Download Capitalism Unleashed

Document related concepts

Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
CAPITALISM UNLEASHED
This page intentionally left blank
Capitalism
Unleashed
finance globalization and
welfare
Andrew Glyn
1
3
Great Clarendon Street, Oxford OX2 6dp
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.
It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide in
Oxford New York
Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press
in the UK and in certain other countries
Published in the United States
by Oxford University Press Inc., New York
© Andrew Glyn, 2006
The moral rights of the author have been asserted
Database right Oxford University Press (maker)
First published 2006
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press,
or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate
reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction
outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department,
Oxford University Press, at the address above
You must not circulate this book in any other binding or cover
and you must impose the same condition on any acquirer
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
Data available
Typeset by Newgen Imaging Systems (P) Ltd., Chennai, India
Printed in Great Britain
on acid-free paper by
Biddles Ltd., King’s Lynn, Norfolk
ISBN 0–19–929199–3
978–0–19–929199–1
1 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2
To Miles, Lucy, Tessa and Jonathan
This page intentionally left blank
Preface
Low inflation, quiescent industrial relations, freedom for capital to
chase profitable opportunities without restraint and the domination
of market-based solutions have become familiar features of the
economic landscape of the rich economies. When such a pattern
becomes firmly established it soon acquires the status of business as
usual. Yet 30 years ago inflation was rising, profits were squeezed,
trades unions were bargaining aggressively and parties of the left
were actively discussing ideas for deeper state intervention in industry. A huge shift in economic policies and behaviour was needed to
launch our economies on their new trajectory. This book provides a
short history of how this transformation was achieved and examines
the impact on growth, stability and equality of letting free enterprise
off the leash.
Authors of books like this one always hope that it will be widely
accessible, in this case to anybody interested in the current debates on
economics and economic policy. Some acquaintance with economic
terminology and ideas is helpful, though I have tried to explain the
less familiar concepts. I trust that it will be useful to students in a
wide range of social sciences, not just economics, who would like to
get a feel for the ‘big picture’ of how the economic system has been
developing.
The focus is on the rich countries—Western Europe, North America,
Japan and Australasia. The rest of the world features only when and
where its economic development has a major effect on the most
developed economies. Thus Africa barely figures, whilst China
receives considerable attention. Those primarily interested in the
‘South’ should still find the book of interest. After all, economic
trends in the rich ‘North’ have such important effects on the rest of
the world that they are far from irrelevant to those whose primary
viii
PREFACE
concerns are with the poorer countries. Moreover, as Marx pointed
out in 1867, ‘[T]he country that is more developed industrially only
shows, to the less developed, the image of its own future’ (Preface to
first German edition of Capital, volume 1).
In previous work with co-authors1 I have analysed the development of the rich economies from 1945 through the 1980s. The main
focus was on profitability, growth and the labour market. The postwar story unfolds around a central theme of the relations between
capital and labour, with the balance of economic power betweeen
the USA, Europe and Japan an important sub-plot. It is often
assumed that the great ‘Golden Age’ boom of the 1950s and 1960s
only required the helping hand of Marshall Aid to emerge smoothly
out of post-World War II devastation. This was far from the case. The
period of reconstruction was one of social and political turmoil,
illustrated in the following quotations from The Economist during
the late 1940s2
The [French] bourgeoisie are not reconciled to the passing of a large measure
of political and even economic power to the organised working class . . . Cold
War in Italian Industry . . . With hoarse democratic shouts of ‘Down with
Communism’ Japanese employers are rushing to . . . knock out the tottering
Japanese trade union movement.
The boom only emerged after the restoration of employer authority
in the factories and macroeconomic discipline—with government
budgets balanced, modest increases in the money supply and low
inflation.
The boom in turn brought a strengthening of labour, the weakening
of the previously dominant position of the USA and the economic
turmoil of the 1960s and 1970s—rising inflation, profits squeeze,
unstable exchange rates, heightened industrial conflict. This turmoil
posed severe challenges to the functioning of capitalism, as Chapter 1
of the present book recounts. The next two chapters deal with the
response of governments—in terms of restoring macroeconomic
discipline, privatization and the encouragement of market forces
and the focus of business on ‘shareholder value’.
Taking the story through from the 1970s up to the present day
necessarily involves a widening of the perspective. Distributional
PREFACE
ix
conflict between capital and labour in the rich economies is for now
not the most problematic element in their functioning. Thus
The Economist, as ever the reliable weathervane for assessing the
concerns of business, published 61 articles with a focus on trade
unions, labour relations and industrial disputes in the period
April–June 1979 and only ten in the corresponding months of 2005.
What then are the most significant new developments which have
to be interwoven with the continuing themes of the position of the
unions, the standing of the dollar, macroeconomic policy and the
behaviour of profitability and capital accumulation? One has been
the growth of the financial sector, in terms of its rising profitability,
its widening sphere of operation and its growing influence on many
aspects of economic life. This has important implications for the
dynamism and stability of the advanced economies. Secondly, the
expansion of manufacturing capacity by low wage producers in
the South has undermined the competitive position of traditional
industries in the North whilst bolstering the living standards of
workers in other sectors. Thirdly, new technology is believed to be
undermining the position of the less qualified workers in the rich
countries. Thus the chapters which follow cover such issues as the
drive for shareholder value, corporate scandals, the growth of
China’s exports, the New Economy boom in the USA, the impact of
globalization on the welfare state, inequality and declining demand
for unskilled labour.
Providing a coherent interpretation of such a wide range of issues
posed a considerable challenge. Fortunately there is a mass of
research now available on most contemporary economic trends and
issues. Important surveys appear regularly in the Journal of
Economic Perspectives, the Oxford Review of Economic Policy and
the working papers of the National Bureau of Economic Research,
for example. The references in the back of the book show how much
I have drawn on all this work, which the internet makes instantly
and freely available to those fortunate enough to have access to a
good university library system. I have used endnotes collected after
the text mainly to indicate sources used and in some cases to explain
a calculation or to amplify a point. In constructing an argument from
this material I have used direct quotations more often than is usual;
x
PREFACE
hopefully it is more convincing to hear directly from the horse’s
mouth. Of course I selected the quotes and I have interpreted the
analyses contained in them to support my own line of argument.
Readers can pursue these issues further using the material referenced. I have avoided lengthy discussion of alternative interpretations of the trends as this would break up the story and may be of
limited interest to many readers. However I have tried to indicate
where such debates can be pursued.
Much of the material in this book is inevitably quantitative in
nature. It is often essential to know not just whether some indicator
moved up or down but roughly by how much. As a result my other
major source was statistical databases. Much of this material is
available on the websites of the national statistical authorities and
the international organizations such as the OECD and IMF.
Wherever possible I have presented the numbers in graphs which I
hope illustrate the argument in an accessible fashion. Since the main
point is always covered in the text, the graphs can be skipped by readers who do not find them helpful. Notes on the sources and definitions for the data in the graphs and tables are collected in the Data
Appendix. Where very standard variables are referred to—inflation,
GDP growth, unemployment—I have used standard OECD series (as
in OECD, Economic Outlook) without referencing the source.
When distributional conflict—inflation, the wage–price spiral and
the profit squeeze—was such a central and destabilizing feature of
many of the developed capitalist economies it seemed clear that a
resolution one way or the other was inevitable. This is how Bob
Sutcliffe and I saw the situation in 1971:
for British capitalism it looks as if this time the wolf is really at the
door . . . From 1964 to 1969 there was a huge increase in the share of the
national income taken by the working class . . . while economic measures
and structural changes could bring some relief to capital they are unlikely to
offer more than a partial way out . . . Capital’s necessary counter-attack
demands that the struggle assumes a more political character.’ (Glyn and
Sutcliffe 1971: 1)
We now know that the outcome of this struggle was the radical
weakening of the labour movement, macroeconomic stabilization
PREFACE
xi
and domination of free market ideas3. This applied in varying degrees
not only throughout the developed capitalist economies but took the
form of a much more thoroughgoing, dramatic and wholly unexpected ‘restoration of capitalism’ in the planned economies of the
USSR and the rest of the formerly communist world. This latter
development has brought a huge crisis for socialists who, however
critical of the communist system, could still look to the centrally
planned economies as evidence that alternatives to capitalism could
at least maintain themselves. Old certainties, which I shared, that
economic problems would be readily solved once free market logic
was supplanted by a planned economy operating according to production for need, now seem far too abstract to carry much conviction
or political credibility.
However we are not at the ‘end of economic history’ to adapt a
famous catchphrase. On the contrary new questions have been
thrown up by the unleashing of capitalism in the 1980s. Will the ever
more complex financial system implode in a major financial crisis
and bring prolonged recession? Will the integration of the vast labour
supplies of China and India into the world economy shift the balance
of power even further in the direction of employers and bring a sustained shift in the distribution of income from labour to capital in
the rich countries or a renewed outbreak of distributional conflict in
the industrializing countries? Can the welfare states of Northern
Europe survive the combined pressures of globalization and free
market ideology and be developed in a way that meet the aspirations
of egalitarians?
Some pointers to possible answers emerge from the analysis
which follows. However it is useless to speculate about the next
instalment of the history of capitalism before trying to understand
the current episode. That is the primary focus of this book.
Corpus Christi College and the University of Oxford gave me a
term’s leave in the autumn of 2004 and the Oxford Economic Papers
Research Fund provided financial support.
I am most grateful for help with references, access to the unpublished
work or data from the following: Chris Allsopp, Philip Armstrong,
Paul Auerbach, Pulapre Balakrishnan, Jo Blanden, Susan M. Collins,
xii
PREFACE
Martin Conyon, Paul Ekins, Jerry Epstein, Jonathan Garner, John
Grahl, Francis Green, Bob Hancke, Brian Harrison, Dieter Helm,
Torben Iversen, John Kelly, Matthias Lang, John Knight, Anthony
Maidment, William Nordhaus, Tao Ran, Kath Scanlon, Kathleen
Thelen, Roberto Torrini and finally Phillipe Van Parijs whose long
campaign in support of Basic Income eventually notched up one
more adherent. Luca Nunziata was graciously unproprietorial about
a key quotation which featured in his thesis. Makoto Itoh gave me
the excellent advice that if I didn’t want to write a long book I could
try writing a short one.
I had very valuable comments on drafts from, Perry Anderson,
Andrea Boltho, David Chambers, Andrew Charlton, Jonathan Garner,
Francis Green, David Howell, Makoto Itoh, John Kelly, Harry Lee, John
Quiggin, Terry Peach, David Soskice and anonymous publishers’
readers. I have benefited enormously from collaborations over a long
period and have drawn freely on joint work with Philip Armstrong,
Dean Baker, V. Bhaskar, Esra Erdem, John Harrison, David Howell,
Alan Hughes, Alain Lipietz, Steve Machin, Bob Rowthorn, John
Schmitt, Ajit Singh, Wiemer Salverda and Bob Sutcliffe.
Mary Robertson provided great assistance and suggestions in the
final stages of writing. Discussions on many of the issues over a long
period with Bob Brenner, Bob Rowthorn, David Soskice and Lynn
Walsh have been extremely helpful. The person who was most responsible for my involvement with political economy, Bob Sutcliffe, read
and commented closely on the whole text, saved me from gaffes, and
urged a positive approach to future prospects. Sarah Caro was a most
encouraging and helpful editor. Finally, and above all, Wendy Carlin
was hugely supportive throughout the whole enterprise and
exceeded any possible obligation by reading and commenting in
detail on the whole draft twice, despite having to complete a far
weightier tome at the same time.
