Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Chapter 5 Income and Substitution Effects Demand Functions • The optimal levels of x1,x2,…,xn can be expressed as functions of all prices and income • These can be expressed as n demand functions of the form: x1* = d1(p1,p2,…,pn,I) x2* = d2(p1,p2,…,pn,I) • • • xn* = dn(p1,p2,…,pn,I) Demand Functions • If there are only two goods (x and y), we can simplify the notation x* = x(px,py,I) y* = y(px,py,I) • Prices and income are exogenous – the individual has no control over these parameters Homogeneity • If all prices and income were doubled, the optimal quantities demanded will not change – the budget constraint is unchanged xi* = xi(p1,p2,…,pn,I) = xi(tp1,tp2,…,tpn,tI) • Individual demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in all prices and income Homogeneity • With a Cobb-Douglas utility function utility = U(x,y) = x0.3y0.7 the demand functions are 0 .3 I x* px 0 .7 I y* py • A doubling of both prices and income would leave x* and y* unaffected Homogeneity • With a CES utility function utility = U(x,y) = x0.5 + y0.5 the demand functions are 1 I x* 1 p x / py p x 1 I y* 1 py / p x py • A doubling of both prices and income would leave x* and y* unaffected Changes in Income • An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel fashion • Since px/py does not change, the MRS will stay constant as the worker moves to higher levels of satisfaction Income Consumption Curve 8 Effects of a Rise in Income • Engel curve - the relationship between the quantity demanded of a single good and income, holding prices constant. • Income-consumption curve shows how consumption of both goods changes when income changes, while prices are held constant. Engel Curves I ($) Engel Curve 92 “X is a normal good” 68 40 0 10 18 24 X (units) 10 Y Effect of a Budget Increase on an Individual’s Demand Curve L1 2.8 Budget Line, L Initial Values PX = price of X = $12 PY = price of Y = $35 I = Income = $419. Income goes up! Price of X PX X PY 12 26.7 I1 X E1 D1 0 26.7 X I , Budget Y= I PY 0 e1 Y1 = $419 0 E1* 26.7 X y L2 Y Effect of a Budget Increase on an Individual’s Demand Curve L1 4.8 2.8 Budget Line, L Initial Values PX = price of X = $12 PY = price of Y = $35 I = Income = $419. Income goes up! $628 Price of X PX X PY 12 I1 26.7 38.2 E1 I2 X E2 D2 D1 0 26.7 38.2 X I , Budget Y= I PY 0 e2 e1 Y2 = $628 Y1 = $419 0 E2* E1* 26.7 38.2 X L3 L2 Y Effect of a Budget Increase on an Individual’s Demand Curve L1 7.1 4.8 2.8 Budget Line, L PX X PY Initial Values PX = price of X = $12 PY = price of Y = $35 I = Income = $837. Price of X 0 12 e2 e1 I1 26.7 38.2 49.1 E1 E2 I3 X D3 D2 D1 0 26.7 38.2 49.1 E3* Y2 = $628 Y1 = $419 0 X Engel curve for X Y3 = $837 Income goes up again! I2 E3 I , Budget Y= I PY Income-consumption curve e3 E2* E1* 26.7 38.2 49.1 X Normal and Inferior Goods • A good xi for which xi/I 0 over some range of income is a normal good in that range • A good xi for which xi/I < 0 over some range of income is an inferior good in that range Increase in Income • If x decreases as income rises, x is an inferior good As income rises, the individual chooses to consume less x and Quantity of y more y C B U3 U2 A U1 Quantity of x Normal and Inferior Goods Example: Backward Bending ICC and Engel Curve – a good can be normal over some ranges and inferior over others 16 Price Consumption Curves Y (units) PY = $4 I = $40 10 Is the set of optimal baskets for every possible price of good x, holding all other prices and income constant. This is the individual’s demand curve for good x. Price Consumption Curve • • • PX = 1 PX = 2 PX = 4 0 XA=2 XB=10 XC=16 20 X (units) 17 Individual Demand Curve PX Individual Demand Curve For Commodity X PX = 4 • PX = 2 PX = 1 XA • XB • XC Quantity increasing X 18 The Individual Demand Curve Price-consumption curve Curve tracing the utilitymaximizing combinations of two goods as the price of one changes. ● Individual demand curve Curve relating the quantity of a good that a single consumer will buy to its price. ● The individual demand curve has two important properties: 1. The level of utility that can be attained changes as we move along the curve. 