distributor at time t during 0,T jd  is:
I dj (t=
) Q j − D j d t , 0 ≤ t ≤ T jd
(2)
Clearly, we have:
Qj
I dj (T jd ) =
0 ⇒ T jd = d
Dj
(3)
The total profit of jth distributor is equal to subtraction of total holding cost and ordering cost of raw
material from its revenue such that its total holding cost is:
1
T jd
HC dj=
 h d T j (Q − D d t )dt  =h d Q − h d
j
j
j
j
j
 j ∫0

d
 D dj T jd

 2
 h dj Q j
=
2

(4)
And the ordering cost is:
A dj D dj A dj
=
T jd
Qj
OC=
j
(5)
Hence, the total profit of jth distributor is:
 h dj Q j D dj A dj
TPjd (Q j ) =
+
(w dj − C dj )D dj − 
 2
Qj

First distributor's inventory
−D
Q1
T1d
(6)
Second distributor's inventory
Time
T 2d
jth distributor's inventory
Qj
− D 2d
Q2
d
1



Time
− D dj
T jd
Time
Fig2. Distributors' inventory profile
3-2- Manufacturer Model
The manufacturer orders different kinds of raw material to distributors, and in order to produce several
products, combines certain percentage of each material together, where production rate of kth product is as
the following:
m
Pk = ∑ θ kj D dj ,
j =1
0 ≤ θ kj ≤ 1 ,
n
∑θ
k =1
kj
=1
(7)
And the production uptime for kth product is:
40
m
m
d d
kj
j j
j 1=
j 1
=
Pk
k
∑θ
∑θ
D T
=
P
T
=
kj
Qj
(8)
Pk
According to Figure (3), during the cycle time of production (T Pk ), the inventory of kth product of
manufacturer is increasing at the rate of Pk − D km and he completely consumes his inventory during
T km −T Pk . The differential equation of this level is:
dI km
= Pk − D km , 0 ≤ t ≤ T P , k = 1, 2,..., n
dt
(9)
k
At the start of each cycle the manufacturer's inventory is zero, so I km (0) = 0 .
dI km
= −D km ,T Pk ≤ t ≤ T km , k = 1, 2,..., n
dt
m
) (Pk − D km )T Pk and I km (T km ) = 0 . Then, the manufacturer's inventory is:
Also we have I k (T P=
k
I km (=
t ) (Pk − D km )t , 0 ≤ t ≤ T Pk
(10)
(11)
Manufacturer's inventory
First product
P1 − D1m
− D1m
Second product
P2 − D 2m
− D 2m
Pn − D nm
−D
T P2
T Pn
nth product
m
n
T P1
T nm T 2m T 1m
Time
Figure3. Manufacturer's inventory profile
And
m
=
I km (t ) D km (T km − t ) ,T Pk ≤ t ≤ T k
According to Equations (10) and (11), the manufacturer's cycle time is:
(12)
m
Pk T Pk
=
T
=
D km
m
k
∑θ
j =1
kj
D
Qj
(13)
m
k
The total holding cost of manufacturer for kth product is:
=
HCkm
Tkm
1  m  TPk
1
 1  m 1

m
(
)
h
P
−
D
tdt
+
Dkm (Tkm −=
t )dt  
hk  Pk TPk 2 + DkmTkm 2 − DkmTkmTPk  
k
k

m  k  ∫0
m
∫
TPk
2
Tk  
  Tk   2

m
 1

1
= h  m Pk TPk 2 + DkmTkm − Dkm=
TPk  hkm
2
 2Tk

m
k
∑θ
j =1
kj
2
And his total ordering cost is:
41
Qj
 Dkm 
1 −

Pk 

(14)
A km
=
T km
m
OC=
k
D km A km
m
∑θ
j =1
kj
(15)
Qj
n
The
C ( Pk=
)
revenue
of
the
manufacturer
m
m
k
k
=
k 1=
j 1
is
equal
to
∑ (w
− C (P ) − ∑w dj )D km
in
which
Lk
+ ϕ k Pk is the production cost of kth product. Finally, the total profit of manufacturer is:
Pk
TP m (w km ) =
n
m
∑ (w km − C (Pk ) − ∑w dj )D km − (HC km + OC km )
=
k 1=
j 1


