Download The current account and precautionary savings for

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup

Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Journal of International Economics
j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w. e l s ev i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / j i e
The current account and precautionary savings for exporters of
exhaustible resources☆
Rudolfs Bems ⁎, Irineu de Carvalho Filho
International Monetary Fund, Research Department, 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, DC 20431, United States
a r t i c l e
i n f o
Article history:
Received 10 August 2009
Received in revised form 13 January 2011
Accepted 24 February 2011
Available online 5 March 2011
JEL classifications:
F41
E21
a b s t r a c t
Exporters of exhaustible resources have historically exhibited higher income volatility than other economies,
suggesting a heightened role for precautionary savings. This paper uses a parameterized small open-economy
model to quantify the role of precautionary savings for exporters of exhaustible resources, when the only
source of uncertainty is the price of the exhaustible resource. The parameterized model fares moderately well
at capturing current account balances in both cross-section and time-series data. The results show that the
precautionary motive can generate sizable external sector savings, the more so the greater the weight of
exhaustible resource revenues in future income.
© 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Small open economy
Exhaustible resources
Precautionary savings
1. Introduction
Exporters of exhaustible resources have historically exhibited
considerably higher income volatility than other economies, suggesting a heightened role for the precautionary motive and related
accumulation of buffer stock savings. Indeed, these exporters have
accumulated sizable external savings over the last decade, contributing significantly towards global current account imbalances. How
much of these savings can be attributed to the precautionary motive?
This paper documents the relevant empirical regularities and
constructs a model that allows for estimation of the size of precautionary savings for exporters of exhaustible resources. To gauge
the link between income volatility and savings, we use a representative agent small open economy model modified to account for an
exhaustible resource sector with the price of the exhaustible resource
as the only source of uncertainty. To focus on the external savings
problem, the model abstracts from domestic investment and resource
☆ We thank Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti for suggesting the topic and the editor in
charge, two anonymous referees, Ran Bi, Olivier Jeanne, Lutz Kilian, Jaewoo Lee, Andre
Meier, Jonathan Ostry, Alessandro Rebucci, David Romer, Damiano Sandri, Abdelhak
Senhadji, Radek Stefanski, Saudi Arabian authorities, participants at the IMF RES
Seminar, NY Fed International Macro seminar and OxCarre conference for the valuable
comments and suggestions. We also thank Huigang Chen and Gabriel Lipsa for the help
with the numerical solution. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors
and do not necessarily represent those of the International Monetary Fund.
⁎ Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: [email protected] (R. Bems), idecarvalhofi[email protected]
(I. de Carvalho Filho).
0022-1996/$ – see front matter © 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.02.004
extraction decisions as well as from explicit insurance against shocks
to export prices. We argue that these considerations are not of primary importance, when estimating precautionary savings for exporters of exhaustible resources. The representative agent then solves a
self-insurance problem, whereby accumulation of foreign assets
diversifies income away from the volatile exhaustible resources.
Precautionary savings are represented by the change in (external)
savings due to this self-insurance motive. The model is parameterized
to replicate the relevant country-specific characteristics of thirteen oil
and gas exporting economies whose exhaustible resource sectors
account for a significant share of economic activity.
The framework is shown to yield quantitative predictions about a
range of phenomena.
The model fares moderately well at capturing historical external
savings behavior in both time-series and cross-section data. Annual
changes in current account balances in the model and data exhibit
a positive correlation with a mean of 0.70. During the post-2000 price
boom, the model generates 2/3 of the accumulated current account
surpluses in data. In a cross-section, the correlation between changes
in net foreign assets, as a share of GDP, in the model and data is 0.73.
The modeling framework allows for a decomposition of external
savings into an intertemporal consumption smoothing component,
which is present even in the absence of uncertainty, and a precautionary savings component. We find that the consumption smoothing
motive is the main determinant of the size of the current account.
At the same time, the precautionary motive can generate sizable
additional external savings and improves the model's fit with data.
These findings are robust to the choice of parameter values and
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
modeling assumptions. In terms of quantitative results, precautionary
savings in 2007 add up to 1% of the sample countries' GDP or 36 billion
dollars. Results for other years are similar in magnitude. The
importance of the precautionary motive varies considerably across
countries and is driven by the weight of exhaustible resource revenues
in expected discounted future income.
In addition to providing estimates for the size of precautionary
savings, the paper contributes to the literature by developing a small
open economy model with aggregate uncertainty, where the net
foreign asset position in the stationary equilibrium is not restricted to
some exogenous value. As has been repeatedly noted (e.g., SchmittGrohé and Uribe, 2003; Ghironi, 2007), the representative agent small
open economy model with aggregate uncertainty exhibits unit root
dynamics in net foreign assets and therefore does not harbor a welldefined stationary equilibrium. The model of this paper avoids this
problem by assuming that the only source of aggregate uncertainty is
the price of the exhaustible resource. Once the resource is exhausted,
the model becomes deterministic. As a result, the value of net foreign
assets in the stationary equilibrium is determined endogenously and
depends on the model's initial conditions as well as the history of
subsequent shocks.
This paper deviates from the extensive literature on precautionary
savings (e.g., Caballero, 1990; Carroll, 2001 and references therein)
along several dimensions. First, it deals with aggregate, as opposed to
idiosyncratic, shocks. Second, the focus is on open economies, with
savings taking place through the external sector. Third, while the
previous literature has concentrated exclusively on advanced economies, the sample in this paper includes both developed and developing
countries.
Two previous studies are closely related to our work. Ghosh and
Ostry (1997) find that aggregate income uncertainty increases current
account balances in a group of advanced economies. Fogli and Perri
(2006) show that differences in precautionary savings, induced by
lower income volatility in the US relative to the rest of the world, can
explain a significant share of the US current account deficits since early
1980s. Both studies find that the link between aggregate income
volatility and external savings is economically significant. For the more
volatile and open exporters of exhaustible resources, this channel is
likely to have added relevance.
Another strand of related literature deals with the intergenerational
equity in exhaustible resource countries. In essence, consumption
smoothing considerations in the deterministic version of our modeling
framework are used to determine the intertemporal allocation of exhaustible resource income.1 Such a model can generate the large current
account surpluses observed in exhaustible resource countries. Our
paper differs from this literature, since we explicitly model the effects of
uncertainty on the external sector dynamics. In the presence of a
precautionary motive, the deterministic model overestimates consumption and therefore underestimates the size of savings and the
current account balance in the short run, more so the greater the uncertainty attached to the exhaustible resource wealth and the larger the
weight of exhaustible resources in economic activity.
The structure of the rest of the paper is as follows. The next section
summarizes the empirical regularities that motivate our study. Section 3
presents the model and its optimal solution. Section 4 discusses the
parameterization procedure and examines the fit between the model
outcomes and historical data. Section 5 decomposes external savings in
the model into two components — consumption smoothing and
precautionary savings. Section 6 performs extensive sensitivity analysis
of the model results. Finally, Section 7 concludes.
1
This modeling framework has been advocated in Davis et al. (2003) and applied by
numerous studies (see, e.g., de Carvalho Filho, 2007 for an application to Trinidad and
Tobago, Takizawa, 2005 for Kuwait, Bailen and Kramarenko, 2004 for Iran and Thomas
et al., 2008 for a cross-country study).
49
2. Income volatility and channels of diversification
This section documents the high income volatility in exhaustible
resource countries and the extent to which high income volatility is
transmitted into volatility of consumption. We also examine the role of
various channels in reducing the volatility of consumption. Throughout
the paper the definition of exhaustible resources is restricted to oil and
gas, for which there are country-level estimates available on historical
resource extraction and the size of the remaining stock of resources.
The volatility of income in exhaustible resource countries has been
2–3 times higher than in other economies (see panel a in Fig. 1). This
finding remains valid in sample sub-periods (see panel a in Fig. 2).
Although income volatility has decreased in recent decades, exhaustible resource countries continue to stand out. As of 2007, the 10-year
rolling income volatility in exhaustible resource countries was more
than twice the volatility in other economies and substantially larger
than in major non-fuel commodity exporting countries.
The finding of high income volatility in exhaustible resource
countries is consistent with other results in the literature. Easterly
et al. (1993) and Broda (2004) among others report a significant
correlation between output volatility and terms of trade volatility,
while Baxter and Kouparitsas (2006) find that terms of trade volatility
is the highest in fuel-exporting countries. Heightened income
volatility in exhaustible resource countries stems from a combination
of more volatile exhaustible resource prices, even when compared to
other commodities, and a larger share of the volatile oil and gas
component in total income. It should also be noted that exhaustible
resource prices exhibit considerably larger variation than extraction
quantities. At an annual frequency, prices over the most recent oil
price cycle, i.e., 1980–2007, were 2–3 time more volatile than
country-level extraction quantities.2
In contrast to income volatility, differences in the volatility of
consumption for exhaustible resource countries are less pronounced.
Panels a–b in Fig. 1 show that over the last half-century, the difference in
the volatility of income of exporters of exhaustible resources and other
countries has been larger than the difference in the volatility of
consumption. Moreover, the difference in the volatility of consumption
has altogether disappeared from 1990s onwards (see panel b in Fig. 2),
as the volatility of consumption in exhaustible resource countries
decreased to levels comparable to the other economies. Panels c in
Figs. 1 and 2 present further quantitative evidence for the gap between
income and consumption volatilities in exhaustible resource countries.
This group of countries has exhibited historical ratios of consumption
volatility to income volatility in the range of 0.5–0.7. In other economies
the same ratios have been close to 1. Finally, panel d in Fig. 1 reports the
correlation between income and consumption. Again, exhaustible
resource countries exhibit lower income–consumption correlations
than other economies. These empirical results indicate that countries
with exhaustible resources have been able to smooth consumption in
the face of large income shocks.