2. At every point on the demand curve, the consumer is maximizing utility by satisfying the condition that the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of X for Y equals the ratio of the prices of X and Y. Demand Curve for “X” Algebraically, we can solve for the individual’s demand using the following equations: 1. pxx + pyy = I 2. MUx/px = MUy/py – at a tangency. (If this never holds, a corner point may be substituted where x = 0 or y = 0) 20 Changes in a Good’s Price • A change in the price of a good alters the slope of the budget constraint –it also changes the MRS at the consumer’s utility-maximizing choices • When the price changes, two effects come into play –substitution effect –income effect Changes in a Good’s Price • Even if the individual remains on the same indifference curve, his optimal choice will change because the MRS must equal the new price ratio – the substitution effect • The individual’s “real” income has changed and he must move to a new indifference curve – the income effect Changes in a Good’s Price: Price of X falls Suppose the consumer is maximizing utility at point A. Quantity of y B A If the price of good x falls, the consumer will maximize utility at point B. U2 U1 Quantity of x Total increase in x Changes in a Good’s Price: Price of X falls Quantity of y To isolate the substitution effect, we hold “real” income constant but allow the relative price of good x to change The substitution effect is the movement from point A to point C A C U1 Substitution effect The individual substitutes x for y because it is now relatively cheaper Quantity of x Changes in a Good’s Price : Price of X falls The income effect occurs because “real” income changes when the price of good x changes Quantity of y B A The income effect is the movement from point C to point B C U2 U1 Income effect If x is a normal good, the individual will buy more because “real” income increased Quantity of x Total Effect or Price Effect(AB) = Substitution Effect (AC) + Income Effect (CB) Changes in a Good’s Price: Price of X rises Quantity of y An increase in the price of good x means that the budget constraint gets steeper C A The substitution effect is the movement from point A to point C B U1 U2 The income effect is the movement from point C to point B Quantity of x Substitution effect Income effect Total Effect: Price Effect (AB) = Substitution Effect (AC) + Income Effect (CB) Price Changes – Normal Goods • If a good is normal, substitution and income effects reinforce one another – when p : • substitution effect quantity demanded • income effect quantity demanded – when p : • substitution effect quantity demanded • income effect quantity demanded Price Changes – Inferior Goods • If a good is inferior, substitution and income effects move in opposite directions – when p : • substitution effect quantity demanded • income effect quantity demanded – when p : • substitution effect quantity demanded • income effect quantity demanded INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS: INFERIOR GOOD Consumer is initially at A on RS. With a ↓ P of food, the consumer moves to B. i) a substitution effect, F1E (associated with a move from A to D), ii) an income effect, EF2 (associated with a move from D to B). In this case, food is an inferior good because the income effect is negative. However, because the substitution effect exceeds the income effect, the decrease in the price of food leads to an increase in the quantity of food demanded. A Special Case: The Giffen Good ● Giffen good Good whose demand curve slopes upward because the (negative) income effect is larger than the substitution effect. UPWARD-SLOPING DEMAND CURVE: THE GIFFEN GOOD •Food: an inferior good • Income effect dominates over the substitution effect, • Consumer is initially at A • After the ↓P of food falls, moves to B and consumes less food. • The income effect F2F1 > the substitution effect EF2, • The ↓P of food leads to a lower quantity of food demanded. Giffen’s Paradox • If the income effect of a price change is strong enough, there could be a positive relationship between price and quantity demanded – an decrease in price leads to a increase in real income – since the good is inferior, a increase in income causes quantity demanded to fall The Individual’s Demand Curve • An individual’s demand for x depends on preferences, all prices, and income: x* = x(px,py,I) • It may be convenient to graph