Download Microeconomics II Lecture 3 Constrained Envelope Theorem

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Routhian mechanics wikipedia , lookup

Nyquist–Shannon sampling theorem wikipedia , lookup

Multiple-criteria decision analysis wikipedia , lookup

Mathematical optimization wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Leonardo Felli
23 October, 2002
Microeconomics II
Lecture 3
Constrained Envelope Theorem
Consider the problem:
max f (x)
x
s.t. g(x, a) = 0
The Lagrangian is:
L(x, λ, a) = f (x) − λ g(x, a)
Necessary FOC are:
0
∗
f (x ) − λ
∗ ∂g(x
∗
, a)
=0
∂x
g(x∗(a), a) = 0
1
Microeconomics II
2
Substituting x∗(a) and λ∗(a) in the Lagrangian we
get:
L(a) = f (x∗(a)) − λ∗(a) g(x∗(a), a)
Differentiating we get:
∗
dL(a)
d x∗(a)
0 ∗
∗ ∂g(x , a)
= f (x ) − λ
−
da
∂x
da
dλ∗(a)
∂g(x∗, a)
∗
∗
− λ (a)
−g(x (a), a)
da
∂a
∗
∂g(x , a)
= −λ∗(a)
∂a
by the necessary FOC.
In other words — to the first order — only the direct
effect of a on the Lagrangian function matters.
Microeconomics II
3
3. Roy’s identity:
xi(p, m) = −
∂V /∂pi
∂V /∂m
By the constrained envelope theorem and the observation that:
V (p, m) = u(x(p, m)) − λ(p, m) [p x(p, m) − m]
we shall obtain:
∂V /∂pi = −λ(p, m) xi(p, m) ≤ 0
and
∂V /∂m = λ(p, m) ≥ 0
which is the marginal utility of income.
Microeconomics II
4
(Notice that the sign of the two inequalities above
prove property 1 of the indirect utility function V (p, m).)
We conclude the proof substituting
∂V /∂m = λ(p, m)
into
∂V /∂pi = −λ(p, m) xi(p, m)
and solving for xi(p, m).
4. Adding up results. From the identity:
p x(p, m) = m
∀p,
∀m
Microeconomics II
5
Differentiation with respect to pj gives:
xj (p, m) +
L
X
pi
i=1
∂xi
=0
∂pj
or, more interestingly, with respect to m gives:
L
X
i=1
pi
∂xi
=1
∂m
There does not exist a clear cut comparative-static
property with the exception of:
0≥
L
X
i=1
pi
∂xi
= −xh(p, m)
∂ph
which means that at least one of the Marshallian
demand function has to be downward sloping in ph
Microeconomics II
6
Effect of a change in income on the level of the Marshallian demand:
∂xl
∂m
In the two commodities graph the set of tangency
points for different values of m is known as the income expansion path.
In the commodity income graph the set of optimal
choices of the quantity of the commodity is known as
Engel curve.
Microeconomics II
7
We shall classify commodities with respect to the effect of changes in income in:
• normal goods:
∂xl
>0
∂m
• neutral goods:
∂xl
=0
∂m
• inferior goods:
∂xl
<0
∂m
Notice that for every level of income m at least one
of the L commodities is normal:
L
X
l=1
∂xl
pl
=1
∂m
Microeconomics II
8
If the Engel curve is convex we are facing a luxury
good in other case a necessity.
x(p, m)
6
luxury
necessity
-
m
Microeconomics II
9
Expenditure Minimization Problem
The dual problem of the consumer’s utility maximization problem is the expenditure minimization
problem:
min p x
{x}
s.t. u(x) ≥ U
Define the solution as:


x = h(p, U ) = 


h1(p1, . . . , pL, U )

..