Next we investigate the channels through which volatility of
consumption is mitigated. In theory, a country could insure against
exhaustible resource income volatility by locking in future sale prices
or by altogether selling the remaining stock of the resource. But usage
of such tools remains very limited. Contrary to the prescriptions of
economic theory, domestic ownership of exhaustible resources in
major oil producing countries has been on the rise in recent decades
and markets for hedging resource price fluctuations remain very
small. As of April 2009, the total open interest in exchanges and overthe-counter markets for hedging resource price fluctuations was
estimated at only 4 weeks of world oil consumption and 0.18% of
proven oil reserves (see Borensztein et al., 2009). Daniel (2001)
2
If one excluded the two Gulf Wars, prices are 4 times more volatile than extraction
quantities (British Petroleum, 2008).
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
(a) Income volatility
(b) Consumption volatility
St.dev. of per capita GDP/CPI growth
0.25
ECU
OMN
KWT
0.2
SAU
GAB
0.15
ARE
NGA
QAT
ZAR
UGA
SDN
PER
IRN
MWI
ZWE
0.1
ETH
GHA
URY
SYR
RWA
SLV
BDI
LSO CHL
SWZ
BOL
PNG
KEN
BWA
ARG
JOR
CMR
NER
DOM
BRA
TUR
JAM
CIV MYS
NPL
BFA
GMB
CRI
IDN
KOR
IRL
MDG
PAN
0.05 HND
EGY
HKG
MEX
SENCOL
MAR
PRY
ISR
THA
PRT
PHL
ZAF
MUS
FIN
IND
LKA
JPN
HUN
PAK
GTM
NLD
NZL
NOR
CAN
ESP
DNK
ITAAUS
SWE
CHE
USA
AUT
FRA
GBR
0
-10
0
10
TTO DZA
VEN
20
30
40
50
60
St.dev. of per capita consumption/CPI growth
50
0.25
ECU
0.2
OMN
0.15
ZAR
PER
SWZ
UGA
SDN
0.1
0.05
0
-10
Mean oil&gas balance, percent of GDP
0
10
TTO
ARE
SAU
IRN
QAT
VEN
DZA
20
30
40
50
60
Mean oil&gas balance, percent of GDP
(c) Ratio of consumption to income volatility
(d) Correlation of income and consumption
1
2
ECU
NLD
UGA
IRL
RWA
SLV
SDN
NPL
GHA
ETH
ZWE
TUR
PER
BDI
JPN
USA
BRA
EGYSYR
MEX
COL
ZAR
PRT
GTM
ITA
MAR
KEN
THA
DOM
KOR
CRI
BFA
JAM
ARG
DNK
CMR
IND
HKG
NER
GMB
MDG
PAK
0.8 HND
GBR
CAN
MUS
CHE BOL
SEN
SWE
ESP
JOR CHL
FRA
PRY
ZAF MYS
NZL
FIN
URY
SWZ MWI
PHL
PANAUT
0.6
CIV
HUN
AUS
SWZ
1.5
1
GAB KWT
ZWE
ETH
GHA
BDI
SYR
PNG
KEN
RWA
JORMWI
SLV
JAM
CMR
NER
DOM
ARG
BRA
CRI
URY
PAN
GMB
TUR
BFA BOL
LSO NPL
PRY
BWA
CHL
LKA
IRL MEX
MYS
ISR
MDG
HND
CIVEGY
SEN
KOR
ZAF
COL IDN
THA
IND
PAK
PHL
PRT
NLD
HUN
MAR
HKG
MUS
FIN
JPN
GTM
NZL
AUT
ESP
NOR
ITA
DNK
USA
GBR
CAN
SWE
CHE
AUS
FRA
LKA
PAN
CRI
JAM
JORPRY
PNG
KEN
BDI
CMR
GMB
DOM
ISR
NLD
BRA
NER
ZAF
BFA
PER
IND
MEX
PAK
AUT
NPL
ARG
SDN
UGA
GHA
ETH
ECU
ZWE
IRL
SEN
HND
TUR
MDG
GBR
SLV
PHL
ZAR
RWA
HUN
EGYSYR
THA COL
PRT
MYS
MUS
KOR
DNK
ITA
BOL
MWI
USA
CIV
LSOMAR
FIN
ESP
IDN
NZL
BWA
GTM
SWE
HKG
AUS
URY
CHL
JPN
FRA
CAN
CHE
NOR
TTO
IRN
0.4
VEN
0.5
DZA
IDN
GAB
ARE
QAT
KWT
0.2
0
-10
0
10
20
30
40
ARE
SAU
NOR
KWT
SAU
OMN
VEN
TTO
LKA
ISR
LSOBWA
PNG
GAB
OMN
DZA
IRN
50
60
Mean oil&gas balance, percent of GDP
0
-10
0
10
20
30
40
QAT
50
60
Mean oil&gas balance, percent of GDP
Fig. 1. Historical income and consumption volatility in exhaustible resource countries, 1964–2008. Sources: World Bank, 2008 World Development Indicators. Notes: Sample
restricted to countries with at least 25 annual observations and a population of at least 1 million, which limits the sample to 90 countries.
argues that political constraints have held back governments from
using explicit insurance.
Another approach would be to vary resource extraction quantities in
a manner that offsets the effect of price changes on exhaustible resource
revenues or reduces the dependence on such resources. An extensive
literature has studied the supply-side of exhaustible resources under
different market structures, but has not reached any consensus.3 For the
purpose of this paper, we note that price variation accounts for 85–90%
of the 1-year changes in exhaustible resource revenues.4 Longer
horizons exhibit higher cross-country variation for contributions of
prices and quantities, but average contributions for the sample of oil
countries remain unchanged — price changes account for 80–95% of the
variation in revenues for horizons of up to 10 years.
To further assess the relationship between the exhaustible
resource price and extraction quantities, we consider the response
of extraction quantities to the oil price boom of 1999–2008, which
was not expected prior to 1999. Energy Information Administration
(1998) forecasted that the real price of oil in 2005 would remain
3
See, e.g., Griffin (1985) and Ramcharran (2002). A survey of the literature on the
structure of the oil market by Cremer and Salehi-Isfahani (1991) concludes that “…the
!
!
level of disagreement is unsettling” (p. 93).
priceit + 1
revenuesit + 1
4
Computed for country i and year t as ln
ln
:
i
i
pricet
revenuest
=
broadly unchanged at 24 USD/barrel (in 2005 prices), while the actual
price in 2005 was 56 USD/barrel (in 2005 prices). Despite the surge in
the price, Energy Information Administration (1998) projections for
total extraction of oil in the sample countries were only 1% below the
observed extraction quantities for 2005. Over that 7-year horizon, oil
production exhibited very limited response to the changes in the
price. A similar comparison of forecasts and realizations for the period
from 1998 to 2008 would suggest an even smaller price elasticity of
supply.
A possible explanation for the lack of response in extraction
quantities – consistent with the model of this paper – is that changes
in extraction capacity are very costly and their implementation requires
large time lags. This property of resource extraction, when combined
with the observation that historically exhaustible resource price follows
a persistent trendless process, implies that extraction quantities cannot
diversify exhaustible resource risk either at short or long horizons. Such
a diversification strategy is prohibitively expensive in the short run,
while the nature of the resource price limits its benefits in the long run.
An alternative to explicit insurance and adjustments in extraction
quantities is income diversification, with an aim to counter income
fluctuations over the oil price cycle and reduce exposure to the volatile
exhaustible resource revenues over longer horizons. One potential
channel for such diversification is external savings, whereby conversion
of exhaustible resource revenues into foreign assets smoothes
(a) Income volatility
(b) Consumption volatility
10-year rolling st.dev. of per capita GDP/CPI grow
10-year rolling st.dev. of per capita C/CPI growth
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
0.25
0.2
0.15
0.1
0.05
0
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
51
0.25
0.2
0.15
0.1
0.05
0
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
(c) Ratio of consumption to income volatility
1.5
1
Exhaustible resource exporters
Other commodity exporters
All other countries
0.5
0
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Fig. 2. Output volatility by decade. Sources: World Bank, 2008 World Development Indicators. Notes: ‘Exhaustible resource exporters' are defined as economies, where median trade
surplus for oil and gas during the period 1964–2007 was at least 10% of the GDP. This procedure identifies 11 exhaustible resource exporters — Algeria, Gabon, Iran, Kuwait, Nigeria,
Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, Venezuela and Trinidad and Tobago. Yemen and Norway are excluded from the group, since in both economies sizable oil and gas
exports started only during the 1990s. Due to the lack of data prior to 1990, CIS countries (e.g., Russia, Kazakhstan, and Azerbaijan) are also excluded from the sample. ‘Other
commodity exporters’ include Iceland, New Zealand, Chile, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Honduras, Malaysia, Ghana, and Côte d'Ivoire.
consumption and gradually increases the share of income from foreign
sources. The presence of this diversification channel would be consistent
with exhaustible resource countries on average running current account
surpluses, with larger surpluses when exhaustible resource prices are
high.
In the absence of reliable data on the evolution of net foreign asset
positions, we examine this channel using current account balances,
depicted in Fig. 3. Exhaustible resource countries have been running
sizable current account surpluses in periods with high exhaustible
resource prices and less-than-offsetting deficits when prices are low.
In particular, an average current account deficit of 1.2% of GDP during
the 90s was followed by an average surplus of 13.7% of GDP in 2000–
2007. Foreign asset accumulation during the price boom of 1974–1981
was similar in magnitude, with an average surplus of 15.4% of GDP.
Another potential diversification channel operates through the
‘conventional’ domestic economic activity that is not directly related to
the extraction of exhaustible resources. Expansion of conventional
economic activity lowers the share of volatile exhaustible resources in
total income and may provide additional diversification, depending on
the correlation of conventional income with the price of exhaustible
resources.
As shown in Fig. 4, with the exception of Venezuela and Libya,
exhaustible resource countries have experienced significant growth in
conventional economic activity over the most recent oil price peak-to-
peak cycle, i.e., 1980–2007. Panel b in Fig. 4 reports a decomposition of
the growth rate into contributions of labor input and labor productivity.
All exhaustible resource countries in our sample have experienced a
sizable increase in labor force, which accounts for the bulk of observed
output growth. At the same time, there is no systematic positive
contribution from labor productivity to output growth for this group of
countries. The latter result is in line with the findings of the ‘resource
curse’ literature (see e.g. Sachs and Warner, 2001), recaptured in Fig. 5.
