Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Sovereign Wealth Fund Strategies following the financial and the oil crisis Roberto Pasca di Magliano* Daniele Terriaca^ Nabylah abo Dehaman° JEL code: G230 Abstract Sovereign Wealth Funds (SWF) are acting as agencies supporting mergers and acquisition operations (M&A) in the international capital market with particular interest to Western companies that are “hungry” for new capital. Indirectly they also act as investment actors in fields like renewable and development projects. On the international capital market more than 70 Sovereign Funds are acting, having a financial power estimated at 7 trillion dollars. Relevant financial power if compared with the hedge funds that count for 1,9 trillion dollars (in decline), the pension funds for 18 trillion, the private equity funds and the merchant banking for 21 trillion1. Unlike major investment companies, the capital of SWFs is owned and controlled by governmental agencies. They act in investment’s market as private groups/actors even if their resources are publicly owned. Sovereign Funds multiplied themselves in recent years by receiving increasing financial resources from rich emerging countries aimed at gaining higher yields than from the conservative investments on State bonds. There are funds of very high dimensions and with widespread holdings: The Government Pension Fund of Norway and the Abu Dhabi Investment Authority are the largest respectively with activities/assets under management of 838 and 773 billion dollars. In 2007, a Chinese fund was established and has since reached 575 billion dollars. One year later, in 2008, the Russian Federation also created two sovereign funds that amount to 170 billion dollars. Global investments are significantly influenced by Sovereign Funds: it is estimated that for each additional unit of the allocated fund, foreign direct investments (FDI) increase by 12%. Other than stabilization, savings and pension, macroeconomic stabilization, SWFs started by investing in low-risk assets (such as bonds), then gradually diversified into equities before focusing on alternative asset classes (real estate, hedge funds, private equity, or infrastructure) and more recently moving towards sustainable and renewable allocation. These new strategies following the oil crisis are seeming to influence positively their investment allocation policy towards responsible and development projects. Some SWFs are pursuing responsible and development goals by allocating resources in long-term socio-economic projects with a strategic importance for the local economy or even for strategic foreign countries. This is the case of the Norwegian fund, the UAE (Mubadala), the Iran National Development Fund, the New Zeland, Australian and Singapore funds that manage a part of the national wealth and seeks to encourage responsible investment in the absence of a developed local financial market. Increasing interest for financial allocation in development project is increasing in other SWFs, both at national and international level. ------------------The paper’s aim is to investigate the increasing influence of the SWFs policy in international investment, with particular concern to questions as follows: 1. Impact of the financial crisis on international markets; 2. Evaluation of variables influencing the creation of a SWF, by an econometric estimation model based on sensible data sets; 3. Strategies motivation following the post oil crisis and governance impact; 4. New allocation strategies: responsible and development projects. 1 Deutche Bank *professor Growth Economics, Sapienza University of Rome ^Phd in Cooperation and Development, Sapienza University of Rome °Phd student in Cooperation and Development, Sapienza University of Rome 1 1. Impact of the financial crisis on international markets Since 2008 the advanced world experienced two interrelated crises: i. a banking crisis, stemming from losses in capital market securities (including US subprime mortgages and other structured products), as well as home-grown, boom-bust problems in the property markets of some countries; ii. a sovereign debt crisis exacerbated by recession, transfers to help banks, and in some cases very poor fiscal management. Due to this global financial crisis, the sovereign debt has become a problem for a broad range of countries – from European high-income countries to the emerging and poorest states on earth – even after they had obtained debt relief through existing multilateral initiatives. Some advanced industrialized countries (among them also France and Germany) that are still considered to be in reasonable fiscal-financial condition are so not in absolute terms, but only when compared to the truly difficult conditions experienced by the their less “virtuous” peers. Nevertheless, in France, the banking system was recently downgraded and Germany (as well as other smaller European economy such as the Netherlands), with its current public fiscal position, would not have been able to join the Euro back in 1999. The dramatic truth is that almost all the countries of the Eurozone do not comply with the requirements laid down by the Maastricht Treaty: a debt ratio ceiling of 60% and an annual deficit of 3% both over Gdp figure. 2 Table 1 – Gross National Debt in % to Gdp in the EU Member Source: Eurostat, 2015 3 Five major issues have been identified as the root of this profound fiscal problem: i. As already mentioned, it derives from the banking crisis. The change from the bailouts system to the bail in ad well other budgetary rescue measures directed at propping up the financial system have had direct financial costs that overheated the financial system triggering the sovereign debt crisis. A clear example of this vicious process is the role played by the cost of bank bailouts in starting the Irish sovereign debt crisis. ii. The second one is an inheritance of the worldwide recession that started in 2008 and lasted in most of the advanced industrial countries until 2011. The recession weakened many government revenue sources and boosted certain public expenditure categories (like unemployment benefits) for the usual cyclical or automatic fiscal stabilizer reasons. iii. The third is an in an increase in the structural primary (non-interest) deficit. The long leg of the recession combined with the ending of assets bubbles (mainly the real estate one) and the decrease/normalization of revenues and profits is expected to produce a lasting reduction in the buoyancy of government revenues with respect to GDP. iv. The fourth is the increasing dependence of sovereign debts on the international financial markets. v. The last one is the lack of needed reforms affecting States’ credibility. All these four conditions are worsening the public financial structure globally and not only in the Euro Area where the media and academia focus on most of their attention. Unless the advanced countries, or at least the “best of the bunch” (the US, the UK, France, Japan and even Germany) are able to properly address the above mentioned root-causes to cope with the fiscal crisis, the sovereign debt will continue to be an emergency for AAA-rated countries as well in a few years from now. Up to now the fiscal debt crisis seemed to be managed as a ‘pass the baby’ game of excessive sectorial debt or leverage: i. Excessively indebted households passed part of their debt back to their creditors – the banks. ii. Banks, excessively leveraged and at risk of default, passed part of their debt to the sovereign debt. iii. Finally, the now overly-indebted sovereign States are passing the debt back to the households, through higher taxes, lower public spending, the risk of default or the threat of monetization and inflation. In most of the industrialized countries, this attitude leads to a spectacular deterioration in the fiscal positions, even more so when set against the remarkable fiscal restraint demonstrated by most emerging markets over the same period. Table 2 - Fiscal deficit as % of Gdp in selected Advanced Countries source: IMF, 2015 4 As seen above in the graph most of the developed countries are in deficit and the United States had a fiscal deficit of more than 11 percent of its Gdp during 2015. One reason for this huge deficit is the global financial crisis that started in the US back in 2008. Other developed countries are also in deficit except for South Korea who has experienced both deficit and surplus during the period 20082015. The emerging countries are better off not only with regards to deficit but also in terms of the overall public debt according to IMF forecasts. Table 3 - Fiscal Deficit as % of Gdp in the BRICS Countries source: IMF, 2015 In terms of fiscal deficit, the developing countries are experiencing a trend similar to that of the developed countries however most of the developing countries have taken measures to reduce their fiscal deficit. As shown in the figure above, the fiscal deficit of India in 2008 was around 10 percent of total Gdp, and it has gone down to less than 7 percent in 2015. The Russian Federation alone was enjoying surplus except for the year 2009 but in 2016 official forecasts will set the deficit to 12 per cent. There is no unique view regarding the role played by fiscal deficit in an economy. On the one hand, the Keynesian view sustains that large fiscal expenditure by the government through deficit financing will improve the economic condition of any country (Lee 2012). On the other hand, the Ricardian approach argues that it doesn’t make a difference as consumers cut expenditure in anticipation of higher tax, which the government will impose on the consumers to pay the borrowings. Similarly the neo-classical economist argues that the increase in the government expenditure negatively affect the saving and hence affects growth (Nickel & Vansteenkiste 2008). Increasing fiscal deficit is one of the major problems faced by growing economies. As already discussed in the previous section, there is no unique view on whether the deficit run by the government is good for the country or not. In the case of developing countries, a study by Terrones & Catão (2005) shows the relationship between fiscal deficit and inflation in developing countries and there has not been any significant relation in advanced countries. 1.1. Reasons for fiscal deficit ad its impact The main motivations for increasing fiscal deficit are either a decrease in revenue collection or an increase in government expenditure. The major expenditure of both the developing and developed countries is shown below with some elements of comparative analysis. 5 Health: The global share of the developing countries (BRICS) in the total health expenditure is increasing. Since 1995 the total share in global health expenditure of these countries increased from 4 % to 12% of their total expenditures. Among the developing nations, Brazil is the leading country in health expenditure, currently 9.31 % of its GDP, whereas the total health expenditure by India is 4 % of its GDP. In the case of developed countries, the global share in healthcare expenditure by developed countries (OECD) is still higher than that of the BRICS countries. However, the ratio of the health expenditure measured by OECD/BRICS fell from 22 times in 1995 to 7 times in 2012. This shows that the health expenditure by the developed countries is declining whereas the expenditure by the developing countries is increasing. Defense: Defense is one of the leading sectors in terms of government spending. According to Frost & Sullivan, the total defense expenditures of BRICS countries was 21.4 percent of the global defense expenditure in 2014 as compared to 13 percent in 2008. Among the developed countries, the US has the highest defense expenditure, which comprises of 34 percent of the global defense expenditure in 2014, which equals 3.5 percent of the US Gross Domestic Product (GDP). However, the defense expenditure of the US has been declining over the time period as a percent of GDP. Subsidies: Subsidies are the benefits provided by the government to individuals or groups of individual in the form of cash or through tax reduction. Subsidies are usually given either to promote a certain industry or to protect the welfare of the people in the industry. With an increase in the provision of subsidies the expenditure of the government increase which is one of the contributor to the deficit in the budget. Subsidies in developed countries such as the US and the UK have declined over the period and have remained the same for some, like South Korea. In case of the BRICS countries there is a mix trend. Countries like India and Brazil have reduced subsidies as a percent of the GDP, while in Russia and China it has increased. China is expected to increase subsidies in various sectors to boost the economy after the recent slowdown of its economy. There has not been any conclusion about whether the fiscal deficit is good or bad for any economy; some economists argued that it is essential for the economic growth of a country because only domestic savings is not enough for investment. And others argue that a huge deficit may lead to an increase in the tax rate and decrease in savings. However it can be concluded that some amount of fiscal deficit is good for economic growth as long as the borrowed money is used for productive purposes and the rate of return from that investment is higher than the interest rate paid. The different number of ways to deal with the national debt crisis are suggested by looking at the simple mathematic of the fiscal adjustment dynamics. A country’s public debt will grow continually higher as a percentage of Gdp (i.e. will be unsustainable) whenever the primary budget surplus as a share of Gdp does not offset the burden of debt service as the economy grows. In formal writing: where: “d” is public debt (D) as a share of Gdp; “pb” is the primary budget balance as a share of Gdp (i.e. it excludes debt service); “i” is the effective interest rate on the public debt; “g” is the rate of nominal economic growth and “t” refers to time. This to say that the reduction of the public dept depends on the capacity both to experience a Gdp rate exceeding the dept-service rate and generating a positive primary balance. 