AJG
Contents
List of Figures
List of Tables
1 Challenges to Capital
xiv
xvi
1
2 Austerity, Privatization and Deregulation
24
3 Finance and Ownership
50
4 Globalization and International Economic Relations
77
5 Labour’s Retreats
104
6 Growth and Stability
129
7 Welfare and Income Inequality
156
Data Appendix
Notes
184
195
References
Index
209
227
List of Figures
1.1 Strikes: Days on Strike per 1,000 Industrial Workers, 1953–2003
6
1.2 Inflation and Real Wage Increases, 1963–2003
6
1.3 Manufacturing Gross Profit Share of Value Added, 1960–2000
7
1.4 Real Commodity Prices, 1952–2004
10
1.5 Consumer Prices in Germany and Italy relative to USA,
1960–2003
12
1.6 Deutschemark and Lira Exchange Rates versus Dollar, 1950–1980
12
1.7 Growth in Labour Productivity, Whole Economy, 1960–2004
14
1.8 OECD Government Expenditure, 1952–2003
17
1.9 Share Prices compared to Average Wages, 1950–2002
22
2.1 Unemployment Rates, 1960–2004
26
2.2 US Short-Term Interest Rates, 1950–2004
26
2.3 Long-Term Real Interest Rates, 1850–2003
29
2.4 Unemployment 1990–1999 and Strikes, 1968–1979
32
2.5 Structural Unemployment and Unemployment Benefits, 1999
48
3.1 US Financial Sector Corporate Profits, 1950–2004
52
3.2 Real Exchange Rates, 1975–2004
68
4.1 Manufacturing Productivity relative to USA, 1979–2003
78
4.2 US$ Exchange Rate: Nominal and Real, 1975–2003
80
4.3 US Current Account and Domestic Investment, 1980–2003
82
4.4 Shares of World Output, 1950–2004
89
4.5 Catch-Up to USA in Asia—per capita GDP, 1950–2001
89
4.6 Shares of World Commodity Exports, 1948–2003
92
4.7 Manufacturing Wages during Catch-Up, 1950–2003
93
4.8 Trade as a Percentage of GDP, 1950–2000
97
LIST OF FIGURES
xv
5.1 Men’s Employment Rate in Industry, 1970–2001
105
5.2 Women’s Employment Rate in Services, 1970–2001
106
5.3 Employment Rates, Men and Women, 1970–2001
106
5.4 Employment Rate Changes by Skill Groups, 1980–2000
108
5.5 Unemployment Benefits: Ratio to Earnings, 1960–1999
115
5.6 Wage Differentials, 1980–2000
117
5.7 Minimum Wages—Ratio to Average Pay, 1964–2000
119
5.8 Trade Union Membership as a Percentage of
Employees, 1960–2001
121
6.1 Growth of Output per Head of the Population, 1960–2004
131
6.2 Contributions to US GDP Growth: Three Long Expansions
132
6.3 US Capital Stock Growth: Private Business, 1950–2003
134
6.4 US Profit Rates: Non-financial Corporations, 1950–2004
136
6.5 Japan Profit Rates: Non-financial Corporations, 1952–2003
141
6.6 Europe Profit Rates: Non-financial Sector, 1950–2003
146
7.1 Correlation between Sons’ and Fathers’ Incomes, 2000
174
List of Tables
1.1 Labour Market Trends, 1960–1979
4
2.1 Budget Deficits, 1952–2004
33
2.2 Production and Incomes in UK Utilities, 1970–2002
40
4.1 Financing the US Balance of Payments Deficit, 1980–2004
85
4.2 Capital Accumulation: Growth Rates of Fixed Capital Stock,
1960–2004
86
4.3 China’s Exports, 1980–2003
91
4.4 Import Penetration of Domestic Markets for Manufactures,
1913–2001
97
4.5 Foreign Direct Investment Flows, 1992–2003
100
6.1 Labour Productivity Growth in Business Sector, 1976–2003
143
6.2 Global Growth Volatility, 1954–2003
148
7.1 Corporation Tax Rates: OECD Countries, 1982–2001
165
7.2 Social Spending: OECD Countries, 1980–2001
166
7.3 Income Inequality: OECD Countries, 1980–2000
169
7.4 Poverty and Impact of the Benefit and Tax System, 2000
171
1
Challenges to Capital
We all had the feeling it could come apart in quite a serious way.
As I saw it, it was a choice between Britain remaining in the liberal financial system of the West as opposed to a radical change
of course because we were concerned about Tony Benn precipitating a policy decision by Britain to turn its back on the IMF.
I think if that had happened the whole system would have begun
to come apart. God knows what Italy might have done; then
France might have taken a radical change in the same direction.
It would not only have had consequences for economic recovery,
it would have had great political consequences. So we tended to
see it in cosmic terms.
(US State Department official recalling UK negotiations with
the IMF in 1976, quoted in Sunday Times, 21 May 1978).
In the 1950s and 1960s the economies of the most developed capitalist
countries (North America, Western Europe, Japan and Australasia)1
enjoyed an unprecedented boom, combined with low unemployment, low inflation and rapidly growing living standards. This was
soon to be designated the ‘Golden Age’, because in the second half of
the 1960s and through the 1970s the whole structure of stable, profitable growth threatened to fall apart. As the comment at the top of
the page indicates, the very stability of the capitalist system seemed
to be under serious threat.
The rest of this chapter outlines the various strands of this story.
The long boom of the 1950s and 1960s brought high employment
and greatly strengthened the bargaining position of workers. This
2
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
led to wage increases and a profits squeeze and powerful unions
challenged the freedom of employers to run their businesses and
invest as they pleased. The relatively orderly international economic
system, presided over by the USA after World War II, was unravelling
as Europe and Japan were closing the gap in productive efficiency
with the USA. Combined with different degrees of wage pressure in
different economies, this led to a splintering of the fixed exchange
rate system. Inflationary pressure was exacerbated by the rise in food
and raw material prices in the early 1970s, a response to high demand
and topped up by speculation. More ominous was the fourfold
increase in oil prices at the end of 1973, initiated by the OPEC
producers and reflecting the much more assertive stance of some
ex-colonial countries. A further underlying problem, though this only
became clear with the benefit of several years’ hindsight, was a severe
decline in the rate of productivity growth from the mid-1970s. Since
productivity growth is the basic source of increased living standards
and improved public services, a slower rate of expansion was bound
to exacerbate conflicts over the distribution of national output.
The common theme to these apparently disparate problems was
that the very success of the ‘Golden Age’ seemed to have undermined its basis. It brought extended full employment and thus the
strengthening of labour; high demand for energy and other materials
was pressing against available supplies; Europe and Japan were
catching up with the USA thus disrupting international economic
relations; productivity growth appeared to be running out of steam
as the potential of existing technologies was used up. Moreover,
although the USSR and the other planned economies had deep economic problems of their own, their continued existence still held
out the possibility of an alternative path for development to that
offered by free market capitalism. Although particularly important
as a model for developing countries, the apparent viability of planned
economies also made more credible a range of proposals from the
labour movements of the rich countries for radical constraints on
free market capitalism. The sections which follow consider the
various aspects of the turmoil of the 1970s in a little more detail.
The origins and nature of this widely heralded ‘crisis of capitalism’
are hotly debated and different authors ascribe varying weights to
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
3
the factors considered below.2 The account given here follows the
emphasis on profitability and capital-labour relations of Armstrong
et al. (1991).
Organized Labour
The most striking employment trend in the highly developed
economies during the long boom of the 1950s and 1960s was the
decline in importance of agricultural employment and the corresponding rise in the number of wage workers in industry and services.
Agricultural employment fell from 25% of total employment in
OECD countries in 1950 to 9% in 19733 and the proportion of those
working classified as self-employed fell from 31% in 1954 to 17% in
1973 as peasants shifted to the towns.4
In Europe the decline in agriculture was not quite as fast as in
Japan but much greater than in the USA, which had far fewer farmers
to start with. The exodus from agriculture contributed as much to
the labour force available for work in industry and services as did the
growing population of working age overall. Services employment
rose more rapidly than industrial employment because of slower
growth of labour productivity in services.5 The proportion of men of
working age (15–64) employed fell as more stayed on in education
and fewer carried on working into retirement. This rise in ‘inactivity’
did not imply an overall shortage of jobs for men, however, as male
unemployment was falling.
Women kept their rather small number of industrial jobs (14% of
urban women worked in industry in 1950 and 1973 whilst 52%
of urban men had industrial jobs in 1950 and 44% in 1973). However
urban women’s employment in Europe rose almost twice as fast as
men’s as large numbers moved from household work into jobs in
services.6
Although net inward migration was significant, by the end of the
1960s and early 1970s, when labour markets had become very tight,
it was only contributing 0.1% per year to the population of the
4
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
highly industrialized economies or a tenth of the total increase in
population of working age. In Europe net inward migration was only
one-fifth as important as a source of additional labour as the shift out
of agriculture.
The motor behind the expansion of jobs in the modern industrial
and services sector was the rapid accumulation of capital. Businesses
increased their stock of capital equipment by about 5% a year in the
1960s and early 1970s.7 Although capital per worker grew strongly,
more workers were still required in the new factories and offices.
The great expansion of urban population brought with it a
strengthening of trade unionism and legislative changes supporting
labour’s bargaining position. Table 1.1 shows a number of relevant
indicators. The proportion of those at work who were union members increased in the average OECD country. The increase was modest since employment in services was expanding and service workers
(apart from the growing group of public sector employees) tended to
be much less unionized than industrial workers. However, with
unemployment low over a prolonged period, union organization was
strengthened. The table also shows that the level of unemployment
benefits rose substantially compared to pay, and eligibility for benefit became more relaxed. Unemployment, as well as being less likely,
was also less costly financially to those affected, thus reducing the
pressure to take the first job that became available regardless of conditions. Employment protection legislation (EPL), against arbitrary
dismissal and generally limiting employer prerogatives over hiring
Table 1.1 Labour Market Trends, 1960–1979
Average for 19
OECD countries
Union
Membership
% of
employment
Employment
protection
legislation
index
Unemployment
benefit as % of
average pay
Unemployment
rate (%)
1960–4
1965–9
1970–4
1975–9
38.8
39.1
41.4
44.8
0.79
0.85
0.99
1.09
28.0
31.0
34.6
43.2
2.1
2.1
2.5
4.3
Sources: Baker et al. (2005). See Data Appendix.
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
5
and firing, was also extended in this period, as shown in the OECD’s
index. Another very significant gain for workers was a sharp fall in
average hours worked from around 2000 per year in 1950 to 1750 in
1973—the equivalent of more than a half day less work per week.8
An important manifestation of labour’s stronger position, and
employers’ resistance to workers’ demands, was the high level of
industrial conflict. The most spectacular examples of labour militancy were the strike waves of the late 1960s. Some 150 million days
were taken in strikes in France in May–June 1968 as workers occupied the factories, initially in protest at the suppression of student
demonstrations. Radical demands for workers’ control were channelled by the trade union leadership into negotiations which settled
for a 10% wage increase, an increase in the minimum wage, and
some extension of trade union rights. In 1969 60 million days in Italy
were taken by successive strike waves, originating on the shop floor.
These culminated in another 10% pay increase, combined with
reductions in working hours, parity of treatment when sick for blue
and white-collar workers and eventually a major extension of trade
union rights at the factory level. Nearly 25 million working days
were given over to strikes in the UK during 1970/71 after a national
incomes policy broke down.9 Even normally peaceful German
industrial relations were ruffled by a wave of unofficial strikes and
the United States topped the OECD league table in days on strike per
worker in 1970 (as it had done in 1954, 1955, 1959, 1960 and 1967).
Figure 1.1 shows the longer-run trend in strikes for OECD countries, with year to year fluctuations ironed out by using a five-year
average. Strikes are measured as days on strike per 1,000 workers in
industry. Strikes build up from the later 1960s to the mid-1970s and
then decline dramatically through the 1980s and 1990s. The 1990s
appear very quiet in terms of open industrial conflict even as compared to the golden years of the 1950s and 1960s.
In each of the European countries the rate of money wage
increases more or less doubled after the major strike movements10
and the trend of real wage increases rose steadily to reach over
4% per year in the early 1970s in the OECD countries (see Fig. 1.2).
The sharp rise in money wages also contributed to the upward trend
in inflation in the second part of the 1960s. Inflation rose more
6
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
sharply in the early 1970s with the rise in oil and commodity prices
(see below); when inflation reaches 12% a year the real value of
pay packets is falling by 1% a month—fast enough to be very noticeable and a source of increased social tension. The rise in inflation
reined in the rate of real wage increases, especially towards the end
of the 1970s.
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 1.1. Strikes: Days on Strike per 1,000 Industrial Workers, 1953–2003
Source: Office of National Statistics. See Data Appendix. 16 countries.
20
Inflation (% p.a.)
Real wages (% p.a. five-year average)
% per year
15
10
5
0
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
Fig. 1.2. Inflation and Real Wage Increases, 1963–2003
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 13 countries.
1990
1995
2000
7
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
Wage pressure also contributed to a squeeze on profitability. By the
mid-1970s the gross profit share in manufacturing, a sensitive and
readily available indicator of returns on investment in the sector of
the economy most exposed to the vicissitudes of industrial strife
and competition, had sunk by more than one-quarter in a decade
(see Fig. 1.3) having been pretty stable until the late 1960s. Gross
profits are calculated before deduction of depreciation on capital
employed. Depreciation was tending to rise as a share of value added,
in part because more of the capital stock was machinery, which
depreciates faster than factory building. Thus the fall in net profits
was proportionately considerably greater than the fall in the gross
share. Further, employers are most concerned with the rate of profits
compared to their capital outlays rather than output produced, and
these outlays were rising faster than output. Allowing for this, the
net rate of profit on capital employed in manufacturing had fallen by
nearly one-half by the end of the 1970s.11 It was apparent that the
profits squeeze was reflecting a combination of militant wage
pressure pushing up earnings and international competition
restraining price increases.12 The rise in imported material costs and
weakening of productivity growth (see below) further exacerbated
the distributional struggle.
0.4
0.3
0.2
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 1.3. Manufacturing Gross Profit Share of Value Added, 1960–2000
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix. 15 countries.
8
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
It is hard, 30 years or so later, to appreciate the sense of alarm
engendered by the industrial strife and distributional conflict of the
late 1960s and 1970s. In the UK the defeat of the Conservative
government in early 1974, after a second successful miners’ strike,
provoked an article in The Times (5 Aug. 1974) headlined ‘Could
Britain be heading for a military takeover’ by Lord Chalfont, a
Defence Minister in a previous Labour government. In it he wrote of
‘the massive power and often ruthless action of the great industrial
trades unions’ and noted that ‘Large industrial concerns are beginning to talk in terms of a co-ordinated defence against industrial
action or wholesale nationalisation’. A reply shortly thereafter (16
Aug. 1974) by the then Defence Correspondent of The Times,
appeared under the headline ‘It would not take a coup to bring British
troops onto the streets’, where he envisaged a scenario when ‘an
annual rate of inflation of 20 per cent would soon bring us to a point
where there had to be a stabilization plan involving great hardship to
most of the country or—even without a stabilization plan—the
effects of rising prices and shortages had caused such chaos that
conventional economic and social life was being overthrown’. He
went on to discuss scenarios in which the forces would be called in
to break strikes, which could escalate to a situation where ‘normal
legal administration is impossible and the only authority left is the
military commander’. Such a scenario, he wrote is ‘still nearly
inconceivable’ (his emphasis).