Over the most recent oil price cycle, per capita income in exhaustible
resource countries on average grew at a slower pace than in other
economies. Furthermore, for the group of countries heavily dependent
on exhaustible resources, the average growth in per capita income was
close to zero. We also find that annual growth rates in the conventional
sector exhibit a small positive correlation with growth rates in the
exhaustible resource sector (see panel c in Fig. 4). The average correlation in the sample of twelve exhaustible resource countries is 0.19.
Thus, the conventional sector does not contribute to the diversification
of income over the oil–price cycle.
Overall, empirical evidence indicates that income diversification in
exhaustible resource countries takes place through two main channels.
First, exhaustible resource countries accumulate foreign assets. By doing
so they smooth consumption relative to income and reduce the share of
volatile exhaustible resources in aggregate income. Second, domestic
‘conventional’ economic activity in countries with exhaustible resources
52
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
100
Current account
30
Percent of GDP
In the exhaustible resource sector, the extraction technology requires no factor inputs and output follows an exogenously specified
sequence:
80
60
20
Oil price (right scale)
40
10
0
-10
20
$ 2007, log scale
40
Zt
-30
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
ð3Þ
where Zt is the quantity extracted. Future extraction quantities,
{Zt}Tt = 0 ≥ 0, are known at time t and such resources are exhausted in
period T. The model does not address the question of optimal extraction quantities and instead takes the available projections for future
extraction as given. The focus is on the uncertainty surrounding the
prices of the exhaustible resource instead of its extraction quantities,
which historically have exhibited a considerably smaller variation.
The aggregate per-period resource constraint of the economy is:
-20
-40
1970
≥0 for t ≤ T
;
=0 for t N T
2005
Year
Fig. 3. The current account balance and the oil price. Sources: International Monetary
Fund (2009) World Economic Outlook and British Petroleum (2008). Notes: ‘Current
account’ defined as the sum of CA balances in exhaustible resource countries,
normalized by the sample countries' GDP, all in current prices. For the definition of
exhaustible resource countries see notes in Fig. 2.
is increasing in tandem with the expanding labor force, reducing the
share of volatile exhaustible resources in aggregate income. In our study
of precautionary savings, we include both of these channels.
To gauge the importance of precautionary savings, while controlling for the other important drivers of savings behavior – the desire to
smooth consumption of the temporary exhaustible income over time
regardless of uncertainty – we need a model. The construction and
application of such a model is the central task of the rest of the paper.
Ct + Bt +1 = ð1 + r ÞBt + pt Zt + Yt :
ð4Þ
In Eq. (4) Ct represents aggregate consumption. The difference between aggregate production and absorption is the trade balance, Bt + 1 −
(1 +r)Bt, where Bt stands for the stock of net foreign assets as of the end
of period t− 1 and r is the risk-free rate of return. We assume, in line with
the empirical evidence, that the economy cannot lock in future prices of
the exhaustible resource in insurance markets and the ownership of the
stock of the exhaustible resource is non-transferable. Hence, in each
period the extracted amount, ptZt, is the only source of exhaustible
resource related revenue.
The relative price of the exhaustible resource – which is determined
outside this economy – follows a multiplicative error process:
pt +1 = ðð1−ρÞp + ρ pt Þεt
+ 1;
ð5Þ
3. Modeling framework
This section presents a model that captures the savings decision
facing producers of exhaustible resources with volatile prices.
3.1. Small open endowment economy
Consider a small open economy with two sectors: one is conventional and the other is an exhaustible resource extracting sector. The
aggregate production technology for the conventional sector is:
Yt = ALt ;
ð1Þ
where Yt is output, A is a measure of productivity and Lt is labor input,
which grows at a constant rate:
Lt
+ 1
= ð1 + nÞLt ;
ð2Þ
and is the only source of growth in the conventional sector. In the
baseline model the conventional sector facilitates income diversification
only through the exogenous growth in the labor force. The model
abstracts from domestic investment/savings decision and the only
endogenous channel of diversification is the external sector.5 The effect
of time-varying productivity is examined in a subsequent section on
sensitivity analysis.
5
In a more general model with endogenous capital, investment would provide an
alternative diversification channel only when the domestic return on capital exceeds
the return on foreign assets. This could be the case if, for example, the economy is
credit constrained or experiences a positive productivity shock. Exhaustible resource
revenues can then be used to exploit the temporarily higher domestic returns.
However, on the balanced growth path, the return on domestic capital has to equal the
world interest rate, limiting the long-run impact of this diversification channel.
where p0 is given, p is the unconditional mean of pt, εt is log normally
distributed with mean 1 and variance σε2 and ρ b 1.6 In line with empirical findings (e.g., Krautkraemer, 1998; Lin and Wagner, 2007, and
references therein), the relative price of the exhaustible resource in
the model is assumed to be trendless in the long run.
The economy is inhabited by a representative household with the
following CRRA preferences:
+∞
t
∑ β Lt U ðCt =Lt Þ;
ð6Þ
t =0
where
8
1−σ
>
< ðCt =Lt Þ
for 0 b σ b 1 or σ N 1
:
U ðCt = Lt Þ =
1−σ
>
:
logðCt = Lt Þ for σ = 1
ð7Þ
In Eq. (6), β is a subjective discount factor, σ determines the degree
of risk aversion and intertemporal elasticity of substitution and Lt is
the number of members in the representative household.
3.2. Optimal solution
To solve the model, it is instructive to recast all quantities in terms
of ratios to the non-exhaustible resource sector output, where
variables expressed in terms of effective units of labor are denoted
6
This process is borrowed from Borensztein et al. (2009). We do not use an AR(1) in
logs, because it complicates the interpretation of precautionary savings (due to E(ept) N
eE(pt)). AR(1) in levels is not used to avoid negative prices.
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
53
(a) Growth in conventional output
(b) Contributions of labor and productivity
NGA
NGA
LBY
LBY
DZA
DZA
ARE
ARE
SAU
SAU
QAT
QAT
OMN
OMN
KWT
KWT
IRN
IRN
BHR
BHR
TTO
TTO
VEN
VEN Productivity
-10
-5
0
-10
10
5
Average annual growth rate, percent
Labor
-5
0
5
10
Average annual growth rate, percent
(c) Correlation with growth in exhaustible resource sector
NGA
LBY
DZA
ARE
SAU
QAT
OMN
KWT
IRN
BHR
Productivity
Output
TTO
VEN
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
Fig. 4. Growth in conventional output, contributing factors and correlation with exhaustible resources (1980–2007). Sources: World Bank, 2008 World Development Indicators,
International Monetary Fund (2009) World Economic Outlook and United Nations (2008). Notes: Due to lack of sectoral data on economic activity ‘Conventional output’ defined as
GDP less exports of oil and gas. Growth in labor is defined as growth in population of age 15–64 from UN data.
by lowercase letters, e.g. yt =
can be formulated as:
+∞
Yt
ALt .
Then the maximization problem
t
max E0 ∑β̃ U ðct Þ;
fct ; bt + 1 g
ð8Þ
out. The balanced growth path is characterized by a common constant
growth rate, n, for consumption, output and the net foreign asset
position, which allows output shares, ct/yt and bt/yt, to remain constant
over time.
t =0
3.2.1. Deterministic case
In the deterministic case, the expression for optimal consumption
is:
subject to:
ct + ð1 + nÞbt +1 = ð1 + r Þbt + pt zt + yt ;
pt +1 = ð1−ρÞ P
p + ρ pt εt +1 ;
1+n S
bS = 0;
lim
S→+∞
1+r
ð9Þ
where β̃ ≡ βð1 + nÞ and b0, p0 are given.7
It is further assumed that r = 1/β − 1, which puts the model
solution on a balanced growth path after exhaustible resources run
7
The problem in Eqs. (8)–(9) has a solution if the growth rate of the nonexhaustible resource sector is less than the real interest rate: n b r.
c = y + ðr−nÞ b0 +
r−n T
∑
1 + r t =0
1+n t
p t zt :
1+r
ð10Þ
Per-period consumption equals the sum of conventional output, the
annuity value from the initial net foreign assets and the annuity value
from the discounted steam of future exhaustible resource revenues. For
a given income stream, the consumption–output ratio is therefore set at
a constant optimal level and the external balance is used to smooth out
any variation in income over time. In particular, the representative
household accumulates wealth in periods with exhaustible resource
revenues, and consumes interest income from the accumulated assets
54
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
10
CHN
Average per capita real GDP growth
8
6
KOR
BWA
TWN
y = -0.052*x + 2.1
(0.027) (0.4)
VNM
THA
SGP
IRL
IND
4
LKAHKG
2
JOR
0
MYS
IDN
CHL
TUR TUN
PAK
DOM
CYP
PRT
BGD
EGY
ESP
FIN GBR
POL
PAN
HUN
JPN
ISR
SWE
USA
ISL
DNK
AUT
BEL
NLD AUS
MAR
URY
CRI
GRC
DEU
CAN
ITA
COL
FRA
SDN
NZL
CHE
GHA
SLV ETH ARG MEX
PHL
PER
KEN BRA
HND
ZAF
PRY
GTM
BOL
CMR
OMN
NOR
YEM
IRN
TTO
BHR
NGA
ECU
SYR
AGO
DZA
VEN
QAT
KWT
CIV
SAU
-2
ARE
LBY
-4
-10
0
10
20
30
40
50
Median oil&gas balance, percent of GDP
Fig. 5. Per capita real GDP growth rates, 1980–2007. Sources: World Bank, 2008 World Development Indicators and International Monetary Fund (2009) World Economic Outlook.
once exhaustible resource revenues run out. The ratio of foreign assetsto-output increases during the period of asset build-up and stays
constant thereafter. To achieve this with a growing labor force, the
economy must run current account surpluses on its balanced growth
path. Since constant per capita consumption is achieved, the curvature
in the utility function does not play any role in this deterministic case.
