* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Part III. General Equilibrium Intermediate Microeconomics (22014) Part III. General Equilibrium Instructor: Marc Teignier-Baqué First Semester, 2011 Part III. General Outline Part III. General Equilibrium Equilibrium Exchange Production Welfare 1. Pure Exchange Economy (Varian, Ch 31) 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Walras' Law 2. Production (Varian, Ch 32) 3. Welfare (Varian, Ch 33) Part III. General Topic 6. General Equilibrium Equilibrium Exchange I Up until now, partial equilibrium analysis: I markets for goods analyzed in isolation, ignoring eect of other prices on the market equilibrium; I demand and supply functions of own price alone. I In general, however, demand and supply in several markets interact to determine equilibrium prices of all goods. I Substitutes and complements. I People's income aected by goods sold. I In top 6, general equilibrium analysis: all markets clear simultaneously. I Considerations of Pareto eciency and also of welfare distribution and "social preferences." Production Welfare Part III. General Equilibrium PURE EXCHANGE ECONOMY (Varian, Ch 31) I Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production Welfare I Since very complex problem, simplications adopted: I Only competitive markets studied, so that consumers and producers take prices as given. I Situations with, at most, two goods and two consumers. I First, pure exchange economy : xed endowments, no description of resources conversion to consumables. I Afterwards, production introduced into the model. Pure exchange economy: I Two consumers, A and B, two goods, 1 and 2. I Endowments of goods 1 and 2: ω A = ω A, ω A , ω B = ω B , ω B . 1 I 1 2 Given a price vector (p1 , p2 ), consumers choose their favorite aordable allocation (as in topic 1): p1 x1A + p2 x2A ≤ p1 ω1A + p2 ω2A p1 x B + p2 x B ≤ p1 ω B + p2 ω B 1 I 2 2 1 2 Prices must be such that allocations chosen are feasible: xA + xB ≤ ωA + ωB , xA + xB ≤ ωA + ωB 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 Part III. General Edgeworth Box Equilibrium I Edgeworth box is diagram showing all possible Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium allocations of the available quantities of goods 1 and 2 between the two consumers. Welfare theorems Walras' Law I Production Welfare I The dimensions of the box are the quantities available of the goods. The allocations depicted are the feasible allocations . Height = 2A 2B Width = Width = 1A 1B Part III. General Endowment allocation Equilibrium I The endowment allocation is the before-trade Exchange allocation: Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium ω 1B Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production Welfare OB ω 2B ω 2A + Endowment allocation ll A ω 2B ω 2 OA ω 1A ω 1A + ω 1B Part III. General Equilibrium Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium Welfare theorems Feasible reallocations I Which reallocation will consumers choose? I I Feasible. Pareto-improving over the endowment allocation. I An allocation is feasible if and only if A + xB ≤ ωA + ωB 1 1 1 A B A B x +x ≤ ω +ω Walras' Law x1 Production Welfare 2 2 2 2 I All points in the box, including the boundary, represent feasible allocations of the combined endowments: xB 1 ω 2A xB 2 + ω 2B OB xA 2 OA x1A ω 1A + ω 1B Part III. General Pareto-improving allocations Equilibrium Exchange I An allocation is Pareto-improving over the endowment Edgeworth Box The Core allocation if it improves the welfare of a consumer Competitive equilibrium without reducing the welfare of another. Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production I Preferences of consumers A and B: Welfare xA 2 Preferences of consumer B Preferences of consumer B Preferences consumer A x1B 1B OB 2B 2A OA 1A x1A x2B Part III. General Pareto-improving allocations Equilibrium I An allocation is Pareto-improving over the endowment Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium allocation if it improves the welfare of a consumer without reducing the welfare of another. Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production 1B Welfare 2B 2A OA OB 1A Set of Pareto‐improving allocations I Since each consumer can refuse to trade, the only possible outcomes from exchange are Pareto-improving allocations. Part III. General Contract curve Equilibrium I An allocation is Pareto-optimal if the only way one Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium consumer's welfare can be increased is to decrease the welfare of the other consumer. Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production Welfare I The set of all Pareto-optimal allocations is called contract curve . Pareto‐optimal allocations are marked by . Convex indifference curves are tangent at . 1B OB 2B 2A OA 1A Th The contract curve t t Part III. General The Core Equilibrium Exchange Edgeworth Box I The core is the set of all Pareto-optimal allocations The Core that are welfare-improving for both consumers relative Competitive equilibrium to their own endowments. Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production Welfare 1B 2B 2A OA OB 1A The Core: Pareto‐optimal p trades not blocked by A or B. I Rational trade should achieve a core allocation. Part III. General Equilibrium Exchange Trade in competitive markets I Specic core alloation achieved depends upon the manner in which trade is conducted. Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production I In perfectly competitive markets, each consumer is a price-taker trying to maximize her own utility given (p1 , p2 ) and her own endowment: Welfare xA 2 Consumer A optimization A A p1x1A p 2x A 2 p1 1 p 2 2 x2* A 2A OA x1* A I Similarly for consumer B. 1A x1A Part III. General Trade in competitive markets Equilibrium I At equilibrium prices p1 and p2 , both consumers Exchange Edgeworth Box maximize their own utility and both markets clear: The Core A + xB = ωA + ωB 1 1 1 A B A B x +x = ω +ω Competitive equilibrium x1 Welfare theorems Walras' Law 2 Production 2 2 2 Welfare Budget constraint for consumer B x1*B 1B x2* B x2* A 2B A 2 OA OB x1* A 1A Equilibrium allocation Equilibrium allocation Budget constraint for consumer A Part III. General First fundamental theorem of welfare economics Equilibrium Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Theorem Given that consumers' preferences are well-behaved, trading Competitive equilibrium in perfectly competitive markets implements a Pareto-optimal Welfare theorems allocation of the economy's endowment. Walras' Law Production Welfare I Note: Indierence curves are tangent, which implies that the equilibrium allocation is Pareto optimal. Part III. General Equilibrium Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium Welfare theorems Walras' Law Second fundamental theorem of welfare economics Theorem Given that consumers' preferences are well-behaved, for any Pareto-optimal allocation, there are prices and an allocation of the total endowment that makes the Pareto-optimal allocation implementable by trading in competitive markets. Production Welfare I In other words, any Pareto-optimal allocation can be achieved by trading in competitive markets provided that endowments are rst appropriately rearranged. Pareto‐optimal allocation cannot be implemented by competitive trading implemented by competitive trading from initial endowment but it can be implemented by competitive trading from alternative endowment . l d OB OA Part III. General Walras' Law Equilibrium Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium Welfare theorems Walras' Law Theorem If consumer's preferences are well-behaved, so that for any positive prices (p1 , p2 ) consumers spend all their budget, the Production summed market value of excess demands is zero. This is Welfare Walras' Law. A + p xA = p ωA + p ωA 2 2 1 1 2 2 B B B B x +p x = p ω +p ω p1 x1 p1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 ⇒ p1 A + xB − ωA − ωB + p xA + xB − ωA − ωB = 0 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 x1 Part III. General Implications of Walras' Law Equilibrium I One implication of Walras' Law for a two-commodity Exchange Edgeworth Box The Core Competitive equilibrium exchange economy is that if one market is in equilibrium then the other market must also be in equilibrium. Welfare theorems Walras' Law Production Welfare p1 A + xB − ωA − ωB +p xA + xB − ωA − ωB = 0 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 x1 ⇒ If x1A + x1B = ω1A + ω1B , A + xB = ωA + ωB. 2 2 2 then x2 I Another implication of Walras' Law for a two-commodity exchange economy is that an excess supply in one market implies an excess demand in the other market. p1 A + xB − ωA − ωB +p xA + xB − ωA − ωB = 0 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 x1 ⇒ If x1A + x1B < ω1A + ω1B , A + xB > ωA + ωB. 2 2 2 then x2 Part III. General Outline Part III. General Equilibrium Equilibrium Exchange Production Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems 1. Pure Exchange Economy (Varian, Ch 31) Welfare 2. Production (Varian, Ch 32) 2.1 Robinson Crusoe economy 2.2 Competitive equilibrium 2.3 Welfare theorems 3. Welfare (Varian, Ch 33) Part III. General Equilibrium Exchange Production Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Welfare PRODUCTION (Varian, Ch 32) I Add input and output markets, rms' technologies. I Robinson Crusoe's Economy: I I I One agent: Robinson Crusoe. Endowment: a xed quantity of time. Decision: use time for labor (production of coconuts) or leisure. I Technology: coconuts are obtained from labor according to the production function C = f (L). Coconuts Production function Feasible production l plans 0 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Equilibrium Exchange Production Robinson Crusoe Economy Robinson Crusoe's preferences I Indierence curves in the leisure-coconut diagram: coconut is a good, leisure is a good: Coconuts More preferred Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Welfare 24 0 Leisure (hours) I Indierence curves in the labor-coconuts diagram: coconut is a good, labor is a bad. Coconuts More preferred 0 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Robinson Crusoe's choice Equilibrium Exchange Production I Robinson chooses time allocation and, as a result, his consumption of coconuts: Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Coconuts