n 
m

= ∑ w km − C (Pk ) − ∑w dj (a − bw km ) −  hkm

=
k 1=
j 1




m
∑θ
j =1
kj
Qj
2

 (a − bw )  (a − bw )A 

1 −
+ m

P
k


θ kj Q j 
∑
j =1

m
k
m
k
m
k
(16)
3-3- Retailers’ Model
The retailers put orders for different kinds of products to the manufacturer, and manufacturer sends
proportion of kth product to ith retailer in his cycle (T km ). According to Figure (4), ith retailer's inventory starts
h
increasing at a rate of µik D km − D ikr ( 0 ≤ µik ≤ 1 and ∑ µik = 1 ) during the collecting time of the kth product
i =1
( [0, Tik ] ) and then decreases to satisfy the market demand.
The differential equations of this level are:
dI ikr
=
µik D km − D ikr , 0 ≤ t ≤ T ik , i = 1, 2,..., h
dt
dI ikr
= −D ikr ,
T ik ≤ t ≤ T ikr , i = 1, 2,..., h
dt
r
According to Figure (4), I ikr (0) = 0 , I=
ik (T ik )
(17)
(18)
(µ
ik
D km − D ikr )T ik and I ikr (T ikr ) = 0 . So, the inventory
level of ith retailer is:
r
I=
ik (t )
(µ
ik
Dkm − Dikr ) t ,
r
I=
D ikr (T ikr − t ),
ik (t )
0 ≤ t ≤ Tik
(19)
T ik ≤ t ≤ T ikr
(20)
42
First product
First retailer's inventory
µ1n D nm − D1rn
Second product
− D1rn
nth product
T12
T11
T1n
T 12r
r
T1nr T 11
Time
Second retailer's inventory
µ2 n D nm − D 2rn
− D 2rn
T 22
T 21
T 2n
r
r
T 21r T 2 n T 22
Time
hth retailer's inventory
µin D nm − D inr
− D inr
T h1
T hn T h 2
T hr2 T hnr
Time
T
r
h
1
Figure4. Retailers' inventory
diagram
Then, the period length of ith retailer is:
m
Tikr
=
µik DkmTik
=
Dikr
µik Pk TP
k
=
Dikr
th
µik ∑ θ kj Q j
(21)
j =1
r
ik
th
D
Total holding cost of i retailer for k product is shown by:
HCikr =
1
Tikr
r
Tikr
 r  Tik
  = hik µik
m
r
r
r
(
)
−
+
−
h
µ
D
D
tdt
D
T
t
dt
ik )
∫Tik ik ik
 ik  ∫0 ( ik k
 
2

43

Dikr  m
1
−
θ Q

m  ∑ kj j
µ
D
1
=
j
ik k 

(22)
And the total ordering cost is:
r
OC=
ik
A ikr
=
T ikr
D ikr A ikr
m
µik ∑ θ kj Q j
(23)
j =1
Finally, the total profit of ith retailer is:
)
TPi r (w ikr =
n
∑ (w
k =1
r
ik
−w km )D ikr − HC ikr − OC ikr 
m

