Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Estimating Monthly GDP for a Small Open Economy: Structural versus Reduced-Form Mix-Frequency Models Ruey Yau Department of Economics National Central University Taoyuan, Taiwan February 2015 Abstract This paper compares monthly GDP estimates for a small open economy from two classes of mixed frequency models. One class is model-based and the other class is a reduced-form model. Our small open economy structural model is a New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE). DSGE modeling has become a popular framework by central banks for policy and forecasting in recent years, for such a model delivers strong theoretical coherence and is appropriate for policy evaluation. In addition, higher frequency observations may arrive for policy makers to include these timely information into their forecast framework. This paper evaluates how much a structural mixed-frequency model can help in generating more accurate estimates of monthly GDP and timely forecasting. The empirical model has a state space representation and is estimated by Kalman filter technique. JEL Classification: C5, E1 Keywords: DSGE model, mixed frequency, state-space representation, Kalman filter 1 Introduction Central banks or institutional analysts are often eager to get access to economic status for policy considerations or timely economic forecasts. Real GDP is considered as one of the most important measures of the aggregate state of an economy; however, it is only available on a quarterly basis. As an alternative, popular coincident indices of business cycles are estimated. Examples include the composite index of coincident indicators released by the U.S. Conference Board, the coincident indicators developed by Stock and Watson (1989, 1991), and the business condition indicator computed by Acruoba et al. (2009) are monthly series. The main criticism of such coincident indices is that they lack direct economic interpretation. To overcome such a criticism, a number of economists estimate monthly GDP directly. In terms of modeling methodology, some authors construct monthly GDP based on univariate models for real GDP, e.g. Bernanke et al. (1997) and Liu and Hall (2001), and others apply multivariate approach, such as Mariano and Murasawa (2003, 2010). These studies are in line with the ‘common factor’ approach proposed by Stock and Watson (1989, 1991). Their basic statistical method is to build state-space models with mixed-frequency series. Being abstract from structural modeling, the common factor approach like the VAR approach is a reduced-form method. The coefficients estimated in such a model are not subject to any structural restrictions. Different from the aforementioned studies that build upon reduced-form time series frameworks, some recent studies consider to merge structural macroeconomic model with the mixed frequency strategy. Two important contributions are Giannone et al. (2009) and Foroni and Marcellino (2014). Giannone et al. (2009) develop a framework to incorporate monthly information in quarterly dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models. They take the parameter estimates from the quarterly DSGE as given and obtain increasing accurate early forecasts of the quarterly variables. Foroni and Marcellino (2014) demonstrate that temporal aggregation bias, as pointed out in Christiano and Eichenbaum (1987), may arise when economists estimate a quarterly DSGE while agents’ true decision interval is on a monthly basis. They propose a mixed-frequency strategy to estimate the DSGE model and find that the temporal aggregation bias can be alleviated.1 However, there are no general rules on to 1 Some other recent studies with the mixed frequency strategy include the fixed-frequency VAR model in Schorfheide and Song (2011) and Rondeau (2012). The latter combines quarterly series with annual series in an effort to estimate a DSGE model for emerging economies. 1 what extent such a complicated framework helps in forecasting real GDP, since it depends on the structure of the DSGE model and on the content of higher frequency available. In this paper we develop a mixed-frequency structural model for a small open economy. The main purpose is to assess the advantage of estimating real GDP from a mixed frequency model with a structural context. We assume that economic agents make decision monthly. Because real GDP is a quarterly series, mixed-frequency technique is adopted to provide early estimates and forecasts. Based on a monthly small open DSGE, we derive its mixfrequency state-space representation. This estimation framework is applied to Taiwan. For comparison, we also estimate a reduced-form mixed frequency model by applying Kalman filter estimation technique of Acruoba et al. (2009). A few other studies are related this paper. Boivin and Giannoni (2006) incorporate a large