International Disorganization
At the end of World War II the USA was in an unrivalled position of
economic and political leadership of the OECD countries. In 1950,
with the bulk of post-war reconstruction completed, the USA
still produced about 60% of the total output of the biggest seven
capitalist countries, and its manufacturing industry was about twice
as productive, per person employed, as that of the UK, three times as
productive as German manufacturing and nine times as productive
as Japanese manufacturing.13 The economic power of the USA placed
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
9
the dollar at the centre of the international financial system, and
other countries fixed the value of their currencies to the dollar at
rates which were competitive after devaluations in 1949.
The long boom of the 1950s and 1960s was much stronger in Japan
and Europe than in the USA. Faster growth of the capital stock,
encouraged by plentiful supplies of relatively cheap labour and
taking advantage of new technologies and management practices
developed in the USA over the previous decades, eroded the productivity gap of European and Japanese manufacturing whilst lower
wage levels kept their exports highly competitive. Between 1955 and
1970 hourly labour productivity in manufacturing grew by 10.3%
per year in Japan and 6.7% in Germany, as compared to 2.3% per year
in the USA.14 Although money (and real) wages grew more slowly in
the USA this was not sufficient to maintain export competitiveness.
The US share of world manufactured exports halved between 1950
and 1970 (from 33% to 16%). Japan, having excelled in heavy
industry (basic metals including steel was estimated as 60% more
productive per hour worked in Japan than in the USA by 1980), was
rapidly developing world leadership in mass production industries.
In electrical machinery and instruments Japanese productivity
exceeded the US level by 1980.15 The US trade account moved into
deficit by the end of the 1960s compounding the weakness of the
dollar caused by heavy outflows of ‘direct investment’ as US corporations expanded their production activities abroad, mainly in other
OECD countries.
A second disorganizing influence on the international economic
relations of the OECD countries was the rise in the cost of raw materials, food and energy imported from outside the OECD. Figure 1.4
shows oil and non-energy commodity prices in real terms, that is as
compared to US domestic inflation. It shows the very sharp rise in all
commodity prices in 1974, especially oil. The combined index for
food, agricultural materials (like cotton) and metals has been on a
pretty continuous slide since then. Oil prices, however, kept up with
US inflation after 1974 before nearly doubling again in 1979/80 to a real
level about seven times as high as during the 1960s and early 1970s.
The OPEC price increases at the end of 1973 were precipitated by
political developments in the Middle East but the underlying factor
10
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
was rapidly increasing demand for oil. Energy and metals consumption
by the OECD countries were both growing at 5–6% per year over the
period 1960–73 and the rapid price increases of the period seemed to
confirm the message of the influential Club of Rome 1972 report,
Limits to Growth.16 This popularized the idea that the existing pattern of growth was unsustainable as the world was running out of
non-renewable resources. It became commonplace to point out that
the discovery of new reserves equivalent to Libya’s production
would be necessary every year to prevent the ‘depletion horizon’ for
oil from shrinking inexorably.
2
Real oil price
Real non-energy commodity price
1.5
1
0.5
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 1.4. Real Commodity Prices, 1952–2004
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 1974 ⫽ 1.
The rise in commodity prices, especially oil, added a vicious
twist to the inflationary pressure which had been bubbling away
since the mid-1960s. Workers found their real wage increases
constrained (see Fig. 1.2), but were able to pass part of the burden of
reduced real incomes onto the employers via the lower profit share
(see Fig. 1.3).
The post-war international monetary system formulated at Bretton
Woods was supposed to keep exchange rates between other currencies and the dollar fixed unless countries moved into ‘fundamental
disequilibrium’ on the balance of payments. This did not rule out
exchange rate changes but these were few and far between (devaluations of the French franc in 1958 and 1959; minor revaluations of
the German mark and Swiss franc in the early 1960s). Somewhat
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
11
surprisingly, countries were equally reluctant to devalue or revalue.
Devaluation added more pressure to inflation as import prices rose
and real wages were cut. In the case of the UK, forced to devalue in
1967, there were the added fears that this would undermine the
reserve role of sterling and the position of the City of London as a
financial centre, though in fact the City adapted by dealing in other
currencies (notably Eurodollars). At the same time, countries with
balance of payments surpluses were very reluctant to revalue as
this reduced the profitability and thus the competitiveness of their
powerful export industries.
However, differences in inflation rates tended to undermine the
fixed exchange rate system. In the 1960s inflation was at relatively
similar rates across the OECD countries and the desire to keep a
fixed exchange rate against the dollar put pressure on countries with
high inflation to cut demand and squeeze down on their economies.
However, the combination of the wage explosions, at different times
and intensities across the most industrialized countries, and the
varying impacts of the commodity price increases, brought an
increasing divergence of inflation rates in the 1970s. Over the period
1973–9 the degree of dispersion of inflation rates across the OECD
more than trebled. Figure 1.5 illustrates this dispersion by comparing Germany, which established its anti-inflationary credentials in
the 1970s, with Italy, the most notoriously inflation-prone of the
larger OECD economies. In the 1960s neither of their inflation rates
significantly diverged from that of the USA, which was the anchor of
the system. In the 1970s faster inflation pushed the nominal price
level in Italy higher and higher compared to the USA, whereas in
Germany low inflation brought steady falls in the price level relative
to that of the USA.
The combination of diverging productivity growth and inflation
rates generated persistent payments imbalances which undermined
the fixed exchange system. Exchange rate depreciations then
reflected, but also perpetuated or even increased, inflation differentials. Figure 1.6 shows how the value of the mark and lira moved
against the dollar; the mark appreciated strongly whilst the value of
the lira declined, reflecting the relatively low inflation in Germany
(relative to the USA) and the high inflation rate in Italy.
12
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
The broadly offsetting movements of inflation and exchange rates
noted above for the examples of Italy, Germany and the USA did not
mean that floating exchange rates painlessly eliminated all problems of international competitiveness. On the contrary, the real
exchange rate of an average OECD country fluctuated by an average
of 6% per year in the 1970s, twice the rate of fluctuation in the
3
Germany/USA
Italy/USA
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 1.5. Consumer Prices in Germany and Italy relative to USA, 1960–2003
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 1973 ⫽ 1.
2.5
Mark
Lira
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
Fig. 1.6. Deutschemark and Lira Exchange Rates versus Dollar, 1950–1980
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 1970 ⫽ 1.
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
13
1960s.17 In the 1970s fluctuations in nominal exchange rates were
daily occurrences rather than the rare events of the 1960s, but they
did not simply iron out the effect of inflation differentials. Such large
year to year changes in the competitiveness of a country’s traded
goods sectors were probably important in discouraging longer-term
investments in manufacturing.
Productivity Slowdown
The slowdown in productivity growth which occurred in the early
1970s was not widely recognized at the time. For example the
McCracken Report, an expert review of recent developments for the
OECD, concluded that ‘We see nothing on the supply side to prevent
potential output in the OECD from growing almost as fast in the
next five to ten years as it did in the 1960s’ (OECD 1977: 16). Given
the slack generated by the recession of 1974/5 they believed that
output could grow by some 5.5% per year over the period 1975–80.
However the slowdown proved to be lasting and made a significant
contribution to the turmoil of the 1970s and the form of the stabilization which followed.
The most basic indicator of productivity is output per hour
worked (see Fig. 1.7). In the USA labour productivity growth halved
after 1973 and stayed very low until the 1990s, when the new
economy boom sparked a productivity revival—discussed further in
Chapter 6. In Europe and Japan labour productivity growth, which
had been much faster than in the USA during the 1960s, nearly
halved after 1973 and fell again in the 1980s.
One contributory factor to the productivity slowdown was the
lower level of investment. Between 1973 and 1990 the rate of growth
of the capital stock in both Europe and Japan fell by more than onethird compared to the period 1960–73 and from the later 1960s
business capital accumulation has been on a downward trend in the
USA (see Fig. 6.3). The decline in accumulation reflected business
anxieties about the decline in profitability, the rise in inflation and
the other indicators of instability. The precise effects of slower
14
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
growth of capital on labour productivity are hard to determine. A
very detailed study for the USA estimated that about a half of the
slowdown in labour productivity growth could be explained by
slower growth of the capital stock.18 However other factors were
certainly involved as well.
7
6
% per year
5
1960 – 73
1973 – 79
1979 – 90
1990 – 2004
4
3
2
1
0
USA
Japan
Europe
Fig. 1.7. Growth in Labour Productivity, Whole Economy, 1960–2004
Source: Groningen Growth and Development Centre. See Appendix.
An obvious influence making for weaker productivity growth in
Europe and Japan was that the scope for their catching up with US
productivity levels had declined. The boom of the 1950s and 1960s
had narrowed the productivity lead of the USA over Japan and
Germany as the technologies developed earlier in the USA were
rapidly introduced by European and Japanese firms. This could
explain a gradual convergence of growth rates in the follower countries on that of the leader (USA). But it could not explain the sharpness of the productivity slowdown after 1973. Moreover catch-up
cannot explain the sharp decline in labour productivity growth in
the USA, still the productivity leader in most sectors.
The broadest explanation of productivity slowdown, which
should apply particularly to the USA as leader country, was that the
mass production system known as ‘Fordism’—assembly line production with workers performing repeated tasks—was reaching its
limits. This would imply that additional investment yielded smaller
productivity gains which in turn tended to discourage investment.
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
15
One aspect of these limits could be the erosion of factory discipline
as the stronger bargaining position of workers allowed them to limit
the speed of work. The rather widespread productivity slowdown in
the motor industry could be taken as symptomatic of these problems.19 Again, however, such effects would tend to explain a more
gradual deceleration rather than the sharp fall-off in productivity
growth which occurred, that also extended beyond the classic
assembly line industries.
What particularly distinguished the years after 1973 was the slow
growth in demand which resulted from the macroeconomic uncertainties discussed above. Consumers and business were hesitant,
real incomes were reduced as oil and other commodities cost more
and, even if interest rates failed to keep up with inflation, in nominal
percentage terms they were forbiddingly high. With unions still relatively strong after the long period of high employment it was difficult for firms to rationalize production and make workers redundant
on the scale needed to keep productivity growing rapidly. In the USA
two thirds of the slowdown in productivity in all those sectors where
it can be reliably measured took place in pipelines, oil extraction,
utilities, motor vehicles and air transport—sectors that were hardest
hit by the energy price shocks of the 1970s. The industries with the
largest decline in productivity growth suffered declines in output
growth of around 5% per year during the two decades after 1973, four
times the average decline. ‘This suggests that at least part of the
productivity slowdown stemmed from slower output growth in
industries characterised by economies of scale’ (Nordhaus 2004: 14).
An Alternative System?
Tight labour markets, industrial militancy, commodity price hikes,
inflation, profit squeeze, and even productivity slowdown and
instability in the international financial system could just be seen as
symptoms of a particularly buoyant burst of capital accumulation.
Surely things would calm down after a period of financial discipline
and demand restraint. But were these problems also symptomatic of,
16
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
and even encouraging to, a more fundamental challenge to the
capitalist system itself?
First of all, as noted earlier, the existence of the Soviet Union and
the planned economies of East Europe and China, together with their
influence over newly decolonized countries, represented an alternative economic system to one dominated by market forces and private
ownership. Although the communist system was bitterly attacked
by much of the New Left in the OECD countries for its undemocratic
nature, it still appeared to demonstrate that public ownership and
centralized planning could work. Growth per head of the population
was respectable in the Soviet Union over the period 1960–73—3.4%
per year as compared to 4.4% per year in Europe and only 3.0%
growth in the USA.20 Indeed with democratic setting of priorities,
and active worker involvement in enterprise operation, why should
a planned economy not work better than in ‘actually existing socialism’ (not to mention actually existing capitalism)?
More than a decade after the collapse of the Soviet system this may
seem rather fanciful. However experts on the Soviet economy in the
1970s and into the 1980s were indeed comparing it to Western capitalism by no means wholly unfavourably. Thus Alec Nove, the leading British authority on the Soviet economy, wrote in 1977:
[However] in the last few years the Western industrialised economies have
been shaken by inflation and recession. The Soviet-type economies have
appeared to be relatively stable in an increasingly unstable world. If their
centralized economy, with the help of computers, can continue to grow,
even at a modest rate, whilst our own economies decline or are threatened
with disintegration, this seems an important advantage, to set against the
many micro-irrationalities of Soviet planning. (Nove 1977: 8)
Nearly ten years later, a prominent US textbook called Soviet
Economic Performance and Structure argued that:
Soviet performance leaves much to be desired, but the bottom line is the
extent to which Soviet consumers can be satisfied with some increases in
the standard of living. Soviet consumers, just like their counterparts everywhere, complain, but why will this form the basis of meaningful pressure
when there is improvement and the vast bulk of the population has a strong,
basic admiration for the system? (Gregory and Stuart 1986: 430)
17
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
The final paragraph of their book pointed out that a ‘bright spot’ for
the Soviet leadership amongst rather gloomy economic forecasts
was that ‘the Western world enters the 1980s with significant troubles of its own. Productivity growth is a problem, high rates of inflation coexist with high rates of unemployment, and real wages are
actually declining in some countries.’ (ibid. 432).
There was one trend within the rich countries themselves which
already seemed to be nudging them away from free market capitalism—
the rise in the share of the state in GDP. Total state spending as a
share of GDP had not changed much in the 1950s as declining
military spending offset some increase in civil expenditure (see
Fig. 1.8). In the 1960s the share rose by about 4 percentage points to
reach 31% of GDP in 1970 and had exceeded one third in 1974.