r
h
µ
ik ik ∑ θ kj Q j
n 
j =1
r
m
r
= ∑  ( wik − wk )(a − bwik ) −

2
k =1





(a − bw )  (a − bw ) A 
1
−
−

m
m 

 µik (a − bwk )  µ
ik ∑ θ kj Q j 
j =1

r
ik
r
ik
r
ik
(24)
4- Solution method
As mentioned, when the chains partners’ have different market power, clearly, powerful partners prefer
to perform as the dominant member in supply chain and optimize their decisions based on the other
dominated partners. In other words, they work individually instead of joining to it. So, in this study, to model
the relation between powerful and powerless partners, we consider a decentralized supply chain in which the
partners with different market power optimize own profit under the Stackelberg game approach where the
retailers are leaders and the distributors and the manufacturer are followers.
In this chain, at the first stage, the manufacturer is leader and the distributors are followers in which the
distributors firstly determine their decision variables. Afterwards, the manufacturer makes decision about his
decision variable. In the second stage, the retailers are leaders and the distributors and the manufacturer are
followers. In this stage, also the retailers optimize their decision variables after characterizing the optimal
values of the decision variables by the followers. The ordering lot size of jth raw material ( Q j ) is a decision
d
variable of the total profit function of jth distributor (TPj ). Moreover the selling prices of the manufacturer (
w km ) is the decision variable of the total profit function of manufacturer and the selling prices of the ith
retailer (w ikr ) for the kth product are decision variables of the ith retailers’ total profit function (TPi r ). In order
to optimize the total profit of each member of supply chain, we should prove that their total profit functions
are concave.
d
Theorem1. The jth distributor's total profit function (TPj (Q j ) ) is concave.
d
Proof. Concavity of the jth distributor can be proved by taking the second order derivative of TPj (Q j )
(Equation (6)) respect to Q j which is strictly negative.
∂ 2TPjd
∂ 2Q j
2D dj A dj
=
−
<0
Q j3
(25)
The root of the first order derivative of jth distributors’ objective function respect to Q j is the optimal
value of Q j and we have:
∂TPjd
∂Q j
2D dj A dj
h dj D dj A dj
*
0
=
−
+
=→
Qj = d
2
Q j2
hj
(26)
m
m
*
Theorem2. The manufacturer's total profit function (TP (w k ,Q j ) ) is concave.
m
m
*
Proof. Similarly, by taking second order derivative of TP (w k ,Q j ) (Equation (16)) respect to w km , the
concavity of the manufacturer's total profit function will be proved because it is strictly negative.
44
∂ 2TP m
=
−2b < 0
∂ 2w km
The
root
(27)
of
the
first
order
derivative
of
total
profit
function,
a − 2bwkm + bC ( Pk )
m
bhkm ∑ θ kj Q j *
j =1
−
2 Pk
+
bAkm
=
0 , respect to w km is its optimal value and after substituting Q*j with Equation
m
∑θ
j =1
kj
Q j*
(26), the optimal price will be:
d
2 D dj Adj
a C ( Pk ) m w j hkm m
wkm* = +
+∑
−
θ
∑ kj hd +
2b =
2
2 4 Pk j 1
j 1=
j
Akm
m
2 D dj Adj
j =1
h dj
2∑ θ kj
(28)
*
r
r
m*
Theorem3. The ith retailer's total profit function, TPi (w ik ,w k ,Q j ) , is concave too.
Proof. Similar to the previous cases, concavity of the total profit function of the ith retailer will be proved
*
r
r
m*
too, because the second order derivative of TPi (w ik ,w k ,Q j ) (Equation (24)) respect to wikr is strictly
negative as shown in Equation (29).
∂ 2TPi r
=
−2b < 0
∂ 2w ikr
(29)
The optimal selling price of ith retailer (w ikr ) will be obtained by solving the first order derivative of the
total
profit
function
m
bhikr
θ kj Q j * +
a − 2bw + bw −
∑
m
2(a − bwk ) j =1
r
ik
ith
of
m
k
retailer
bAikr
to
w ikr ,
=
0 , which is:
m
µik ∑ θ kj Q j
respect
*
j =1
r*
ik
w
m
2 D dj Adj
hikr
a wkm
= +
−
∑θkj hd +
2b 2 4(a − bwkm ) j =1
j
Aikr
m
2 D dj Adj
j =1
h dj
2 µik ∑ θ kj
In order to solve the model, the following solution algorithm is developed.
Solution algorithm
Step1. Input the desired price sensitive demand function of the manufacturer for raw material jth.
Step2. Determine Qj* using Equation (26).
Step3. Determine Qk* using Equation (28).
Step4. Input the desire price sensitive demand function of hth retailer for kth product.
Step5. Determine wikr*
using Equation (30).
45
(30)
5- Numerical Example and Sensitivity Analysis
5-1- Numerical Example