6 It is clear from the above equation that there are a set of options available to manage the debt crisis by tuning the preferred variable: Draconian fiscal policy (at the end of the day, they are still the cradle of the Western culture): increase in taxes and reduction of public spending to bring the budget balance to the point where it offsets the debt-service burden, after allowing for the growth of the economy. Inflation (unexpected and hateful surprise): the “g” of the equation is the nominal growth of Gdp (i.e. the sum of real growth and inflation). Here is the trick then inflation essentially reduces the real burden of the debt. Growth: increase the real growth of the Gdp via structural reforms for a sustainable economy in the long run (recent Italian experience). Restructuring the level of outstanding debt: the effective interest rate can be reduced by renegotiating the terms and conditions of the outstanding debt with the holders or alternatively a haircut to the outstanding stock of debt can be performed so to reduce the debt service burden. Bail-out: payments to banks in difficulties that can be interpreted either as a current transfer payment from abroad or a capital transfer from abroad as an equivalent public dept must be emitted. Bail-outs occur when outside investors, such as a government, rescue a borrower by injecting money to help make debt payments. This help save the companies from bankruptcy, with taxpayers assuming the risks associated with their inability to repay the loans. Bail-outs are designed to keep creditors happy and interest rates low. Bail-outs of failing banks in Greece, Portugal and Iceland were primarily financed by taxpayers. Bail-in: payments to banks in difficulties from outside investors who rescue a borrower by injecting money to help service a debt. It imply a devaluation of shares and bonds to cope for bank’s losses and insure fresh capital to the recovery bank. Bail-in occurs when the borrower's creditors are forced to bear some of the burden by having a portion of their debt written off. This approach eliminates some of the risk for taxpayers by forcing other creditors to share in the pain and suffering. Bail-ins are ideal in situations where bail-outs are politically difficult or impossible, and creditors aren't keen on the idea of a liquidation event. Bail-in is ruled by the 2015 UE Directive BRRD (Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive) to manage the sovereign bank’s crisis in Europe as taxpayers cannot be called to pay for banks bankrupt (bail-out). For example, in June 2013 bondholders in Cyprus banks and depositors with more than 100,000 euros in their accounts were forced to write-off a portion of their holdings. Transformation of short term depth in long term ones through a mix of loans and guarantee from other authorities (i.e. ECB or ESFS in the EU). Unfortunately whereas the available “paths to debt sustainability” are mathematically determinate and easy to be find, their implementation is politically driven and managed. Therefore, in the real world, the decision on which is the best path will be the outcome of a mediation between different interests. It is interesting to try to give an overview on which are the pre-conditions or determinants that will make choose each of the above mention options. Let’s start with inflation. As EU monetary policy is in the hands of the European Central Bank (ECB), the possibility of initiating an inflationary policy is not an option for the Euro area. Were the ECB to carry out quantitative easing to the point where EU-wide inflation accelerated, this would benefit all European debt-service burdens; but it is not an immediate option for the crisis countries within Europe now. Generally speaking, inflation is a more realistic option where the Central Bank is a weak and not independent authority. Moreover the inflation has to be unexpected in order to have impact on the debt burden and it will have a negative effect on the future credibility (ie level of the interest rate and capability of placing the new debt issues abroad) towards financial markets. 7 The growth rate of real Gdp is not, unfortunately, a policy instrument. With respect to structural reform, the largest preferences go to: i. policies to improve the functioning of labour markets, and the requirement that labour mobility play a key competitiveness adjustment role; ii. the reform of pension systems, to ensure they are fully funded, which is essential to reduce the fiscal burden on future generations; iii. addressing the structure of competition and the consistency of regulations and governance for improving efficiency. However, structural reform is likely to be a process the success of which will be measured in decades. The market tolerance for sovereign debt is unlikely to be improved by promises, also because the past behavior suggests that psychologically and politically higher growth also raises the pressures for increased public spending; iv. liberalization and privatization of public services in order to improve efficiency and increase the competition; v. more in general reforms are well addressed whether they are designed to improve institution’s credibility (i.e. Government and Parliament rules, efficiency and rapidity of justice, etc.) For the near term, therefore, the market is focused on budget consolidation: the plausibility of its success, on the one hand, and the temptation to default on the other. The projection of the IMF suggest that all advanced countries can restore its fiscal sustainability through a long-term fiscal tightening worth less than 14% of Gdp annually, in the worst case for the most fiscally unbalanced country. The EU Commission are proposing that member States not respecting the Maastrict rules (dept stock < 60% Gdp and annual deficit < 3% Gdp) should have to reduce their own dept at the annual rate of 5% for the exceeding part. Table 4 - Advanced economies, Fiscal Tightening (% of Gdp) needed between 2010-2020 to achieve 60% of Gdp public debt ratio by 2030 This evidence suggests that there is a political inability in identifying a national social choice mechanisms to come up with a fiscal burden sharing scheme that is both fair and efficient. The common political practice shows that (in some country more than in others) assigning blame and trying to shift the burden of the fiscal correction (tax increases and public spending cuts) to 8 other groups or individuals takes precedence over searching for timely, fair and efficient retrenchment measures. The result is that fiscal adjustment is delayed and postponed, making the eventual burden even greater. The lack of less polarized policy, strong institutions and effective leadership will avoid the budget consolidation but also the following economic growth effect as indicated by general economic theory. Expectation on the credibility of government action is a key element of the so called non-Keynesian fiscal effects: for example, a significant and sustained reduction of government expenditures may lead consumers to assume that this will create room in the medium term for a permanent tax reduction. In that case, an expected increase in permanent income may lead to a rise in private consumption, also generating a better environment for private investment. Moreover, Blanchard (1990) and Sutherland (1997) demonstrate that a fiscal consolidation that credibly attempts to reduce public sector spending may produce an induced positive wealth effect, leading to an increase in private consumption also through the reduction of the risk premium associated with government debt issuance, which reduces real interest rates and allows the crowding-in of private investment. And finally, from an historic point of view (Giudice, 2007) around half of the fiscal consolidations in the EU in the last 30 years have been followed by higher growth. 1.2. Default consequences and risk of contagion Default is not an unrealistic option during national debt crisis (Reinahart and Rogoff 2009): it has been common phenomena in many part of the world such as Central and East European Nations and the CIS after the fall of the Berlin wall in 1989. When there is a default (a single business as a nation) there is a redistribution of wealth between creditors and debtors. The first ones are mainly banks and private savers, debtors are the States and ultimately taxpayers, public employees and retired people. The beneficiaries of a sovereign default are future tax payers and future beneficiaries of public spending, who would, in the absence of default, bear the burden of servicing the public debt. But there are some side effects that can offset the immediate benefit: The main sanction against defaulting sovereign is temporary exclusion from capital markets. This means that the more a country will need additional funds in the near future the less probable is it will force a default. More important when the State itself defaults on its obligations, the rule of law inevitably is harmed. Social capital and trust are destroyed. This is why sovereign defaults tend to occur only in countries that have either been shocked by extraordinary events, often beyond their control, or that are have little social capital, weak and corrupt political institutions and ineffective political leadership. The recent default of Argentina is a good example: besides the economic crisis, characterized by an increasing inflation, the social costs of the default have been enormous. The recovery figure of today is deceptive: economic growth is driven by the price of commodities (agricultural and natural resources) that are determined by international demand (from China and India) and not by high productivity and competiveness of the Argentinean economy and business sectors. The probability of default for a sovereign bond can be calculated from yield spreads and a fixed rate of recovery assumption, according the following formula: Where the market-implied probability of default (PD) for a sovereign bond can be calculated from the yield on the bond (i), the yield on a risk-free benchmark bond (i*) (here the German 10-year Bund) and a fixed recovery rate assumption (RR). 9 The calculation of the default/restructuring probability is tricky exercises due to multiple issues: recovery rates cannot be measured in the same way as for a corporate bond because they depend on the ability to tax citizens and service the loans and there is a high political/social cost related to default that makes actual sovereign defaults much fewer than market-driven default probability calculations would indicate. There are two situations that make sovereign-debt default/restructuring more likely: 1. A relatively small primary deficit indicates the government has already taken significant steps to eliminate most or all of the primary deficit – it is living within its means – and going any further is likely to produce unpopular economic hardship. 2. The larger the initial dept share, a. the more likely that the debt service burden in perpetuity will be too high; this is a permanent burden on taxpayers, and when a significant amount of debt is held by foreigners, this represents a real transfer abroad (and a widening gap between GDP and GNP); b. the lower the chances of the government getting a bailout from other countries, c. the lower the possibility for the government to return to the capital markets for funding (when support packages are in place), since the markets may refuse to roll over and fund new debt; d. the lower the amount of sovereign debt held by domestic banks, since the losses on such debt could add to banking-sector problems. The risk of contagion is well represented by the following picture, dated 2014, that is very powerful in visualizing the possible spreading effect of the debt crisis. 10 Figure 1 - Where is the sovereign debt? In the absence of mitigating policies, a sovereign default or disorderly bank failures could threaten Europe’s financial sector and cause liquidity shock with potentially negative global contagion. Recent empirical studies (Arghyrou and Kontonikas, 2010; Norbert Metiu, 2011) have highlighted how the countries of the Euro Area have been vulnerable to the cross-border contagion of sovereign debt crisis, being the main exporters of sovereign risk were Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and Spain. The contagion could spread through the following channels: i. Financial contagion: direct exposure to sovereigns and banks at risk of default. According to BIS data, banks are constantly reducing their cross border exposure to sovereign debt. This contagion would hurt the banking system of solid country (Germany and France) because they hold a large share of the debt at risk as well as the financial system and the overall economy of the smaller counties that have tight economic relationship with the country at risk. An example of this last situation is that if Greek banks lost access to funding that might encourage them to shrink their balance sheets in those countries (Bulgaria and Romania) where they own a large segment of banking sector, putting downward pressure on growth there rather than home. ii. Fiscal contagion: maybe investors will search for other countries with a fiscal stress similar to the one of Greece, Portugal, Spain and Ireland in other region. An obvious target for deep investigation would be new EU countries coming from the former Warsaw pact (Hungary already had its debt crisis in 2009). But such a contagion might reach also Japan the highest indebtedness country in the world and USA, both countries were recently downgraded by rating agencies. 