During the turbulent period which followed the share of state spending lurched up and reached 40% in 1980, as ambitious spending
programs collided with a slowdown in GDP growth. In Europe the
share was considerably higher (more than 45%), with social democratic Sweden leading the way at 59.8% and the Netherlands close
behind.
The total of state spending includes a very large element of government redistribution of spending power (taxes raised to pay pensions,
45
% 0f GDP
40
35
30
25
20
1950
1960
1970
1980
Fig. 1.8. OECD Government Expenditure, 1952–2003
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
1990
2000
18
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
unemployment benefits and so forth); this category of state spending
left production (of the goods and services bought by pensioners for
example) in the hands of the private sector. Even so there was also
rapid growth of welfare state programs that did involve the state in
producing the services by employing teachers, doctors, social workers etc. These people working for the government were not producing
to make a profit for their employer and comprised around one-fifth of
total employees in many countries. Thus growing state employment
represented a shrinkage of the profit-oriented sector of the economy.
In addition most of the taxation to finance state spending had to be
paid by taxation on profits and wages in the private sector and this
tended to exacerbate distributional struggle as workers sought wage
increases to offset rising tax bills and employers sought higher prices
to maintain profit margins in the face of rising wages.21
On top of the seemingly inexorable rise in government spending
came proposals from the labour movement to restrict the prerogatives of capital within its own sphere—private business. A range of
plans emerged in the later 1960s and 1970s going well beyond the
customary collective bargaining issues of jobs and working conditions. To give a flavour of what was involved a brief discussion follows of German co-determination, Swedish wage-earner funds, the
British Labour Party’s ideas for planning agreements and finally the
French Socialist government’s plans for extensive nationalizations
in the early 1980s.
In Germany workers had achieved a system of co-determination
in the early 1950s with equal representation of employees and shareholders on boards of iron and steel companies. They secured lesser
representation within other companies but had the right to appoint
the labour director responsible for personnel affairs. In the 1970s
there was strong pressure to increase co-determination rights, which
resulted in an extension to cover employment contracts and training,
and in 1976 the proportion of worker representatives was increased
from one-third to a half for larger companies (though with a
shareholder-appointed chair having a casting vote). These extensions
were strongly resisted by employers, politically and in the courts.
German co-determination may have had fairly modest effects
on managerial freedom,22 but a comment in 1984 by a prominent
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
19
American economist, Armen Alchian, shows how it was viewed by
advocates of shareholder sovereignty: ‘The campaign for . . . codetermination on boards of directors appears to be attempts to control the
wealth of shareholders’ specialised assets . . . a wealth confiscation
scheme’ (quoted by Gorton and Schmid 2000: 1).
Co-determination was feared for its potential to limit management prerogatives and thus transfer value added to workers, in the
form of security or better conditions. The Swedish scheme for wageearner funds proposed by the trades unions in 1976 had potentially
more radical implications:
Firms above a certain size (fifty or a hundred employees) should be required
to issue new stocks corresponding to 20 per cent of annual profits
and . . . these stocks should be owned by funds representing wage earners as
a collective group . . . . Such a reform . . . would also counteract the tendency
towards increased concentration of wealth and complement industrial
democracy legislation . . . .Under this scheme the higher the rate of profit,
the more quickly collectivisation would occur. The committee calculated
that it would take thirty-five years for the wage-earner collective to acquire
forty-nine per cent of stocks in a firm operating at a ten per cent profit rate.
(Pontusson 1987: 13)
Rudolph Meidner, the chair of the committee which drew up the proposals, said in an interview, ‘we want to deprive the capitalists of the
power that they exercise by virtue of ownership’ (Pontusson 1987:
14). The committee also envisaged that wage-earner ownership could
chivvy firms into following government industrial policies.
Dividends would be used in part to finance ‘adult education, wageearner consultants and various other programs to help wage-earners,
and union activists in particular, take advantage of the new labor
laws and exercise their ownership role. The gradual transfer of
ownership would thus be accompanied by a new competence within
the ranks of the union movement.’ (Pontusson 1992: 192).
It is important to appreciate just how seriously these proposals
were taken at the time. In a lengthy dissection of the ‘Rise and Fall of
the Swedish Model’ in the Journal of Economic Literature, a very
prominent Swedish economist Erik Lundberg argued in 1985 that
the wage-earner funds represented a decisive move away from the
20
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
Social Democrats’ tradition of pragmatism, which had previously
seen radical proposals for socialization or central planning abandoned rather quickly. ‘At the present time the socialist goals are
more serious and against the background of a crisis in the functioning of the Swedish economy, the plans are more appealing, at least to
a strong minority of Social Democrats’ (Lundberg 1985: 31). He
noted also that ‘the bourgeois parties have refused emphatically, to
accept the proposal for collective funds in any form. The Opposition
includes the entrepreneurial organizations of private corporations,
as well as those of small firms. Their antagonism is complete’ (ibid.
31). The opposition was largely successful and only a highly diluted
form of the plan was implemented, but the point to underline here is
that the project was viewed by business with great alarm.
In the early 1970s the British Labour Party formulated an interventionist strategy aimed at industrial modernization. The 1973
Party Conference approved a plan for the next Labour government to
compulsorily nationalize 20–25 of the largest manufacturing companies, around one third of manufacturing output. The idea was to
take over a leading and profitable firm in each sector and use it to
introduce new products or processes forcing, through competitive
pressure, the other firms in the industry to follow suit. The other
firms would be obliged to sign planning agreements with the government detailing their plans for output, investment and employment which were to be consistent with the government’s overall
economic objectives. In the event the programme was watered down
before Labour came to power and no major firms were nationalized
and no serious planning agreement signed.
Labour’s plan was neither well worked in terms of how the leverage acquired over the private sector would be used, nor did it have the
political support and resolve required to push it through. However it
was still seen as a serious threat by the employers. The
Confederation of British Industry told the Labour Prime Minister
that ‘there was absolutely no room for compromise or negotiation
about further state intervention in industry and further nationalisation’ (Financial Times, 16 Sept. 1974).
During the Labour government’s 1976 negotiations over a loan
from the IMF, the left wing of the Labour Party, led by Tony Benn,
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
21
pushed unsuccessfully in the cabinet for import controls and other
measures as an alternative to spending cuts and deflation. They hoped
to maintain economic expansion and help secure the election manifesto objective of a ‘fundamental and irreversible shift in the balance
of power and wealth in favour of working people and their families’.
Two years after the fall of the Labour government in the UK the
French Socialist government of François Mitterrand came to power
in 1981 with the plan to double, from 11% to 22%, the share of
nationalized industries in industrial employment by taking over five
major groups in electronics and chemicals, the largest two steel
groups, 39 banks (bringing the share of public ownership of banks to
90%) and a major firm in a number of other sectors. As in the UK, the
plans called for these nationalized groups to spearhead industrial
modernization, within the context of five-year ‘plan contracts’
between the management and government.
The extent to which the nationalizations threatened private capital should not be exaggerated. Shareholders in the big five industrial
groups received compensation described by the Financial Times as
‘far too generous’ (24 May 1982), and Mitterrand reassured business
that he wanted the economy merely ‘a little more mixed’ (Financial
Times, 3 Oct. 1981). The Minister for Planning was credited with the
view that the market is ‘all embracing and irreplaceable’ (Financial
Times, 22 July 1981). Nevertheless the nationalization plans did
reflect the belief that private industry was incapable of adequately
modernizing the French economy and that this process needed to be
strongly state-led. In the event the nationalized firms, many of
which were loss making, were given large amounts of capital by the
government and they carried out major programmes of rationalization of their activities, which paved the way for their return to the
private sector (see Chapter 2).
Challenges Repulsed?
If nothing else, the level of stock market prices is a good indicator of
the degree of optimism amongst industrialists, financiers and
22
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
investment managers. Equity prices reflect prospects for profit making and in extreme cases even prospects for the survival of capitalism
itself. A sharp way, therefore, of comparing the fortunes of capital
and labour is to examine how equity prices move in relation to a
worker’s wage. Figure 1.9 tells a remarkable story. By the mid-1970s
share prices had fallen by about three-quarters relative to average
wages from the peak in the early 1960s as the Golden Age was getting
into full swing. The fall was sharpest in Europe, where in the late
1970s share prices had declined in relative terms by about fivesixths. However even in Japan and the USA the falls were by around
one-half. This collapse in confidence in financial markets reflected
all the developments discussed above—uncertainties raised by
industrial conflict, rising inflation, profits squeeze, productivity
slowdown, international disorganization, industrial conflict and
threats of deeper state involvement in industry.
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 1.9. Share Prices compared to Average Wages, 1950–2002
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 2000 ⫽ 1.
By 2000, however, share prices had regained all their previous
losses (Fig. 1.9), strikes had declined towards insignificance (Fig. 1.1),
the inflationary surge had been suppressed and real wages were
creeping up at a quite unthreatening rate (Fig. 1.2), profits had made
a substantial recovery (Fig. 1.3), commodity and oil prices had fallen
back to real levels not significantly higher than in the 1960s
(Fig. 1.4), the dollar appeared to be riding high and a zone of exchange
CHALLENGES TO CAPITAL
23
rate stability was about to be created by the formation of the
Eurozone, the rise in government spending had been halted (Fig. 1.8),
the Soviet Union, together with its economic system based on state
ownership and central planning, had collapsed and radical moves to
threaten the dominance of private capital had been abandoned.
Whilst new threats were to emerge, as recounted in later chapters,
the challenges of the 1970s seemed to have been decisively repulsed.
The four chapters which follow analyse the key components of
this decisive recovery in capitalism’s strength and stability. The next
chapter recounts the dramatic shifts in government policy, followed
by an analysis of the growth of the power of the finance sector and
the dominance of shareholder profit in the operation of firms. The
retreat from government intervention and return to reliance on market forces can be seen as the reassertion of the ‘fundamental workings of the capitalist economy’. In Makoto Itoh’s vivid formulation
‘capitalism seems to be running the film of history backwards by
“melting down” the sustained trend of a century, and returning to an
older stage of liberalism’ (Itoh 1990: 14).
2
Austerity, Privatization and
Deregulation
The Federal Reserve had to show that when faced with the
painful choice between maintaining a tight monetary policy to
fight inflation and easing monetary policy to combat recession,
it would choose to fight inflation. In other words to establish its
credibility, the Federal Reserve had to demonstrate its willingness to spill blood, lots of blood, other people’s blood
(Michael Mussa, Director of the Department of Research at the
IMF, reflecting on the tightening of US monetary policy in 1979
(Mussa 1994: 112))
Throughout the 1960s and 1970s the governments of the highly
developed economies were reacting to the pressures described in the
previous chapter. Budget discipline was breaking down as demands
for rising public spending ran well ahead of political capacity to levy
high taxes and the inflation resulting from conflict between workers
and employers was accommodated with lavish doses of money and
credit. Employers were under pressure to accede to more stringent
limits on their ability to hire and fire whilst the growth of the welfare
state tempered the impact on workers of market forces; further
incursions into management prerogatives to allocate capital where
and when they liked were threatened. This chapter will outline the
counter-revolution in macroeconomic policy which saw tight monetary policy and fiscal austerity imposed in the name of defeating
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
25
inflation. This was followed rapidly by the unwinding of much of the
detailed government intervention into particular sectors and markets
which had characterized the previous decades. Privatization, and the
deregulation of the industries concerned, the substitution of private
sector sources of supply for public sector in-house service provision
and the deregulation of labour markets are all aspects of this process.
Monetary Policy and Unemployment
The rise in unemployment in almost all of the OECD in the mid1970s can readily be accounted for by the jolt both to aggregate
demand and to business expectations caused by the rising inflation,
oil price increases, profit squeeze and industrial unrest discussed in
the previous chapter. Governments were caught in the ‘stagflation’
dilemma—running an expansionary monetary policy (low interest
rates) and fiscal policy (rising deficits) risked ‘accommodating’ the
inflation. Their fear was not just that higher inflation would persist
but that it would increase and increase, as argued by Milton
Friedman in his famous address to the American Economic
Association in 1967.1 On the other hand, a squeeze on the economy
would push unemployment up further, which was felt to be politically unsustainable. Incomes policies, attempting to persuade union
bargainers to accept wage increases below the going rate of inflation,
were widely introduced. These took varied forms depending on the
institutional history of the country and with varying degrees of
success. Japan, Sweden and briefly the UK were among the countries
where wages increases were sharply ratcheted down in the mid1970s through agreements of various forms with trades unions.2
Figure 2.1 shows the considerable rise in unemployment in Europe
and the USA in the mid-1970s. However this was not generally
sufficient to squeeze out inflation. The decisive policy shift came in
late 1979 when, with US inflation again rising into double digits,
Paul Volker at the US Federal Reserve pushed up interest rates to
unprecedented levels (see Fig. 2.2). The real interest rate, with inflation
subtracted from the nominal cost of borrowing, rose suddenly from
26
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
being negative (the real value of repayments falling short of the real
value borrowed) to more than plus 5%. This precipitated a sharp recession and unemployment rose from around 5% in 1979 to nearly 10%
in 1982 (see Fig. 2.1). Inflation fell from 13% in 1980 to 3% in 1983.
The Volker ‘coup’ against loose monetary policy was aimed at
protecting the value of the dollar, internally but also on the foreign
12.0
Europe
Japan
USA
Euro area
10.0
%
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 2.1. Unemployment Rates, 1960–2004
Source: OECD. Data Appendix.
15
Nominal rate
Real rate (nominal less inflation)
% per year
10
5
0
1950
1960
1970
1990
1980
–5
Fig. 2.2. US Short-Term Interest Rates, 1950–2004
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix.
