Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Lindahl Pricing and Equilibrium – Proof of Pareto Optimality A Lindahl equilibrium is a method for finding the efficient level of provision for public goods. Recall that for public goods, in equilibrium all agents consume the same quantity but may face different prices1. As it is framed in our textbook, the Lindahl equilibrium occurs when the perunit price paid by each agent sums to the total per unit cost of the public good. The Graph We start with a good ol’ fashioned demand curve for a public good. The lower the price of the good, the more Person 1 wants to consume. Now imagine that the dashed horizontal line is the full price of the good. At this point, the demand curve makes it look like Person 1 will demand very little. But what if rather than the price dropping, the percentage of the price he have to pay goes down? As far as Person 1 is concerned, this is equivalent to the price he sees going down, so he’ll demand more. Full price Price * 50% Price * 25% Price * 0% D1 Qfull price QPrice * 50% QPrice * 25% Q Now lets look at another demand curve (Person 2). This person sees the vertical axis flipped the other way around, with the full price on the bottom and percentage decreasing as one moves upward. Like Person 1, Person 2 will demand more as her observed price goes down. Price * 0% D2 Price * 50% Full price Qfull price QPrice * 50% Q 1 This differs from equilibrium of private goods, which instead has all agents viewing the same price with the possibility to consume different quantities. Prepared by Nick Sanders, UC Davis Graduate Department of Economics 2006 Again, note that here Person 2’s observed price going down means we move further up the vertical axis. Equilibrium is when both of these people demand the same amount of the public good. This happens when the two demand curves intersect each other. If we draw a line over to the price axis from that point of intersection, we get the percentage share for each agent that is required to get that price. Person 2 P*55% D2 Person 1 P*45% D1 Full price = P Q* Q So Person 1 is paying P*45% per unit, Person 2 is paying P*55% per unit, and the economy produces Q* units. Here we have a Lindahl equilibrium, and the corresponding prices are called Lindahl prices. But is it a Pareto Optimal (PO) equilibrium? Well, recall from the last couple of chapters that a PO allocation occurs with public goods when the sum of the marginal rates of substitution equals the marginal rate of transformation. So if we can show that holds true in a Lindahl equilibrium, we know it is PO. The Math Let’s say there are two goods: a public good, and “everything else”. Call the price of the public good Ppublic and the price of everything else Pelse. Under the current system, no one actually sees the full price of the public good – they just see the percentage that’s been allocated to them in equilibrium. In the graph above, that turned out to be P*45% for Person 1 and P*55% for Person 2. In general lets call the percentage that Person 1 pays α, and the percentage that Person 2 pays (1-α). If Person 1 is a utility maximizer, we know that he’ll choose a bundle where " * Ppublic = MRSPerson1 Pevery (1) This is just the usual price ratio/marginal rate of substitution deal . . . the only change is that we multiply Ppublic by α to allow for the price adjustment to the public good. Similarly, Person 2 will ! their bundle such that choose Prepared by Nick Sanders, UC Davis Graduate Department of Economics 2006 (1" # ) * Ppublic = MRSPerson 2 Pevery (2) So now we have both agents utility maximizing . . . so far, so good. We know that in a competitive equilibrium, it must be the marginal cost ratio (price ratio) is equal to the marginal ! transformation, or rate of MC public Ppublic = = MRT MCevery Pevery (3) What we set out to show was that the Lindahl equilibrium is PO. That would require that ! MRSPerson1 + MRSPerson 2 = MRT Using (1), (2), and (3) ! MRSPerson1 + MRSPerson 2 = " * Ppublic (1# " ) * Ppublic + Pevery Pevery = " * Ppublic # " * Ppublic + 1* Ppublic Pevery = Ppublic Pevery = MRT As they say in mathematical circles, Q.E.D.2 ! The Issues As with all good ideas in economics, there are some issues with real world applications of the Lindahl equilibrium. For one, it assumes that we know each individuals preferences. What if people intentionally hide their true willingness to pay? This starts getting into the “free rider” problem issue again, where people decide to let others cover the costs, but reap the benefits themselves. Even if we DID know exactly what everyone’s preferences were, things would still get significantly more complicated as there were more and more people involved in the discussion. It’s one thing to get two people to agree on some provision of a public good, but getting a city of 100,000 people to do so is just plain nuts3. 2 It’s an abbreviation for the Latin phrase “quod erat demonstrandum”, or “that which was to be demonstrated”. It basically means the proof is done . . . use it to impress your friends and family. 3 Basically, that means we’re dealing with up to 100,000 prices for just one good. This makes finding an equilibrium much, much harder. Prepared by Nick Sanders, UC Davis Graduate Department of Economics 2006