Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Leonardo Felli 23 October, 2002 Microeconomics II Lecture 3 Constrained Envelope Theorem Consider the problem: max f (x) x s.t. g(x, a) = 0 The Lagrangian is: L(x, λ, a) = f (x) − λ g(x, a) Necessary FOC are: 0 ∗ f (x ) − λ ∗ ∂g(x ∗ , a) =0 ∂x g(x∗(a), a) = 0 1 Microeconomics II 2 Substituting x∗(a) and λ∗(a) in the Lagrangian we get: L(a) = f (x∗(a)) − λ∗(a) g(x∗(a), a) Differentiating we get: ∗ dL(a) d x∗(a) 0 ∗ ∗ ∂g(x , a) = f (x ) − λ − da ∂x da dλ∗(a) ∂g(x∗, a) ∗ ∗ − λ (a) −g(x (a), a) da ∂a ∗ ∂g(x , a) = −λ∗(a) ∂a by the necessary FOC. In other words — to the first order — only the direct effect of a on the Lagrangian function matters. Microeconomics II 3 3. Roy’s identity: xi(p, m) = − ∂V /∂pi ∂V /∂m By the constrained envelope theorem and the observation that: V (p, m) = u(x(p, m)) − λ(p, m) [p x(p, m) − m] we shall obtain: ∂V /∂pi = −λ(p, m) xi(p, m) ≤ 0 and ∂V /∂m = λ(p, m) ≥ 0 which is the marginal utility of income. Microeconomics II 4 (Notice that the sign of the two inequalities above prove property 1 of the indirect utility function V (p, m).) We conclude the proof substituting ∂V /∂m = λ(p, m) into ∂V /∂pi = −λ(p, m) xi(p, m) and solving for xi(p, m). 4. Adding up results. From the identity: p x(p, m) = m ∀p, ∀m Microeconomics II 5 Differentiation with respect to pj gives: xj (p, m) + L X pi i=1 ∂xi =0 ∂pj or, more interestingly, with respect to m gives: L X i=1 pi ∂xi =1 ∂m There does not exist a clear cut comparative-static property with the exception of: 0≥ L X i=1 pi ∂xi = −xh(p, m) ∂ph which means that at least one of the Marshallian demand function has to be downward sloping in ph Microeconomics II 6 Effect of a change in income on the level of the Marshallian demand: ∂xl ∂m In the two commodities graph the set of tangency points for different values of m is known as the income expansion path. In the commodity income graph the set of optimal choices of the quantity of the commodity is known as Engel curve. Microeconomics II 7 We shall classify commodities with respect to the effect of changes in income in: • normal goods: ∂xl >0 ∂m • neutral goods: ∂xl =0 ∂m • inferior goods: ∂xl <0 ∂m Notice that for every level of income m at least one of the L commodities is normal: L X l=1 ∂xl pl =1 ∂m Microeconomics II 8 If the Engel curve is convex we are facing a luxury good in other case a necessity. x(p, m) 6 luxury necessity - m Microeconomics II 9 Expenditure Minimization Problem The dual problem of the consumer’s utility maximization problem is the expenditure minimization problem: min p x {x} s.t. u(x) ≥ U Define the solution as: x = h(p, U ) = h1(p1, . . . , pL, U ) .. hL(p1, . . . , pL, U ) the Hicksian (compensated) demand functions. We shall also define: e(p, U ) = p h(p, U ) as the expenditure function. Microeconomics II 10 Properties of the expenditure function: 1. Continuous in p and U . 2. ∂e ∂U > 0 (2.1) and ∂e ∂pl ≥ 0 (2.2) for every l = 1, . . . , L. Proof: (2.1): Suppose not: there exist U 0 < U 00 (denote x0 and x00 the corresponding solution to the e.m.p.) such that p x0 ≥ p x00 > 0. If the latter inequality is strict we have an immediate contradiction of x0 solving e.m.p.; if on the other hand p x0 = p x00 > 0 then by continuity and strict monotonicity of u(·) there exists α ∈ (0, 1) close enough to 1 such that u(α x00) > U 0 and p x0 > p αx00 which contradicts x0 solving e.m.p.. Microeconomics II 11 (2.2): consider p0 and p00 such that p00l ≥ p0l but p00k = p0k for every k 6= l. Let x00 and x0 be the solutions to the e.m.p. with p00 and p0 respectively. Then by definition of e(p, U ) e(p00, U ) = p00 x00 ≥ p0 x00 ≥ p0 x0 = e(p0, U ). 