2000
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
27
exchanges where it had been under heavy pressure, by squeezing out
inflation at whatever it cost in terms of unemployment. The minutes of the Fed’s Open Market Committee noted that despite a likely
rise in unemployment in 1980 the intention was to slow monetary
growth further ‘in line with the continuing objective of curbing
inflation’ (quoted Romer and Romer 2002: 44). This was only months
after the Council of Economic Advisers’ Economic Report to the
President had stated that ‘We will not try to wring inflation out of
our economic system by pursuing policies designed to bring about a
recession’ (quoted ibid. 42). The Fed reiterated its ‘willingness to
accept high unemployment to bring inflation down’ (ibid. 43) several
times during the early 1980s. The President of Chase Manhattan
bank noted that the policy would ‘tend to deepen what has been seen
as a relatively shallow recession but is a price worth paying. Inflation
is a terrible cancerous disease that takes radical action’ (quoted
Epstein 1981: 169).
Volker himself, looking back some years later, underlined the
links between deflationary monetary policy and the broader issue of
the weakening of labour: ‘the most important single action of the
administration in helping the anti-inflation fight was defeating the
air traffic controllers’ strike. He thought that this action had rather a
profound, and from his standpoint, constructive effect on the climate
of labour–management relations, even though it had not been a wage
issue at the time’ (quoted by Brenner 1998: 191).
Because of the importance of the US economy, and its influence on
worldwide interest rates, the turn in policy there is always accorded
particular significance. However in reality the USA was following
the lead of Germany, which had maintained high real interest rates
throughout the inflationary 1970s. The rising mark which resulted
had helped to moderate inflation by pressing down on the export sector and established the Bundesbank’s credentials as anti-inflationary
zealot (in 1979 inflation was 4.1% in Germany as compared to 11.3%
in the USA). Mrs Thatcher’s government had also begun to squeeze
before Volker, and long-term real interest rates in the UK shifted
from minus 3% to plus 4% between 1979 and 1982. This not only
increased borrowing costs but helped to push up the exchange rate,
launching a ferocious squeeze on manufacturing. In the UK case
28
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
fiscal policy was also aggressively shifted towards restriction, with
the budget deficit reduced in 1981 despite the recession which was
pushing down tax revenues. Unemployment rose from less than 5%
in 1979 to more than 11% by 1983. It was regarded as vital that the
presentation of the policy should be phrased in terms of targets for
the money supply. Letting the cat out of the bag as to what was
implied for jobs would have been a ‘very hazardous exercise’ according to an adviser to the Governor of the Bank of England because ‘the
objectives would either have been unacceptable to public opinion or
inadequate to ensure a substantial reduction in the rate of inflation,
or both’ (Fforde 1983: 207).3 Of course inflation, especially at rates
recorded in the 1970s, was itself unpopular as real incomes fell
month on month between the dates that nominal incomes (wages,
pensions and so forth) were adjusted. In the 1980s the majority of UK
workers who kept their jobs saw real wages rising steadily.
Of great symbolic importance was the abandonment in 1983 by
Mitterrand’s Socialist government in France of their expansionary
plans and the launching of the ‘Franc fort’ policy. ‘The Socialist
attempt to revive the economy sank on the shoals of rising inflation
and a foreign exchange crisis by early 1983, so that the government
of the left has in the end introduced a tougher, more market oriented
programme than anything considered by the previous centre-right
administration’ (Sachs and Wyplosz 1986: 262). This policy was
labelled ‘competitiveness through disinflation’, aimed at keeping
French goods competitive on world markets by pushing the inflation
rate down to, and then keeping it below, that of competitors. This
contrasted with the traditional policy of restoring competitiveness
through devaluation.4 By the end of the decade the inflation differential with Germany (6–8% per year higher in France in the early
1980s) had been all but eliminated. However unemployment
reached 10% by the mid-1980s and remained stubbornly stuck.
Our final example of the decisive turn to policies aimed at reducing
inflation came in 1991 from the Swedish Social Democrats. They had
traditionally relied on occasional devaluations to restore export competitiveness whenever their centralized bargaining system had not
been able to contain money wage increases at a competitive level.
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
29
Ruling out further devaluations, which were becoming unmanageable
given financial liberalization and the huge speculative flows (see
Chapter 3), the 1991 Budget Statement proclaimed:
in the longer run it is not possible to safeguard employment in an economy
which has a higher inflation rate than the surrounding world. In order to
protect employment and prosperity economic policies in the next few
years . . . will have to aim at a permanent reduction in inflation. This task
must take priority over all other aims and ambitions. (quoted Notermans
1993)
The recession which followed, involving the collapse of a consumer
boom (see Chapter 3), pushed unemployment above 9%, a previously
unimaginable level for Sweden.
The turn towards restrictive policies was no temporary aberration.
Real interest rates throughout the OECD stayed much higher
through the 1980s and first half of the 1990s than during the Golden
Age, when low real interest rates helped to maintain high investment
levels. Even when they fell back towards the end of the 1990s they
stuck at around the very long-term historical average (see Fig. 2.3).
The spectacular effect of the high real interest rates in helping to push
down inflation is clear from Figure 1.2 and applied right across the
OECD. In 1980 Japan’s inflation rate was 4% and Germany together
6
5
% per year
4
3
2
1
0
1956 – 73
1974 – 80
1981 – 96
1997 – 2003
–1
Fig. 2.3. Long-Term Real Interest Rates, 1850–2003
Source: Rowthorn (1995). See Data Appendix.
1850 – 2003
30
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
with half a dozen of its close neighbours who were following
similarly orthodox policies had inflation rates in the range 5–7%.
However, in the same year inflation was running at about 14% in
Sweden, France and the USA while UK inflation was 18% and Italy’s
21%. By 1997 the range of inflation rates was drastically reduced.
Low inflation countries had no inflation at all whilst an inflation rate
of only 3% (as in the UK) put a country in the top inflation bracket.
How fundamental was the reversion to tight monetary policy and
the hike in real interest rates in generating the higher unemployment over the 1980s and 1990s? Such a case has been strongly argued
by Keynesians, who point to the correlation between the tightness of
monetary policy in a country and its rise in unemployment in the
1980s.5 This is no surprise since the immediate factor behind most
rises in unemployment is a fall in aggregate demand and tight monetary policy does act in that direction. However when interest rates
are the triggering factors the monetary authorities will usually be
responding to some perceived problem in the economy, as is clear
from the discussion above. For example if they believe that higher
unemployment is required to bring down inflation then it is the factors explaining the inflationary pressure which really lie behind the
rise in unemployment. The tight monetary policy is the vehicle
through which the lower level of aggregate demand and higher
unemployment is reached. Governments squeezed harder (via
higher interest rates for example) in countries where the ‘NonAccelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment’ (NAIRU) increased
by a greater amount.
Of course it is quite possible that monetary authorities may be
excessively cautious and depress demand and employment more
deeply and for longer than could be objectively justified by inflationary tendencies (as is widely believed was the case in the early 2000s
at the European Central Bank, which sets interest rates for the
Eurozone). There may also be alternative routes to lower inflation
other than increasing unemployment, through social pacts between
labour and capital to lever down wage claims. Some countries like
Sweden and Austria avoided big increases in unemployment in the
1980s in this way and wage restraint in Japan reflected an implicit
agreement with a similar effect.
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
31
Explaining the shift in monetary policy discussed in this section is
fundamental to understanding why unemployment rose so much in
OECD countries in the 1980s. In very broad terms tight monetary
policy was the reaction to the turmoil of the 1970s—rising inflation,
industrial conflict, profit squeeze and the other developments discussed in Chapter 1. As the Polish economist Kalecki had brilliantly
forecast in 1943 at the height of enthusiasm for Keynesian full
employment policies:
Indeed under a regime of permanent full employment, the ‘sack’ would
cease to play its role as a disciplinary measure. The social position of the
boss would be undermined, and the self-assurance and class consciousness
of the working class would grow. Strikes for wage increases and improvements in conditions of work would create political tensions . . . ‘discipline in
the factories’ and ‘political stability’ are more appreciated than profits
by business leaders. Their class instinct tells them that lasting full employment is unsound from their point of view and that unemployment is an
integral part of a ‘normal’ capitalist system. (Kalecki 1990 1943: 351)
The concept of the NAIRU is often criticized for suggesting that
high unemployment is inevitable or even ‘natural’ to use Milton
Friedman’s term. However following Kalecki it is really Marx’s
‘reserve army of labour’ in disguise—the unemployment whose
function in capitalism is to keep wages in check.6 Unemployment
could then be seen as a response to industrial conflict, and its various
destabilizing economic manifestations like inflation and profit
squeeze, as business investment would decline with the fall in
confidence and governments would turn to restrictive policies to
restore discipline. Such an interpretation is quite consistent with
the pattern of unemployment shown in Figure 2.4. Unemployment
in the years 1990–9 is plotted against the level of strikes in the
country over the years 1968–79 (covering both the wage explosions
and workers’ subsequent attempts to maintain living standards as
inflation rose). Despite all the intervening events (such as German
unification) and all the other differences between countries (for
example massive agricultural decline in Spain), a country’s unemployment is significantly related to the degree of industrial conflict a
quarter of a century earlier.7
32
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
Much was made later in the 1980s of the importance of the
Central Bank being independent of political manipulation if it was to
implement suitably restrictive anti-inflationary monetary policies.
That this was far from necessary was shown by the case of the UK
where Thatcherite monetary policy remained firmly under the control of the government, although there could be circumstances
where it would be politically convenient to put the blame for
unpopular policies on ‘independent’ experts. Making the Bank of
England responsible for setting interest rates was one of the first
actions of Gordon Brown as Chancellor of the Exchequer in the Blair
government, in a successful bid to convince the financial markets
that Labour had fully adjusted to the non-inflationary epoch.
20
Unemployment 1990 – 99 %
SPA
15
IRE
FIN
FRA
ITA
10
5
GER
SWE DEN
NETH
AUSTRIA
NOR
SWI
JAP
BEL
NZ
UK
AUSTL
CAN
USA
0
0
500
1000
1500
Strike days 1968–79 per 1000 workers
2000
Fig. 2.4. Unemployment 1990–1999 and Strikes 1968–1979
Source: Office of National Statistics. See Data Appendix.
Government Deficits
The use of expansionary fiscal policy to maintain demand and
employment was repudiated by the deliberate tightening of fiscal
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
33
policy by the Thatcher government during the early 1980s recession,
by the commitment of the Clinton administration to deficit reduction in 1992 and by the adoption by the EU of progressively tougher
constraints culminating in the Stability and Growth Pact commitment to balancing budgets on average over the economic cycle.
Keynesian orthodoxy had argued that in a recession the deficit
should be allowed to rise through the ‘automatic stabilizers’ (as tax
receipts fell), supplemented where necessary by deliberate fiscal
expansion (for example increases in government spending) to help
maintain demand. This was not supposed to involve governments
running substantial deficits in the longer run. Keynes envisaged that
the spending boost would ‘prime the pump’ of private investment
which would take over the running from a government-induced
boost to demand. Indeed private investment was sufficiently
dynamic in the 1950s and 1960s that sustained government deficits
were not needed in the OECD countries to bolster growth (Table 2.1).
The Keynesian prescription to run temporary deficits where there
was a deficiency of aggregate demand was never intended as a longterm solution to welfare state financing. Indeed in the Scandinavian
version, which developed the welfare state most extensively,
governments typically ran substantial budget surpluses from which
loans were made to the private sector.8
Government deficits became substantial and sustained only during
the period after the 1974 OPEC oil shock when there was pressure to
continue expanding the welfare state and supporting aggregate
Table 2.1 Budget Deficits, 1952–2004
General
government
balance, % of GDP
1952–73
1974–9
1980–90
1991–5
1996–2000
2001–04
USA
Europe
(Eurozone ⬎ 90)
Japan
OECD
⫺0.8
0.2
⫺1.5
⫺3.3
⫺3.5
⫺4.3
⫺4.5
⫺2.2
0.0
⫺2.1
⫺3.2
⫺2.3
1.0
⫺0.2
⫺3.4
⫺2.5
⫺1.1
⫺3.3
⫺1.7
⫺4.3
⫺5.8
⫺1.3
⫺7.3
⫺2.8
Sources: OECD. See Data Appendix.
34
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
demand despite stagnating tax revenue. Deficits were larger still in
the early 1990s (considerably larger if adjusted for the smaller effect
of inflation in reducing the real value of outstanding debt). It was
not until the second half of the 1990s that major reductions in
government deficits in Europe and the USA (though not Japan)
marked a seemingly decisive restoration of financial orthodoxy in
public sector financing.
Why are financial markets so opposed to government deficits,
when after all a tidy proportion of their business derives from
government borrowing? Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal
Reserve, was reported as having spelt out the argument very clearly
in his pre-inauguration meeting with President-elect Clinton in
December 1992:
Bondholders and traders were sophisticated and anticipated that the federal
budget deficit would continue to explode for many years. The anticipated
cumulative growth of the deficit over those years was so large that it was
perceived to be unstable. History showed, Greenspan said, that with such
vast federal expenditures, inflation would inevitably soar at some point.
The double-digit inflation of the 1970s had been induced by budget deficits
from the Vietnam War. Investors were now wary and demanding a higher
long-term return [long-term interest rate on Treasury bonds—AG] because
of the expectations on the federal deficit. (Woodward 1994: 69)
Clinton accepted Greenspan’s argument.9 His deficit reduction
programme saw the budget in surplus at the end of the decade and
was regarded as ‘key and indispensable’ in generating the 1990s
boom in the USA according to Robert Rubin, later to be the Treasury
Secretary.