the individual’s demand for x assuming that income and the price of y i.e (py) are held constant The Individual’s Demand Curve Quantity of y As the price of x falls... px …quantity of x demanded rises. px’ px’’ px’’’ U1 U2 x1 I = px’ + py x2 x3 I = px’’ + py U3 Quantity of x I = px’’’ + py x x’ x’’ x’’’ Quantity of x Shifts in the Demand Curve • Three factors are held constant when a demand curve is derived –income –prices of other goods (py) –the individual’s preferences • If any of these factors change, the demand curve will shift to a new position Shifts in the Demand Curve • A movement along a given demand curve is caused by a change in the price of the good –a change in quantity demanded • A shift in the demand curve is caused by changes in income, prices of other goods, or preferences –a change in demand Compensated Demand Curve • The demand curves shown thus far have all been uncompensated, or Marshallian, demand curves. • Consumer utility is allowed to vary with the price of the good. • Alternatively, a compensated, or Hicksian, demand curve shows how quantity demanded changes when price increases, holding utility constant. Compensated Demand Curves • The actual level of utility varies along the demand curve • As the price of x falls, the individual moves to higher indifference curves –it is assumed that nominal income is held constant as the demand curve is derived –this means that “real” income rises as the price of x falls Compensated Demand Curves • An alternative approach holds real income (or utility) constant while examining reactions to changes in px –the effects of the price change are “compensated” so as to force the individual to remain on the same indifference curve –reactions to price changes include only substitution effects Compensated Demand Curves • A compensated (Hicksian) demand curve shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity purchased assuming that other prices and utility are held constant • The compensated demand curve is a twodimensional representation of the compensated demand function x* = xc(px,py,U) Compensated Demand Curves Holding utility constant, as price falls... Quantity of y px p ' slope x py …quantity demanded rises. slope px ' ' py px’ px’’ slope px ' ' ' py px’’’ Xc U2 x’ x’’ x’’’ Quantity of x x’ x’’ x’’’ Quantity of x Compensated & Uncompensated Demand px At px’’, the curves intersect because the individual’s income is just sufficient to attain utility level U2 px’’ x xc x’’ Quantity of x Compensated & Uncompensated Demand px At prices above px’, income compensation is positive because the individual needs more income to remain on U2 px’ px’’ x xc x’ x* Quantity of x Compensated & Uncompensated Demand px At prices below px’”, income compensation is negative to prevent an increase in utility from a lower price px’’ px’’’ X xc x*** x’’’ Quantity of x Compensated & Uncompensated Demand • For a normal good, the compensated demand curve is less responsive to price changes than is the uncompensated demand curve –the uncompensated demand curve reflects both income and substitution effects –the compensated demand curve reflects only substitution effects Compensated Demand Functions • Suppose that utility is given by utility = U(x,y) = x0.5y0.5 • The Marshallian demand functions are x = I/2px y = I/2py • The indirect utility function is utility V ( I, px , py ) I 2 px0.5 py0.5 Compensated Demand Functions • To obtain the compensated demand functions, we can solve the indirect utility function for I and then substitute into the Marshallian demand functions x 0 .5 y 0 .5 x Vp p 0 .5 x 0 .5 y Vp y p Compensated Demand Functions x 0 .5 y 0 .5 x Vp p 0 .5 x 0 .5 y Vp y p • Demand now depends on utility (V) rather than income • Increases in px reduce the amount of x demanded –only a substitution effect The Response to a Change in Price • We will use an indirect approach using the expenditure function minimum expenditure = E(px,py,U) • Then, by definition xc (px,py,U) = x [px,py,E(px,py,U)] The Response to a Change in Price xc (px,py,U) = x[px,py,E(px,py,U)] • We can differentiate the compensated demand function and get x c x x E px px E px x x c x E px px E px The Response to a Change in Price x x c x E px px E px • The first term is the slope of the compensated demand curve – the mathematical