11 iii. Real contagion: the debt crisis of the Euro Area may negatively affect the neighborhood noUE countries that might be deprived of a export-led growth in UE. There is a general consensus both at EU and IMF level (Euro Area Policies: 2011, IMF Staff Report; The EMU sovereign-debt crisis: Fundamentals, expectations and contagion, (Economic papers n.463, European Commission, 2011, Arghyroua and Kontonikas 2011) in looking at the evolution of the bond pricing mechanism: in the pre-crisis period the bond risk was priced according to the ‘convergence trade’ hypothesis (all Euro countries took advantage of the German low risk profile) in the post-crisis period markets have been pricing both the international risk factor and individual macro-fundamentals on a country-by-country basis. These consideration suggest that to find a solution to the sovereign debt crisis, the focus should be on strong program implementation, with sufficient proceeds from privatization, adequate financing from other official sources on terms supporting debt sustainability, and private sector based solutions to banking problems on a per county base. Moreover there is the need for governments to maintain, or regain, the confidence of markets that they are fully committed to a permanent improvement in macro-fundamentals. Such a result can only be achieved through clear evidence of its determined implementation of the necessary reforms, even in the face of significant short-term welfare losses, otherwise it is very likely that markets will continue to doubt the sustainability of these countries’ long-term participation in the Euro Area, and the risk that these expectations will become self-fulfilling will remain. At the European Union level, the crisis has highlighted the necessity of quickly scale up the capacity of fiscal supervision and policy co-ordination and flexibility of the European institutions in order to prevent future debt crises and to prevent its escalation in the affected country and its contagion to other countries, in particular emerging and developing ones. 12 2. SWF in the World Capital Market The extreme volatility of the financial markets due to the expansive monetary policies pursued by the major world’s central banks give the SWFs greater opportunities in moving capitals towards most profitable investments. Their role in the international financial market is increasing, particularly regarding both merger and acquisitions (M&A) and foreign direct investments (Fdi). The rapid growth of the emerging economies and of the oil producer countries give up to an extraordinary accumulation of financial resources that would need to be managed in most profitable way. SWFs became the better instrument to manage the excess capital in searching investment opportunities in the global market. While in the last century capital accumulation characterize the Western industrialized countries, the emerging phenomena shifts the location and the ownership but not the allocation that are still preferring the more secure and stable advanced markets. The expression Sovereign Wealth Fund was declined first by Rozanov in 2005 even if the creation of the first fund, Kuwait Investment Authority (KIA), dates in 1953 with the aim of finding alternative use to the estreme domestic liquidity as well to accumulate saving for future generation by diverfying the economy. The International Working Group of Sovereign Wealth Funds (Iwg) has given a more precise definition: “investment State vehicles using capital flows in excess to be managed sepparately by the central banks”. Large part of the SWFs have been created since the begining of the third Millennium due to the increasing surplus of the balance of payments (Ocampo e Griffith-Jones, 2010). Table 5 - Sovereign wealth funds by year of establishment (%) source: Preqin At the end of 2015 they were surveyed about 80 active funds worldwide, whose main ones are listed in the Annex 1, who manage equity of more than $ 7 billion. SWFs are then operating as private agencies in searching profitable allocation; not only as they are searching for diversification opportunities that could open new roots to the mono-sector economies (oil producers) or even to the poor technology producing systems. They are confronted with both opportunities and concerns that can be synthesize as follows: • The depth of the financial crisis and the increasing State debts emphasized the lack of fresh capitals in the advanced countries by inducing their companies to open the door to new actors. 13 • New actors (investors) are attracted by stable institutional and legal framework, efficient public administration, high technology industries, modern services, infrastructure, etc.. • Nevertheless, the State-owned structure of the SWFs do not always fit with the private nature of the market economy, i.e. SWF capital participation strategy could be influenced by political choice. • Moreover, great part of SWFs agencies are run by countries often ruled by undemocratic regimes. Thus, the OCDE countries are attempting to find a proper balance between the need for capitals and the risk of political influence or management control. In a context characterized by the deep structural financial instability, the SWF, as "silent" investors, are attracting the interest of private and public companies as well of policy makers, who are all seeking new sources of funding to compensate for the domestic lack of capital. Questions such as that of transparency, accountability and reciprocity emerge as the main issues for governance rules. Capital flows need balanced international regulations to promote investments and at the same time prevent from the risk of political pressure. 2.1.The macroeconomic power Despite repeated financial crises and recent tensions in European markets, the assets under management (AuM) of these instruments recorded a steady growth path since 2009, after suffering losses of an average of between 5 and 15% ( with upcoming tips to 30%) for those with a riskier portfolio (Jen, 2010), whose values have increased significantly between 2013 and 2014. XX The table shows also that the assets under management do not appear to be equally distributed. The first five sovereign wealth funds hold more than 50% of the total, with up to 76% even when you consider the top ten. Since the years 2000, due to the commodity boom and the rise of emerging market economies, SWFs have become increasingly relevant on the global economic and financial scenes as their assets under management have grown exponentially even in spite of the economic crisis and of the plunge of oil prices. These projections suggest that the trend is likely to persist in the coming years. With reference to the strategic objectives identified by Kunzel et all. (2011) and Chiarlone and Miceli (2013) 2, it is possible to identify eleven Savings funds (about 25% of the total of AuM) and, albeit with a lower abundance, are the Reserve investment funds that hold most of the wealth3. In addition, in a selected list of 20 funds classified as commodity (or that derive their financing from natural resources, oil and otherwise) the total assets reach of about 3.7 trillion dollars. Given this particular composition, it is evident that the evolution of AuM is strongly related to the evolution of oil prices. 2 Gli autori arrivano a delineare cinque categorie di riferimento: Saving funds (distribuire la ricchezza tra le generazioni diversificando i propri asset verso attività più remunerative), Stabilization funds (perseguono la finalità di isolare le economie domestiche dalle fluttuazioni cicliche del prezzo delle commmodities), Pension reserve funds (finalità pensionistiche), Reserve investment funds (utilizzano gli eccessi di liquidità per massimizzare i profitti) e Development funds (allocano le risorse in attività destinate allo sviluppo socio-economico nazionale). 3 Tali classificazioni non devono essere però utilizzata in modo particolarmente rigido, infatti molti Swf possono perseguire contemporaneamente più obiettivi oppure modificarli nel tempo a seconda delle esigenze nazionali. Secondo quanto evidenziato da Kimmitt (2008) sono solitamente i fondi commodity ad essere maggiormente caratterizzati da cambiamenti strategici nel tempo. 14 Table 6 – Top 20 Commodity SWFs n° Country Fund Billion $ Date of creation Source 1 Norway Government Pension Fund – Global 838 1990 Oil 2 UAE – Abu Dhabi Abu Dhabi Investment Authority 773 1976 Oil 3 Saudi Arabia SAMA Foreign Holdings 675.9 n/a Oil 4 Kuwait Kuwait Investment Authority 410 1953 Oil 5 Qatar Qatar Investment Authority 170 2005 Oil & Gas 6 Russia National Welfare Fund 88 2008 Oil 7 Russia Reserve Fund 86.4 2008 Oil 8 Algeria Revenue Regulation Fund 77.2 2000 Oil & Gas 9 UAE – Dubai Investment Corporation of Dubai 70 2006 Oil 10 Kazakhstan Kazakhstan National Fund 68.9 2000 Oil 11 Libya Libyan Investment Authority 66 2006 Oil 12 UAE – Abu Dhabi International Petroleum Investment Company 65.3 1984 Oil 13 Iran National Development Fund of Iran 58.6 2011 Oil & Gas 14 UAE – Abu Dhabi Mubadala Development Company 55.5 2002 Oil 15 US – Alaska Alaska Permanent Fund 49.5 1976 Oil 16 Brunei Brunei Investment Agency 40 1983 Oil 17 Azerbaijan State Oil Fund 34.1 1999 Oil 18 US – Texas Texas Permanent School Fund 30.3 1854 Oil & Other 19 Iraq Development Fund for Iraq $18 2003 Oil 20 US – New Mexico New Mexico State Investment Council 17.3 1958 Oil & Gas TOTAL 3.692 Oil & Gas The following table suggests that in the seven years that followed the financial and economic crisis of 2007-08, the assets under management of SWFs have more than doubled. The graph also reveals that while in 2008, SWFs funded through hydrocarbon-exports revenues managed more than two thirds of SWFs’ total assets under management (AuM), the non-commodity SWFs now account for a greater share of these assets, that is roughly 40% of the 7.0 trillion dollars in AuM. 15 Table 7 – SWFs asset under management ($bn) source: SWF Institute; The City UK estimates The forecast for the next two years indicate the maintenance of this expansion trend, while the only uncertainties could be linked to the future evolution of crude oil prices. If the sharp decline in crude oil , which began towards the end of 2014 , should also continue in the long -term holders of these countries funds they would be more oriented to use part of the AuM to compensate for the reduction of state revenues avoiding and, consequently , pressure on debt exposure. 2.2.Regulatory framework Just this AuM bias over the years has triggered a broad debate, academic and empirical, on the potential impacts of such investors and their portfolio management so as to stimulate a protectionist approach by the major vessels of the operations conducted by the SWF. According to Beck and Fidora (2008; 2009), most of these fears stem from the fact that the objectives could not be exclusively economic in nature, or simply maximizing the value of investments, but are directed to the possession of advanced technologies or supported by "political” reasons. These elements of concern are further amplified by the fact that, as previously indicated, the most SWFs are active within non-OECD countries, managed by non-democratic regimes and with a reduced institutional development. Referring to the first 10 countries of SWFs holders, in Table 8 related information was collected not only the amount of the AuM managed (over 85% of the total) but also to the so-called Rule of Law4 (proxy of the degree of institutional development), the ability of the State to ensure the efficiency of its regulatory framework (summarized by the Freedom from Corruption and Property Rights) 5. 4 Elaborate dall’Heritage Foundation e raccolte nel c.d. Index of Economic Freedom (2015). Secondo quanto indicato dal centro di ricerca, valori più alti sono associati allo sviluppo di un sistema democratico. 5 L’asse orizzontale e quello verticale rappresentano rispettivamente il Freedom from Corruption (FC) e il Property Rights (PR) mentre la dimensione della bolla e’ proporzionale all’ammontare degli Aum. 16 Table 8 - Swf and Rule of Law source: elaboration on SWF Institute data Just 3 countries that are located in the upper part of the dial (Norway, Singapore and Hong Kong), jointly presenting significant values for the indicators considered to demonstrate high efficiency of the State apparatus. The rest of the audience of the countries where the assets reaches a value close to $ 3 trillion, are characterized by a weak governance structure. In particular, in 3 cases (China, Russian Federation and Kazakhstan) there is a widespread state control of economic management. The assumptions that derive from this simple descriptive analysis might corroborate the thesis of the opacity behavior of such financial instruments although there are no confirmations regarding the danger of financial transactions they conduct on the markets. On the contrary, some empirical investigations (Chiarlone, 2010) come to demonstrate how the acquisitions made by these instruments could generate greater liquidity in financial markets and, given the nature of long-term investors, it would seem very low probability that they can achieve massive divestment transactions that may impact adversely on stock prices. Despite widespread concerns, studies (Bortolotti and Fotak, 2009; Balding, 2009) have shown that it is not yet revealed no evidence of any tampering on the strategies of the investee companies and investment decisions of the funds from the reference countries. In support of SWFs is possible to find some positive aspects related mainly to the greater liquidity they manage in supporting the growth of target enterprises, helping to lower the cost of risk capital and reducing financial market volatility in bad times (Lesmond, 2005). Furthermore, it could be argued that SWFs constitute an opportunity for States to regain some power and authority over financial markets. A power that financial globalization seemingly had taken away from theses sovereign actors in its ascent leaving them at the mercy of the risks and volatility that characterize financial markets. So SWFs represent in a way the return of the State and of politics within the financial world. The crisis has made this ever more evident and has prompted reactions on the part of States that have sought ways to reassert their sovereignty within the global 17 financial realm. SWFs, if well conceived and properly managed, have proven to be efficient instruments to preserve local economies from the vicissitudes of financial markets. More precisely, because of their sovereign character and because most of them originate from countries that still face important infrastructure gaps and glaring inequalities, it can reasonably expected them to be more than simple stabilizing or saving funds and to aspire to bring about not only protection but also positive change from a developmental standpoint. It has been argued, in effect, that SWFs have been and could be increasingly relevant in financing development as they dispose of significant resources and because their investment horizon tends to be much longer than that of other investment vehicles. Increasingly confronted with a lack of capital and funding, companies have for instance expressed a growing interest for SWFs’ investments as the latter presents multiple advantages as they are stable shareholders with a long-term investment horizon that can accompany the firms in their development and open up new commercial alleys for them. Therewith, many studies have demonstrated that most development projects require investments over the long term in order to induce positive outcomes and impact development in meaningful ways. Notwithstanding the suspicions with regards to the motives behind SWFs’ investment choices and the overall lack of transparency that characterize their governance – as most SWFs are owned by non-democratic States – there is a growing sense that these long-term investors could be key instrument in financing development both in their home country and abroad. While the objectives behind their set up are multifold, one of them is indeed developmental and some have even referred to them as Sovereign Development Funds. The need for a regulatory framework that meets the requirement of free capital movement and transparency of foreign investors pushed main players in the international financial system to look for a common proposal. The recent setting-up of the International Working Group on Swf, which brings together the representatives of the Sovereign Wealth Funds and of the main multilateral financial institutions (IMF, OECD, EU), is the concrete demonstration of this necessity. The working group, directed by Jaime Caruana, Director of the Money Markets and Capital of the International Monetary Fund Department, and Hamad al Suwaid, Chairman of the powerful sovereign fund of Abu Dhabi and Undersecretary of State, has launched a proposal for a voluntary code of conduct in 24 principles, which China has already adopted. Within the members of the EU, there are different attitudes: from the liberal position of the United Kingdom down to the more conservative and protectionist view of France and Germany, even if there are some differences between them as well. The Italian attitude would seem to be more open to capital inflows as the need to attract Fdi is greater. 