In this section, a numerical example is presented for a chain with five distributors, five raw materials,
one manufacturer, four products and three retailers in a proposed three-echelon supply chain. Consider
a=10000, b=45. The other data of the distributors, the manufacturer and the retailers are shown in Tables (1),
(2) and (3), respectively. The results of the leaders and the followers are presented in Tables (4) and (5).
Table1. Data of the distributors
Distributors j
Raw Material j
C dj
h dj
A dj
w dj
D dj
1
2
3
4
5
1
2
3
4
5
8
7
11
9
8
0.50
0.30
0.60
0.55
0.40
2
3
5
4
1.5
18
16
22
20
17
550
680
450
500
600
Table2. Data of the manufacturer
Product k
θk 1
θk 2
θk 3
θk 4
θk 5
Lk
ϕk
hkm
A km
1
2
3
4
0.3
0
0.3
0.4
0.6
0.2
0.2
0
0
0.8
0
0.2
0.3
0
0.5
0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.4
4000
4800
4500
4200
0.01
0.02
0.01
0.015
0.9
1
0.8
0.7
30
35
33
37
Table3.Data of the retailers
Retailer i
µi 1
µi 2
µi 3
µi 4
hir4
A ir1
A ir2
A ir3
A ir4
1
2
3
0.4
0.3
0.3
0.25
0.3
0.45
0.3
0.4
0.3
0.35
1
1
1.1 0.9
0.35 1.05 0.98 1.08 0.92
0.3 1.1 0.95 1.12 0.9
40
43
45
47
46
45
43
45
46
42
48
40
hir2
hir1
hir3
Table4.Results of the followers
Q
*
1
66.33
Q 2*
Q 3*
Q 4*
Q 5*
116.61
86.60
85.28
67.08
Table5.Results of the leaders
Product k
w km *
w 1rk *
w 2r k *
w 3rk *
1
2
3
4
164.08
167.78
164.52
165.90
193.57
195.88
193.99
194.73
193.76
195.71
193.86
194.83
193.79
195.46
194.04
194.81
5-2- Sensitivity Analysis
In this section, the effects of followers' parameters changes’ versus the leaders' decision variables, is
studied. So a sensitivity analysis is carried out by increasing or decreasing parameters, at a time, by %25,
%50 and %75 changes. We study the effects of distributors' holding cost, ordering cost and purchasing cost
changes on the manufacturer and the retailers' selling price.
According to Table (6), the manufacturer's selling price is increased by increasing the holding cost and
decreasing ordering cost of followers, but manufacturer's selling price is not sensitive respect to the changes
46
of followers' purchasing cost. Diagram of manufacturer's selling price changes versus the changes of
distributors’ holding cost and ordering cost are shown in Figures (5) and (6), respectively.
Table 6. Effects of the changes of followers' costs on the selling price of manufacturer
Parameters
% Changes
h dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w 1m *
-0.061
-0.032
-0.014
+0.011
+0.021
+0.030
m*
2
-0.074
-0.039
-0.017
+0.014
+0.026
+0.038
w 3m *
-0.061
-0.033
-0.014
+0.012
+0.023
+0.033
m*
4
-0.077
-0.043
-0.019
+0.016
+0.031
+0.044
A dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w 1m *
+0.090
+0.039
+0.015
-0.010
-0.019
-0.026
w
m*
2
+0.111
+0.048
+0.018
-0.013
-0.023
-0.032
w
m*
3
+0.097
+0.041
+0.016
-0.011
-0.020
-0.027
w
m*
4
+0.134
+0.056
+0.021
-0.015
-0.026
-0.035
C dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w 1m *
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
m*
2
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
m*
3
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
m*
4
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
w
Manufacturer's selling price changes
0.06
0.04
0.02
0
-0.02
-0.04
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
-0.06
-0.08
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Followers' holding cost changes
Figure5. The changes of manufacturer's selling price versus the changes of followers' holding cost
47
0.8
Manufacturer's selling price changes
0.14
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
0.12
0.1
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
0
-0.02
-0.04
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' ordering cost changes
Figure6. The changes of manufacturer's selling price versus the changes of followers' ordering cost
Evidently, increasing the holding cost of raw materials influences on the manufacturer’s order quantity
and the manufacturer compels to order less of each type of raw materials in order to avoid additional costs.
In turn, his selling price increases. In contrast, increasing ordering cost leads to increase the order quantity of
the manufacturer. This change will decrease the number of replenishment times and consequently, his selling
price of finished products decreases. Although price of each product and its scale of changes depend on their
operational costs which are different for each item.