I remember the economic malaise of the early 1990s very well and one of the
central features was a loss of confidence . . . in part because our fiscal position was taken to symbolize a larger inability on the part of our country to
manage its economic life effectively and with discipline. The consequence
of the deficit reduction program of 1993, once the market actually believed
that it was real, was not only lower interest rates, but also—in my judgment
much more importantly—a great increase in confidence . . . [which] affected
business decisions about investment, expansion and hiring, as well as
consumer decisions, and produced a greater flow of foreign capital into our
savings deficient nation to finance investment here . . . without the boost to
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
35
confidence provided by the deficit reduction package the investment boom
would not have occurred (Rubin 2001: 131, 138)
Rubin’s argument turns pump-priming on its head; the adverse effects
on bond market and business confidence of a rise in the deficit could
make Keynesian fiscal expansion contractionary as real investment
fell. The validity of this argument, long proposed by conservative
economists in Germany, clearly depends on the economic and
political circumstances. Where the government’s debt is growing
faster than GDP, and threatening to spiral upwards in an unsustainable way, adverse reactions to even larger budget deficits are quite
plausible. However this does not mean that increased deficits
can never sustain demand. The very expansionary effect of the
Keynesian boost to the Germany economy after unification in 1990
or the impact of the George W. Bush tax cuts are just two examples of
strong positive effects on demand of expansionary fiscal policy.
Financial markets are far from neutral about how deficit reductions should be achieved; the Business Roundtable in Washington
‘believed that deficit reduction should come largely or exclusively
from spending cuts, with very little, if any, increase in taxes’ (Rubin
2003: 128). Such a focus on spending cuts was given additional credibility by a widely cited study of episodes of deficit reduction in
OECD countries.
Fiscal adjustments that relied primarily on tax increases, especially tax
increases on households, typically fail to stop permanently the growth of
public debt. On the contrary, successful adjustments are those that aggressively tackle the expenditure side, particularly the components of it which
are always thought of as untouchable: social security and government
wages and employment. (Alesina and Perotti 1995: 239)
The validity of this finding is hotly contested, especially its
interpretation of the Irish growth ‘miracle’ which followed fiscal
stabilization in the mid-1980s. If tax increases would be met by
higher wage claims, cuts in government employment and welfare
benefits could be more effective by weakening labour’s bargaining
power. In other circumstances organized labour might agree to tax
increases in return for preserving welfare spending. Despite these
complexities, welfare spending cuts rather than tax increases were
36
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
promoted in an unqualified way by the European Commission in its
quest for deficit reductions ahead of the introduction of the Euro.10 In
the event, budgetary consolidation in the Eurozone came mostly
from reduced spending but the biggest part of the decline was in
interest payments (as rates fell) rather than spending on programmes. Budget targets for the EU’s Growth and Stability Pact—
deficits limited to 3% of GDP with the aim of budget balance over
the cycle—foundered in 2004 on German and French deficits, which
remained stubbornly high as growth in the Eurozone stagnated.
The turn to fiscal orthodoxy was much more successful in the
USA than in Europe but was even more short-lived. The recession
after the collapse of the stock market/new economy boom in 2000
was met by the Bush administration with tax cuts and spending
increases (especially military), pushing the US deficit up to around
5% of GDP in 2004. The US bond market proved remarkably indulgent as evidenced by low long-term interest rates. Few in the Bush
administration probably still believed in the ‘voodoo economics’ of
President Reagan that tax cuts to the rich would have major effects
on incentives to work and save and thus boost economic growth. But
as the Financial Times pointed out, if the hoped-for expansion did
not materialize, and the deficit proved unsustainably high, the
Republicans would be handed a convenient scenario for forcing
through cuts in social programmes.11 Indeed the campaign against
government deficits had already provided useful ammunition in the
successful battle to limit the upward march of government spending
after 1979 (see Fig. 1.8).
By 2005 the aim of ‘budgetary consolidation’ was in disarray. Japan
had had a huge deficit for years, there was a ballooning deficit in the
USA and bickering in Europe with France and Germany failing to
reach the EU’s 3% deficit target. Persistent budget deficits are telltale signs of lack of business confidence in the prospects for profitable investment. For high investment pushes up output and
incomes and thus tax revenue and reduces the deficit, as happened in
the US boom of the late 1990s. Investment was relatively sluggish
throughout the OECD countries after 2000, despite the low and stable inflation, the profits recovery and the absence of industrial conflict. We will return to this puzzle in Chapter 6.
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
37
Privatization of Nationalized Industries
The priority given to financial discipline and defeating inflation was
complemented by attempts to reduce government intervention in
industry. The most spectacular example of this was the privatization
of state-owned enterprises.
Nationalized industries have always occupied an uncomfortable
position in capitalist economies. Mainly located in utilities and other
basic industries they hovered uncomfortably between operating as a
socialistic beachhead on the one hand and supplying cheap inputs
which boosted the profits of the private sector on the other. In
the former conception nationalized firms could influence the
structure of the economy, avoid exploitation of monopoly positions
and allow experiments in worker involvement in decision-making.
Alternatively, as purveyors of inputs to the private sector, they
would be criticized for not being efficient enough and for absorbing
government subsidies.
Although individual companies had periodically shifted into the
public sector as ‘lame ducks’ and out again when restored to health,
privatization as a programme only took off in the mid-1980s, building
up to a world-wide peak in the later 1990s before slipping back as the
best prospects had been privatized in many countries. The share of
state-owned enterprises in global GDP is estimated as falling from
more than 10% in 1979 to less than 6% in 2004. More than $1.25
trillion has been raised from privatization worldwide; total receipts
up to the end of 2000 raised the equivalent of 3% of one year’s GDP
in Japan, France and Germany and 10% in the UK. Privatized firms
represent around 30% of the total market capitalization of stock
markets outside the USA. Privatized oil or telecoms companies were
the most valuable companies listed on the stock exchanges of the
UK, France, Germany and Italy and the second most valuable firms
in Australia and Japan.12 The discussion below will focus on the UK,
the trailblazer in this process. The UK is now held up as a paragon in
terms of deregulation and lack of state control, moving from fifteenth
to first place out of 22 OECD countries in the Fraser Institute’s
overall ranking of ‘Economic Freedom’.13
38
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
There are a host of issues surrounding the introduction of
competitive pressure into privatized industries, by breaking up
existing monopolies, by liberalization of market entry and by public
regulation of pricing.14 Our concern here is with the broad effects on
productivity and how resulting gains were distributed between
shareholders, consumers and workers.
Privatization reduced the contribution of government-owned
companies from 12% of UK GDP in 1979 to less than 2% now. The
first major privatization was British Telecom and the motivation at
that stage was mainly financial. BT had a major backlog of investment to catch up with new technology and, whilst it remained in the
public sector, the finance required would add to the government
deficit. Reducing the deficit was a key component of the government’s macroeconomic strategy to impose financial discipline on
the economy by restricting monetary growth. The resulting sale of
over 50% of BT’s shares in 1984 was hugely successful with the
shares so priced that subscribers secured an instant gain of 33%.
British Gas, British Airways, British Steel, the water authorities and
the electricity industry followed in quick succession. British Rail and
British Coal were privatized after the 1992 election.
The financial motivation for privatization always seemed weak.
Although paying off some national debt with the proceeds of privatization would economize on the government’s interest payments, it
would lose the government an equivalent stream of profits from the
corporation. The difference between the government raising money
to fund BT’s investment by selling bonds and a privatized BT selling its
own bonds to the public was rather cosmetic. Nevertheless government deficits were large (4% of UK GDP in 1984) and even ‘selling off
the family silver’, as ex-Prime Minister Harold Macmillan termed it,
could be temporarily reassuring for financial markets.
Over and above the immediate financial advantage to the government, the fundamental motivation for privatization was the theory
that the firms would be more efficient when subject to competitive
private sector disciplines and that this would bring real benefits to
the economy in the form of lower prices and higher living standards.
These benefits were supposed to swamp the negative effects of a private company being able to exploit its monopoly positions. Opening
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
39
up markets to competition where feasible, or regulation of prices
where it was not, together with pressure from institutional investors
to increase profits, were the routes through which new private sector
managements would be forced to cut costs in previously sluggish
enterprises.
It is hard to find robust evidence of the effects on productivity of a
switch in ownership to the private sector.15 A detailed OECD study of
telecoms found lower prices, higher productivity and improved service levels after privatization. However the evidence was consistent
with this being the effect of introducing competition into the
industry, which can be done without privatizing the dominant state
provider. The OECD found no clear evidence of the impact of
privatization itself, additional to the effect of competition.16 The
most recent analysis of UK privatizations concluded: ‘it is probably
fair to characterize our results as showing that firms tended to
improve their productivity significantly in the run-up to privatization (with some exceptions) but giving little evidence that the faster
growth rate was sustained after privatization. In other words, there is
catch-up rather than a permanent change of pace . . . Whether the
commitment to privatize is essential to getting the gains from preprivatization restructuring, remains an open question . . .’ (Green and
Haskel 2004: 91). The government had a great incentive to rationalize the industries before privatization in order to boost profits and
thus the prospective sale price;17 the fact that such rationalizations
occurred before privatization showed that private ownership per se
was not directly responsible.
The most frequently privatized sectors were utilities and the UK
gas, electricity and water sectors provide an interesting example
of who gains and who loses from privatization, being privatized
at varying dates between 1986 (British Gas ) and the early 1990s
(electricity). Table 2.2 below shows what happened to capital and
labour inputs into the sector, to productivity growth and to wages
and profits. The first period shown covers 1970–9, including the turbulent years of the Labour government. The period 1979–90 includes
Thatcher’s restructuring of industry generally, including serious
attempts to rationalize the sector prior to privatization via government
imposition of financial targets. Finally 1990–2002 covers a lengthy
40
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
run of years when the three industries were all privatized and the
regulation regimes were settling down.
Capital stock growth only accelerated to a rather minor degree,
which must be disappointing for those who anticipated faster introduction of new technology. The trend in jobs was more dramatic
however: employment had been declining over the longer term in
this sector but the fall speeded up in the 1980s prior to privatization
and by even more in the 1990s. A 4% per year loss of jobs over 12 years
represents a near halving of the workforce since 1990. The effect of
this rationalization was a sharp increase in labour productivity.18
Table 2.2 Production and Incomes in UK Utilities, 1970–2002
Average annual
percentage
changes
Real
output
Employment
Capital
stock
Labour
Productivity
Real
wage bill
Real
profits
1970–79
1979–90
1990–2002
3.7
2.0
2.5
⫺1.1
⫺2.0
⫺4.1
1.1
0.6
1.4
4.9
4.1
6.9
5.5
1.6
⫺2.8
2.7
0.7
1.6
Source: Office of National Statistics. See Data Appendix.
How were the benefits of this rationalization distributed? After
1979 prices of energy and water grew less fast than the consumer price
index overall.19 This differential doubled to 2.7% per year after 1990.
This suggests that competitive and regulatory pressure was distributing some of the benefits from higher productivity to consumers.
After 1990, real profits rose as the wage bill fell. However the
growth of profits was not spectacular and this is consistent with the
finding that long-term shareholders did no better from the privatized
industries than from shares as a whole in the private sector.20
The big gainers from privatization were those that ‘stagged’ the
issues of shares (selling them for a quick profit), the firms in the City
which earned large fees from arranging the privatizations and management, whose pay was ratcheted up.21 The main losers were those
workers who lost relatively well-paid, unionized jobs. Although privatization of the coal industry was termed the ‘ultimate privatization’ because of its effect on the power of the mineworkers, studies
suggest little evidence that in the UK the act of privatization per se
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
41
was associated with a decline in union membership or bargaining
rights. In contrast, in Japan the privatization of railways, telecoms
and the tobacco and salt monopoly had a major impact in weakening
the militant wing of the Japanese union movement.22
Even the OECD’s very positive assessment of restructuring and privatization admits that they ‘tend to be accompanied by some degree
of dislocation and job loss, at least in the short term. Furthermore
. . . in many instances employment reductions have continued after
privatization.’ They also noted that while employees in privatized
companies receive generous salaries, they are ‘reported to often have
longer hours, decreased job security and union power’ (OECD 2003a:
43). An industrial disputes arbitrator noted that privatized and
deregulated bus operators in London had little scope to compete by
means ‘other than worsening employees’ terms and condition’ and
that this brought ‘a declining sense of employee commitment to
public transport as a service’ (quoted by Sachdev 2004:16).
Privatization in OECD countries shifted within a decade or so
from being a radical policy of hard-line right-wing governments
(notably Mrs Thatcher’s) to being the conventional wisdom even
amongst governments of the left. The experience of France exemplifies this. In 1981 Mitterrand was elected to the presidency with a
strong programme to extend state ownership by taking over major
industrial groups in electronics and chemicals, 39 banks (raising the
state’s share of banking from 60% to 90%) together with major firms
in other industries (see Chapter 1). These nationalizations doubled
the state’s share of industrial employment to 22%.23 The programme
was first put on hold after the 1983 macroeconomic crisis and policy
shift (see above), and successive right-wing governments privatized
selected companies whilst preserving interlocking cross-holdings of
companies in conglomerate groups. Finally, in the second half of the
1990s the Socialist government of Lionel Jospin privatized more
than the previous six governments put together, including almost
all government holdings in the banking and insurance sectors.
Le Monde noted that ‘never had the sales of public companies
generated so little controversy’ (quoted by Gordon and Meunier
2001: 22). Overseas financial firms took large stakes in many of
the privatized firms.