representation of the substitution effect The Response to a Change in Price x x x E px px E px c • The second term measures the way in which changes in px affect the demand for x through changes in purchasing power – the mathematical representation of the income effect The Slutsky Equation • The substitution effect can be written as x c x substitution effect px px U constant • The income effect can be written as x E x E income effect E px I px The Slutsky Equation • The utility-maximization hypothesis shows that the substitution and income effects arising from a price change can be represented by x substitution effect income effect px x x px px U constant x x I The Slutsky Equation x x px px U constant x x I • The first term is the substitution effect – always negative x x px px U constant x x I • The second term is the income effect – if x is a normal good, income effect is negative – if x is an inferior good, income effect is positive Marshallian Demand Elasticities • Most of the commonly used demand elasticities are derived from the Marshallian demand function x(px,py,I) • Price elasticity of demand (ex,px) ex ,px x / x x px px / px px x Marshallian Demand Elasticities • Income elasticity of demand (ex,I) e x ,I x / x x I I / I I x • Cross-price elasticity of demand (ex,py) e x ,py x / x x py py / py py x Price Elasticity of Demand • The own price elasticity of demand is always negative – the only exception is Giffen’s paradox • The size of the elasticity is important – if ex,px < -1, demand is elastic – if ex,px > -1, demand is inelastic – if ex,px = -1, demand is unit elastic Price Elasticity and Total Spending • Total spending on x is equal to total spending =pxx • Using elasticity, we can determine how total spending changes when the price of x changes ( p x x ) x px x x [ex ,px 1] px px Price Elasticity and Total Spending ( p x x ) x px x x[ex,px 1] px px • If ex,px > -1, demand is inelastic – price and total spending move in the same direction • If ex,px < -1, demand is elastic – price and total spending move in opposite directions Compensated Price Elasticities • It is also useful to define elasticities based on the compensated demand function Compensated Price Elasticities • If the compensated demand function is xc = xc(px,py,U) we can calculate – compensated own price elasticity of demand (exc,px) – compensated cross-price elasticity of demand (exc,py) Compensated Price Elasticities • The compensated own price elasticity of demand (exc,px) is exc,px x c / x c x c px c px / px px x • The compensated cross-price elasticity of demand (exc,py) is x / x x py c py / py py x c e c x ,py c c Price Elasticities • The Slutsky equation shows that the compensated and uncompensated price elasticities will be similar if –the share of income devoted to x is small –the income elasticity of x is small Relationship among demand elasticities • 1) Homogeneity • 2) Engel aggregation • 3) Cournot aggregation Homogeneity • Demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in all prices and income • Any proportional change in all prices and income will leave the quantity of x demanded unchanged Engel Aggregation • Engel’s law suggests that the income elasticity of demand for food items is less than one – this implies that the income elasticity of demand for all nonfood items must be greater than one. Income elasticity of demand for various goods Automobiles 2.98 Books 1.44 Restaurant Meals 1.40 Tobacco 0.64 Public Transportation −0.36 Cournot Aggregation • The size of the cross-price effect of a change in px on the quantity of y consumed is restricted because of the budget constraint. • Differentiate the budget constraint with respect to Px. Consumer Surplus • Suppose we want to examine the change in an individual’s welfare when price changes Consumer Welfare • If the price rises, the individual would have to increase expenditure to remain at the initial level of utility expenditure at px0 = E0 = E(px0,py,U0) expenditure at px1 = E1 = E(px1,py,U0) • In order to compensate for the price rise, this person would require a compensating variation (CV) of CV = E(px1,py,U0) - E(px0,py,U0) Consumer Welfare Quantity of y Suppose the consumer is maximizing utility at point A. If the price of good x rises, the consumer will maximize utility at