3.2.2. Stochastic case
In addition to considerations covered by the deterministic case, the
risk-averse representative household now faces uncertainty about the
future price of the exhaustible resource and wants to insure against
variation in future income. In the absence of explicit insurance, the
household solves a simple self-insurance problem. Holdings of net
foreign assets are used to lower the exposure to the uncertain income
from exhaustible resources.
In the model, precautionary savings are defined as the change in net
foreign assets due to this self-insurance motive — and for any given
period they can be calculated as the difference in net foreign asset
positions between the deterministic and stochastic versions of the
model.8
The exhaustible nature of the resource plays a crucial role in the
model's solution. It makes the model deterministic from period T
onwards and ensures a finite optimal value for expected consumption
at the infinite horizon. To accommodate the precautionary savings
motive, the optimal consumption in the stochastic model is upward
tilting (until resources are exhausted and uncertainty is resolved) and
accompanied by gradual accumulation of a buffer stock of net foreign
assets. In initial periods, consumption is lower than in the deterministic case, but as savings accumulate and the interest income from
foreign assets grows, it eventually exceeds the consumption path
from the deterministic case. The stochastic version of the model does
not have a closed form solution, but it can be solved numerically.
Details of the solution method are presented in Appendix A.
8
This definition of precautionary savings differs from the one used by studies of
precautionary savings in models with idiosyncratic shocks, as in e.g. Carroll (2001),
where precautionary savings are usually defined as change in the distribution of
savings in a stationary steady state.
4. Parameterization and fit with historical data
This section applies the model to selected exporters of exhaustible
resources in a historical context. The gist of the exercise is to specify
the required model inputs and then solve for the optimal model
responses in terms of consumption and external savings to a sequence
of actual oil price realizations (i.e., shocks). The results of this section
focus on the fit between country-specific model outcomes and
historical data.
4.1. Model parameterization
The model is applied to thirteen exhaustible resource economies —
Algeria, Iran, Kazakhstan, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Norway, Oman, Qatar,
Russia, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates and Venezuela. Model
economies differ in terms of their labor growth rate, stock of initial net
foreign assets, share of exhaustible resource revenues in total output
and extraction path for exhaustible resources. All other inputs of the
exercise are identical across model economies.
To parameterize the model, one period is taken as one year in the
data. For all sample economies the subjective discount rate is assumed
to take a value of β = 1/(1.04) and the curvature in CRRA utility is set
toσ = 2. Both values are in the range of what is considered standard in
the literature.
Parameters of the price process in Eq. (5) are based on a maximum
likelihood estimation of the process using annual oil price data for
1970–2007, depicted in Fig. 3.9 The relevant parameter values are
ρ = 0.89 [S.E. = 0.12] and σ2ε = 0.092 [S.E. = 0.016]. The estimated
unconditional mean price, expressed in 2007 US dollars, is p = 39:1.
All countries in the sample face the same price process.
The remaining model inputs are country-specific and are summarized in Tables 1 and 2. Oil and gas reserves are obtained from United
States Geological Survey (2000), which estimates the two stocks as of
end-of-1995 for each sample country (see column 5 in Table 1). The
stock is defined as the sum of “known oil/gas”, “undiscovered oil/gas”
9
For details on the estimation procedure see Borensztein et al. (2009).
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
55
Table 1
Country-specific model parameters and initial values.
Labor force growth
rate (%)
Algeria
Iran
Kazakhstan
Kuwait
Libya
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Qatar
Russia
Saudi Arabia
United Arab Emirates
Venezuela
1996–2006
post-2006
4.2
3.4
0.8
6.0
2.5
2.8
1.4
4.6
6.5
0.5
0.6
8.1
3.5
0.7
0.3
0.2
1.0
0.9
2.0
0.3
1.3
0.7
− 0.9
1.4
1.2
0.9
End-of-1995 NFA position
(% of GDP)
Oil and gas revenues
(% of GDP in 2007)
End-of-1995 oil and gas reserves
(bn brls oil equivalent)
Projected exhaustion
year for resources
− 71
−9
− 16
181
50
− 105
4
−6
985
−3
40
277
−1
44
27
24
54
59
32
24
45
56
19
53
41
27
98
432
91
113
71
128
115
29
148
1012
707
152
149
2077
2171
2105
2129
2117
2108
2091
2057
2148
2163
2221
2095
2159
Sources: International Monetary Fund (2009) World Economic Outlook, British Petroleum (2009), United States Geological Survey (2000), Energy Information Administration
(2008), United Nations (2008), Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007).
Note: Parameters and initial values not reported in the table are identical for all sample countries.
and “reserve growth”, less “cumulative oil/gas” extracted as of end-of1995. Consistent with the dating of the reserve estimates, we set 1996
as the first year in the parameterized model.10 Paths for oil and gas
extraction quantities for 1996–2008 are obtained from British
Petroleum (2009). Projections for the subsequent 2010–2030 period
are taken from Energy Information Administration (1998). To project
beyond 2030, we assume that resource extraction proceeds at a
constant level until reserves are exhausted. The calculation is done
separately for oil and gas and resulting country-specific extraction
paths are summarized in Table 2. Annual labor force growth rate, n, is
obtained from United Nations (2008) data and projections for
working age population. For 1996–2006 average growth rate from
historical series is used, while from 2007 onwards n is set equal to
each country's average projected growth rate over 2010–2050. The
initial net foreign asset stock, b1996, is calculated as the end-of-1995
share of net foreign assets over the total output and obtained from the
External Wealth of Nations data set (Lane and Milesi-Ferretti, 2007).
Finally, the size of the exhaustible resource sector, ptzt, in the model is
normalized to match the trade balance for oil and gas, as a share of
GDP, which is our proxy for the size of the exhaustible resource sector
in data. This normalization is done for the base year, which we set to
2007. For all other years the size of the exhaustible resource sector in
the model is then determined by the evolution of Lt and ptzt.11
Country-specific model inputs exhibit considerable variation
across the 13 sample countries. For example, with an exhaustible
resource output share of 0.19, Russia in 2007 is the least dependent on
exhaustible resource revenues. At the other end of the spectrum,
Libya's exhaustible resource output share exceeds that of the conventional sector. In terms of the exhaustible resource lifespan, Oman
10
The exercise is not extended to earlier years because of lack of consistent reserve
estimates. For the majority of sample countries data on the stock of reserves prior to
1996 show significant reserve growth. To allow for reserve growth in our model, one
would need to introduce shocks to the stock of reserves, which is beyond the scope of
the current paper. Results of an extended exercise for Norway, covering 1974–2007,
are reported in Bems and de Carvalho Filho (2009).
11
The model parameterization in this paper contains several differences from an
earlier working paper (Bems and de Carvalho Filho, 2009). First, the assumed
curvature in the utility function is lowered from σ = 6 to σ = 2 to reflect the standard
choice in the RBC literature. Second, the amount of remaining reserves is based on
estimates from the United States Geological Survey (2000) rather than British
Petroleum (2008). We judge the former source's definition of reserves to be more
appropriate for the purpose of this paper. Third, the price process for exhaustible
resources is changed from AR(1) to a multiplicative error process. Fourth, the base
year is moved from 2006 to 2007 and the sample is extended to include Oman and
Russia. These changes did not alter the main findings of the paper.
is assessed to be the first to run out of exhaustible resources, by 2057.
On the other end of the spectrum, in Russia, Iran, Saudi Arabia and
Venezuela, extraction is projected to continue beyond 2150. Similarly,
there is significant variation in the extraction time profiles in Table 2.
By 2030 extraction quantities in Norway are projected to decrease
by 20% relative the peak in 2007, while in Kazakhstan extraction
quantities are projected to more than double over the same period.
4.2. Model results
To obtain time-series of optimal model outcomes, the infinite
horizon problem is solved from the perspective of each year from
1996 till 2008. For each optimization, the initial price of exhaustible
resources, p0, is taken from the annual data used in the estimation of
the price process. Historical price realizations can then be interpreted
as positive or negative shocks to the exhaustible resource price, where
shock is defined as the difference in the path of the conditional mean
price between the current and previous year's price realizations.
Optimizations from the perspective of adjacent years are connected
though the choice of net foreign assets. In particular, the optimal
choice of bt + 1 from the perspective of year t is taken as the initial
Table 2
Summary of historical and projected extraction path for liquids (oil and gas, billion
barrels oil equivalent per year).
1996 2000 2005 2007 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2050
Algeria
Iran, I.R. of
Kazakhstan
Kuwait
Libya
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Qatar
Russia
Saudi
Arabia
United Arab
Emirates
Venezuela,
Rep. Bol.
0.9
1.6
0.2
0.8
0.6
0.8
1.4
0.4
0.3
5.7
3.7
1.1
1.8
0.3
0.9
0.6
0.9
1.5
0.4
0.4
5.7
3.8
1.3
2.2
0.6
1.0
0.7
1.1
1.6
0.4
0.7
7.1
4.5
1.3
2.3
0.7
1.0
0.8
1.1
1.6
0.4
0.8
7.3
4.4
1.5
2.4
0.9
1.0
0.9
1.2
1.5
0.4
1.0
7.5
4.5
1.7
2.5
1.2
1.2
0.8
1.4
1.4
0.5
1.3
7.9
5.1
1.9
2.7
1.3
1.2
0.8
1.5
1.3
0.6
1.6
8.2
5.5
2.0
2.9
1.5
1.3
0.8
1.7
1.3
0.6
1.8
8.4
5.8
2.2
3.2
1.7
1.3
0.8
1.8
1.2
0.7
2.0
8.8
6.1
0.8
3.2
1.7
1.3
0.8
1.8
1.2
0.3
0.8
8.9
6.1
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.4
1.5
1.6
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.3
1.4
1.2
0.9
0.8
0.9
1.0
1.2
1.2
1.2
Source: Data for 1996, 1997,…, 2007 refers to the actual extraction as reported in British
Petroleum (2009). Data for 2010, 2015,…, 2030 are projections from Energy
Information Administration (2008). Quantities for years between 2007 and 2030
were extrapolated using a linear trend. After 2030 production quantities kept constant
until reserves, as reported in column 5 of Table 1, are exhausted.