Note that, as it is shown in the above Figures, the first and the fourth product have the most changes of
all, in term of selling price, while the second and the third items’ selling price changes are moderately,
depended on the holding and the ordering cost of the different kinds of raw materials combined to produce
each product.
In the other hand, the retailers’ price changes’ versus the operational costs of the followers is examined
in Tables (7), (8), and (9). Based on Table (7), the first retailer' selling price is increased by increasing the
holding cost and decreasing the ordering cost of followers, but their price is not sensitive respect to the
purchasing cost of leaders, too. Diagram of the changes of the first retailer's selling price versus the changes
of the holding cost and ordering cost of followers are presented in Figures (7) and (8), respectively.
In this stage, as the first stage, changes on the ordering and holding cost of the distributors’ raw
materials as the followers affect on the order quantity and the number of replenishment times of retailers as
the leaders, respectively.
In other word, the first retailer decreases his order quantity of finished products by increasing the raw
material holding costs because it leads to increase the selling prices of finished products in previous stage.
Moreover, he obligates to increase his order quantity in order to decrease replenishment times when the raw
materials ordering costs increase.
According to Figures (7) and (8), the first retailer’s selling prices for the first and the second item have
the most changes while the selling prices of the third and the fourth product change mildly.
48
Table7. Effects of followers' costs on the selling price of the first retailer
Parameters
% Changes
d
j
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
r*
11
-0.143
-0.081
-0.036
+0.031
+0.060
+0.086
w 12r *
-0.263
-0.151
-0.068
+0.060
+0.114
+0.163
w 13r *
-0.196
-0.112
-0.051
+0.044
+0.084
+0.121
w 14r *
-0.212
-0.122
-0.055
+0.048
+0.092
+0.133
A dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w 11r *
+0.264
+0.111
+0.041
-0.028
-0.050
-0.067
w 12r *
+0.503
+0.209
+0.078
-0.054
-0.094
-0.126
w 13r *
+0.372
+0.155
+0.058
-0.040
-0.070
-0.093
w 14r *
+0.410
+0.170
+0.064
-0.044
-0.076
-0.102
C dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w 11r *
0
0
0
0
0
0
w 12r *
0
0
0
0
0
0
w 13r *
0
0
0
0
0
0
w 14r *
0
0
0
0
0
0
h
w
First retailer's selling price changes
0.2
0.1
0
-0.1
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
-0.2
-0.3
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' holding cost changes
Figure7. The changes of the first retailer's selling price versus the changes of the followers' holding cost
49
First retailer's selling price changes
0.6
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' ordering cost changes
Figure8. The changes of the first retailer's selling price versus the changes of the followers' ordering cost
For the second retailer, changes of selling price on the holding, ordering and purchasing cost changes
are demonstrated in Table (8) which it seems to be a rational behavior and follow the logic presented for the
first retailer. In addition, Figures (9) and (10) indicate these changes.
Table8. Effects of followers' cost on the selling price of the second retailer
Parameters
% Changes
h dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
r *
w 21
-0.192
-0.110
-0.049
+0.043
+0.082
+0.118
r *
w 22
-0.222
-0.127
-0.057
+0.050
+0.095
+0.136
r *
w 23
-0.161
-0.092
-0.041
+0.036
+0.068
+0.098
r *
w 24
-0.237
-0.137
-0.062
+0.054
+0.104
+0.149
A dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
r *
w 21
+0.361
+0.151
+0.056
-0.039
-0.068
-0.091
w
r *
22
+0.419
+0.175
+0.065
-0.045
-0.079
-0.105
w
r *
23
+0.301
+0.126
+0.047
-0.032
-0.057
-0.076
w
r *
24
+0.460
+0.191
+0.071
-0.049
-0.085
-0.114
C dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w
r *
21
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
r *
22
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
r *
23
0
0
0
0
0
0
w
r *
24
0
0
0
0
0
0
50
Second retailer's selling price changes
0.15
0.1
0.05
0
-0.05
-0.1
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
-0.15
-0.2
-0.25
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' holding cost changes
Second retailer's selling price changes