2.3. Reason to create an SWF Behind the creation of a sovereign fund, then lies the remarkable availability currency that can not be absorbed immediately into the economic system and / or that the same policy makers decide to use in order to get returns for future generations diversifying national economies. The relevant economic literature identifies, essentially, two reasons that lead the States holders to efficiently use this surplus: 1. The first is defined as "competitive" (or new mercantilism), mainly adopted in type export-led countries, it aims to balance the costs arising from a massive current account surplus while keeping the exchange rate depreciated and promoting better competitiveness of goods in international markets. 2. The second is identified as "self-insurance", ie on the need to stabilize the domestic economy in the face of financial turmoil, more and more frequent resulting from significant economic integration post globalization. The work of Jeanne and Rancière (2006) also showed that if the level of reserves held appears optimal for some countries, for example those of Latin America, for those in Asia is witnessing a 18 particularly large accumulation process that could be justifiable only in the case of a financial crisis of international dimensions. Theoretical Model Even if there are no theoretical models to identify completeness motivations that underlie the creation of a sovereign fund (Das et all. 2009), a part of the academic literature focuses on variables as follows: the accumulation of capital (Aizenman and Glick , 2008) or on national saving, or even on the wealth of the resident population (Zilinsky, 2009) identified from time to time as the most significant macroeconomic variables on the decision to create such investment vehicles. In addition to these, the creation of a SWF is often influenced by the will to assert its role in the international markets (Clark and Monk, 2011; Hatton and Pistor, 2011). On the contrary, it is possible to identify impediments elements such as lack of human capital and / or the presence of non-viable institutions (Kauffman et al. 2010). In order to verify the validity of the assumptions described above and highlight any other reasons it was decided to create a separate dataset dividing the countries on the basis of the presence or absence of a sovereign fund, using the World Development Indicator Data Bank (2013). The observations cover a very wide span of time, from 1960 to 2012, during which were identified 48 countries with an active SWF, associating a dummy that identify their presence at a given date. Preliminary statistics contained in Table 9 allow to obtain some initial information. Table 9 - Summary statistics without Swf N. Mean with Swf Std. Deviation N. Mean Std. Deviat. Reserve 4.046 50,35 216,42 223 218,34 485,22 Fuel export 4.974 13,04 30,20 532 42,02 38,90 Goods export 6.861 33,83 223,36 614 56,29 46,31 Current account 892 10,42 239 10,63 36,20 Fdi in 5.439 3,09 8,18 627 4,50 6,86 Gdp growth 7.161 3,81 6,26 667 4,70 6,41 Gdp p.c. growth 7.126 2,05 6,06 664 2,01 6,35 Gross saving 4.130 18,73 10,00 489 30,28 18,21 Inflation 5.866 36,64 510,26 565 4,86 5,35 External debt 4.011 66,63 84,35 229 38,00 34,84 -5,60 source: estimates, World Development Indicator, 2013 In the entire period observed, for example, holders of a SWF countries on average have an incidence of reserves to total external debt greater than about 4 times than the other those economic systems, confirming the thesis of Jeanne and Rancière ( 2006) and Aizenman and Jaewoo (2007), namely that once exceeded a threshold defined as a functional, high availability of foreign exchange resources tend to be used for alternative purposes to the traditional ones (such as the macroeconomic requirements of the holder country) and oriented delivering more profitable activities. 19 To this evidence contributed significantly also the accumulation process took place in the countries oil exporter thanks to an increase in crude oil prices. Suffice it to say that in no SWF countries the weight of petroleum goods in total output goods (fue exports) is about four times lower than the remainder of the sample. Next to the energy component, is also observed the different relevance of outgoing goods, in countries with SWF the ratio of exports to GDP (goods exports), an average stands at 56% while for others is reduced to 40%. Items of interest also derive from the analysis of the current account than the national wealth (current account) The countries with a sovereign investment fund have a surplus of 10%, totally opposite value to the deficit reported for the remaining part of the sample. While remaining within the framework of Balance of Payments, the focus can be moved on capital inflows. As for the passive internationalization processes, the impact of Fdi entry in the gross domestic product (fdi in) is slightly lower than for countries without a sovereign fund. Finally, looking to the macroeconomic environment, the defending countries denote values significantly higher than the growth rate , both national (gdp growth) is per capita (gdp growth pc) , and the level of national savings (gross saving); by contrast assume lower values considering the level of inflation (inflation) and external debt (external debt). Variables influencing the creation of a SWF: base line model Compared to the approaches presented in the literature (Aizenman and Glick, 2008; Zylinski, 2009) we built a data bank more extensive and detailed data in terms of time horizon and countries to get a more precise verification of the thesis first described through an econometric model. The model, considering the presence or not of a SWF as the dependent variable, unable to isolate those macroeconomic variables that most affect the probability of creating such investment vehicles. The econometric model was built using one logit estimator6 that is applied on a panel data structure and does not cross -section Swfi,t = αi + βi Indicatori Basei,t + γ xi,t + εi,t (1) where: Swfi,t assume value 1 when the country i decide to create a SWF at time t; Indicatori Base is a macro variables set representing relevant forecast predictor for the creation of a SWF; xi,t is a controll vector strictly interdependent as the value at time t will impact on it self at time t+1; εi,t i the error component. The baseline model has been subsequently integrated with additional control variables that may intervene on the probability of realization of a SWF and whose expected results are presented in the Table 10. The variable column includes the additional variables we take into consideration. 6 Il modello descritto dalla (1) prevede che la variabile dipendente assume un numero finito di realizzazioni, espresse come [0, 1], alle quali si associa con p la probabilità che si verifichi l’evento osservato e con p-1 la situazione opposta. Per quanto riguarda la selezione dello stimatore, la scelta di uno stimatore logit appare appropriata sia perché restituisce dei coefficienti più efficienti rispetto a un probit sia perché più adatto nel trattamento di un dataset di natura panel, particolarmente ampio, con variabili qualitative dipendenti (Maddala, 1987). 20 Table 10 - Expected results according the literature (base line 1 and 2) and our estimation (model 3) Model Variables Direction Details for Swf creation + Impact over the current account balance and additional source of assets + More efficient management of reserve goods_exp + Impact over the current account balance and additional source of assets gross_sav + National saving as new source of assets gdp_pc_gro + Economic growth as proxy of new capitals injection fdi_in + Impact over the capital account balance New hypothesis (model 3) ext_debt - Inefficient management of capital and more external exposure Inflation - Inefficient management of liquidity fuel_exp Base line (model 1) res_ed (Aizenman e Glick, 2008) Saving and growth (model 2) (Zilinsky, 2009) In addition to the development of the baseline model, the observed sample was subject to a series of hypotheses of robustness (robustness check) by carrying out various restrictions in level in terms of both time horizon (pre or post globalization) both of countries observed. Model I - The first test has been done on the entire sample taken into consideration aiming to offer only a general view on the elements influencing a SWF’s creation. Looking at the first column, where is described the baseline model, we reach the same conclusions as those observed by Aizenman and Glick (2008). Concerning the variable fuel export the obtained positive coefficients coincide with expectations. Many of the SWF were in fact created in order to limit the national dependence on non-renewable sources and use the revenue to cushion any negative cycles in prices. Even for the variable goods exports the result obtained is as expected; most of the funds set up in the new millennium are born with the need to manage the huge current account surpluses. Particularly for export-led countries, the positive dynamics of this entry has a positive impact on the current account balance can result in an accumulation of resources. A similar argument can be made with regard reserve accumulation. In this case, the positive and significant sign is consistent with the literature in that, after passing the optimal threshold, for a country appears efficiently use these resources to more profitable purposes than ordinary operations being carried out by the central bank. However, as shown by the low value of r2, the starting hypothesis reveal a fable explanatory power7. The columns 2 and 3 show a further deepening of the starting hypotheses, taking into account the hypothesis that has been introduced by Zilinsky (2009). However, while presenting a positive sign, the coefficients obtained are not significant for both the gross national savings (gross savings) for both growth per capita (gdp p.c. growth). Column 4 shows, finally, the further implementations of the basic model. The first control variable takes into account is foreign direct investment input (fdi in). In line with expectations, we will show positive and significant coefficients, as such flows produce an improvement in the capital side of the balance of payments. This report should also be read with reference to the trends that Fdi have Non deve essere interpretato come il tradizionale R2 utilizzato nei modelli lineari, l’indice di Mac Fadden confronta la bontà del modello rispetto ad un altro calcolato esclusivamente con l’intercetta; il suo valore è compreso tra 0 e 1. 7 21 had in the last years: taking into account the first 20 receivers investments economies, in more than half there is the presence of a SWF. Concerning external debt (external debt) and the level of consumer prices (inflation) it has experimented the negative coefficients accompanied by a strong relevance of the p-value. The negative impact from the estimates is justified by the fact that greater debt exposure towards foreign countries is correlated with a decreased availability of resources for a SWF; on the same way, the presence of a spiral on consumer prices could be symptomatic of the inability to efficiently manage excess liquidity. Table 11 - Model I (without restrictions) (1) Fuel export Reserve Goods export (2) (3) (4) 0,037*** 0,019 0,037*** 0,037* (0,01) (0,01) (0,01) (0,01) 0,017*** 0,020*** 0,017*** 0,01 (0,00) (0,01) (0,00) (0,01) 0,177*** 0,153*** 0,177*** 0,279*** (0,02) (0,03) (0,02) (0,05) Gross saving 0,004 (0,04) Gdp p.c. growth 0,013 (0,03) Fdi in 0,280** (0,10) External debt -0,028** (0,01) Inflation -0,394*** (0,06) N 596 411 595 472 0,384 0,385 0,385 0,728 aic 340,880 248,681 340,847 135,343 bic 354,051 264,755 358,401 160,285 -167,440 -120,341 -166,424 -61,671 208,642 150,799 208,005 330,331 0,0000 0,0000 0,0000 0,0000 r2_p ll chi2 p In parenthesis t-statistics based on standard errors; ***indicates significance at the 1%level; **indicates significance at the 5%, level; * indicates significance at the 10% level. 22 Model II – From these first considerations, the second step of the analysis will be addressed to the segmentation of the sample observed by referring exclusively horizon post globalization time. The reasons for this approach are derived essentially from the fact that most of the SWFs have been created at the turn of the 90s and the new millennium; then this sample design allows not only to check the stability of the previously tested hypothesis but also to check for any new assumptions linked to a limited historical period. The analysis of the coefficients confirms the hypothesis comprehensive treaty. The estimate is of significance in terms of sign, pointing out that, even under the pressure of globalization, the variables of interest have maintained consistent with expectations. The only major difference is observed in column 2 where, replicating the model Zilinsky (2009), with the introduction of domestic savings. The fuel export variable improves its significance while keeping the positive sign. Model II – Finally, shifting the focus on the institutional characteristics of the countries, the reference literature shows that generally the presence of a SWF is associated with greater transparency and government efficiency (less relevance to the so-called fuel-export countries) and as indicated by Avendano and Santiso (2009) these tools, mainly used for purposes of macroeconomic analysis, pursue investment strategies only financial and not political ones. Based on this information, the last experiment is done by restricting the observations which differentiates between countries on the basis of their governmental status, as identified by the Economist Intelligence Unit (so-called Democracy Index) and do not belong to the OECD group. The aim is to verify weather the previously observed stylized facts can be confirmed or not. As it concerns the exports of manufactured goods, the result remains stable in the various partitions as observed in the baseline model. Instead, they are in contrast to what is observed for the incidence of those oil (significant only for non-OECD countries) and for the foreign reserves (valid results you only maintain for non-democratic countries). Moving on to the complete model (as described in column 2), the results observed for the level of inflation do not change in different partitions while for foreign direct investment the significance is not verified only in the case of non-democratic countries. Finally, the high debt exposure would tend to negatively impact on the probability of realization of a SWF only in non-democratic economies and not belonging to the OECD group. 