Welfare MRS = MPL Production function C* Outputt Labor 0 24 Leisure L* 24 0 Labor (hours) Leisure (hours) Part III. General Competitive equilibrium in the Robinson economy Equilibrium Exchange Production Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium I Robinson esquizofrenia: I Welfare Theorems Welfare I We rst consider Robinson as a prot-maximizing rm , who takes prices as given and decides how much hours to hire and how much to produce. Then, we consider Robinson as a utility-maximizing consumer who gets the rm prots and decides his hours of work and his consumption of coconuts. I Let p be the coconuts price and w the wage rate. I Use coconuts as the numeraire good; i.e. price of a coconut = 1. Part III. General Equilibrium Exchange Robinson as a rm I Optimization problem of the rm: given w , choose labor demand and coconut supply to maximize prots: Production max π Robinson Crusoe Economy L Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Welfare I = C − wL = f (L) − wL ⇒ MP (L ∗ )=w Labor demanded: L∗ , output supplied: C ∗ = f (L∗ ). I Graphically, rm demands L such that production function tangent to isoprot line: Coconuts w = MPL Isoprofit line: * C * wL * Production function C* * 0 L* 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Equilibrium Robinson as consumer I Optimization problem of the consumer: choose labor Exchange supply and coconut demand to maximize utility subject Production to the budget constraint: Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems max U (C , L) s.t. C C ,L Welfare I = π ∗ + wL ⇒ ∂ U (C , L) /∂ L =w ∂ U (C , L) /∂ C Labor supplies: L∗ , coconuts demanded: C ∗ . I Graphically, consumer chooses C and L such that the indierence curve is tangent to the budget constraint: Coconuts MRS = w Budget constraint: C * wL. C* * 0 L* 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Market equilibrium Equilibrium Exchange I In equilibrium, wage rate must be such that Production Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems quantity labor demanded = quantity labor supplied (quantity output supplied = quantity output demanded) Welfare Coconuts MRS = w = MPL C* * 0 L* 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Equilibrium First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Theorem Exchange If consumers' preferences are convex and there are no Production externalities in consumption or production, a competitive Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Welfare market equilibrium is Pareto ecient. = MP : Competitive equilibrium achieves Pareto eciency: w is the common slope of the isprot line and the budget constraint. I Pareto eciency: MRS I Coconuts 0 MRS = MP 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Equilibrium Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Exchange Production Robinson Crusoe Economy Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Welfare Theorem If consumers' preferences are convex, rms' technologies are convex, and there are no externalities in consumption or production any Pareto ecient economic state can be achieved as a competitive market equilibrium. Part III. General Non-convex technologies Equilibrium Exchange I The First Welfare Theorems still holds if rms have Production non-convex technologies since it does not rely upon Robinson Crusoe Economy rms' technologies being convex. Competitive Equilibrium Welfare Theorems Welfare I The Second Welfare Theorem does not hold if rms have non-convex technologies. Coconuts Coconuts MRS = MPL 0 Iff competitive i i equilibrium ilib i exists, the common slope is the relative wage rate w th t implements that i l t the th Pareto P t efficient plan by decentralized pricing. 24 Labor (hours) MRS = MPL. 0 This Pareto optimal allocation cannot be implemented by a competitive equilibrium. 24 Labor (hours) Part III. General Outline Part III. General Equilibrium Equilibrium Exchange Production Welfare 1. Pure Exchange Economy (Varian, Ch 31 2. Production (Varian, Ch 32) 3. Welfare (Varian, Ch 33) Part III. General WELFARE (Varian, Ch 33) Equilibrium Exchange Production Welfare I Social choice: Dierent economic states will be preferred by dierent individuals. How can individual preferences be aggregated into a social preference over all possible economic states? I Fairness: Some Pareto ecient allocations are unfair (for example, one consumer eats everything). Under what conditions, competitive markets guarantee that a fair allocation is achieved? Part III. General Social welfare functions Equilibrium Exchange Let ui (x ) be individual i's utility from overall allocation x. Production Welfare I Utilitarian social welfare function: n W = ∑ ui (x ) i =1 I Weighted-sum social welfare function: n W = ∑ ai ui (x ) , i =1 ai >0 I Minimax welfare function: W = min {u1 (x ) , u2 (x ) , ...., un (x )} Part III. General Fair allocations Equilibrium Exchange Production Welfare I An allocation is fair if it is I I Pareto ecient envy free (no agent prefers the allocation of other agents to their own). I If every agent's endowment is identical, then trading in competitive markets results in a fair allocation (may not be true for non-competitive markets).