Figure9. The changes of the second retailer's selling price versus the changes of the followers' holding cost
0.5
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' ordering cost changes
Figure10. The changes of the second retailer's selling price versus the changes of the followers' ordering cost
Also, the selling price changes of the second retailer for the third and the fourth product are more
remarkably than the first and the second one, as indicated in Figures (9) and (10).
Furthermore, for the third retailer, as the other ones, the selling price changes versus the distributors’
costs are surveyed presented in Table (9) and also the changes diagrams are drawn in Figures (11) and (12).
Note that based on Figures (11) and (12), the selling prices changes of the second and the fourth product
at the third retailer are more noticeable.
Consequently, since dominant members as the leader of supply chain decide based on the best response
of the dominated members (followers), so, the optimal decisions of leaders (the manufacturer and the
retailers) are sensitive to the changes of followers’ operational costs so that the least changes in the
dominated members costs influence on the leaders’ decisions.
51
Table9.Effects of followers' cost on the selling price of the third retailer
Parameters
% Changes
d
j
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
w
r *
31
-0.199
-0.114
-0.051
+0.045
+0.085
+0.122
w
r *
32
-0.158
-0.089
-0.040
+0.035
+0.066
+0.095
r *
w 33
-0.207
-0.119
-0.054
+0.047
+0.089
+0.128
r *
w 34
-0.232
-0.134
-0.061
+0.053
+0.101
+0.145
A dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
r *
w 31
+0.376
+0.157
+0.059
-0.040
-0.071
-0.095
r *
w 32
+0.291
+0.122
+0.046
-0.031
-0.055
-0.074
r *
w 33
+0.395
+0.164
+0.061
-0.042
-0.074
-0.099
r *
w 34
+0.449
+0.186
+0.070
-0.048
-0.083
-0.111
C dj
-75
-50
-25
+25
+50
+75
r *
w 31
0
0
0
0
0
0
r *
w 32
0
0
0
0
0
0
r *
w 33
0
0
0
0
0
0
r *
w 34
0
0
0
0
0
0
h
Third retailer's selling price changes
0.15
0.1
0.05
0
-0.05
-0.1
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
-0.15
-0.2
-0.25
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' holding cost changes
Figure11. The changes of the third retailer's selling price versus the changes of the followers' holding cost
52
Third retailer's selling price changes
0.5
First product
Second product
Third product
Fourth product
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Followers' ordering cost changes
Figure12. The changes of the third retailer's selling price versus the changes of the followers' ordering cost
6- Conclusion
This paper studied a production-inventory model for multiple products in a three-echelon supply chain
of pharmacological industry under both pricing and ordering decision policies, considered by none of the
previous researches in supply chain area, including non-competing multiple distributors, one manufacturer
and non-competing multi-retailer. Each distributor delivers one kind of raw material to the manufacturer and
it combines certain percentage of different kinds of raw material to produce each product. Finished products
are sent to the retailers and the retailers satisfy end users’ demand. The model is developed for
pharmaceutical raw material and products under a real case in pharmacological industry. In addition, it is
assumed that demand is price-sensitive and shortage is not allowed. The closed form solutions of decision
variables are presented so that the concavity of the total profit functions is satisfied. The order quantity of the
distributors and the selling prices of the pharmaceutical manufacturer and the retailers are the decision
variables of the proposed model.
We employ a Stackelberg game theoretic-approach among members of the chain in which the
distributors and manufacturer, considered as the followers, identify the optimal values of their decision
variables and the retailers, considered as the leaders, determine their selling prices. Eventually, a real case is
studied to illuminate the applicability of the proposed model and then some sensitivity analyses are
performed to survey the effect of the changes of followers’ operational costs on the optimal decisions of
leaders.
We conclude that, in the first echelon of the supply chain, decreasing ordering cost of followers
(distributors) and increasing the holding cost lead to increase the manufacturer's selling price while the