23 3. Responsible investment It comes as quite an intuitive concept that investing in a company not only has an impact on that business but also on society at large. Suffice it to mention that investing in a company that produces cluster munitions or anti-personnel mines seriously undermines and infringes upon the principle laid down in international law of civilians’ protection in armed conflict as it has been repeatedly proven that the use of these specific weapons indiscriminately harm civilian populations. The principle of socially responsible investment stems from the very observation that investment activities are not innocuous and points out to the necessity – nay, the moral obligation – for investors to seek investments that provide financial returns but that also entail positive social, environmental and governance impact or that at least refrain from having deleterious societal repercussions. Historically, socially responsible investment has tended to reflect the political and social climate of the times. The 1960s for instance saw a growing awareness with regards to issues such as social inequalities, women rights, civil rights more generally and these concerns soon translated into calls for more socially responsible behaviors on the part of actors across all sectors of society, including financial investors. The weight and power of investors was fully grasped and appreciated when public and private investors alike pressured the South-African white minority government in the 1980s into giving up the racist apartheid regime that had been tearing the country apart for decades. The use of investment and disinvestment as means of moral pressure proved to be an efficient instrument into triggering social and political change. The climate crisis has since put the environment at the top of the agenda of the international community and socially responsible investors have thus followed up on the necessity to finance forms of sustainable development through what has come to be known as green investments. Today, socially responsible investors encourage an array of corporate practices that promote consumer and worker protection, human rights, and environmental stewardship among other things. Following the financial and economic crises, the financial world has come under greater scrutiny and irresponsible behaviors on the part of financial agents were blamed for having led to the collapse of the financial system. Responsible investment is not merely about being morally and ethically righteous, it has also demonstrated to be more sound financially speaking. Indeed, investing in a company that has a mediocre relationship with its employees or that carries out operations that negatively impact the environment might prove financially unsustainable over the medium to long term. The financial performance of the firm might eventually be affected by these shortcomings and the result for the investor might end up being nothing short of disappointing. Furthermore, beyond the situation of single firms, it is the health and the stability of the market as a whole that is at stake and that socially responsible investors seek to actively preserve. So, the socially responsible investment strategy that considers successful returns on investment and responsible corporate behavior as indivisible has inevitably gained momentum and is being adopted by an increasing number of actors among which some of the sovereign wealth funds. It makes perfect sense for sovereign investors to seek both financial returns and positive societal impact, as their ultimate shareholders could be considered to be the citizens of their countries. Besides, many SWFs share the common objective of providing for future generations. This commitment entails a greater sense of responsibility when deciding upon portfolio strategy and evaluating the various investment opportunities. With assets under management of $7 trillion and counting, SWFs have a say in the corporate practices of the companies they invest in. Furthermore, as sizeable investors, they can set the ethical bar high and inspire best practices on the part of other investors. 3.1. Propensity for responsible investments on the part of SWFs We will attempt to construe the propensity of SWFs to adopt responsible practices in terms of investment. Such tendency will be analyzed according to whether SWFs include in their investment decision-making process environmental, social and governance (ESG) criteria and if not whether and why it would make sense for them to do so from both a commercial and ethical standpoint. The 24 ESG criteria are not set in stone and they continuously evolve so as to include new factors in order to better tailor responsible investment strategies to ever-changing conditions. Examples of ESG factors can be found in the table below. Table 12 - Examples of ESG factors8 Environmental Social Governance - Climate change - Working conditions, - Executive pay - Greenhouse gas (GHG) including slavery and - Bribery and corruption emissions child labor - Political lobbying and - Resource depletion, - Local communities, donations including water including indigenous - Board diversity and - Waste and pollution communities structure - Deforestation - Conflict - Tax strategy - Health and safety - Employee relations and diversity Indeed, while at the inception of the socially responsible investing movement in the 1960s, the latter was considered a marginal segment in the investment world as it appeared to be rather a valuebased approach rather than a properly thought out and sound financial strategy, it became an object of interest and study and recent developments have shown that it might be in some cases shielding more yields than unsustainable approaches have so far – at least on the longer term9. We will solely consider responsible investment as defined by the Principles for Responsible Investment (PRI), a global network of investors who created in 2006 a list of six principles for responsible investment10 that investors around the world can voluntarily choose to adhere to. The list of signatories has grown considerably since 2006 and now counts over 1,500 entities from over 50 countries with assets amounting to more than $60 trillion11. Therein, RI is defined as “an approach to investing that aims to incorporate environmental, social and governance (ESG) factors into investment decisions, to better manage risk and generate sustainable, long-term returns.”12 RI is to be distinguished from other value-based investing approaches such as socially responsible investment (SRI), green, sustainable or impact investment for instance. These approaches might intersect with RI but the main point of rupture is that the said approaches aim at promoting dual return structures on investments: both financial and social/green etc. Conversely, RI does not advocate for social returns per se. Rather it insists on the importance of having a holistic approach to investment by including ESG factors in the evaluation process of returns and risks insofar as not doing so would eventually affect the investments’ financial performance. The example of Norway’s Government Pension Fund Global (GPFG) will be put forward as it stands out from both the literature and among its peers as the clear leader in terms of responsible investment practices but other funds will be mentioned and looked into to try and understand the different factors that may influence a fund to take upon such endeavors and those that might bring it to refrain from doing so. While the ethical argument for the adoption of a responsible investment 8 What is Responsible Investment? https://www.unpri.org/about/what-is-responsible-investment 9 See Kempf, A. and Osthoff, P. :“The Effect of Socially Responsible Investing on Portfolio Performance” https://drupal.financite.be/sites/default/files/references/files/2184.pdf 10 The list of the six principles can be found in annex I 11 About the PRI – Principles for Responsible Investment https://www.unpri.org/about 12 What is responsible investment? https://www.unpri.org/about/what-is-responsible-investment 25 strategy for SWFs is rather clear but needs to be restated – considering its liabilities, its lack of direct and legally binding fiduciary responsibility, its public character etc. – the hypothesis we depart from is that it is also sound from a financial point of view and that returns over the long-term could only be improved by integrating ESG criteria into investment choices. As institutional investors, SWFs evolve in a world that is in constant mutation and where new challenges come forth every day. They are required, like other institutions and other investors, to adapt to these changes and to meet these challenges to remain relevant and to insure they are able to meet the mandates they were set up for. In this light, it is interesting to look into whether SWFs behave rather as trend-setters in terms of investment practices or whether they follow on the trends set by other investing vehicles: be them of other public investors (pension funds) or private investors (hedge funds) as a SWF is considered to be a public institution behaving like a private entity on the market. It is also relevant to ponder upon the influence that norms-setting international institutions might have on the behavior of SWFs and to what extent SWFs might act hand in hand with these institutions and assist them in setting up new principles and standards by which to abide in terms of responsible investment. We will attempt to fathom where SWFs stand in terms of putting responsible investment on the agenda of other investors and whether they can act as leaders in making the financial world more responsible and more acutely aware of the problems that stem from inconsiderate investment practices be it at the environmental, social or governance level. Inversely we will look at how other institutions’ or entities’ evolving practices with regards to responsible investment may infer upon those of SWFs. Subsequently, in the following chapter, the potential inclination of SWFs towards financing domestic and foreign development projects will be scrutinized in order to fathom whether they may or may not play an active role in financing development along with fulfilling their other mandates (intergenerational redistribution of resources’ revenues – macroeconomic stability and so forth) or whether these different mandates might clash or supersede/impede one another. In particular, we will attempt to figure out in which case setting up a SWF may be of help for a country whose economy is still developing and what are the challenges that may impair the proper functioning of the said SWF. We will address the optimistic view put forth by Javier Santiso and the sympathetic critic brought forward by Clark and Monk while taking into consideration the calls of international institutions (UNCTAD- FAO- UNGA-…) for a greater involvement in financing development on the part of institutional investors. On the other hand we will try to construe the challenges and barriers encountered by foreign investors – such as SWFs – when trying to invest in assets based in developing countries and the financing partnership schemes that may be engineered in order to overcome these difficulties and find new alleys for financing development. Both the integration of ESG criteria in the investment choices of SWFs in this chapter and the latters’ potential participation in financing development at home and abroad in the next, will be addressed in light of the megatrends put forward by PwC13 that have been at play in the global economy and that will continue to disrupt and shape the global economic landscape for decades to come, as they surely influence the investment decisions of all investors, and not least of sovereign investors among which the SWFs find themselves. 1. The reshaping of the global economic order: the shift of economic power towards the East/South is crucial for sovereign investors insofar as they must therefore now grant greater importance to developing markets that tend to be more dynamic all the while offering more numerous investment opportunities as they often still suffer from a lack of infrastructures and services. Javier Santiso insists on the necessity to “reload our cognitive maps”14 in the sense that “not only is the center of gravity of the world shifting but traditional concepts also 13 “Global megatrends”: PwC, http://www.pwc.com/gx/en/issues/megatrends.html Santiso, Javier: “Sovereign Wealth Funds and the shifting wealth of nations”, in Sovereign Wealth Funds and Long-term investing, edited by P. Bolton, F. Samama and J. E. Stiglitz, p.127 14 26 need to be reset”15. There is indeed a blatant need to rethink the world in other terms that the traditional center/periphery and developed/emerging dichotomies as the latter no longer reflect the current state of affairs. Indeed according to the IMF, while during the 1980s, emerging and developing economies accounted for around 36 percent of global GDP (measured in purchasing power parity, or PPP, terms) and some 43 percent of global GDP growth (with PPP weights), for the 2010-2015 period, the numbers were 56 percent and 79 percent, respectively16. This trend was surely enough accentuated by the financial and economic crises that have also discouraged many institutional investors to risk investing in what used to be known as safe securities in developed markets, bringing them to start considering other alternative assets to diversify their portfolio and alleviate their risk level. Also worth mentioning is that most SWFs originate from the East and the South as evidenced by the graph below. This contributes to reinforce their inclination towards investing their assets in countries that are closer to them. This can be justified by direct geographical proximity as the latter presents clear advantages in terms of information networks in the sense that countries have a greater historical knowledge of their neighbors thus bearing lesser costs in dealing with these markets and optimizing the positive externalities. Table 13 - Number of SWFs by region17 2. A demographic shift: the shift in demographics with some countries having to cope with ageing population and others doted of a large, growing young active workforce will inevitably draw a line between SWFs and pension funds whose fiduciary responsibility will become more significant and pressing in the coming years. Unless open migration policies are enacted to overcome the shortage in workers, pension funds of States with ageing populations like Canada or Japan will face much heavier pension obligations that may force them to revise their investment decisions and risk aversions levels. This might sharply modify the sovereign investing landscape of these institutions, affecting their traditional long-term span and shifting the priority to investment in more liquid assets (you might want to back that with a quote). 