hL(p1, . . . , pL, U )
the Hicksian (compensated) demand functions.
We shall also define:
e(p, U ) = p h(p, U )
as the expenditure function.
Microeconomics II
10
Properties of the expenditure function:
1. Continuous in p and U .
2.
∂e
∂U
> 0 (2.1) and
∂e
∂pl
≥ 0 (2.2) for every l =
1, . . . , L.
Proof: (2.1): Suppose not: there exist U 0 < U 00
(denote x0 and x00 the corresponding solution to the
e.m.p.) such that p x0 ≥ p x00 > 0.
If the latter inequality is strict we have an immediate
contradiction of x0 solving e.m.p.;
if on the other hand p x0 = p x00 > 0 then by continuity and strict monotonicity of u(·) there exists
α ∈ (0, 1) close enough to 1 such that u(α x00) > U 0
and p x0 > p αx00 which contradicts x0 solving e.m.p..
Microeconomics II
11
(2.2): consider p0 and p00 such that p00l ≥ p0l but p00k =
p0k for every k 6= l.
Let x00 and x0 be the solutions to the e.m.p. with p00
and p0 respectively.
Then by definition of e(p, U )
e(p00, U ) = p00 x00 ≥ p0 x00 ≥ p0 x0 = e(p0, U ).
3. Homogeneous of degree 1 in p.
Proof: The feasible set of the e.m.p. does not change
when prices are multiplied by the factor k > 0.
Hence ∀k > 0, minimizing (k p) x on this set leads
to the same answer. Let x∗ be the solution, then:
e(k p, U ) = (k p) x∗ = k e(p, U ).
Microeconomics II
12
4. Concave (graphic intuition) in p.
Proof: let p00 = t p + (1 − t) p0 for t ∈ [0, 1]. Let x00
be the solution to e.m.p. for p00. Then
e(p00, U ) = p00 x00 = t p x00 + (1 − t) p0 x00
≥ t e(p, U ) + (1 − t) e(p0, U )
since u(x00) ≥ U and by definition of e(p, U ).
Properties of the Hicksian demand functions:
h(p, U )
1. Shephard’s Lemma.
∂e(p, U )
= hl (p, U )
∂pl
Proof: by constrained envelope theorem.
Microeconomics II
13
2. Homogeneity of degree 0 in p.
Proof: by Shephard’s lemma and the fact that the
following theorem.
Theorem. If a function F (x) is homogeneous of
degree r in x then (∂F/∂xl ) is homogeneous of
degree (r − 1) in x for every l = 1, . . . , L.
Proof: Differentiating the identity that defines homgeneity of degree r:
F (k x) = k r F (x)
∀k > 0
with respect to xl we obtain:
∂F (k x)
r ∂F (x)
k
=k
∂xl
∂xl
Microeconomics II
14
The latter equation corresponds to the definition of
homogeneity of degree (r − 1):
∂F (k x)
(r−1) ∂F (x)
=k
.
∂xl
∂xl
Euler Theorem. If a function F (x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then:
r F (x) = ∇F (x) x
Proof: Differentiating with respect to k the identity:
F (k x) = k r F (x)
∀k > 0
Microeconomics II
15
we obtain:
∇F (kx) x = rk (r−1) F (x)
for k = 1 we obtain:
∇F (x) x = r F (x).
3. The matrix of cross-partial derivatives (Substitution matrix) with respect to p

∂h1
∂h1
·
·
·
∂pL
 ∂p1
.. . . . ..
S=

∂hL
∂hL
·
·
·
∂p1
∂p




L
is negative semi-definite and symmetric. (Main diagonal non-positive).
Microeconomics II
16
Proof: Simmetry follows from Shephard’s lemma
and Young Theorem.
Indeed:
∂hl
∂
=
∂pi ∂pi
∂e(p, U )
∂pl
=
∂
∂pl
∂e(p, U )
∂pi
=
∂hi
∂pl
While negative semi-definiteness follows from the concavity of e(p, U ) and the observation that S is the
Hessian of the function e(p, U ).
Microeconomics II
Identities:
V [p, e(p, U )] ≡ U
xl [p, e(p, U )] ≡ hl (p, U ) ∀l
e[p, V (p, m)] ≡ m
hl [p, V (p, m)] ≡ xl (p, m) ∀l
Slutsky decomposition:
start from the identity
hl (p, U ) ≡ xl [p, e(p, U )]
if the price pi changes the effect is:
∂hl ∂xl ∂xl ∂e
=
+
∂pi ∂pi ∂m ∂pi
17
Microeconomics II
Notice that by Shephard’s lemma:
∂e
= hi(p, U ) = xi[p, e(p, U )]
∂pi
then
∂hl ∂xl ∂xl
=
+
xi .
∂pi ∂pi ∂m
or
∂xl ∂hl ∂xl
=
−
xi .
∂pi ∂pi ∂m
Own price effect gives Slutsky equation:
∂xl ∂hl ∂xl
=
−
xl .
∂pl ∂pl ∂m
18
Microeconomics II
19
Slutsky decomposition:
∂xl ∂hl ∂xl
=
−
xi .
∂pi ∂pi ∂m
Slutsky equation:
∂xl ∂hl ∂xl
=
−
xl .
∂pl ∂pl ∂m
This latter equation corresponds to the distinction
between substitution and income effect:
Microeconomics II
20
Substitution effect:
∂hl
∂pl
Income effect:
∂xl
xl
∂m
x1
6
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
HH
e
e
e
e HH
e
e HH
1
HH
e
e
HH e s
e
HH e y
e
e
e
HH
e
e H
H
eH
0
es
eHH s
e
2 e
e HH
e
HH
e
e
HH
e
e
e
HH
e
e
HH
e
e
HH
e
e
HH
e
e
HH
e
e
HH
e
e
x
x
x
-
x2
Microeconomics II
21
We know the sign of the substitution effect it is nonpositive.
The sign of the income effect depends on whether the
good is normal or inferior.
In the case that:
∂xl
>0
∂pl
we conclude that the good is Giffen.
This is not a realistic feature, inferior good with a
big income effect.