56
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
DZA
IRN
1 Fit = 0.18
0.5
1 Fit = 0.49
0.5
0
1995
2000
2005
0.5
0
1995
2000
KWT
2005
2005
0.5
0
1995
2000
NOR
0.5
0
1995
2000
2000
2005
0
1995
QAT
2000
2005
Fit = 0.40
0
1995
2000
SAU
1 Fit = 0.21
0.5
2005
0
1995
2005
ARE
1 Fit = 0.11
0.5
2005
0.5
RUS
2000
0
1995
1
Fit = 0.24
0.5
1 Fit = 0.50
0
1995
2005
OMN
1
Fit = 0.32
2005
1 Fit = 0.52
0.5
2000
2000
NGA
1 Fit = 0.17
0.5
0
1995
0
1995
LBY
1 Fit = 0.15
1
KAZ
1 Fit = 0.32
0.5
2000
2005
0
1995
2000
2005
VEN
1 Fit = 0.18
Model
0.5
Data
0
1995
2000
2005
Fig. 6. Exhaustible resource share in economic activity in the model and data. Notes: “Fit” for each country calculated as root mean square error normalized by the average size of the
exhaustible resource sector.
value, b0, for the subsequent year's problem. Notice that the setup of
the exercise implies that – consistent with the model of Section 3 – in
the absence of price shocks the model is deterministic and needs to be
solved only once.
It is instructive to first compare the share of exhaustible resources
in total output in the model and data, reported in Fig. 6. In the data this
share is approximated by net exports of oil and gas, as a share of GDP.
By construction, the two shares coincide in 2007. However, for other
years they can deviate to the extent that changes in the price of the
exhaustible resource, extraction quantities and labor input in the
model do not capture all the variation in economic activity in data.
Results show that for majority of the sample countries the model can
capture the trend in data. This finding supports our earlier empirical
claim that changes in the labor force and oil and gas revenues account
for the bulk of growth in countries with exhaustible resources.
For several countries the fit with data is more problematic. This is
the case for Russia and to a lesser extent Norway, which have ex-
perienced significant growth in labor productivity, not captured by
the model. These two economies are also the least dependent on
exhaustible resources, further limiting the applicability of the model.
Other major discrepancies between model outcomes and data in
Fig. 6, i.e., Qatar, Nigeria and Kazakhstan, are driven by differences in
exhaustible resource revenues as measured by the oil price and
extraction quantities in the model and net exports of oil and gas in
aggregate data. Model results for these countries should be interpreted with caution.
Per capita growth rates for output and consumption in the model
are summarized in Fig. 7. Per capita output growth in the conventional
sector is by assumption zero, therefore any variation in aggregate
output is driven entirely by changes in per capita revenues in the
exhaustible resource sector. As expected, aggregate volatility increases
with the share of exhaustible resources in economic activity.
The optimal consumption choice smoothes the deterministic change
in per capita extraction quantities, so that the remaining variation in
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
DZA
IRN
KAZ
0.2
0.2
0.2
0
0
0
-0.2
1995
2000
2005
-0.2
1995
2000
KWT
2005
-0.2
1995
LBY
0.2
0.2
0
0
0
2000
2005
-0.2
1995
2000
NOR
2005
-0.2
1995
OMN
0.2
0.2
0
0
0
2000
2005
-0.2
1995
2000
RUS
2005
-0.2
1995
SAU
0.2
0.2
0
0
0
2000
2005
-0.2
1995
2000
2000
2005
2000
2005
ARE
0.2
-0.2
1995
2005
QAT
0.2
-0.2
1995
2000
NGA
0.2
-0.2
1995
57
2005
-0.2
1995
2000
2005
VEN
0.2
Output
0
Consumption
-0.2
1995
2000
2005
Fig. 7. Per capita growth rates for output and consumption in the model.
consumption is due to the effect of resource price shocks on the discounted future income. With the assumed price process for exhaustible
resources, such variation is a fraction of the current period variation
in the price of the exhaustible resource. Allowing for uncertainty in
the resource price adds precautionary savings considerations to the
deterministic model, which lowers the level of per capita consumption,
but does not have a quantitatively significant effect on consumption
growth rates. Cross-country differences in consumption growth rates
are driven by several factors, including the share of the exhaustible
resource sector in GDP and the time-profile of exhaustible resource
extraction quantities. As a result, countries with equal current share of
exhaustible resources in GDP can exhibit different consumption growth
rates in response to the same price shock. For example, given a price
shock and an equal current share of exhaustible resources in GDP,
consumption will respond more in a country that expects to exhaust the
resource sooner because of a larger effect of the price shock on discounted future wealth.
Table 3 compares standard deviations for output and consumption
growth rates as well as the correlation between the two in the model
and data. The variation in the model for both output and consumption
is a fraction of the variation in data. This is to be expected, given that
shocks in the model are restricted to exhaustible resource prices. We
find that the model explains more of the consumption volatility for
countries in which exhaustible resources dominate economic activity.
There is also more consumption smoothing taking place in the model
than in the data. Consumption variation in the model is in the range of
20–50% of the variation in output, with a median of 35%. In the data,
the median value for the same ratio is 54%. Correlations between
output and consumption in data are in line with our earlier findings
(see Fig. 1), even though the length of time-series in Table 3 is
considerably shorter. Comparable correlations in the model are uniformly higher, ranging from 0.69 to 0.97. However, as results in Fig. 7
indicate, high correlation in the model does not preclude consumption smoothing.
58
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
Table 3
Comparison of per capita output and consumption volatility and correlation in the
model and data (1997–2008).
Data
Algeria
Iran, I.R. of
Kazakhstan
Kuwait
Libya
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Qatar
Russia
Saudi Arabia
United Arab Emirates
Venezuela, Rep. Bol.
Sample mean
Sample median
Model
std(Y)
std(C)
corr(Y,C)
std(Y)
std(C)
corr(Y,C)
0.08
0.07
0.07
0.13
0.16
0.13
0.05
0.10
0.12
0.09
0.09
0.10
0.12
0.10
0.10
0.02
0.03
0.09
0.05
–
–
0.01
0.07
0.10
0.09
0.05
0.04
0.09
0.06
0.05
− 0.03
0.42
0.59
0.25
–
–
− 0.06
0.18
0.16
0.77
0.75
0.63
0.82
0.41
0.42
0.07
0.03
0.03
0.10
0.10
0.04
0.03
0.09
0.09
0.02
0.08
0.07
0.05
0.06
0.07
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.04
0.05
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.79
0.89
0.85
0.68
0.90
0.88
0.86
0.62
0.80
0.88
0.64
0.80
0.61
0.78
0.80
Source: World Bank, 2008 World Development Indicators.
Next, we turn to the model results for the external sector. In the
absence of exhaustible resources, external balances are trivially determined by the initial net foreign asset position. Countries with positive
(negative) net foreign assets would run persistent current account
surpluses (deficits) that ensure a constant NFA-to-output ratio.
Exhaustible resources affect external savings in the model through
several channels. First, the extraction path for exhaustible resources
plays a crucial and complex role, as it can increase or decrease external
savings in a given period. For example, ceteris paribus, a longer lifespan of exhaustible resources decreases the size of current external
savings, while a higher dependence on such resource increases external savings. Furthermore, a sufficiently back-loaded extraction path
can generate negative initial savings. This is the case for Kazakhstan in
our model parameterization. Similarly, the exhaustible resource price
induces additional external savings when it is above its estimated
mean and reduces savings when it is below the mean. The mechanism
through which the path of prices affects external savings is the same
as the mechanism for extraction profiles, because the two jointly
determine the path for exhaustible resource revenues. Thus, to make
an analogy with the back-loaded extraction path, if the initial price was
sufficiently low relative to the mean, the model economy would
initially run current account deficits. Finally, in the stochastic version
of the model uncertainty about future exhaustible resource prices and
accompanying precautionary motive lower current period consumption and increase external savings. This factor increases current
account balances in the model for as long as there is uncertainty
attached to a fraction of income.
How do external savings in the model economies compare to
external savings behavior in the data? We find that the model fits the
data moderately well, although there are large variations across
sample countries. Changes in current account balances exhibit a
positive correlation in the 0.33–0.94 range, with a mean of 0.70. The
coefficients are higher for countries for which the model can capture a
larger share of exhaustible resources in GDP. Correspondingly, Russia,
Qatar and Kazakhstan exhibit the lowest “fit” in Fig. 6 and the lowest
correlation coefficients in Fig. 8. In level terms, the model fits data
better in the post-2002 period, during which it generates 2/3 of
accumulated current account surpluses in data. In contrast, the pre2002 period is characterized by an aggregated current account deficit
in the model, while there is a surplus in the data. Excluding Russia,
Qatar and Kazakhstan from the sample significantly improves the
model's fit with the data both before and after 2002.
To further examine the fit, panel a in Fig. 9 compares changes in
net foreign asset positions, as a share of GDP, in the model and data
over the sample period. This variable summarizes the model's fit in
terms of both accumulated external savings and output changes.12
The correlation between the model and the data is 0.73 and for a
majority of countries the changes in the data exceed the changes in
the model. Panels b and c show the results separately for the pre and
post-2002 periods. In line with results from Fig. 8, the fit, as measured
by correlation and mean square error, is considerably better for the
post-2002 period.
Overall, we find that the model replicates the relevant historical
data moderately well. For a majority of the model economies, the
share of exhaustible resources in economic activity captures the trend
in data and changes in external balances correlate closely with the
data. In a cross section, changes in net foreign assets also exhibit a
strong positive correlation with the data over the sample period.
5. Role of consumption smoothing and precautionary savings
This section decomposes external savings in the model into two
underlying motives — consumption smoothing and precautionary
savings. For the purpose of tractability, we start by examining the
results from the perspective of the base year — 2007. Focus on a single
year simplifies the discussion of the determinants of savings, since we
avoid dealing with multiple price shocks. Subsequently, we present
decomposition results for the whole historical episode of 1996–2008
and contrast them to the results for 2007.