15 Ibid. “IMF Survey: The Global Economy in 2016”, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/2016/INT010416A.htm 17 Institutional Investor Profiles, SWFs, Sovereign Wealth Funds Institute, http://www.swfinstitute.org/sovereign-wealth-fund-profiles/ 16 27 Figure 2 - Level of concern about ageing of the population18 Another phenomenon of importance for the sovereign investing landscape in terms of demographic shifts is the growth of the middle class in the said emerging economies as in Asia for instance where it now accounts for over 60% of the total population19. This should contribute to emphasize an already ongoing phenomenon: that of the emerging markets capturing a growing share of the totality of global foreign direct investments. There is no reason why SWFs should derogate from the rule and sulk these investment opportunities as the expansion of the middle class and sustained growth in emerging countries seem to be trends that will persist over the long-term while the recovery in the so-called advanced countries is still lagging behind. 3. Accelerating urbanization: the accelerated urbanization of the BRICS countries among others which has been characterized by the appearance of megalopolis in India or China for instance will surely call for large infrastructure needs and thus for significantly increased financing. Needless to say that this rapid urbanization phenomenon will contribute to put the issues of sustainability and responsible investment even higher on the agenda. Urbanization is often accompanied by the rise of a middle class that quickly translates into a higher demand for goods and services along with an overall increase in per capita purchasing power. As mentioned above, this will surely only reinforce the attraction of foreign sovereign investors for these new markets. It might also fuel the temptation for developing countries with resource revenues or exceeding commercial balance to set up a SWF in order to manage these extra earnings to cope with the infrastructure-financing gap. Indeed, this last decade has been characterized by a decrease in available funds from international organizations and developed countries through the traditional aid channels forcing developing countries to find other sources of financing. Apart from more traditional private investors, sovereign ones might be the right ones to point at given their long-term investment span. The phenomenon of rapid urbanization also represents a challenge in terms of urban-planning. Every year, the world’s urban population grows of an extra 75 million people: between 2005 and 2015, the urban population swelled by around 750 million people, four fifth of which in Asia and Africa. Most cities in the developing world are already very densely populated and there are real and lingering problems regarding urban infrastructures 18 United Nations, World Population Policies Database, https://esa.un.org/PopPolicy/charting/worldmaps.aspx Santiso, Javier: “Sovereign Wealth Funds and the shifting wealth of nations”, in Sovereign Wealth Funds and Long-term investing, edited by P. Bolton, F. Samama and J. E. Stiglitz, p.128 19 28 such as roads and public spaces. Indeed cities are expanding without letting the adequate space for road construction for instance20. The questions raised by this rapid growth should be addressed by adequate funding but most importantly by sound planning and a securing of property rights that would entice otherwise reluctant professional developers to step in21. 4. Climate change and resource scarcity: while climate change stands out as one of the biggest challenges of our times and that it is expected to have dramatic consequences in particular for populations of the least developed countries, the international community has been failing to address it with the urgency and commitment necessary. To tackle climate change requires an effort that involves both mitigation – to avoid the unmanageable – and adaptation – to manage the unavoidable. So far, the steps taken by the international community fall short in the face of the gravity of the current situation. Moreover, the issue of food scarcity and the prediction of a growth in population worldwide are inherently intertwined with the challenges posed by climate change. These developments have been inspiring a number of cross-border acquisitions in a move by import-dependent countries to insure their own food security. Concerns over food security thus drives foreign arable land acquisitions and investments in agribusinesses abroad (China and the Gulf Cooperation Council – GCC – countries have already set in motion such investment schemes) in order to rely ever less on imports and to be less vulnerable to the volatility of prices of food products. Indeed the 2008 crisis of food prices made those countries that heavily rely on imports to feed their population realize the extent to which they were exposed to such price surges. However, it is crucial to look closer at the impact that these investments have had and are having on the local populations of the countries in which they are made. Indeed, China’s investments in Africa have been pointed the finger at insofar as some have described them as plain ‘land-grabbing’. The lack of regulation and the difficulty to gather data due to very low levels of transparency in the operations of most SWFs make these issues even more relevant and worth scrutinizing. 5. Technological breakthroughs: some sovereign investors have been sensible to the recent and upcoming innovations in the field of new technologies and start ups choosing to put increased focus on venture capital and incipient Internet companies. Southeast Asian funds for one have been the first to open up offices in San Francisco Bay for instance to locally monitor their investments in the companies and startups of the Silicon Valley. In June 2016, the sovereign fund of Saudi Arabia invested $3.5 billion in the capital of Uber, Silicon valley’s most highly valued private company22. Southeast Asian and Middle Eastern funds are not the only ones to have started invested in these tech companies as both the Alaskan and New Zealand funds also came through with investments in digital healthcare and in clean technology business respectively. Sovereign funds have indeed made investments in venture capital and start ups for a total of $10 billion through 93 deals, 63% of which during the year 2014 and 201523. Javier Santiso who had come up with the term Sovereign Development Funds in a 2008 OECD working paper24 to designate these funds enclined to invest in development projects both in their home country and abroad, now refers to these 20 In a study on seven African cities (Accra, Addis Ababa, Arusha, Ibadan, Johannesburg, Lagos and Luanda), Shlomo Angel of NYU calculates that only 16% of the land was set aside for roads in the newly residential areas built since 1990. Urban planners usually recommend reserving twice this figure for road space. 21 “The right kind of sprawl” and “Bourgeois shanty towns”, The Economist, July 2nd 2016 22 “Sovereign wealth funds throw funding lifeline to tech ventures”, E. Auchard and S. Ahzar, Reuters http://www.reuters.com/article/us-wealthfunds-tech-idUSKCN0YT1OC 23 Data from the Sovereign investment lab presented in the 2015 report of the Sovereign Investment Lab of the Bocconi University: “The sky did not fall”, in “The rise of sovereign venture funds”, D. Lopez, p65 https://www.unibocconi.eu/wps/wcm/connect/961cda94-6412-4d5b-93e912af00ac8bb9/DEF_report_SIL+2016_low.pdf?MOD=AJPERES 24 Santiso, J. “Sovereign Development funds, Key financial actors of the shifting wealth of nations” http://www.oecd.org/dev/41944381.pdf 29 funds undertaking such investments in tech firms and start ups, as Sovereign Venture Funds25. It comes as quite an intuitive concept that investing in a company not only has an impact on that business but also on society at large. Suffice it to mention that investing in a company that produces cluster munitions or anti-personnel mines seriously undermines and infringes upon the principle of civilians’ protection in armed conflict laid down in international law as it has been repeatedly proven that these specific weapons were used indiscriminately to harm civilian populations in the context of war or armed conflicts. Similarly, investments in coal companies or tobacco companies have harmful consequences respectively on the environment and on public health. The principle of responsible investment thus stems from the very observation that investment activities are not innocuous and points out to the necessity – nay, the moral obligation – for investors to seek investments that provide financial returns but that also entail positive social, environmental and governance impact or that at least refrain from having deleterious overall societal repercussions. Furthermore, responsible investments are sound from a financial standpoint if one is to consider yields over the long-term. Indeed, there is evidence that unsustainable practices inevitable harm the reputation of a company and may affect its performances over the medium to long term. Historically, responsible investment has tended to reflect the political and social climate of the times. The 1960s for instance saw a growing awareness with regards to issues such as social inequalities, women rights, civil rights more generally and these concerns soon translated into calls for more socially responsible behaviors on the part of actors across all sectors of society, including financial investors. The weight and power of investors was fully grasped and appreciated when public and private investors alike pressured the South-African white minority government in the 1980s into giving up the racist apartheid regime that had been tearing the country apart for decades. While divestment might not have caused the dismay of the regime, it contributed greatly to isolating it and making it unsustainable. The use of investment and divestment as means of moral pressure proved to be an efficient instrument into triggering social and political change and better corporate governance practices. The climate change crisis has since put the environment at the top of the agenda of the international community and socially responsible investors have thus followed up on the necessity to finance forms of sustainable development through what has come to be known as green investments. Today, socially responsible investors encourage an array of corporate practices that promote consumer and worker protection, human rights, and environmental stewardship among other things. As sovereign investors, SWFs have a responsibility as they are managing assets that are by essence public assets. While they have to fulfill a commitment of yielding financial returns, they also have to do with a more implicit commitment to respect international legal requirements and thus find themselves at the heart of a non-negligible dilemma, which is to find the adequate balance between their financial and ethical commitment. As Anna Gelpern puts it: “How do we reconcile diverse accountability demands on SWFs when such demands do not necessarily stand in a hierarchical relationship to one another?”26 According to her, there are four dimensions along which demands for accountability behoove SWFs: public, private, internal and external although as she points out “there is no stable ex ante ordering saying which dimension comes out on top.”27 The challenges that arise from these various layers of accountability translate mostly into ordeals in terms of governance, transparency and in some ways in the choice of investment strategies and the type of management of existing investment in equities for instance. Following the financial and economic crises, the financial world has come under greater scrutiny and irresponsible behaviors on the part of financial agents were blamed for having led to the collapse of the financial system. Responsible investment is not merely about being morally and Santiso, J. Forthcoming, Cambridge University Press, as mentioned in “The rise of sovereign venture funds”, D. Lopez, p63 in the 2015 report of the Sovereign Investment Lab of the Bocconi University: “The sky did not fall” 26 Gelpern, A. “Reconciling sovereignty, accountability and transparency in sovereign wealth funds” in Sovereign Wealth Funds and long-term investing, edited by Bolton, P., Samama, F. and Stiglitz, J.E. p205 27 Ibid. p206 25 30 ethically righteous, it has also demonstrated to be more sound financially speaking. Indeed, investing in a company that has a mediocre relationship with its employees or that carries out operations that negatively impact the environment might prove financially unsustainable over the medium to long term precisely as a result of these malpractices. The commercial performance of the firm might eventually be affected by these shortcomings and the result for investors might end up being nothing short of disappointing. Furthermore, beyond the situation of single firms, it is the health and the stability of the market as a whole that is at stake and that socially responsible investors seek to actively preserve. So, the socially responsible investment strategy that considers successful returns on investment and responsible corporate behavior as indivisible has inevitably gained momentum and is being adopted by an increasing number of actors among which some sovereign wealth funds. It makes perfect sense for sovereign investors to seek both financial returns and positive societal impact, as their ultimate shareholders could be considered to be the citizens of their countries28 although their fiduciary responsibility is not as clear-cut and direct as that of pension funds for instance. However they do belong to states and are associated to governments given their ownership status. As such, the actions taken up by SWFs and their being associated with firms that have unsustainable practices might tarnish the reputation of the state in question and stand in contrast with its international legal obligations. Besides, many SWFs share the common objective of providing for future generations. This commitment entails a greater sense of responsibility when deciding upon portfolio strategy and evaluating the various investment opportunities along with taking riskmeasurement seriously. With assets under management of $7 trillion and counting, SWFs have a say in the corporate practices of the companies they invest in and taking a more active ownership approach seems evermore necessary and justified. Richardson indeed argues that the next logical step in the evolution of SWFs would be for them to take it upon themselves to invest in a more sustainable fashion. He points out in his comparative study of Norway’s GPFG and of the New Zealand SF that neither of these funds yet manage their portfolio comprehensively to actively promote sustainable development29. We shall come back to this observation in our analysis of the GPFG’s practices in terms of responsible investment. Furthermore, as sizeable investors, there is a reasonable expectation that they could – nay should – set the ethical bar high and inspire best practices on the part of other investors. 