3. Homogeneous of degree 1 in p. Proof: The feasible set of the e.m.p. does not change when prices are multiplied by the factor k > 0. Hence ∀k > 0, minimizing (k p) x on this set leads to the same answer. Let x∗ be the solution, then: e(k p, U ) = (k p) x∗ = k e(p, U ). Microeconomics II 12 4. Concave (graphic intuition) in p. Proof: let p00 = t p + (1 − t) p0 for t ∈ [0, 1]. Let x00 be the solution to e.m.p. for p00. Then e(p00, U ) = p00 x00 = t p x00 + (1 − t) p0 x00 ≥ t e(p, U ) + (1 − t) e(p0, U ) since u(x00) ≥ U and by definition of e(p, U ). Properties of the Hicksian demand functions: h(p, U ) 1. Shephard’s Lemma. ∂e(p, U ) = hl (p, U ) ∂pl Proof: by constrained envelope theorem. Microeconomics II 13 2. Homogeneity of degree 0 in p. Proof: by Shephard’s lemma and the fact that the following theorem. Theorem. If a function F (x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then (∂F/∂xl ) is homogeneous of degree (r − 1) in x for every l = 1, . . . , L. Proof: Differentiating the identity that defines homgeneity of degree r: F (k x) = k r F (x) ∀k > 0 with respect to xl we obtain: ∂F (k x) r ∂F (x) k =k ∂xl ∂xl Microeconomics II 14 The latter equation corresponds to the definition of homogeneity of degree (r − 1): ∂F (k x) (r−1) ∂F (x) =k . ∂xl ∂xl Euler Theorem. If a function F (x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then: r F (x) = ∇F (x) x Proof: Differentiating with respect to k the identity: F (k x) = k r F (x) ∀k > 0 Microeconomics II 15 we obtain: ∇F (kx) x = rk (r−1) F (x) for k = 1 we obtain: ∇F (x) x = r F (x). 3. The matrix of cross-partial derivatives (Substitution matrix) with respect to p ∂h1 ∂h1 · · · ∂pL ∂p1 .. . . . .. S= ∂hL ∂hL · · · ∂p1 ∂p L is negative semi-definite and symmetric. (Main diagonal non-positive). Microeconomics II 16 Proof: Simmetry follows from Shephard’s lemma and Young Theorem. Indeed: ∂hl ∂ = ∂pi ∂pi ∂e(p, U ) ∂pl = ∂ ∂pl ∂e(p, U ) ∂pi = ∂hi ∂pl While negative semi-definiteness follows from the concavity of e(p, U ) and the observation that S is the Hessian of the function e(p, U ). Microeconomics II Identities: V [p, e(p, U )] ≡ U xl [p, e(p, U )] ≡ hl (p, U ) ∀l e[p, V (p, m)] ≡ m hl [p, V (p, m)] ≡ xl (p, m) ∀l Slutsky decomposition: start from the identity hl (p, U ) ≡ xl [p, e(p, U )] if the price pi changes the effect is: ∂hl ∂xl ∂xl ∂e = + ∂pi ∂pi ∂m ∂pi 17 Microeconomics II Notice that by Shephard’s lemma: ∂e = hi(p, U ) = xi[p, e(p, U )] ∂pi then ∂hl ∂xl ∂xl = + xi . ∂pi ∂pi ∂m or ∂xl ∂hl ∂xl = − xi . ∂pi ∂pi ∂m Own price effect gives Slutsky equation: ∂xl ∂hl ∂xl = − xl . ∂pl ∂pl ∂m 18 Microeconomics II 19 Slutsky decomposition: ∂xl ∂hl ∂xl = − xi . ∂pi ∂pi ∂m Slutsky equation: ∂xl ∂hl ∂xl = − xl . ∂pl ∂pl ∂m This latter equation corresponds to the distinction between substitution and income effect: Microeconomics II 20 Substitution effect: ∂hl ∂pl Income effect: ∂xl xl ∂m x1 6 e e e e e e e e e HH e e e e HH e e HH 1 HH e e HH e s e HH e y e e e HH e e H H eH 0 es eHH s e 2 e e HH e HH e e HH e e e HH e e HH e e HH e e HH e e HH e e HH e e x x x - x2 Microeconomics II 21 We know the sign of the substitution effect it is nonpositive. The sign of the income effect depends on whether the good is normal or inferior. In the case that: ∂xl >0 ∂pl we conclude that the good is Giffen. This is not a realistic feature, inferior good with a big income effect.