changes of followers' purchasing cost is not influence on the manufacturer's selling price. Furthermore, in the
second one, the retailers' selling price is increased by increasing the holding cost and decreasing the ordering
cost of followers, but their price is not sensitive respect to the purchasing cost of leaders. Also, it is found
that the selling prices of retailers for each product depend on their operational costs and they are changeable.
The presented model has some limitations. For example, it was assumed that lead time is negligible and
shortage is not allowed. It is evident that by considering lead time and each kind of shortage, the practical
applicability of the model would be increased. If market demand is deemed in stochastic setting, the model
will become more realistic. In addition, here, we assume that the production rate of the manufacturer is
infinite while it can be considered as a fixed parameters or a decision variable (finite variable) and develop
the model under this constraint. We leave these extensions for future researches.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank the three anonymous reviewers for their helpful suggestions which have strongly
enhanced this paper. The authors would like to thank the financial support of the University of Tehran for
this research under Grant Number 30015-1-02.
53
References
Abad, P.L., (2003). Optimal pricing Lee, H., Rosenblatt, M.J., (1986). A generalized quantity discount
pricing model to increase and lot-sizing under conditions of perishability, finite production and partial
backordering and lost sale. European Journal of Operational Research, 144 (3), 677–685.
Arkan, A., Hejazi, S.R., (2012). Coordinating orders in a two echelon supply chain with controllable lead
time and ordering cost using the credit period. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 62, 56–69.
Ben-Daya, M., Darwish, M., Ertogral, K., (2008). The joint economic lot sizing problem: Review and
extensions. European Journal of Operational Research, 185, 726–742.
Boyaci, T., Gallego, G., (2002). Coordinating pricing and inventory replenishment policies for one
wholesaler and one or more geographically dispersed retailers. International Journal of Production
Economics, 77, 95–111.
Cachon, G., Netessine, S., (2004). Game theory in supply chain analysis. In: Simchi-Levi, E.b.D., Wu, S.D.,
Shen, M. (Eds.), Supply Chain Analysis in the e-Business Era. Kluwer Academic, Norwell, MA (Chapter 2).
Cai, G., Zhang, Z.G., Zhang, M., (2009). Game theoretical perspectives on dual-channel supply chain
competition with price discounts and pricing schemes. International Journal of Production Economics, 117,
80–96.
Cai, G., Chiang, W.C., Chen, X., (2011). Game theoretic pricing and ordering decisions with partial lost
sales in two-stage supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics, 130, 175–185.
Cardenas-Barron, L.E., Sana, S.S., (2014). A production-inventory model for a two-echelon supply chain
when demand is dependent on sales teams' initiatives. International Journal of Production Economics, doi:
10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.03.007 (In Press).
Chen, X., Li, L., Zhou, M., (2012). Manufacturer’s pricing strategy for supply chain with warranty perioddependent demand. Omega, 40, 807–816.
Dai, Y., Chao, X., Fang, S.C., Nuttle, H.L.W., (2005). Pricing in revenue management for multiple firms
competing for customers. International Journal of Production Economics, 98, 1–16.
Ekici, A., Altan, B., and Özener, Ö. Ö. (2015). Pricing decisions in a strategic single retailer/dual suppliers
setting under order size constraints. International Journal of Production Research,
doi:10.1080/00207543.2015.1054451 (In Press).
Giri, B.C., Sharma, S., (2014). Manufacturer's pricing strategy in a two-level supply chain with competing
retailers and advertising cost dependent demand. Economic Modelling, 38, 102–111.
Guan, R., Zhao, X., (2011). Pricing and inventory management in a system with multiple competing retailers
under (r, Q) policies. Computers & Operations Research, 38, 1294–1304.
Hill, R.M., (1999). The optimal production and shipment policy for the-single vendor single-buyer integrated
production-inventory problem. International Journal of Production Research, 37, 2463–2475.
Hua, G., Wang, S., Cheng, T.C.E., (2012). Optimal order lot sizing and pricing with free shipping. European