3.2. Norway’s Government Pension Fund Global Among all SWFs, Norway’s Government Pension Fund Global (GPFG) is often pointed out to as the most transparent, most ethical and overall most deserving of praise of its peers. Unlike its name would have ones believe, the GPFG is not a pension fund insofar as it does not have designated beneficiaries, as it is not ruled by the principle of fiduciary duty and does not have a set time horizon over which to realize its commitment (Clark and Monk). Its stated objective is to turn petroleum revenue into financial wealth, aiming for the highest possible returns bearing an acceptable level of risk. Its commitment to socially responsible investment is both a translation and a consequence of its obligation and dedication to have its operations subject to both transparency and accountability. It is accountable to the Norwegian people through the Ministry of Finance and publishes yearly reports, highlighting its investment strategy and activities. The Ministry of Finance which is charged with the management of the fund, sets the bar in terms of investment strategy but also gets involved in ethical matters as it defines the ethical guidelines to be followed. In its task, it is assisted by two advisory bodies part of the Minister of Finance: the Council of Ethics and the Strategy Council on Investment. However, operationally, it is the Norges Bank through Norges Bank Investment Management (NBIM) that manages the GPFG. Considered in general to be both an ethical and responsible sovereign investor, GPFG has doted itself of various tools to support 28 Lo Turco, Cecilia Richardson, B.J. “Sovereign Wealth Funds and the Quest for Sustainability: Insights from Norway and New Zealand”, Nordic Journal of Commercial Law issue 2011#2, p1 29 31 responsible investment practices. It expresses expectations as an investor and exercises active ownership through voting in companies’ board meetings and by engaging with the board and the management to encourage socially responsible investments and good corporate governance. It has also started since 2008 to include particular areas of focus dear to SRI into its investment and risk monitoring and management processes. In 2008, it chose to focus first on children’ rights to later come in 2010 to both climate change and water management. These three areas fall under the broader umbrella of topics inherent to sustainable development as defined by the United Nations in 1987 as “development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs.” The GPFG thus sees its involvement in the promotion of responsible investment as part of an overarching strategy to act for sustainable development. It is reflective of Norway’s standing in the international community as pointed out by Clark, Dixon and Monk that see the GPFG as both “an instrument of long-term national welfare and as an expression of Norway’s commitment to global justice.” They regard the GPFG as “a moralist sovereign wealth fund.” This characterization is true to the extent that the GPFG uses naming and shaming to deter other entities from investing in companies that carry out unsustainable practices. But that is not all it does. Indeed, the GPFG has contributed to improving industry standards by participating to both institutional discussions on the topic and private companies roundtables. It has also enhanced its own legitimacy by insisting that its own activities be reported transparently to the public. This has led the fund to come under great scrutiny when it supposedly had divested from coal producing companies but then it was made public later that these assets had only been redirected to coal transforming industry instead. However when confronted with these shortcomings, the GPFG divested all its assets once and for all from all coal related industries. In 2014 it divested from 49 companies and like every year it published the list of the latters on its website with a joint justification that mentioned the reason behind the divestment. The same year, it conducted an analysis of greenhouse gases emissions from the companies in their equity portfolio in order to get an idea of their portfolio emissions’ intensity. Their contribution to research is part of their dedication to SRI insofar as it also allows for a better-informed active ownership in the companies they invest in. NBIM’s market value as of July 2016 is of $847 billion. With such important assets under management, the decisions and operations of the fund are scrutinized by other investors and companies around the world as it clearly has the potential to make or break the places it chooses to invest or divest from. 3.3.Sustainable investments (New Zeland) TO BE DEVELOPPED 32 Annex 1 - The six principles for responsible investment Principle 1 We will incorporate ESG issues into investment analysis and decision-making processes. Possible actions: ➢ Address ESG issues in investment policy statements. ➢ Support development of ESG-related tools, metrics, and analyses. ➢ Assess the capabilities of internal investment managers to incorporate ESG issues. ➢ Assess the capabilities of external investment managers to incorporate ESG issues. ➢ Ask investment service providers (such as financial analysts, consultants, brokers, research firms, or rating companies) to integrate ESG factors into evolving research and analysis. ➢ Encourage academic and other research on this theme. ➢ Advocate ESG training for investment professionals. Principle 2 We will be active owners and incorporate ESG issues into our ownership policies and practices. Possible actions: ➢ Develop and disclose an active ownership policy consistent with the Principles. ➢ Exercise voting rights or monitor compliance with voting policy (if outsourced). ➢ Develop an engagement capability (either directly or through outsourcing). ➢ Participate in the development of policy, regulation, and standard setting (such as promoting and protecting shareholder rights). ➢ File shareholder resolutions consistent with long-term ESG considerations. ➢ Engage with companies on ESG issues. ➢ Participate in collaborative engagement initiatives. ➢ Ask investment managers to undertake and report on ESG-related engagement. Principle 3 We will seek appropriate disclosure on ESG issues by the entities in which we invest. Possible actions: ➢ Ask for standardised reporting on ESG issues (using tools such as the Global Reporting Initiative). ➢ Ask for ESG issues to be integrated within annual financial reports. ➢ Ask for information from companies regarding adoption of/adherence to relevant norms, standards, codes of conduct or international initiatives (such as the UN Global Compact). ➢ Support shareholder initiatives and resolutions promoting ESG disclosure. Principle 4 We will promote acceptance and implementation of the Principles within the investment industry. Possible actions: ➢ Include Principles-related requirements in requests for proposals (RFPs). ➢ Align investment mandates, monitoring procedures, performance indicators and incentive structures accordingly (for example, ensure investment management processes reflect longterm time horizons when appropriate). ➢ Communicate ESG expectations to investment service providers. ➢ Revisit relationships with service providers that fail to meet ESG expectations. ➢ Support the development of tools for benchmarking ESG integration. ➢ Support regulatory or policy developments that enable implementation of the Principles. Principle 5 We will work together to enhance our effectiveness in implementing the Principles. 33 Possible actions: ➢ Support/participate in networks and information platforms to share tools, pool resources, and make use of investor reporting as a source of learning. ➢ Collectively address relevant emerging issues. ➢ Develop or support appropriate collaborative initiatives. Principle 6 We will each report on our activities and progress towards implementing the Principles. Possible actions: ➢ Disclose how ESG issues are integrated within investment practices. ➢ Disclose active ownership activities (voting, engagement, and/or policy dialogue). ➢ Disclose what is required from service providers in relation to the Principles. ➢ Communicate with beneficiaries about ESG issues and the Principles. ➢ Report on progress and/or achievements relating to the Principles using a comply-or-explain approach. ➢ Seek to determine the impact of the Principles. ➢ Make use of reporting to raise awareness among a broader group of stakeholders. 34 4.Development Financing Among the diverse stated or implicit objectives of SWFs, one can find that of fulfilling a developmental mandate. This mandate can be applied either domestically or through foreign investments. In other words, a sovereign fund can make domestic investments that have a dual return structure, insuring both financial and socio-economic – nay-developmental – returns. It is quite a reach, as some would argue for as we discussed in the first chapter, some choose to define SWFs as funds that invest only in foreign assets. But others still do refer to these Sovereign Development Funds (SDFs) as part of the bigger SWFs’ family. SDFs as they have been defined30 have been the object of academic and institutional scrutiny insofar as they represent sizeable pools of capital and that like traditional sovereign wealth funds they tend to adopt a long-term investment horizon fit to finance development projects. There are a number of reasons that could be put forward to explain the recent appeal of investing domestically rather than concentrating on commercial investments abroad. While the latter investments might have proven more profitable, the recent global crisis has put a toll on the traditional sources of infrastructure financing in developing countries. Long term investment are a bet on the synergies between human and institutional capital. There are various ways in which a sovereign fund can impact domestic development but as it has been argued and as we will address further, a SDF is not a panacea for all the problems faced by developing countries in their attempt to foster economic growth and development. For instance, in resource-rich countries, where financial and macroeconomic equilibrium are threatened by the burst and booms cycles that derive from the fluctuations of resource prices, it might make much more sense to set up a sovereign fund with a stabilization mandate rather than a sovereign development fund as the latter might not have positive externalities in an economy that has not been stabilized before hand. There is thus a necessity for countries that consider creating a SDF to ponder over whether it is the right instrument for the challenges the country is facing and in order to solve the critical issue of timing. According to the IMF, “a development fund can make investments that support, if implicitly, wider socio-economic projects and industrial development that help raise a country’s potential output31.” So, according to the IMF, the role of a SDF with a domestic mandate is to support or boost the country’s productivity by making strategic investments in sectors that may crave financing and to finance wider projects that contribute to the development of the country from a socio-economic rather than industrial perspective. In their sympathetic critic of SDFs, Clark and Dixon describe two sub-types of funds belonging to this categorization. The first type is almost identical to the definition put forward by the IMF insofar as it takes upon the role of “supporting productive efficiency through strategic investments and through the contribution to the development of local financial market capacity.”32 They distinguish this investment vehicle from a second type of SDFs with a slightly different mandate that focuses rather on enhancing distributive justice. This second type of fund accordingly chooses to invest in a global portfolio to then redistribute some of the returns through a cash dividend destined to every citizen – present and future? By doing so, it contributes to boost the purchasing power of the poorer segments of the population hence positively impacting demand while reducing socio-economic inequalities. As mentioned earlier, most SWFs are to be found in emerging/developing countries and the discrepancy between the amount of reserves accumulated and the living conditions in the SWF’s sponsor country – be it with regards to infrastructure, telecommunications, health conditions and Javier Santiso – Clark, Monk Making the global economy work for all, IMF Annual Report, 2008 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ar/2008/eng/pdf/ar08_eng.pdf 32 Clark and Monk 30 31 35 education – has brought some countries to allow and even to encourage their SWFs to