42
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
Privatization is just one, highly visible, aspect of government’s
withdrawal from intervention in the market sector of the economy.
The OECD has produced an index of the degree of regulation in seven
industries covering energy, post and telecoms and transport (rail, air
and road freight). The index, covering not only public ownership, but
ease of entry into the industry and aspects of its market structure,
charts the course of deregulation over the 1980s and 1990s. In 1978
the USA had least regulation out of 21 OECD countries.24 By 1998
only three countries (Greece, Italy and Portugal) had a greater degree
of regulation than the USA had in 1980. In 15 countries the index
was at least one-third lower in 1998 than 20 years earlier and the UK
had become the least regulated country of all, with a level of regulation one-quarter of the US level in 1978.
This process of product market deregulation took off in the 1980s
really only in the USA, becoming widespread in the 1990s. A more
extensive analysis by OECD covering the years since 1998 showed
deregulation continuing apace in all three areas considered—state
controls on industry, barriers to entrepreneurship (administrative
and legal difficulties in starting a business) and barriers to international trade and investment (ownership barriers, tariffs and so forth).
Taken as a whole the OECD’s assessment25 is that regulation was
reduced by about one-quarter in that five-year period alone, with a
strong tendency for the most regulated countries to be cutting
regulation by most (Italy and France being good examples).
Government Services and Private Procurement
Government spending has always involved services provided within
the public sector and purchases of goods and services from the private sector. Along with privatization of nationalized industries
which produce goods and services for sale, there has been a trend
towards government procurement moving from in-house provision
of services to purchases from the private sector. Shifting to private
provision may result in savings if the private provision is cheaper
(contracting out hospital cleaning services) and the threat of such a
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
43
switch can also be used to put pressure on workers in the public
sector. Between 1987 and 2003 the proportion of UK government
current expenditure on goods and services which represented
purchases from the private sector rose from 37% to 48%. The trends
to outsourcing, and to putting contracts out to competitive tendering,
are common to most countries.26
A review of the effect of contracting out services previously
provided in the UK public sector concluded that cost savings have
frequently been in the range 10–30%.27 Some, though not all, studies
suggest that the savings are similar if the contract is retained
in-house after being opened up to competitive tender. As with privatization the issue is whether cost savings come from the shift to
private ownership of the enterprise supplying the service or from
tighter financial controls and competition, which may not require
privatization. The UK results noted above are broadly similar to
those reported in a review covering other countries. Fears that
cost savings were funded by quality reduction were not borne out
by studies of school cleaning. However it seems very plausible that
the biggest element of cost-cutting costs often comes from ‘raising
effort . . . lower wages and less favourable work conditions’
(Lundsgaard 2002: 84–5). The Guardian reported that a government
review of outsourcing, set up after trade union pressure but abandoned for undisclosed reasons, had found that ‘efficiency’ savings
came from cuts in staffing and lowering of pay rates mainly for
manual workers (8 Mar. 2002 quoted by Pollock 2004:193).
The UK government has also pioneered the use of private finance
to fund investment projects for use within the public sector (PFIs).
Begun under the Conservative government, this form of funding has
contributed 10–15% of public services investment since 1997 and by
the middle of 2003 had delivered 600 new public facilities including
34 hospitals, 119 other health facilities and 239 new and refurbished
schools.28 Just as with privatization a decade earlier, an important
attraction for the government was the fact that some investment
spending was removed from the public spending total. This was particularly absurd given that the Chancellor’s own Fiscal Rules explicitly permit budget deficits in order to finance public investment.
Indeed the main effect has been to push spending into the future as
44
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
building costs are paid in an annual rental rather than as lump-sum
construction costs. Moreover more is paid out over the life of the
project than would be the case with ordinary contracts. This is
because of the considerably higher rates of return allowed to the
private sector contractors than the government would pay on its
own borrowing. A recent review of the costs of this kind of finance
concluded:
In certain situations where contracts are easy to define, risks are well understood, transaction costs are low, and competition to provide finance is
active, then the costs of public and private finance are likely to be very
similar. Unfortunately for many public services such conditions simply do
not hold, and insisting on private financing will impose significant costs on
taxpayers in general, and/or the users of the services. (Jenkinson 2003: 333).
Over and above temporary accounting advantages from PFI, the
contractor constructs and often then manages the whole project.
Over-runs with construction projects in terms of cost and completion
date have been found to apply to 20–25% of PFI projects as compared
to 70–75% of public projects.29 When the private contractor has a
contract to maintain the building and provide services such as cleaning, PFI in effect involves the contracting out of some of the ancillary
services (with the potential for cost savings noted earlier).
Mainly as a result of privatization, but assisted by the developing
trend to purchase for the public sector inputs made in the private
sector, the share of UK employment which was in the public sector
fell from 27.4% to 18.1% between 1981 and 2003.30
A feature of the increasing involvement of the private sector in the
British NHS, depressingly familiar from the defence sector, has been
the interchange of personnel between those responsible for making
policy for the NHS and the private sector companies hoping to profit
from outsourcing.31 If the provision of public services was no different in kind from the provision of goods and services for private consumption then the logic of importing private sector methods into the
public services would be clear. But many public services, like health
and education, have been publicly provided because they have been
produced ‘for the benefit of the public’. This reflects the egalitarian
idea that everybody, regardless of income or foresight, should have
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
45
access to a decent standard of these services, and that all in society
benefit from a healthy and well-educated population. These features
give additional motivation to those who work in public services,
recently summarized as follows: ‘not-for-profit activity and publicsector bureaucracies are organisations that try to cohere around a
mission. The notion of a mission replaces the conventional focus on
profit. We argue that people work harder when they buy into the
mission of the organisation and this raises productivity’ (Besley and
Ghatak 2003: 237). The danger is that work to high standards out of
commitment to the public services will be undermined by the profitoriented goals of private sector management. An influential adviser
suggested that the UK government has made exactly this mistake in
its attempts to ‘reform’ public services with its stress on rewarding
individual performance ‘rather than providing proper pay for each
grade and stressing the importance of the job and of the professional
norms and professional competence’ (Layard 2005: 160).
Labour Market Deregulation and
Unemployment
The rise in unemployment in the 1980s brought a concerted drive by
international organizations to champion the case for labour market
deregulation. The OECD took the lead on publishing a massive Jobs
Study in 1994. Some of the recommendations of the resulting Jobs
Strategy were uncontroversial, such as setting macroeconomic
policies to encourage sustainable growth and improving labour force
skills and competences. But they included the following more
contentious proposals:
Make wage and labour costs more flexible by removing restrictions that prevent wages from reflecting local conditions and individual skill levels, in
particular of younger workers.
Reform employment security provisions that inhibit the expansion of
employment in the private sector.
46
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
Reform unemployment and related benefit systems—and their interaction
with the tax system—such that societies’ fundamental equity goals are
achieved in ways that impinge far less on the efficient functioning of labour
markets.
Examples of the policies advocated were
If it is judged desirable to maintain a legal minimum wage as part of an antipoverty strategy, consider minimising its employment effects, including
● Indexing it to prices, rather than average earnings
● Ensure sufficient differentiation by age and region . . . .
loosen mandatory restrictions on dismissals where the current provisions
appear to seriously hinder economic restructuring and the hiring chances of
new labour force entrants
Restrict UI [unemployment insurance] benefit entitlements in countries
where they are especially long to the period where job search is intense and
rapid job-finding remains likely.
Reduce after tax replacement ratios where these are high and review
eligibility requirements where these require little employment history
before withdrawing benefits (OECD 1994a: 43–8)
The OECD went beyond general injunctions for reform and made
specific recommendations to each country as part of its programme
Implementing the Jobs Study.32 These came under 30 sub-headings.
Fourteen of the headings covered benefits and taxation, such as
lowering replacement rates or tightening eligibility conditions.
Six related headings referred to wage formation, including widening
the wage distribution. Ten covered employment protection, such as
easing severance regulations and regulations covering temporary
workers. At one extreme, Australia and the USA received four
recommendations whilst Finland received 21 and Germany 23. The
OECD also published measures of the degree to which their recommendations had been followed. New Zealand and the UK led the
field with over 80% compliance; France languished near the bottom.
More recently the IMF joined the clamour with a chapter in their flagship World Economic Outlook entitled confidently: ‘Unemployment
and Labor Market Institutions: Why Reforms Pay Off.’ As the IMF
noted, international organizations have long argued that ‘the causes
of unemployment can be found in labor market institutions.
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
47
Accordingly, countries with high unemployment have been repeatedly urged to undertake comprehensive structural reforms to reduce
“labor market rigidities” ’ (IMF 2003: 129). Indeed they claimed that
‘high and persistent unemployment can only be solved through
structural reforms’ (ibid. 133 n. 8). They described reducing unemployment benefits, labour taxation and employment protection legislation from Euro-area levels to US levels as ‘popular measures’ and
claimed (their table 4.1) that this would reduce unemployment by
nearly 3 percentage points.
How strong is the evidence that these policy recommendations
would have the desired effect? It is far less conclusive than is
suggested by the confidence with which labour market reforms are
advocated. As a simple example take the case of unemployment
benefits, which are widely thought to cause unemployment.
Replacement ratios did rise, especially in Europe from the late 1960s
to the early 1980s. But if we look at the cross-country position at the
turn of the century, we can use the considerable degree of variation in
both replacement ratios and unemployment rates across Europe to
try and pin down the relationship with unemployment (see Fig. 2.5).
According to the OECD data, six European countries had a lower
NAIRU than the USA, and three more (including Germany) were
not very much higher. The relation between unemployment and
benefits is, if anything, in the ‘wrong’ direction (higher benefits go
along with lower unemployment). Of course there are a host of other
influences on unemployment but if benefits were very important we
might expect some degree of correlation in the ‘right’ (positive) direction. Baker et al. (2005) show that such a lack of a simple relation
with unemployment applies to the other likely suspects such as
employment protection and union membership.
Such simple cross-country comparisons, whilst very seductive
when they seem to support the point at issue, are very simple and
ignore a host of factors which should be controlled for. These include
differences across countries in the ‘shocks’ their economies have had
to contend with, changes in labour market institutions over time,
interactions between them and so forth. There is a huge literature on
all this, which is far too vast to even briefly summarize. However a
comparison of such studies, which use a variety of data sets and
48
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
methodologies, concludes that the statistical results are quite ‘unrobust’ in the sense that the magnitudes of the effects found vary
widely between the studies.33 This does not mean that there may not
be some effects in the supposed direction but that their quantitative
importance is not well measured and may very well be small.
12
Structural unemployment (NAIRU) %
SPA
10
GRE
ITA
FRA
FIN
8
IRE
6
GER
BEL
UK
USA
4
CAN
AUSTL
JAP
NZ
AUSTRIA SWE DEN
NETH
NOR POR
SWI
2
40
60
80
Net unemployment benefit replacement ratio (% of earnings)
100
Fig. 2.5. Structural Unemployment and Unemployment Benefits, 1999
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
Further consideration will be given to the impact of labour market
deregulation in Chapter 5 below. However the point to stress here is
that it has been strenuously promoted despite weak evidence for the
magnitude of its benefits and in almost total neglect of its costs.
There are immediate and obvious costs,34 namely the cut in the
incomes of a badly off section of the community (the unemployed) or
the extra precariousness of the jobs of large numbers of workers
(including the low one paid). If the pay-off in terms of higher employment was clear and substantial then the costs and benefits could be
compared. But employers would unambiguously benefit from
greater latitude in hiring and firing and so forth. Thus there is plenty
of support for such deregulation from business even without strong
evidence that unemployment would be reduced.
AUSTERITY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEREGULATION
49
Conclusions
This chapter has documented the turn towards tight monetary policies, with priority accorded to maintaining low inflation and the
efforts at limiting budget deficits. These measures were quite successful in economies which were growing rapidly but foundered
successively in Japan, Europe and the USA as stagnation or the fear
of recession took over. Complementing the turn to financial austerity, the degree of government intervention in the dominant market
sector of the economy has been drastically cut through privatization
and latterly reductions in a wide range of product market regulations. Finally there has been a forceful campaign from the international organizations in favour of freeing up market forces in the
labour market by cutting unemployment benefits, minimum wages
and employment protection, the hard-won gains of the 1960s and
1970s. The broad impact of these developments on growth, stability
and inequality will be reviewed in later chapters. First, however, the
reassertion of the power of capital ownership over the functioning of
private sector firms, and the associated rise in the importance of the
financial sector, must be examined.
3
Finance and Ownership
It was deliciously intense and exciting to have been a part of creating LTCM [Long-Term Capital Management]. For making it
possible, I will never be able to adequately express my thanks to
my extraordinarily talented LTCM colleagues.
The distinctive LTCM experience from the beginning to the
present characterizes the theme of the productive interaction of
finance theory and finance practice. Indeed, in a twist on the more
familiar version of that theme, the major investment magazine,
Institutional Investor characterized the remarkable collection of
people at LTCM as ‘The best finance faculty in the world.’
From Merton Miller’s autobiographical notes on receiving the
1997 Nobel Prize in Economics. On LTCM see below.
Adam Smith described money as the ‘great wheel of circulation’ and
traditionally the finance sector has been seen as playing a rather
passive role in economic development, channelling credit more or
less effectively towards profitable firms. However financial liberalization and advances in communications encouraged financial
innovation and brought finance into much greater prominence—
with effects both on the economy as a whole (aggregate demand) as
well as on the behaviour of individual firms.