External savings are decomposed into consumption smoothing
and precautionary savings components by separately solving the
model with and without uncertainty. The model without uncertainty
is the deterministic case, where all savings represent the consumption
smoothing motive. When solving this deterministic model from the
perspective of each year t = {1996, …, 2008}, the sequence of prices
fed into the model is the conditional mean of the price process, given
the observable initial price pt. We use conditional rather than unconditional mean price because the goal of the exercise is to obtain a
meaningful decomposition of savings into precautionary and consumption smoothing components. In this case, the initial observable
price should be taken into account by the deterministic model, so that
the difference in model-derived savings between the parameterizations with unconditional and conditional mean price sequences represents consumption smoothing of observed (and expected) price
fluctuations. Precautionary savings are then defined as the difference
in external savings between the stochastic and deterministic solutions
and are limited to the model response to the stochastic nature of the
price process.
The decomposition of model derived optimal 2007 current accounts
for sample countries is summarized in Table 4. The first column reports
the current account balance for year 2007.13 The ‘consumption
smoothing’ component of the current account – presented in the
second column – is the optimal current account from the deterministic
model, while the ‘precautionary savings’ component – presented in the
third column – is calculated as the difference between optimal external
savings in stochastic and deterministic versions of the model.
As already discussed in the previous section, the large variation in
the size of the consumption smoothing component across countries is
explained – in addition to dependence on exhaustible resources and
their lifespan – by the variation in the current and future exhaustible
resource weights in output. The focus on a single year allows us to
12
Its dynamics are also affected by the initial net foreign asset position, reported in
Table 1. In particular, large positive initial NFA-to-output ratios for Qatar and United
Arab Emirates, combined with growth in output, induce downward trends in NFA-tooutput that are only partly off-set by current account surpluses.
13
The exercise is identical to the one of the previous section, except for the initial
NFA, for which we use end-of-2005 figures from the data. This deviation has a
negligible effect on the derived current accounts.
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
DZA
0.5
IRN
0.2
Corr = 0.78
0
2000
2005
-0.2
1995
2000
0
2005
2000
2005
QAT
2000
2005
-0.5
1995
2000
-0.5
1995
2005
ARE
0.4
Corr = 0.80
0
2005
2005
Corr = 0.46
SAU
0
2000
2000
0
-0.5
1995
0.5
Corr = 0.33
-0.2
1995
-0.5
1995
0.5
Corr = 0.91
RUS
0.2
2005
0
2000
Corr = 0.69
OMN
0
2005
0
-0.5
1995
0.5
Corr = 0.81
-0.2
1995
2000
NGA
0
2000
-0.2
1995
0.5
Corr = 0.74
NOR
0.2
2005
LBY
0.5
Corr = 0.94
-0.5
1995
Corr = 0.46
0
KWT
0.5
KAZ
0.2
Corr = 0.54
0
-0.5
1995
59
Corr = 0.86
0.2
2000
2005
0
1995
2000
2005
VEN
0.2
Corr = 0.57
Model
0
-0.2
1995
Data
2000
2005
Fig. 8. Current account time series in the model and data, share of GDP. Notes: “Corr” refers to correlation, based on changes in the time-series.
examine these factors in more detail, with Fig. 10 depicting the path of
the relevant weights for exhaustible resources. Compare, for example,
the case of Norway and Kazakhstan. In 2007 the two economies exhibit
similar dependence on exhaustible resources as well as expected lifespan of resources. Also, both countries face the same sequence of
exhaustible resource prices. Nevertheless, the model prescribes a
broadly balanced external account for Kazakhstan, while Norway is
prescribed a surplus of 11.6% of GDP (see column 2 in Table 4). The
difference is explained by the divergence in the future dependence on
exhaustible resources. Results in Table 4 and Fig. 10 show that
assumed trends in extraction profiles are a major determinant of the
‘consumption smoothing’ component of the current account.
Precautionary savings in the model cannot be derived analytically,
but are largely also driven by the current and future exhaustible resource
shares in output, as depicted in Fig. 10. In this case, both larger output
shares and longer lifespan of exhaustible resources increase the share of
a household's total wealth that is exposed to the uncertain exhaustible
resource income. Consequently, precautionary savings increase in both
factors — the output share and the lifespan of the exhaustible resources.
Applying these criteria to Table 4 explains why among the thirteen
sample countries, precautionary savings as a share of output are the
largest in Qatar and the smallest in Norway and Nigeria.
Quantitatively, external savings in 2007 are dominated by the
consumption smoothing motive. Precautionary savings add between
0.3 and 3.9% of GDP to the optimal current account balances and,
when aggregated over the thirteen sample countries, add up to 1% of
the GDP or 36 billion dollars. This is a fraction of the surpluses induced
by the consumption smoothing motive, which amounts to 11% of the
GDP. Nevertheless, allowing for precautionary savings improves the
model's fit with data. Fig. 11 depicts the cross-section comparison for
both the deterministic and stochastic versions of the model. The latter
model generates higher correlation coefficient with data and also a
smaller mean square error. Given the relatively small size of precautionary savings, for both statistics the improvement is marginal.
How does the size of precautionary savings in 2007 compare to
other years? The comparison can be made with each of the years
60
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
Panel a: 1996-2008
2
Corr = 0.73
1.5 R.M.S.E. = 0.59
OMN
Model
1
0.5
SAU
NOR
LBY
IRN
KWT
RUS
0
-0.5
NGA
DZA
VEN
ARE
KAZ
-1
-1.5
-2
-2
-1.5
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
Data
Panel b: 1996-2001
1.5
Panel c: 2002-2008
1.5
Corr = 0.20
R.M.S.E. = 0.65
1
0.5
OMN
VEN
NGA
0
Model
Model
1
Corr = 0.95
R.M.S.E. = 0.29
KWT
DZA
NOR
RUS
0
-0.5
-1
-1
IRN
KAZ
KWT
LBY
-0.5ARE
SAU
KAZ
-0.5
DZA
SAU
NGA
OMN
VEN
NOR
0.5
ARE
IRN
RUS
LBY
0
0.5
1
1.5
Data
-1
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
1.5
Data
Fig. 9. Changes in net foreign asset positions in the model and data, as share of GDP. Notes: “R.M.S.E.” calculated as root mean square error between model and data. “Corr” refers to
correlation between model and data. Qatar is excluded from the figure, because it is an outlier. Its coordinates in panel a are (− 8.1; − 7.3), in panel b (− 5.0; − 2.8) and in panel c
(− 3.0; − 4.5).
covered in the previous section. Similar to decomposition for 2007,
the consumption smoothing component is obtained by sequentially
solving the deterministic model for each year covered in Section 4,
while the precautionary savings component is the difference between
current accounts in the deterministic and stochastic models.
Results in Fig. 12 show that the size of precautionary savings,
relative to GDP, is close to constant over time and directly comparable
to the estimate for 2007. Each country's exposure to the volatile
income from exhaustible resources changes only incrementally from
year to year, resulting in similar amounts of precautionary savings.
Over a longer horizon, as income is diversified away from the exhaustible resources and such resources draw closer to exhaustion,
Table 4
Optimal 2007 current accounts in the baseline model.
Algeria
Iran, I.R. of
Kazakhstan
Kuwait
Libya
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Qatar
Russia
Saudi Arabia
United Arab Emirates
Venezuela, Rep. Bol.
Sample mean
Sample median
Of which:
CA in
2007,
Consumption
% of GDP
smoothing
Precautionary
savings
(1)
(2)
(3)
20.4
7.9
1.7
30.3
33.2
19.0
10.7
28.5
20.1
2.2
28.6
23.8
13.1
18.4
20.1
18.6
7.0
0.2
28.4
31.1
18.6
10.4
26.6
16.2
1.6
26.8
22.7
12.6
17.0
18.6
1.9
0.9
1.5
1.9
2.1
0.4
0.3
1.9
3.9
0.6
1.8
1.0
0.6
1.4
1.5
precautionary savings converge to zero. Notice that the relative importance of the consumption smoothing and precautionary savings
motives varies considerably over the sample years. This is because
precautionary savings by definition are positive, while the consumption smoothing component of external savings is decumulated during
the period of low exhaustible resource prices. Hence, results for 2007 –
a year with an above average resource price – underestimate the longterm role of the precautionary motive in accumulated external savings.
We find that over 1996–2008 the contribution of the precautionary
motive to the total external savings increases to 35%, from 9% in 2007.
Overall, results from this section offer several key findings. First,
the main driver of external sector balances for exhaustible resource
countries is the consumption smoothing motive. Second, despite its
lesser role, optimal outcomes from the parameterized model prescribe economically significant precautionary savings for exporters of
exhaustible resources, amounting to around 1% of the GDP per year.
Furthermore, adding precautionary savings motive to the deterministic model increases its fit with data. Finally, we show that the size of
precautionary savings is close to constant over time, while its relative
contribution to external savings over the resource price cycle is
significantly underestimated in years with high resource price, such as
2007.
6. Sensitivity analysis
The modeling framework of this paper is a relatively simple one.
The price of this simplicity comes in the form of several exogenous
sequences (i.e., labor force and exhaustible resource quantities) and
an exogenous stochastic process for the price of exhaustible resources,
all of which can significantly affect model results. Another important
parameter with scarce empirical motivation is the curvature in the
CRRA utility, which governs the size of precautionary savings. In view
of such concerns, our approach in parameterization has been to lean
on the available data as much as possible.
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
61
60
QTA
LYB
Percent of GDP
50
40
KWT
ARE
30
DZA
OMN
KAZ
SAU
20
RUS
VEN
10
IRN
NGA
20
07
20
12
20
17
20
22
20
27
20
32
20
37
20
42
20
47
20
52
20
57
20
62
20
67
20
72
20
77
20
82
20
87
20
92
20
97
21
02
21
07
21
12
21
17
21
22
21
27
21
32
21
37
21
42
21
47
0
NOR
Fig. 10. ‘Output at risk’: expected share of exhaustible resource revenues in GDP.