invest domestically. As of 2012, thirteen SWFs had domestic investment mandates, as reported in the table33 to be found below. It can be observed that eleven out of these thirteen are indeed emerging or developing countries whose SWFs’ domestic investments aim at supporting sustainable growth for their countries and provide the population – and future generations – with sustained returns. The list has since grown and Monk came up with a list of 20 SWFs with domestic investment mandate in 2013. While these domestic investments could be key in financing development locally, to be effective the SWFs’ quality of management is paramount as dealing with financial assets is nothing short of an arduous task and neither is insuring that the outcomes for the country be constructive. To be sure, sovereign funds that choose to place their investments locally must have in-house talents that are familiar with the local market and enterprises. SDFs might choose to partner up with foreign investors on large-scale projects and to do so they must be able to act as a qualified intermediary between the investors and the local agents. The governance of the fund ought to be top-notch to encompass the challenges posed by seeking to insure a dual return structure and to be able to attract foreign investors looking for reputable partners. It should also be able to stand up to foreign due diligence – that is to prove that it is in fact able to deliver upon what it promises to achieve. Moreover, the governance of the fund should be as detached as possible from the political play as it shall not be dependent upon the electoral cycles – for the sake of insuring viable long-term investments and projects – and should avoid to fall prey to malpractices – among which corruption – that are common in many developing countries. Alan Gelb, S. Tordo, H. Halland, N. Arfaa and G. Smith, “Sovereign Wealth Funds and long term development finance: risks and opportunities”, February 1st 2014, Policy Research Working Paper, The World Bank 33 36 Table 14 - SWFs domestic investment mandates Moreover the state of governance in some developing countries might make it difficult for even an internally well-managed fund to have concrete positive fallouts on the real economy. Indeed, a SDF while it offers some hope and real opportunities can substitute neither a well-functioning government with sound monetary and fiscal policies nor the application of the rule of law. The example of the Nigeria Excess Crude Account (ECA) that was set up in 2003 by the government of 37 then President Olusegun Obasanjo is telling although it was not clearly designed as a SWF. While the fund started off well as the rise of oil prices allowed it to set aside a considerable amount of money (20 billion dollars), it soon became clear that the ECA would not fulfill quite what it had been set out for. Indeed as reported by Dixon and Monk, over a relatively short period of time, government and state officials withdrew 17 billion dollars from the fund: “withdrawals that did nothing to improve the quality and quantity of infrastructure even though a majority of the outflows were designated for this purpose34.” The failure of the ECA shows how important it is for a fund to be able to function aside from the political play lest it performances may be hindered by corruption, and malpractices of all kinds. 4.1. Financing domestic development projects (Brasil) 4.2. Financing foreign development projects (China, Dubay, Quatar) 4.3. Elements for discussion Adam Dixon and Ashby H. B. Monk, “What role for Sovereign Wealth Funds in Africa’s development?”, Oil-to-Cash Initiative background paper, Center for Global Development, October 2011 34 38 39 Bibliography Adrian Blundell-Wignall and Patrick Slovik: A Market Perspective on the European Sovereign Debt and Banking Crisis; OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends 2011 IMF Staff Report, Euro Area Policies: 2011 Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the Executive Director for Member Countries Karl Whelan, Bank and Sovereign Debt Resolution: ‘Never Again’ Meets ‘Not Yet’; Directorate General For Internal Policies Policy Department A: Economic And Scientific Policies Economic And Monetary Affairs, Draft pre-published 2010 Michael G. Arghyrou and Alexandros Kontonika, The EMU sovereign-debt crisis: Fundamentals, expectations and contagion; Economic Papers n. 436, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, European Commission 2011 Michael G. Arghyrou and Alexandros Kontonikas: The EMU sovereign-debt crisis: Fundamentals, expectations and contagion, 2011 Norbert Metiu, The EMU in debt distress: Contagion in sovereign bond markets, 2011 Reinhart, Carmen and Kenneth Rogoff, “Growth in a time of debt”, American Economic Association, Papers and Proceedings, 2009 S. Valentina Lizarazo, Contagion of Financial Crises in Sovereign Debt Markets, 2005 Willem Buiter: Global Economics View, Sovereign Debt Problems in Advanced Industrial Countries; Citigroup Global Markets 2010 Dembinski P., 40 ans de la price de pouvoir des marchés sur l’economie mondiale, Le Temps, 15 aout 2011 Feldestein N., Il default greco e I due anni di speranza, Il Sole 24 Ore, 29 settembre 2011 Nerenberg A., Our world is now ruled by finance, The Gazete, Montreal, October 7th 2011 Parkinson D., Four tales from a troubled quarter, The Globe and Mail, Montreal October 1st 2011 Rinke A. and Melander I., Merkel walks fine line in bid to aid Greece: Eurozone rescue fund, National Post, Montreal September 28th 2011 Sargent Thomas J. and Evans David, History of dependent public policies, 2011 Sims Christopher A., Communicating about uncertainty of policy projections, workshop-talk presented at meetings of the Society for Economic Dynamics and Control in Prague, June 2007 Baharumshah A.Z., Thanoon M., (2006) “Foreign capital flows and economic growth in East Asian countries” in China Economic Review, vol. 17, pp. 70– 83. Barba Navaretti G., J.Venables A., (2006) Le multinazionali nell’economia mondiale, Il Mulino, Bologna. Basu P., Guariglia A. , (2007) “Foreign Direct Investment, inequality, and growth” in Journal of Macroeconomics. Becattini G., Rullani E. , (1993) “Sistema locale e mercato globale” in Economia e Politica, n. 80, pp. 25-48. Becattini G. (1993), Sistema locale e mercato globale, in Fuà G., Zacchia C. (a cura di), Industrializzazione senza fratture, Il Mulino, Bologna. 40 Brainard S.L., (1997) “An empirical assessment of the proximity-concentration trade-off between multinational sales and trade” in American Economic Review, vol. 87, pp. 520-544 Chakrabarti A., (2003) “A theory of the spatial distribution of foreign direct investment” in International Review of Economics and Finance, pp. 149 – 169 Deutsche Bank, “Sovereign Wealth Funds, State investment on the rise”, Deutsche Bank Research , September 10th 2007 Doh J., Ramamurtia R., (2004) “Rethinking foreign infrastructure investment in developing countries” in Journal of World Business, pp. 151 – 167 Eggera P., Winnerb H., (2005) “Evidence on corruption as an incentive for foreign direct investment” in European Journal of Political Economy, pp. 932 – 952 Eichengreen B., Tong H., (2007) “Is China’s FDI coming at the expense of other countries?” in Journal of Japanese International Economies, pp. 153 – 172 Fernandez-Ariasa E., Hausmannb R., (2001) “Is foreign direct investment a safer form of financing?” in Emerging Markets Review, pp. 34 – 49 IMF, Sovereign Wealth Funds—A Work Agenda, prepared by the Monetary and Capital Markets and Policy Development and Review Departments in collaboration with other departments, approved by Mark Allen and Jaime Caruana, February 29th, 2008 JP Morgan, Sovereign Wealth Funds: A Bottom-up Primer, May 22nd 2008 Global Economics (2007), October 5th Goldstein I., Razin A., (2006) “An information-based trade off between foreign direct investment and foreign portfolio investment” in Journal of International Economics, vol. 70, pp. 271–295. Grogan L., Moers L., (2001) “Growth empirics with institutional measures for transition countries” in Economic Systems, pp. 323 – 344 IL SOLE 24 ORE, (2007) articoli vari (Bortolotti, Cristalli, Debenedetti, Garten, Merli, Pasca di Magliano, Riveda, Summers) ISIAE (2007), Rapporto sui Fondi di Ricchezza Sovrana, Roma Higino Schneider P., (2005) “International trade, economic growth and intellectual property rights: A panel data study of developed and developing countries” in Journal of Development Economics, pp. 529 – 540 Hines J.R., (1999) “Lessons from behavioural responses to international taxation” in National Tax Journal, vol. 52, pp. 305-322 Hooper V., Kim S.J., (2007) “The determinants of capital inflows: Does opacity of recipient country explain the flows?” in Economic Systems, vol. 31, pp. 35–48. Jen S., (2007) “Russia the Newest Member of the “SWF club”, Morgan Stanley Research Global. Jenkins R., Edwards C., (2006) “The economic impacts of China and India on sub-Saharan Africa: Trends and prospects” in Journal of Asian Economics, vol. 17, pp. 207–225. Li X., Liu X., (2005) “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: An Increasingly Endogenous Relationship” in World Development, pp. 393 – 407 Markusen J.R., Maskus K., (2001) “Discriminating among alternative theories of the multinational enterprise” in Review of International Economics, vol. 10, pp. 694-707 41 Merril Lynch (2007), The overflowing bathtub, the running tap and SWFs Noy I., Vu T., (2007) “Capital account liberalization and foreign direct investment” in North American Journal of Economics and Finance Russ K.N., (2007) “The endogeneity of the exchange rate as a determinant of FDI: A model of entry and multinational firms” in Journal of International Economics, vol. 71, pp. 344–372. The Economist (2008), “The Invasion of the Sovereign wealth-funds”, January Truman E.M., (2007) “SWF: the need for greater transparency and accountability”, Peterson Institute for International Economics Policy Brief. Stephen J,. Morgan Stanley, (2007) “How big could Sovereign Wealth Funds be by 2015?”, 4 May UNCTAD, (2006) WIR 2006 FDI From Developing And Transition Economies: Implication For Development, United Nations, New York and Geneva UNCTAD, (2007) WIR 2007 Transnational Corporations, Extractive Industries And Development, United Nations, New York and Geneva Yeaple S., (2003) “The role of skill endowments in the structure of Us outward foreign investments” in Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 85, pp. 726-734 42 Annex 1 - Swf operating on the international capital market Rank Country 1 Funds Assets (US$Billion) Origin CIC / SAFE / NCSSF / CADF 1,461.7 Non-commodity ADIA / ADIC / EIA / ICD / IPIC / MDC / RIA 1,246.8 Oil GPF 847.6[2][3] Oil 758.4 Oil 592 Oil China 2 United Arab Emirates 3 Norway 4 PIF / SAMA Saudi Arabia 5 Kuwait 6 KIA GIC / TH 537.6 Non-commodity HKMA 442.4 Non-commodity Singapore 7 Hong Kong 8 Qatar 9 QIA 256 Oil SKJSC / KNF / NIC 164.1 Oil RNWF / RRF / RDIF 152.2 Oil Kazakhstan 10 Russia 11 United APF / NMSIC / PWMTF / PSF / PUF / ATF / NDLF / LEQTF /CSF / WVFF 142.4** States 12 Oil & Gas / Non-commodity / Minerals / Public Lands AFF / WAFF 95.3 Non-commodity KIC 91.8 Non-commodity LIA 66 Oil NDFI 62 Oil RRF 50 Oil BIA 40 Oil OIF / SGRF 40 Gas / Oil Australia 13 South Korea 14 Libya 15 Iran 16 Algeria 17 Brunei 17 Oman 18 SOFAZ 37.3 Oil KN 34.9 Non-commodity SIF 25.5 Non-commodity NPRF 23.5 Non-commodity SESF / PRF 23.1 Copper/ Non-commodity NZSF 20.2 Non-commodity AHSTF 17.5 Oil / Non-commodity TLPF 16.9 Gas / Oil Azerbaijan 19 Malaysia 20 France 21 Ireland 22 Chile 23 New Zealand 24 Canada 25 East Timor 26 Finland 27 Solidium 11.5*** Non-commodity MHC 11.1 Oil FSF (or FEF) 9.2 Non-commodity Bahrain 28 Peru 29 Mexico 29 ORSFM 6 Oil ISF 6 Non-commodity PF 5.7 Diamonds / Minerals [1] 5.5 Oil SFB 5.3 Non-commodity Italy 30 Botswana 31 Trinidad and Tobago 32 Brazil 43 Rank Country 33 Funds FSDEA Assets (US$Billion) 5 Origin Oil Angola 34 Nigeria 35 NSIA / BDIC 2.9 Oil / Non-commodity FAP 1.2 Non-commodity FINPRO 1.2 Non-commodity 1 Non-commodity Panama 35 Bolivia 36 SSIF - FONSIS Senegal 37 DFI 0.9 Oil PIF 0.8 Non-commodity FEM 0.8 Oil RERF 0.6 Phosphates SCIC 0.5 Non-commodity GPF 0.45 Oil GSWF 0.4 Oil GIU 0.3 Non-commodity NFHR 0.3 Gas / Oil FSF 0.3 Mining FFG 0.08 Oil Iraq 38 Palestine 38 Venezuela 39 Kiribati 40 Vietnam 41 Ghana 42 Gabon 43 Indonesia 43 Mauritania 43 Mongolia 44 Equatorial Guinea TOTAL 7.297,93 ** The Oregon Common School Fund (CSF} is not in the Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute's list. However, it has been added here. *** Solidium is not in the Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute's list. However, it has been added here. 44 Annex 2 – Top operating SWFs n° Country Fund Billion $ Date of creation Source 1 Norway Government Pension Fund – Global $838 1990 Oil 2 UAE – Abu Dhabi Abu Dhabi Investment Authority $773 1976 Oil 3 Saudi Arabia SAMA Foreign Holdings $675.9 n/a Oil 4 China China Investment Corporation $575.2 2007 Non-Commodity 5 China SAFE Investment Company $567.9 1997 Non-Commodity 6 Kuwait Kuwait Investment Authority $410 1953 Oil 7 China – Hong Kong Hong Kong Monetary Authority Investment Portfolio $326.7 1993 Non-Commodity 8 Singapore Government of Singapore Investment Corporation $320 1981 Non-Commodity 9 Singapore Temasek Holdings $173.5 1974 Non-Commodity 10 Qatar Qatar Investment Authority $170 2005 Oil & Gas 11 China National Social Security Fund $160.6 2000 Non-Commodity 12 Australia Australian Future Fund $88.7 2006 Non-Commodity 13 Russia National Welfare Fund $88 2008 Oil 14 Russia Reserve Fund $86.4 2008 Oil 15 Kazakhstan Samruk-Kazyna JSC $77.5 2008 Non-Commodity 16 Algeria Revenue Regulation Fund $77.2 2000 Oil & Gas 17 South Korea Korea Investment Corporation $72 2005 Non-Commodity 18 UAE – Dubai Investment Corporation of Dubai $70 2006 Oil 19 Kazakhstan Kazakhstan National Fund $68.9 2000 Oil 20 Libya Libyan Investment Authority $66 2006 Oil 21 UAE – Abu Dhabi International Petroleum Investment Company $65.3 1984 Oil 22 Iran National Development Fund of Iran $58.6 2011 Oil & Gas 23 UAE – Abu Dhabi Mubadala Development Company $55.5 2002 Oil 24 US – Alaska Alaska Permanent Fund $49.5 1976 Oil 25 Malaysia Khazanah Nasional $40.5 1993 Non-Commodity 26 Brunei Brunei Investment Agency $40 1983 Oil 27 Azerbaijan State Oil Fund $34.1 1999 Oil 28 US – Texas Texas Permanent School Fund $30.3 1854 Oil & Other 29 France Strategic Investment Fund $25.5 2008 Non-Commodity 30 New Zealand New Zealand Superannuation Fund $20.3 2003 Non-Commodity 31 Kazakhstan National Investment Corporation $20 2012 Oil Source: Sovereign Wealth Funds Institute (March 2014) 45