data set that contains additional variables (i.e. non-core variables) that are not considered in a DSGE model. Their approach is appealing conceptually, because it exploits information contained in the other indicators when making inferences about the latent state of the economy. The DSGE model parameters as well as the factor loadings for the noncore variables are jointly estimated using Bayesian methods. Nevertheless, their study solely employs data at the quarterly frequency. In reality, higher frequency information may arrive and central banks or institutional forecasters would like to include the additional information in their forecasting framework. Rubaszek and Skrzypczynski (2008) and Edge et al. (2008) have surveyed the literature on evaluating the forecasting properties of the DSGE model in a real-time environment. Schorgheide, Sill, and Kryshko (2010) examine whether a DSGE model could be used to forecast variables that are not included in structural model. Instead of jointly estimating all the parameters in the system, they suggest a two-step Bayesian method to reduce the computational burden. The next section lays out the models we use, including a small open DSGE, its implied structural mixed frequency state space model, and a reduced-form mixed frequency state space model. representation. Section 3 presents the empirical findings and the final section concludes. 2 The Models The goal of this paper is to study the extent to which the incorporation of monthly observations via DSGE framework improves estimates of the model parameters and produce forecast 2 gains. We assume that the agents in the economy make decisions on a monthly basis. Based on a small open economy DSGE model, we derive its mixed-frequency state-space representation and estimate the model with maximimum likelihood method. To assess the forecast performance, we also estimate a monthly reduced-form mix-frequency model. 2.1 A Log-Linearized Small Open DSGE Model The structural small open-economy model used in this paper is taken from Lubik and Schorfheide (2007), which is a simplified version of Gali and Monacelli (2005). The model is derived from a structural New Keynesian DSGE model that consists of households, firms and a central bank. Given that the decision rules of agents form a system of nonlinear difference equations with rational expectations, a log-linear approximation to this system around its steady state is derived. The log-linearized model consists of the following equations: γ ∗ , yt = Et yt+1 − [τ + γ)](Rt − Et πt+1 + αEt ∆qt+1 ) − ρa at + Et ∆yt+1 τ πt = βEt πt+1 + αβEt ∆qt+1 − α∆qt + κ (yt − ȳt ), τ +γ ∆et = πt − πt∗ − (1 − α)∆qt , ∆qt = (1) (2) (3) 1 (∆yt∗ − ∆yt ) + εq,t , τ +γ (4) Rt = ρR Rt−1 + (1 − ρR )[ψπ πt + ψy (yt − ȳt ) + ψe ∆et ] + εR,t , (5) where at = ρa at−1 + εa,t (6) ∗ yt∗ = ρy∗ yt−1 + εy∗ ,t (7) ∗ + επ∗ ,t πt∗ = ρπ∗ πt−1 (8) and γ = α(2 − α)(1 − τ ). Eq (1) is essentially an open-economy IS curve. It is derived from the consumption Euler equation of a representative household who makes decisions on consumption of domestic goods and imported goods, labor supply, and investment. It describes how aggregate output (yt ) is related to its future expected value, the expected real interest rate (Rt − Et πt+1 ), the expected change in terms of trade (Et ∆qt+1 ), the growth rate of world technology (at ), ∗ and the expected world output growth (Et ∆yt+1 ). In this equation, τ is the intertemporal 3 substitution elasticity, ρa is the first-order autocorrelation coefficient in the dynamic process of at , and α is the import share that measures the degree of openness with α = 0 in a closed economy. The terms of trade, qt , is defined as the relative price of exports in terms of imports. The world output, yt∗ , is exogenous to the small open economy. Eq (2) is the Phillips curve derived from the optimal pricing setting behavior of domestic firms. Under the New Keynesian pricing scheme considered in Calvo (1983), there are nominal rigidities in the domestic goods sector. In this equation, β is the discount factor, κ measures the degree of price stickiness and ȳt = [−α(2 − α)(1 − τ )/τ ]yt∗ is the potential output in the absence of nominal rigidities. Eq (3) illustrates the dynamics in the nominal exchange rate (et ), with rising value in et indicating a depreciation in the domestic currency. This equation states that dynamics in the nominal exchange rate is explained by the deviation from the purchasing power parity, πt −πt∗ , and is adjusted by a fraction of changes in the terms of trade, ∆qt , when the economy is not completely open to the world economy. Eq (4) describes the behavior of the terms of trade as a function of the relative demand changes in the world and the domestic market. When the growth of world output is higher than the growth of domestic output, the demand for the domestically produced goods rises so that