Journal of Operational Research, 218, 435–441.
Huang, Y., Huang, G.Q., Newman, S.T., (2011). Coordinating pricing and inventory decisions in a multilevel supply chain: A game-theoretic approach. Transportation Research Part E, 47, 115–129.
54
Jorgensen, S., Kort, P.M., (2002). Optimal pricing and inventory policies: Centralized and decentralized
decision making. European Journal of Operational Research, 138, 578–600.
Khouja, M., (2003). Optimizing inventory decisions in a multi-stage multi-customer supply chain.
Transportation Research part E, 39, 193–208.
Kovacs, A., Egri, P., Kis, T., Vancza, J., (2013). Inventory control in supply chains: Alternative approaches
to a two-stage lot-sizing problem. International Journal of Production Economics, 143(2): 385-394.
Lee, H. L., & Rosenblatt, M. J. (1986). A generalized quantity discount pricing model to increase supplier's
profits. Management science, 32(9), 1177-1185.
Mutlu, F., Cetinkaya, S., (2013). Pricing decisions in a carrier–retailer channel under price-sensitive demand
and contract-carriage with common-carriage option. Transportation Research Part E, 51, 28–40.
Nagarajan, M., Sosic, G., (2008). Game-theoretic analysis of cooperation among supply chain agents:
Review and extensions. European Journal of Operational Research, 187, 719–745.
Pal, B., Sana, S.S., Chaudhuri, K., (2012). A three layer multi-item production–inventory model for multiple
suppliers and retailers. Economic Modelling, 29, 2704–2710.
Qi, Y., Ni, W., Shi, K., (2015). Game theoretic analysis of one manufacturer two retailer supply chain with
customer market search. International Journal of Production Economics, doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2015.02.005 (In
Press).
Rosenthal, E.C., (2008). A game-theoretic approach to transfer pricing in a vertically integrated supply
chain. International Journal of Production Economics, 115, 542–552.
Ru, J., Wang, Y., (2010). Consignment contracting: Who should control inventory in the supply chain.
European Journal of Operational Research, 201, 760–769.
SeyedEsfahani, M.M., Biazaran, M., Gharakhani, M., (2011). A game theoretic approach to coordinate
pricing and vertical co-op advertising in manufacturer–retailer supply chains. European Journal of
Operational Research, 211, 263–273.
Soon, W., (2011). A review of multi-product pricing models. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 217,
8149–8165.
Szmerekovsky, J.G., Zhang, J., (2009). Pricing and two-tier advertising with one manufacturer and one
retailer. European Journal of Operational Research, 192, 904–917.
Taleizadeh, A.A., Noori-daryan, M., (2015a). Pricing, manufacturing and inventory policies for raw material
in a three-level supply chain. International Journal of System Science, 47(4), 919-931.
Taleizadeh, A.A, Noori-daryan, M., Cárdenas-Barrón, L.E., (2015a). Joint optimization of price,
replenishment frequency, replenishment cycle and production rate in vendor managed inventory system with
deteriorating items. International Journal of Production Economics. 159, 285–295.
Taleizadeh, A.A, Noori-daryan, M., Tavakkoli-Moghaddam, R., (2015b). Pricing and ordering decisions in a
supply chain with imperfect quality items and inspection under buyback of defective items. International
journal of Production Research. 53(15), 4553-4582.
55
Xiao, T., Jin, J., Chen, G., Shi, J., Xie, M., (2010). Ordering, wholesale pricing and lead-time decisions in a
three-stage supply chain under demand uncertainty. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 59, 840–852.
Yu, Y., Liang, L., Huang, G.Q., (2006). Leader–follower game in vendor-managed inventory system with
limited production capacity considering wholesale and retail prices. International Journal of Logistics:
Yu, Y., Huang, G.Q., (2010). Nash game model for optimizing market strategies, configuration of platform
products in a Vendor Managed Inventory (VMI) supply chain for a product family. European Journal of
Operational Research, 206, 361–373.
Zhao, X., Atkins, D., (2009). Transshipment between competing retailers. IIE Transactions, 41(8), 665-676.
Zhao, J., Wang, L., (2015). Pricing and retail service decisions in fuzzy uncertainty environments. Applied
Mathematics and Computation, 250, 580–592.
Whitin, T.T., (1955). Inventory control and price theory. Management Science, 2, 61–68.
56