This section, in turn, presents extensive sensitivity analysis of
the model results. In order to interpret model responses to various
deviations in inputs, the examination is focused on the base year (i.e.,
2007). The examination covers four areas: (i) consumer preference
parameters, (ii) the source and the size of growth in the non-exhaustible
resource sector, (iii) exhaustible resource extraction quantities and
(iv) parameters of the exhaustible resource price process. The results of
sensitivity tests are summarized in Table 5. The first column in this table
numbers the sensitivity test. The second column describes the type of
deviation from the baseline that a particular sensitivity test considers.
For example, row 2 looks at the case when risk-aversion parameter is
higher than in the baseline while all other parameters and initial values
are kept unchanged. The remaining columns report the size of consumption smoothing and precautionary savings components of the
current account for each sensitivity test. Results are compared with the
baseline case, reported in row 1. To conserve space, for each test only the
mean and median values for sample countries are reported.14
growth path. The net effect for model economies is an increase in the
annuity value of exhaustible resource wealth, which increases consumption and lowers savings, as captured by the lower consumption
smoothing component of the current account (see row 5 in Table 5).
Higher levels of consumption and lower savings imply that a larger
share of total income is derived from the uncertain exhaustible
resources (instead of the risk free foreign asset). In response to this
increased uncertainty about future income, the optimal level of
precautionary savings rises.
Within the range of considered values of the discount factor,
sensitivity tests show relatively minor changes in the consumption
smoothing and precautionary savings components of the current
account. Furthermore, since the effect on the two current account
components comes with the opposite sign, the overall impact on the
current account balance is muted.
6.1. Preference parameters
In the model of Section 3, labor is the only source of growth in the
conventional sector. The effect of changes in the growth rate of the
labor force on the two current account components is similar to that of
the subjective discount factor (see rows 6–7 in Table 5). In the
deterministic model, lower labor force growth rate increases the per
worker return on exhaustible resource wealth, thus raising the level of
consumption and lowering the consumption smoothing component
of the current account. At the same time, it increases the share of
future income from the uncertain exhaustible resources, which leads
to larger precautionary savings. The opposite forces are at work when
the labor force growth rate is reduced.
How sensitive are the model's results to the assumption of zero
productivity growth in the non-exhaustible resource sector? During
the period 1970–2006, the average growth rate for real output per
worker in Norway was close to 2%, suggesting that this assumption is
restrictive. To address such concerns, row 8 in Table 5 presents results
for the case when time-varying productivity is added to the modeling
framework of Section 3. This is done by substituting A with At in
Eq. (1) and assuming that At + 1 = (1 + g)At, where g = 0.02 is the
productivity growth rate. With this specification, the interest rate on
the stable growth path needs to satisfy R = (1 + g)σ/β, which for
baseline parameter values implies an 8% risk free annual return.
Although productivity growth affects external savings though several
channels, quantitatively, for this specification, the higher output
The size of precautionary savings depends crucially on the value of
the coefficient of relative risk aversion in the utility function, σ. To see
this, note that if σ = 0, utility is linear and the optimal model solution
exhibits no precautionary savings. In order to assess the sensitivity of
baseline results to this curvature parameter, the model is solved for
cases of σ = 4 and σ = 1. As expected, changes in precautionary savings
are substantial. The lower curvature parameter decreases the size of the
mean and median precautionary savings for sample countries from 1.4
and 1.5% of the GDP to 1.0 and 1.1% of the GDP respectively. The higher
curvature parameter increases the same statistics to 2.8 and 2.8% of the
GDP respectively (see rows 1, 2 and 3 in Table 5). Since curvature of the
utility function does not affect the optimal solution in the deterministic
case, the consumption smoothing component of the current account is
unaltered and any change in the total 2007 current account is entirely
due to changes in precautionary savings.
Next, consider the effect of a change in the subjective discount factor,
β, reported in rows 4 and 5 of Table 5. Heavier discounting lowers the
net present value of exhaustible resource wealth, but at the same time
increases the risk-free interest rate that puts the economy on a stable
14
More detailed tables with country-by-country results for each sensitivity test are
available from the authors upon request.
6.2. Growth in conventional output
62
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
50
Deterministic model: Corr = 0.75; R.M.S.E.= 9.3
Stochastic model: Corr = 0.77; R.M.S.E.= 8.9
40
LBY
30
KWT
Model
OMN
SAU
ARE
20
DZA
QAT
NGA
VEN
NOR
10
IRN
0
-10
-10
RUS
KAZ
0
10
20
30
40
50
Data
Fig. 11. Actual and model-based 2007 current account balances, in percent of GDP. Notes: “R.M.S.E.” calculated as root mean square error between model and data. “Corr” refers to
correlation between model and data.
growth rate on the stable growth path induces additional savings so
as to sustain a constant consumption–output ratio. As a result, the
consumption smoothing component of the current account increases.
In contrast, the precautionary savings component decreases because
of the reduced weight for exhaustible resources in future income.
Since it is hard to empirically justify an 8% risk-free interest rate, an
alternative specification is also considered. Assume that instead of the
utility specified in Eq. (6), the household maximizes consumption per
effective unit of labor, U(Ct/Yt). Under this specification, the interest
rate on the stable growth path satisfies R = (1 + g)/β, which amounts
to 6%. Results for this sensitivity test are presented in row 9. In this
case, the lower interest rate further increases the amount of additional
savings that are required to attain a constant consumption–output
ratio on the balanced growth path. As a result, we see a further increase in the 2007 consumption smoothing component and a further
decrease in the 2007 precautionary savings component of the current
account (see row 9 in Table 5).
Both ‘productivity growth’ scenarios show that, although levels of
precautionary savings can be significantly altered, the main finding
from the baseline model – economically non-negligible levels of
precautionary savings – survives introduction of productivity growth
into the model. Furthermore, Norway has outperformed the rest of the
sample in terms of labor productivity growth. For the sample as a
whole, in line with the findings of the literature on the ‘resource curse’
(see e.g. Sachs and Warner, 2001 and Fig. 5), the average labor
productivity growth rate over the most recent oil price cycle is close to
zero and, thus, in line with the baseline parameterization.
6.3. Path and lifespan of exhaustible resource extraction
The exhaustible resource extraction path in the model is obtained
by combining estimates from the 2000 US Geological Survey for oil
and gas reserves and EIA's projected future extraction quantities until
2030. These underlying estimates and projections are subjected to
significant uncertainty, primarily with regards to reservoir characteristics, future extraction technologies and costs, but also related to
limitations in the coverage of available exhaustible resource reserve
estimates.
The sensitivity analysis with respect to exhaustible resource quantities covers two scenarios. In the first one, the size of the exhaustible
resource reserves are changed by varying the weight of exhaustible
resource income in total output in all periods, keeping the lifespan of
resources fixed. In the second scenario, the size of the exhaustible
resource reserves is changed by varying the lifespan of the reserves,
while keeping the exhaustible resource share in output constant. In
both cases we consider a 10% increase/decrease in total reserves of
exhaustible resources.
Results for the two scenarios are reported in rows 10–13 of Table 5.
As already conveyed in the previous section, an increase in per-period
quantities of exhaustible resources should increase precautionary
savings as well as the consumption smoothing component of the
current account. In contrast, an increase in the lifespan of exhaustible
resources should increase precautionary savings, but decrease the
consumption smoothing component. Overall, a 10% change in total
exhaustible resource reserves leads to relatively minor deviations from
the baseline results. Notice that a change in reserves has a smaller effect
when introduced by varying the lifespan of exhaustible resource,
because intertemporal discounting substantially lowers the net present
value of additional revenues to be extracted from period T onwards.
6.4. Process for exhaustible resource prices
The parameterized process for the exhaustible resource price is
another crucial input in the baseline model. Taking as given the
assumed price process, rows 14–17 in Table 5 report sensitivity results
with respect to two key inputs — the persistence of the process and its
expected mean value.
A higher expected mean value of the price process decreases the
2007 consumption smoothing component of the current account, but
increases precautionary savings. The consumption smoothing component decreases because higher expected mean price implicitly
lowers the size of the initial positive 2007 price shock, or could even
reverse its sign. With a smaller positive shock it is optimal to consume
more of the current period's exhaustible resource income. In contrast,
the precautionary savings component increases, as a higher expected
mean price raises the weight of exhaustible resources in total output
and thus increases uncertainty about the future wealth.
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
63
20
Percent of sample GDP
15
10
5
Precautionary
0
Consumption smoothing
-5
-10
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
Year
Fig. 12. Decomposition of model's external savings into precautionary and consumption smoothing motives (aggregated sample of 13 countries).
This result offers an interesting insight into the optimal behavior
for exhaustible resource exporters. The recent increase in the price of
exhaustible resources has motivated exporting countries (correctly or
incorrectly) to increase the expected long-run price of the resource,
which in turn justifies higher current consumption levels. However, it
should be borne in mind that the higher consumption levels need to be
adjusted downwards to account for the implicitly assumed increase in
the long run weight of the more volatile exhaustible resource revenues
in total income, brought about by the assumed increase in the long run
price of the resource.
A more persistent price process makes the reversion to the mean
following the initial positive price shock more gradual. As a result, the
Table 5
Summary of sensitivity analysis for current account components.
Row
number
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
Deviation from baseline
Baseline
σ'=σ+4
σ'=σ−1
β ' = β + 0.005
β ' = β − 0.005
ni ' = ni + 0.005 ∀ i
ni ' = ni − 0.005 ∀ i
At + 1/At = 0.02 ∀ t (Case 1)
At + 1/At = 0.02 ∀ t (Case 2)
zt ' = 1.1zt ∀ t
zt ' = 0.9zt ∀ t
Ti ' = 1.1Ti ∀ i
Ti ' = 0.9Ti ∀ i
— —
p ' = p + 10
—
p ' =—
p − 10
ρ ' = ρ + 0.05
ρ ' = ρ − 0.05
Consumption
smoothing, % of
GDP
Precautionary
savings, % of GDP
Mean
Median
Mean
Median
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
17.0
17.0
17.0
18.9
15.6
21.2
12.9
20.3
25.1
18.7
15.5
16.7
17.5
12.7
20.7
11.3
19.2
18.6
18.6
18.6
21.1
16.8
23.0
14.5
20.2
26.1
20.5
17.0
17.8
19.9
14.0
22.2
12.0
21.3
1.4
2.8
1.0
1.2
1.5
1.0
1.8
1.2
0.8
1.6
1.2
1.4
1.3
1.8
1.0
4.1
0.7
1.5
2.8
1.1
1.2
1.7
1.1
1.9
1.3
1.0
1.7
1.3
1.5
1.4
1.9
1.1
4.2
0.8
Note: In the column reporting the type of deviation from baseline ‘primed’ parameters
represent the deviation and subscript i indexes sample countries. For definitions of Case
1 and Case 2 in rows 8–9 see Section 6.2.