the terms of trade improve. In the equation, εq,t is an exogenous terms of trade shock or measurement error. Eq (5) describes the central bank’s monetary policy rule, that is to raise its interest rate in response to an increase in CPI inflation, positive output gap, and currency depreciation, where ρR is an indicator of interest rate smoothing, ψi ’s are the policy reaction coefficients, and εR,t is the exogenous shock to monetary policy and is assumed to be a white noise process. Following Lubik and Schorfheide (2007), in equations (6)- (8) we assume the world technology growth (at ), the world output (yt∗ ), and the world inflation shock (πt∗ ) all evolve according to univariate AR(1) processes with autoregressive coefficients ρj ’s. Together with the shocks to monetary policy (εR,t ) and the shocks to terms of trade (εq,t ), there are five structural shocks. These shocks are assumed to be mutually independent and distributed as εj,t ∼ iidN (0, σj2 ), for j = a, R, q, π ∗ and y ∗ . 4 2.2 State-Space Representation of the DSGE Model The log-linearized rational expectations model can be solved with a numerical method and the solution is transformed into a state-space representation, where the measurement equation relates the model’s variables to the observable ones and the state equation describes the law of motion of the endogenous and driving forces in the model.2 0 Let St = [Rt , yt , πt , ∆et , ∆qt , yt∗ , πt∗ , at ] denote the vector of non-predetermined endogenous variables that contains endogenous state variables and exogenous driving force variables 0 and εt = [εa,t , εR,t , εq,t , επ∗ ,t , εy∗ ,t ] denote the vector of exogenous structural shocks. The solution to the log-linearized rational expectations model has the following form of transition for state variables: St = Φ1 (θ)St−1 + Φ2 (θ)εt , (9) where Φ1 and Φ2 have elements as functions of the deep parameters (θ) from the model and we denote Σε as the diagonal variance matrix of underlying structural shocks εt . To estimate the DSGE model, a measurement equation based on a set of observables Yt is added as Yt = Λ(θ)St + ut , (10) where Λ(θ) defines the relationship between the observed variables and states and ut is the measurement error term. Jointly, equations (9) and (10) form a state-space representation.3 In a conventional DSGE model estimation, eq (9) is usually timed at the quarterly frequency. This assumption is imposed mainly because real output measure such as GDP does not have monthly observations. However, as argued in Aadland and Huang (2004), Kim (2010), and Foroni and Marcellino (2014), if the true decision period is a month, then assuming instead a quarter may lead to misspecification error or temporal aggregation bias. In the following, we describe how to estimate the monthly DSGE model of (9)-(10) with a mixed-frequency framework. 2 The most popular solution methods are Sims (2002), Blanchard and Kahn (1980), Klein (2000), and Uhlig (1999). 3 In the empirical analysis of Lubik and Schorfheide (2007), the choice for the vector of of observable Yt is composed of annualized interest rates, annualized inflation rates, GDP growth, currency depreciation 0 rate, and changes of the terms of trade. That is, Yt = [4Rt , 4πt , ∆yt + at , ∆et , ∆qt ] . We will estimate the model with another set of observables, including variables that are available at high frequency, in the mixed-frequency model. 5 2.3 A Structural Mixed-Frequency Model Given the assumption that agents made decisions at monthly frequency, our next task is to estimate the monthly model of (9)-(10). Because there are many missing values in this monthly econometric model, our first task is to handle unobserved flow and stock variables differently. The time index t is at monthly frequency. Let yit be the ith element of Yt , and ỹit be the same variable in month t that is observed at the quarterly frequency. If it is a variable with monthly observations, then ỹit = yit ∀t. If it is a stock variable with quarterly observations, ỹit is equal to yit in the last month of each quarter and is a missing value otherwise. Specifically, yit if t = MAR, JUN, SEP, DEC, ỹit = NA otherwise. When it is a flow variable with quarterly observations, the temporal aggregation problem arises. In the last month of each quarter, ỹit is the sum of yit over the past three months, and is a missing value otherwise. yit + yit−1 + yit−2 if t = MAR, JUN, SEP, DEC, ỹit = NA otherwise. For example, GDP is a quarterly flow variable, and the relationship between yit and ỹit is ˜ t = GDPt + GDPt−1 + GDPt−2 . GDP We can write compactly the aggregation rule of monthly observations into quarterly ones as Ỹt = H(L)Yt = H0 Yt + H1 Yt−1 + H2 Yt−2 . (11) Then, the measurement equation (10) can be modified as Ỹt = [ H0 Λ(θ) H1 Λ(θ) H2 Λ(θ) H0 H1 6 H2 ] St St−1 St−2 ut ut−1 ut−2 . . (12) Next, the state equation (9) is St Φ1 (θ) 0 