* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download bankrunsissues08-09short
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Banking and Bank Runs • We are going to learn a bit about what a bank does and why it leads to the possibility of bank runs. – We will start out today with a couple of movie clips. – Then discuss a theoretical model of a bank. Mary Poppins • Two things to notice. – Bank Run was caused by panic w/o financial reasons. The bank was fully solvent. – The bank closed its doors: stopped payment. It’s a Wonderful Life • It was a systemic panic. • There may have been a justification for the bank run. • A bank takes money and invests it in long-term assets (mortgages). • The bank can’t easily liquidate these assets. • The bank did not fully suspend payments. Doing so would hurt depositors. • There was a degree of negotiation on who gets what. Diamond Dybvig Model (1983) • Captures elements of what a bank does. • Shows that there is a basic problem of bank runs. • The model consists of two parties. – Depositors – Banks • The model has three time periods: yesterday, today and tomorrow. Depositors • Depositors placed money (say £1000) in a bank (yesterday) before learning when they need the money. • Depositors either need their money today (impatient) or tomorrow (patient). There is a 50% chance of being either type. • The ones that need their money tomorrow can always take the money today and hold onto it. • The ones that need money today get relatively very little utility for the money tomorrow. Banks • Banks have both a short term and a long term investment opportunity for the money. – The short term investment (reserves) is locking the money in the vault. This investment returns the exact amount invested. – The long term investment returns an amount R tomorrow. It is illiquid and returns only L<1 today. Deposit Contract • The depositors invested £1000 yesterday have a contract with the bank. • The depositors can withdraw their money today and receive £1000 or wait until tomorrow and receive R*£1000. Bank’s decision • How can the bank meet this contract? – The bank can divide into two parts. • Take half and keep it as reserves. • Take the other half and put it in the long term investment. • Say there are 10 depositors: 5 patient and 5 impatient. The bank puts £5000 in the vault and invests £5000. • Demands today are 5*1000, and 5*R*1000. The bank has 5000 and R*5000 tomorrow. • Thus, a bank makes zero profit. Danger! • The bank can not always remain solvent. • If too many depositors try to withdraw today, it won’t be able to meet the contract tomorrow. • For instance if 7 depositors withdraw today, then the bank can pay 5000 out of reserves. It then must sell its illiquid asset to meet the rest of the needs, £2000. • How much must it sell to meet the needs? How much is left? • How much does those withdrawing tomorrow receive? • On average, how much does those withdrawing today receive? • At what value of L does is the bank unable to meet demands today for those 7 depositors? Multiple equilibria • This leads to multiple (Nash) equilibria. • It is inherent in banking. • Here is an example with 2 patient depositors (and 2 impatient depositors). • This forms a 2x2 game between the patient depositors. • R=1.5 and L=.5 Game between patient depositors Depositor 1 Tomorrow Today 0 3/4 Today 3/4 1 Depositor 2 1 3/2 Tomorrow 0 3/2 R=1.5, L=.5 Experiment • We then went to the lab and had 3 treatments with 9 patient and 9 impatient. • Credit Crunch: R=1.1, L=.11 • Normal Conditions: R=2, L=.7 • Credit Crunch with 90% deposit insurance. • How many other patient depositors need to withdraw today for you to want to withdraw today? Normal Conditions Credit crunch Credit crunch w/ 90% deposit ins. Hidden assumption • Depositors withdraw sequentially: a bank cannot count the number of people wanting to withdraw today and then decide how much to pay them. • Otherwise, they can just pay them 5000/N where N is the number withdrawing early (for the 10 depositor case). This would make suspension less painful. What is not captured in the model • Uncertainty in depositor’s preferences. – Too many actually need the money today. • Riskiness in technology. – Riskiness in R: Perhaps there really isn’t enough to meet demand tomorrow. • Implication: it will be worthwhile to withdraw money independent of what others do. Sometimes a bank run will be the unique equilibrium. – Riskiness in L: Perhaps one can’t really get L. Particularly if it is a systemic risk. • With LTCM, prices went down on any asset that LTCM owned! Dual listed stocks arbitraged by LTCM diverged Early Solutions to Bank Runs • Put money in the windows • Slow up payments. Solutions. • Make sure R & L are not risky. Difficult & doesn’t stop multi. Equilibria. • Pay early withdrawers less than 1 or pay late withdrawers less than R (and keep more reserves/Narrow Banking) – Problems: not best contract. • Suspend payments/ Partial Suspension. – Problem when number needing money today is uncertain. • Creditor Coordination. – Long Term Capital Management ran into trouble in 1998. – The NY FED organized a bailout with creditors. • Lender of last resorts. – Central bank will stop in and loan the bank money to replace deposits. – This should work with depositors in the case of a problem with liquidity – In 1975, • April 14th, Credit Suisse announced lost some money in one of its branches. It didn’t mention details. • April 25th, The Swiss Central Bank announced it was willing to lend money. • This had the opposite result causing share price to tumble 20%. • Combination Bailout. – 1907 Banking panic (JP Morgan and US treasury). • Deposit Insurance. – This works well. Risk-Sharing between banks. Insurance Problem: Moral hazard • Todd buys theft insurance for his laptop. • Because he buys the insurance, he is more likely to leave the laptop in his car. • Ideally, he would like to commit to not leaving the computer in his car. • Sometimes, we can contract on it. • Other times, we can’t. • Do we have a moral hazard problem with deposit insurance? Answer: Yes. • Marc is the manager of a Springfield S&L. • Marc pays higher interest than a bigger and safer bank claiming his small size helps him cut costs. • Springfield has deposit insurance (100%). • Todd puts money in Springfield. • Springfield lends money to a dodgy lecturer at Springfield State University at a higher rate. • When there is no default, everyone wins. • When there is a default, Todd still gets paid. • Without insurance, Todd wouldn’t invest if he sees Springfield’s risky behavior. Model of Moral Hazard. • The bank can choose any investment x, where 3>x=>1. • Any investment costs £.95 and is either successful and pays of x or unsuccessful and pays £0. • The probability of the investment being successful is P(X)=(3-x)/2. • Choosing x=1 is safe, choosing x close to 3 is unsafe. • Todd is close to risk neutral and wants to earn at least as much as £1 (in expectation) which the other banks are offering as a risk free investment. He wants R where R*P(x)=1. • Without insurance, the bank maximizes – P(X)*(X-R) where R=1/P(x) • With insurance, Todd only needs R=1. So the bank maximizes – P(X)*(X-R) where R=1 Savings and Loans scandal • In the 1980s about 1000 S&L’s went bankrupt. • They originally lent money out at fixed rates of 6% and paid deposits 3%. • With inflation, they had to pay deposits 14% and lost money. • Took gambles to catch up, went to Vegas. • They were able to take high risk due to the deposit insurance. • This cost US taxpayers $120 billion. Solution to Moral Hazard • One solution is for insurance to not be 100% (co-pay as in the UK). • However, this requires the depositors to be savvy and this still keeps the multiple equilibrium problem. • In the US, in 2006 Bush signed a law allowing the FDIC to charge premiums based upon risk.