2007 consumption smoothing component of the current account
decreases and precautionary savings increase. The quantitative effects
from altering the persistence of the price process can be substantial.
For example, an increase in the persistence parameter from ρ = 0.89
to ρ = 0.94 triples the mean and median sizes of precautionary savings
in the sample, while a reduction to ρ = 0.84 cuts precautionary
savings by half.
We also examine if the model results under various sensitivity
tests preserve the correlation with data observed in Fig. 11. In this
regard two results are noteworthy. First, for all sixteen sensitivity
tests the correlation between the current account in the model and
data remains above 0.67 and in the case of the added productivity
growth (rows 8 and 9), the correlation increases to 0.82. Second, in all
sixteen cases the stochastic model exhibits higher correlation and
lower mean square error between current accounts in the model and
data than the deterministic model. This result reiterates our earlier
finding that the precautionary motive is a significant determinant of
current account balances.
7. Conclusions
This paper introduces the precautionary savings motive into the
framework of a deterministic small open economy model to study the
optimal consumption–savings choices in economies with exhaustible
resources. The model fares moderately well at capturing savings/current
account behavior in exhaustible resource countries in both cross-section
and time-series data. According to the model, the sizable contribution of
the exhaustible resource exporters to global imbalances over the last
decade is justified on the grounds of the exhaustible nature of the
resource, historically high resource prices and uncertainty about future
prices.15
The model results show that, while the desire to smooth consumption is the main determinant of external sector dynamics, allowing for
uncertainty in the price of exhaustible resources can generate sizable
15
This benign view of current account surpluses in oil exporting countries is also
espoused by Blanchard and Milesi-Ferretti (2009).
64
R. Bems, I. de Carvalho Filho / Journal of International Economics 84 (2011) 48–64
external savings, more so for countries where extraction of exhaustible
resources dominates economic activity. When aggregated over all
sample countries, precautionary savings in 2007 add up to 36 billion
dollars, which amounts to 1% of the sample's GDP. The size of precautionary savings for other years is similar in magnitude. We also find
that the precautionary motive improves the model's fit with data.
Extensive sensitivity analysis shows that the main finding from the
model – economically non-negligible levels of precautionary savings – is
not driven by the parameterization of the baseline exercise.
There are several important issues that are left for future research.
First, the ‘small open economy’ assumption is employed throughout
the paper. When taken separately, each of the exhaustible resource
economies is likely too small to affect outcomes in the rest of the
world. However, when taken as a group, it is possible that the savings
behavior of exhaustible resource countries affects the world interest
rate.
Second, we have abstracted from the investment requirements for
the extraction of exhaustible resources. For economies in the process of
expanding their exhaustible resource output, e.g., Kazakhstan, this
assumption might be problematic, since expansion of the extraction
capacity requires large upfront investments. In such instances, current
account deficits might be driven not only by the consumption smoothing
and precautionary savings motives, but also by the required investment
in the exhaustible resource sector.
Finally, several aspects of the paper's exercise suggest that the
estimated precautionary savings represent a lower bound. There might
be more uncertainty about the price of the exhaustible resource at
distant horizons than the assumption of stationarity implies. There is
also considerable uncertainty about the remaining stock of exhaustible
resources, which we do not model. As rows 14–17 in Table 5 show,
added uncertainty can significantly increase the size of precautionary
savings.
Appendix A. Solution Method (case of n = 0)
The problem we want to solve is:
+∞
t
max
E
∑
β
U
ð
C
Þ
0
t
∞
fCt gt = 0
s:t:
t =0
Bt
+ 1
= Bt ð1 + r Þ + Y + pt Zt −Ct ;
where notation is the same as in Section 3. B0 is given and pt is a
random sequence. This problem does not have a steady-state solution,
so one needs a shortcut to solve it. The shortcut we use is to assume
that there is no randomness beyond the exhaustible resource
depletion date T. Then the problem can be solved recursively. In the
first period after depletion, T+1, the consumption–savings decision
going forward is:
V BT
+ 1
s:t:
Bt
ET
= max
+ ∞
fCt gT
+ 1
+ 1
+ 1
+ ∞
t−T−1
∑ β
t =T + 1
U ðCt Þ
= Bt ð1 + r Þ + Y−Ct :
With CRRA preferences this problem has a closed-form solution:
V BT
+ 1
=
Y + rBT + 1 1−σ
;
ð1−βÞð1−σ Þ
where for each possible value on a grid for BT+1 (it can be a large
positive or negative number), we can calculate the value of the
program going forward. The problem can then be solved recursively
back to the initial period. For T, the last period with positive output in
the exhaustible resource sector, the problem to be solved numerically
over a grid on BT, pT with a finite number of nodes is:
VT ðBT ; pT Þ = max
CT
s:t:
BT
+ 1
U ðCT Þ + βVT
+ 1
BT
+ 1
= BT ð1 + r Þ + Y + pT ZT −CT ;
For all periods up to T-1, the decision problem incorporates the
uncertainty over prices going forward:
Vt ðBt ; pt Þ = max U ðCt Þ + βEt Vt
CT
s:t:
Bt
+ 1
+ 1
Bt
+ 1 ; pt + 1
= Bt ð1 + r Þ + Y + pt Zt −Ct :
References
Bailen, Jose, Kramarenko, Vitaliy, 2004. Issues in medium-term management of oil
wealth. IMF Country Report No. 04/308. Washington: International Monetary Fund,
pp. 22–36.
Baxter, Marianne, Kouparitsas, Michael A., 2006. What can account for fluctuations in
the terms of trade. International Finance 9 (1), 63–86.
Bems, Rudolfs, de Carvalho Filho, Irineu, 2009. Current Account and Precautionary
Savings for Exporters of Exhaustible Resources. IMF Working Paper No.09/33,
March.
Blanchard, Olivier, Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, 2009. Global imbalances: in midstream.
IMF Staff Position Note SPN/09/29.
Borensztein, Eduardo, Jeanne, Olivier, Sandri, Damiano, 2009. Macro-hedging for
commodity exporters. IMF Working Paper No. 09/229.
British Petroleum, 2008. Statistical Review of World Energy.
British Petroleum, 2009. Statistical Review of World Energy.
Broda, Christian, 2004. Terms of trade and exchange rate regimes in developing
countries. Journal of International Economics 63, 31–58.
Caballero, Ricardo J., 1990. Consumption puzzles and precautionary savings. Journal of
Monetary Economics 25 (1), 113–136.
Carroll, Christopher D., 2001. A theory of the consumption function, with and without
liquidity constraints (expanded version). NBER Working Paper No. 8387.
Cremer, J., Salehi-Isfahani, D., 1991. Models of the Oil Market. Harwood Academic
Publishers, New York.
Daniel, James, 2001. Hedging government oil price risk. IMF Working Paper No. 01/185.
Davis, Jeffrey, Ossowski, Rolando, Fedelino, Annalise, 2003. Fiscal Policy Formulation
and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries. Washington: International
Monetary Fund.
de Carvalho Filho, Irineu, 2007. Medium-term fiscal sustainability in Trinidad and
Tobago. IMF Country Report No. 07/08, pp. 2–14.
Easterly, William, Kremer, Michael, Pritchett, Lant, Summers, Lawrence H., 1993. Good
policy or good luck?: country growth performance and temporary shocks. Journal
of Monetary Economics 32 (3), 459–483.
Energy Information Administration, 2008. International Energy Outlook.
Energy Information Administration, 1998. International Energy Outlook.
Fogli, Alessandra, Perri, Fabrizio, 2006. The great moderation and the U.S external
imbalance. Monetary and Economic Studies 24 (S-1), 209–234.
Ghironi, Fabio, 2007. The role of net foreign assets in a new Keynesian small open
economy model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (6), 1721–2060.
Ghosh, Atish R., Ostry, Jonathan D., 1997. Macroeconomic uncertainty, precautionary
savings, and the current account. Journal of Monetary Economics 40 (1), 121–139.
Griffin, James M., 1985. OPEC behavior: a test of alternative hypothesis. The American
Economic Review 75 (5), 954–963.
International Monetary Fund, 2009. World Economic Outlook Database.
Krautkraemer, Jeffery, 1998. Nonrenewable resource scarcity. Journal of Economic
Literature 36, 2065–2107.
Lane, Philip R., Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, 2007. The external wealth of nations mark II:
revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, 1970–2004. Journal
of International Economics 73 (2), 223–250.
Lin, Cynthia C.-Y., Wagner, Gernot, 2007. Steady-state growth in a hotelling model of
resource extraction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 54, 68–83.
Ramcharran, Harri, 2002. Oil production response to price changes: an empirical
application of the competitive model to OPEC and non-OPEC countries. Energy
Economics 24, 97–106.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., Warner, Andrew M., 2001. The curse of natural resources. European
Economic Review 45 (4–6), 827–838.
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie, Uribe, Martín, 2003. Closing small open economy models.
Journal of International Economics 61 (1), 163–185.
Takizawa, Hajime, 2005. Fiscal sustainability and options for fiscal adjustment. IMF
Country Report No. 05/234, pp. 25–39.
Thomas, Alun H., Kim II, Jun, Aslam, Aqib, 2008. Equilibrium non-oil current account
assessments for oil producing countries. IMF Working Paper No. 08/198.
United Nations, 2008. World population prospects. The 2008 Revision Population
Database.
United States Geological Survey, 2000. World Petroleum Assessment.
World Bank, 2008. World Development Indicators Database.