St−1 I 0 I St−2 0 u = 0 0 t ut−1 0 0 ut−2 0 0 extended as 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 I 0 0 0 0 I 0 St−1 St−2 St−3 ut−1 ut−2 ut−3 + Φ2 (θ) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 I 0 0 εt u . t (13) 0 Define a new vector of state variables as ft = [St , St−1 , St−2 , ut , ut−1 , ut−2 ] and a new vector 0 of measurement errors as ηt = [εt , ut ] . Then, eq. (12)-(13) form a mixed-frequency statespace representation based on the structural model described in the previous section and can be expressed compactly as Ỹt = Gθ ft , (14) ft = Mθ ft−1 + Pθ ηt , (15) with the covariance matrix of the new error term as 0 Σε 0 . Eηt ηt = 0 Σu To sum up, our DSGE empirical model with mixed frequency consists of the state equation (15) and the measurement equation (14). They form a mixed-frequency state-space representation because there are missing values in Ỹt when the variable is only available at quarterly frequency. The goal is to jointly estimate the structural parameters of the theoretical model {θ, Σε , Σu } and the measurement equation parameters in (14), if any. Based on the monthly frequency state space representation, the model is estimated with maximum likelihood method with the likelihood function being evaluated by the Kalman filter algorithm proposed in Acruoba, Diebold and Scotti (2009). 2.4 A Reduced-Form Mixed-Frequency Model To assess whether the structural model helps in short-term forecast, we estimate a reducedform mixed-freqency model with the same set of observable variables as stated in the previous section with structural model. We assume in the reduced-form model that the endogenous variables in vector Yt links to a single business condition indicator, or a single dynamic factor along the line of Stock and Watson (1989, 1991), in the following form: Yt = Axt + wt , (16) 7 where xt is the single indicator that summarizes the current economic and business condition and wt is a vector of measurement errors with covariance matrix Σw . In this reduced-form equation, the coefficient vector A contains free parameters to be estimated. We assume that the single business condition indicator follows an AR(1) process: xt = ρxt−1 + ζt , (17) where ζt is the shock to xt with zero mean and variance σζ2 . Given the measurement equation (16) and state equation (17), a state-space for this reduced-form model is derived after incorporating the aggregate rule (11): Ỹt = G∗ ft∗ , (18) ∗ ft∗ = M ∗ ft−1 + P ∗ ηt∗ , (19) 0 where the corresponding state vector is ft∗ = [xt , xt−1 , xt−2 , wt , wt−1 , wt−2 ] , the vector of 0 measurement errors is ηt∗ = [ζt , wt ] . 3 Empirical Results In this section, the estimation precision and forecast assessment is conducted for the Taiwanese data. The sample period covers from 1983:Q1 to 2007:Q4. For the variables in the DSGE model, R is the annualized call rate, y is detrended real GDP in logarithm, π is demeaned GDP deflator inflation rate in annual percentage, ∆e is the depreciation rate of Taiwan dollars against U.S. dollars, ∆q is the logarithm of the terms of trade index, y ∗ is detrended U.S. real GDP in logarithm. (To be continued) References Aadland, D. and K.X.D. Huang (2004). Consistent high-frequency calibration, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28, 2277-2295. Acruoba, B., F. Diebold, and C. Scotti (2009). Real-time measurement of business conditions, Journal of Business Economics and Statistics, 27(4), 417-427. 8 Adolfson M., S. Laseen, J. Linde, and M. Villani (2007a). Bayesian estimation of an open economy DSGE model with incomplete pass-through, Journal of International Economics, 72, 481-511. Adolfson M., J. Linde, and M. Villani (2007b). Forecasting performance of an open economy DSGE model, Econometric Review, 26, 289-328. Bai, J., E. Ghsels, and J.H. Wright (2011). State space models and MIDAS regressions, Manuscript, Johns Hopkins University. Bernanke, B.S., Gertler, M. and Watson, M.W. (1997). Systematic monetary policy and the effects of oil price shocks. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 91V157. Blanchard, O. and C. Kahn (1980). The solution of difference equations under rational expectations, Econometrica, 48, 1305-1311. Boivin, J. and M. Giannoni (2006). DSGE models in a data-rich environment, NBER Working Paper. Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383-398. Christiano, L.J. and M. Eichenbaum (1987). Temporal aggregation and structural inference in macroeconomics, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 26, 64-130. Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. Evans (2005). Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy, Journal of Political Economy, 113, 1-45. Coenen, G., P. McAdam, and R. Straub (2008). Tax reform and labor market performance in the Euro area: A simulation-based analysis using the New Area-Wide model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32, 2543-2583. Del Negro, M. and F. Schorfheide (2004). Priors from General Equilibrium Models for VARs, International Economic Review, 45, 643-673. Edge, R., M. Kiley, and J. Laforte (2008). A comparison of forecast performance between Federal Reserve Staff forecasts, simple reduced-form models, and a DSGE model, Manuscript, Federal Reserve Board of Governors. Foroni, C. and Marcellino, M. (2014). Mixed-frequency structural models: Identification, estimation, and policy analysis. Journal of Applied Econometrics 29, 1118-1144. Frale, C., M. Marcellino, G.L. Mazzi, and L. Proietti (2008). A monthly indicator of the Euro area GDP, EUI Working Paper. Gali, J. and T. Monacelli (2005), Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy, Review of Economic Studies, 72, 707-734. 9 Ghysels, E., P. Santa-Clara, and R. Valkanov (2006). Predicting volatility: Getting the most out of return data sampled at different frequencies, Journal of Econometrics, 131(1), 59-95. Ghysels, E., A. Sinko, and R. Valkanov (2007). The MIDAS regressions: Further results and new directions, Econometric Reviews, 26(1), 53-90. Giannone, D., L. Reichlin, and D. Small (2008). Nowcasting: The real-time informational content of macroeconomic data, Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, 665-676. Giannone D., Monti, F., and Reichlin, L. (2009). Incorporating conjunctural analysis in structural models. In The Science and Practice of Monetary Policy Today. Springer: Berlin, 41-57. Justiniano, A. and B. Preston (2008). Monetary policy and uncertainty in an empirical small open economy model, Working paper. Justiniano, A. and G. Primeceri (2008). Monetary policy and uncertainty in an empirical small open economy model, working paper. Kim, T.B. (2010). Temporal aggregation bias and mixed frequency estimation of New Keynesian model. Duke University: Mimeo. Klein, P. (2000). Using the generalized Schur form to solve a multivariate linear rational expectations model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24, 1405-1423. Liu, H. and Hall, S.G. (2001). Creating high-frequency national accounts with state-space modelling: a Monte Carlo experiment. Journal of Forecasting 20, 441V449. Lubik, T., and Schorfheide, F. (2005). A Bayesian Look at New Open Economy Macroeconomics, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 20, 313-366. Lubik, T., and Schorfheide, F. (2007). Do central banks respond to exchange rate movements? A structural investigation, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 1069-1087. Mariano, R.S., and Y. Murasawa (2003). A new coincident index of business cycles based on monthly and quarterly series, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(4), 427-443. Mariano, R. and Murasawa, Y. (2010). A coincident index, common factors, and monthly real GDP. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 72, 27-46. Rondeau, S. (2012). Sources of fluctuations in emerging markets: DSGE estimation with mixed frequency data, Ph.D. thesis, Columbia University. Rubaszek, M. and P. Skrzypczynski (2008). On the forecasting performance of a small-scale DSGE model, International Journal of Forecasting, 24, 498-512. 10 Schorfheide, F., K. Sill, and M. Kryshko (2010). DSGE model-based forecasting of nonmodelled variables, International Journal of Forecasting, 26, 348-373. Schorfheide, F. and D. Song (2011). Real-time forecasting with a mixed frequency VAR, Working Paper. Sims, C.A. (2002). Solving linear rational expectations models, Computational Economics, 20, 1-20. Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2004). Forecasting with a Bayesian DSGE model: An application to the Euro area, Journal of Common Market Study, 42, 841-867. Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2007). Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach, American Economic Review, 97, 586-606. Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W. (1989). New indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators, NBER Macroeconomics Annual 4, 351-409. Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W. (1991). A probability model of the coincident economic indicators, in Lahiri K. and Moore G. H. (eds), Leading Economic Indicators, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 63-89. Teo, W.L. (2009). Estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the Taiwanese economy, Pacific Economic Review, 14, 194-231. Uhlig, H. (1999). A toolkit for analyzing nonlinear dynamic stochastic models easily, in Marimon, R., Scott, A. (eds.) Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK., 114-142. 11 Table 1: Parameter Estimation Parameter Estimate S.D. ψπ ψy ψe κ τ ρR ρa ρy ∗ ρπ∗ ρa σq σa σy ∗ σπ∗ σR 1.31 0.37 0.44 0.40 0.22 0.87 0.79 0.92 0.74 0.88 1.4 1.1 1.62 2.3 0.35 12 (0.25) (0.16) (0.32) (0.14) (0.09) (0.22) (0.20) (0.32) (0.15) (0.29) (0.44) (0.21) (0.20) (0.75) (0.08)