point B. The consumer’s utility falls from U2 to U1 A B U2 U1 Quantity of x Consumer Welfare Quantity of y The consumer could be compensated so that he can afford to remain on U2 CV is the amount that the individual would need to be compensated CV C A B U2 U1 Quantity of x Consumer Welfare • The derivative of the expenditure function with respect to px is the compensated demand function c x ( p x , p y ,U ) E( p x , p y ,U ) p x • The amount of CV required can be found by integrating across a sequence of small increments to price from one price to another. Consumer Welfare px When the price rises from px0 to px1, the consumer suffers a loss in welfare welfare loss px1 p1x p1x p x0 p x0 CV dE x c ( px , py ,U 0 )dpx px0 xc(px…U0) x1 x0 Quantity of x Consumer Welfare • A price change generally involves both income and substitution effects –should we use the compensated demand curve for the original target utility (U0) or the new level of utility after the price change (U1)? The Consumer Surplus Concept • The area below the compensated demand curve and above the market price is called consumer surplus –the extra benefit the person receives by being able to make market transactions at the prevailing market price Consumer Welfare px px1 Is the consumer’s loss in welfare best described by area px1BApx0 [using xc(...,U1)] or by area px1CDpx0 [using xc(...,U0)]? C B A px0 Is U1 or U0 the appropriate utility target? D xc(...,U1) xc(...,U0) x1 x0 Quantity of x Consumer Welfare px px1 We can use the Marshallian demand curve as a compromise The area px1CApx0 falls between the sizes of the welfare losses defined by xc(...,U1) and xc(...,U0) C B A px0 D x(px,…) xc(...,U1) xc(...,U0) x1 x0 Quantity of x Consumer Surplus • We will define consumer surplus as the area below the Marshallian demand curve and above price – shows what an individual would pay for the right to make voluntary transactions at this price – changes in consumer surplus measure the welfare effects of price changes Welfare Loss from a Price Increase • Suppose that the compensated demand function for x is given by x c ( px , py ,V ) Vpy0.5 px0.5 • The welfare cost of a price increase from px = $1 to px = $4 is given by 4 CV Vp p 0 .5 y 1 0 .5 x 2Vp p 0 .5 y p 4 0 .5 x x p 1 X Welfare Loss from a Price Increase • If we assume that V = 2 and py = 4, CV = 222(4)0.5 – 222(1)0.5 = 8 • If we assume that the utility level (V) falls to 1 after the price increase (and used this level to calculate welfare loss), CV = 122(4)0.5 – 122(1)0.5 = 4 Welfare Loss from a Price Increase • Suppose that we use the Marshallian demand function instead x ( px , py , I ) 0.5 Ipx-1 • The welfare loss from a price increase from px = $1 to px = $4 is given by 4 Loss 0.5 Ip dpx 0.5 I ln px -1 x 1 px 4 p x 1 Welfare Loss from a Price Increase • If income (I) is equal to 8, Loss = 4 ln(4) - 4 ln(1) = 4 ln(4) = 4(1.39) = 5.55 – this computed loss from the Marshallian demand function is a compromise between the two amounts computed using the compensated demand functions Revealed Preference Hypothesis • The theory of revealed preference was proposed by Paul Samuelson in the year 1938. • Assumptions: – 1) Rationality – 2) Consistency – 3) Transitivity – 4) Revealed Preference axiom Revealed Preference Axiom • Consider two bundles of goods: A and B • If the individual can afford to purchase either bundle but chooses A, we say that A had been revealed preferred to B • Under any other price-income arrangement, B can never be revealed preferred to A Revealed Preference Hypothesis: Derivation of Demand Curve • Initially consumer at B with budget line RS. • A ↓ PF shifts budget line from RS to RT. • The new market basket chosen must lie on line segment BT' of budget line R′T' (which intersects RS to the right of B), and the quantity of food consumed must be greater than at B. Revealed Preference Theory • Preferences predict consumer’s purchasing behavior • Purchasing behavior infer consumer’s preferences Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference • If commodity bundle 0 is revealed preferred to bundle 1, and if bundle 1 is revealed preferred to bundle 2, and if bundle 2 is revealed preferred to bundle 3,…, and if bundle K-1 is revealed preferred to bundle K, then bundle K cannot be revealed preferred to bundle 0