A number of aspects of the heightened role of the financial sector
are considered in the chapter which follows. The development of
consumer and mortgage credit seems to free mass consumption from
the age-old budget constraint encapsulated in the epigram ‘workers
spend what they get’. Financial markets claimed spectacular success
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
51
in generating the 1990s ‘new economy’ boom in the USA and have
increased their control of corporate managements, pressing them to
cut costs and maximize short-term profits. International financial
flows hold out the promise of liberating a country’s rate of investment
from the limitation imposed by its savings. Increasingly elaborate
financial instruments allow hedge funds and others to parcel out
yield and risk in ever more complicated ways, promising to detach
returns for the sharpest investors from the profitability of the underlying assets.
In what ways is the rise of finance linked to the shifts in government
policy discussed in the previous chapter? The financial sector was
always in the forefront of demanding orthodox financial policies and
the defeat of inflation. High inflation, and particularly unpredictable
inflation which tends to be associated with it, cause sudden shifts in
the real value of financial assets such as bank deposits or bonds.
Whilst the most agile or well-informed investors like such ‘volatility’ as it opens up anomalies in financial markets which they can
exploit, the financial sector overall is much more comfortable with
macroeconomic stability. In this respect, however, there is no major
difference of interest between finance and the big industrial firms,
which also stood to gain from wages being brought under control and
profits being restored. Industry also stood to gain from financial liberalization if it opened up cheaper sources of funds. The possibility
of replacing the instability of the 1960s and 1970s, which derived in
good part from conflict between bosses and workers, with instability
deriving from bubbles and crashes in unfettered financial markets
was not one that was contemplated in advance.
The Rise of the Financial Sector
Numerous indicators testify to the increasing role for finance in
the rich countries—burgeoning ratios to GDP of stock market capitalization, of consumer borrowing, of derivatives turnover and of
cross-border financial flows. All this activity has been reflected in
the profits of the financial sector, viewed (like Wall Street or the City
52
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
of London) as comprising a distinct set of interests. The expansion of
finance has been at its most dramatic in the USA, where aggregate
profits of financial corporations rose from being one-fifth as big as
non-financial profits in the 1970s and 1980s to a half after 2000 (see
Fig. 3.1). The stock market valuation of US financial companies (a
reflection of expected long-term profits) was 29% of the value of nonfinancials in 2004, a fourfold increase over the previous 25 years; in
the UK there was a slower increase in this ‘capitalization ratio’ from
a higher starting point to some 40% now. However the ascent of
finance has not been without setbacks. In the 1990s both the
German growth slowdown and the Japanese banking crisis saw the
relative capitalization of the financial sector halved since heady
peaks in the 1980s.
0.8
Ratio to non-financial profits
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 3.1. US Financial Sector Corporate Profits, 1950–2004
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Data Appendix.
Finance and Household Consumption
From Marx to Keynes at least, consumption was viewed as an essentially passive component of the growth process. Capital accumulation,
investment spending on machinery and buildings, was the essential
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
53
driving force on the demand as well as on the supply side. It was the
capitalists’ access to finance which allowed capital spending to
exceed the previous period’s savings and fuelled the expansion of
demand; future profits ensured that such borrowing was repaid with
a real return. Deficit spending by the government could, in wartime
for example, impart a similar impulse to demand, at least till capital
markets took fright at the growing debt interest burden and worries
about inflation. However household consumption, some two-thirds
of aggregate demand, was seen as playing the role of sustaining the
current output level rather than driving it up.
Savings ratios often fell during recessions, as consumers
attempted to maintain spending in the face of falling incomes.
Indeed, Milton Friedman criticized the Keynesians for exaggerating
the dependence of consumption on current income and ignoring the
extent to which savings could be used to ‘smooth’ out the path of
consumption. More recently, rather than acting as a stabilizing
influence, sharp falls in the savings ratio have occurred during
expansions. By boosting consumption proportionately more than
the rise in incomes this has intensified upswings, with the danger of
sharp falls in demand if savings rebound sharply when the expansion
slackens and pessimism builds up.
Buoyant household consumption has been most notable in the
USA where household savings have slumped. From the 1950s to the
1980s the household savings ratio averaged 8–9.5% each decade. In
the 1990s the ratio fell to 5.2% and then averaged 1.9% over the
period 2000–3. Without this fall in savings consumption would have
grown 1% per year slower during the long expansion from 1992 to
2000. Household spending on consumption and residential investment contributed nearly 80% of the total increase in US demand during the new economy boom of 1995– 2000 as compared to 65–70%
during the comparable periods at the end of the 1960s and 1980s
booms.1 There were similarly powerful boosts to consumption from
falling savings ratios in the UK, Netherlands, Sweden, Italy, Finland,
Canada and Australia at various periods in the 1990s.2 Whilst this list
extends beyond the most market-oriented group of economies,
France and Germany are notable absentees with consumption
remaining more closely confined to the growth of real incomes.
54
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
The expansion of household borrowing, from banks, credit card
companies, mortgage companies, has been very rapid in the 1990s.
The ratio of this borrowing to disposable income rose by 20–40%
between 1991 and 2003 in the USA, Germany and the UK to exceed
previous peaks. Mortgage borrowing, which is more comparable
across countries, exceeded 100% of GDP in the UK and was 60–85%
of GDP in the USA, Germany and Japan.3
Before the 1980s financial institutions had been constrained in
many countries as to the interest rates they could offer and charge,
what sort of loans they could make, what type of financial assets
they could purchase and whether they could gain access to overseas
markets. People who wanted to borrow for house purchase had to
make substantial deposits up front, and could only borrow relatively
small multiples of their income. Removal of such restrictions (financial deregulation) generated aggressive competition for customers
and much easier access to credit. The result was greater access to
borrowing and periodic boosts to household spending, particularly in
the USA and UK. Another factor probably contributing to increased
consumer borrowing was that the slower growth of household
incomes in the 1980s and 1990s lagged behind consumption aspirations which could therefore only be realized by increased borrowing.
Moreover, as it became easier to borrow against increases in wealth,
capital gains on assets held by consumers were more likely to be
translated into higher consumption. With housing supply expanding
slowly, credit expansion itself increased house prices in many countries. These capital gains then provided the backing for further borrowing, which consumers could use to finance purchases of cars or
holidays. For a time at least consumption took over as the motor of
economic expansion.
Shareholder Value and the Stock Market Boom
The US financial system has been widely taken to be the model for
flexibility and dynamism. The pricing of companies’ securities by
active financial markets is supposed to provide a rational allocation
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
55
of capital as companies’ prospects are assessed by people with every
interest in exploiting all available information. So finance chases
after those investment prospects which are likely to realize the
greatest return. Managements with the greatest entrepreneurial
skills in seeking out profitable opportunities from new technology
or products will find it easy to raise funds to make those investments. The same financial markets keep the pressure on incumbent
managements to minimize costs and rationalize wherever this is
profitable. Poor profit results leave the firm vulnerable to takeover
with control passing to more effective or aggressive management.
In economics textbooks firms maximize profits by their marginal
pricing and output decisions. Cost minimization, a necessary condition for profit maximization, is presumed to be unproblematic.
These assumptions were challenged by Berle and Means in the 1930s
who pointed out that many companies had large numbers of owners
with relatively small shareholdings and thus little ability to assess
whether management was really up to scratch. This gave managements, especially in industries where product market competition
was not so fierce, considerable latitude to pursue their own objectives (for example growth even at the expense of profits or a quiet life
in preference to cost minimization). The rise in the power of organized labour, discussed in Chapter 1, acted as a constraint over what
management could achieve. This was manifested in conflicts on the
shop floor on manning levels and production line speeds, collective
bargaining over job security and in some countries like Germany it
was institutionalized in co-determination legislation. The crisis in
profitability of the 1960s and 1970s, outlined in Chapter 1, showed
the extent to which the prerogatives of the owners of capital had
been undermined. The period since has seen a strong counter-attack
under the slogan ‘shareholder value’, with the financial markets
playing a crucial role in transmitting the pressure for improved
profitability.
An important factor behind the drive for shareholder value in the
Anglophone countries was the rise in the proportion of corporate
equity owned by financial institutions. Pension funds have swelled;
traditionally they were tightly controlled by governments as to what
assets they could hold, in order to protect savers from risk. However,
56
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
partly in response to the low or negative real returns on safe financial
assets in the 1960s and 1970s, the financial sector lobbied successfully to have these restrictions relaxed, allowing these funds to
invest in corporate equities and in risky (‘junk’) bonds rather than
safe government assets.4 Big institutional shareholders have the
resources and incentives to closely monitor company performance
and bring pressure on laggards. In the UK and USA (largest 500
companies) around 40% of equity is held by financial institutions.
Proportions are much lower elsewhere—15–18% in France and
Germany and 6% in Japan—with dominant blocks of shares often
held by families or by other (non-financial) companies.5 They may be
less concerned with maximizing short-run profits than with the
long-run fortunes of the company better served by increasing market
share or maintaining good relations with customers, suppliers,
banks and even the workforce.
Widespread benefits have been claimed for the US trend towards
institutional investment.
‘As institutional investors with larger stakes took over from individual
investors . . . the power of investors vis-à-vis management has grown . . . .’
the paramount duty of management and the board is to the shareholder
and not . . . to other stakeholders’ (Business Roundtable) . . . Because
governance has been improved, firms have been paying more attention
to the utilisation of the funds they generate . . . . The consequence of this
newfound awareness has been a substantial increase in the rate of return . . .
As governance improves, and managers begin to work in their investors’
interests, everyone benefits. (Rajan and Zingales 2003: 74–5; emphasis
added).
Such claims assume that financial markets do indeed make rational
appraisal of the prospects of the firms whose shares they are holding.
Stock markets are viewed as being high if equity prices are high
relative to the profits of the companies concerned. Since owning a
stock entitles you to a share in the future growth of profits, high
equity prices are justified if there is good reason to expect rapid
growth of the profits and thus the dividends of the companies concerned. The US stock market boom of the later 1990s brought it, by
this measure, to the highest peak it had ever achieved. In 2000 US
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
57
equities were valued at about 45 times underlying corporate earnings, as compared to around 30 times earnings before the Great
Crash in 1929.6 Enthusiasm for new economy stocks, particularly
connected with the internet, reached incredible levels. In February
2000 the market valuation of internet-involved companies (including portal companies like Google and e-commerce companies like
Amazon) was estimated at $943 billon despite the fact that these
companies were together reporting losses totalling $6 billion per
year. After surveying a mass of evidence Ofek and Richardson (2002)
conclude that it is very difficult to explain the internet boom as
being consistent with financial market rationality. One of their
examples of absurd valuations was Zapata, founded in the 1950s by
former US President George Bush as an oil and gas company, but by
1998 specializing in meat-casings and fish oil. After an earlier
abortive foray into an internet venture it announced that it was
forming an internet business subsidiary called Zap.com. This
brought an immediate rise in its share price of 98%!
A recent survey by a leading finance specialist concluded that ‘the
recent worldwide stock market boom, and then crash after 2000, had
its origin in human foibles and arbitrary feedback relations [rising
prices promoting expectations of further price rises, increasing
investor demand—AG] and must have generated a substantial real
misallocation of resources’ (Shiller 2003: 102). Another assessment
was even more damning:
In part the massive overvaluation of equity that occurred in the late 1990s
and early 2000s was an understandable market mistake. Society often
seems to overvalue what is new—in this case high-tech telecommunications, and Internet ventures. But this catastrophic overvaluation was also
the result of misleading data from managers, large numbers of naïve
investors, and breakdowns in the agency relationships within companies, in
investment banks, and in audit and law firms many of whom knowingly
contributed to the misinformation and manipulation that fed the overvaluation. (Jensen 2003: 14)
The circumstances which led to this bitter reproach to US business,
from one of the leading prophets of shareholder value, deserve some
explanation, and this is the subject of the next section.
58
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
Shareholder Value and Corporate Governance
In the 1980s extra pressure on management which was exerted by US
financial markets came via hostile takeovers. The consequent
restructuring often involved major increases in borrowing by the
companies taken over, the idea being that the obligation to pay
interest on the debt would force management into cost-cutting. The
‘leveraged buy out’ firms, such as Kohlberg, Kravis Roberts, gave
management teams ‘high-powered’ incentives in the form of stock
options which allowed managers to buy shares in the company at a
later date at what would be an extremely favourable price if the company was successful. This gave managers a very strong incentive to
do whatever would help to boost profits and thus the share price.
This trend was then taken up by institutional investors: ‘With the
implicit assent of institutional shareholders [e.g. pension funds—
AG], boards substantially increased the use of stock option plans
that allowed managers to share in the value created by restructuring
their own companies. Shareholder value thus became an ally [of management—AG] rather than a threat’ (Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003: 8).
This is a very mild way of describing the frenzied increase in management pay, mainly by the issuing of stock options. In 2001 the ten
most highly rewarded CEOs in the top 500 companies were granted
option packages with an estimated average value of $170 million, an
amazing amount, especially since several of them already held large
amounts of stock. ‘It is hard to argue that these people needed
stronger shareholder incentives. An obvious explanation is that
they have been able to use their positions of power to command
excessive rewards’ (Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003: 13). For the largest
500 US companies the ratio of CEO pay to production worker earnings rose from 30 in 1970 to 570 in 2000, with most of the increase
taking the form of stock options. This contrasts with ratios in the
10– 25 range in Japan and Europe. CEO compensation (that is for one
person per company) averaged 7.9% of corporate profits in a large US
sample of companies. Stock options (on shares which management
still held) reached 15% of equity currently outstanding. It is hardly
surprising that all this potential for personal enrichment caused
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
59
‘management to obsess over their firm’s day-to-day share price’
(Coffee 2003: 32).7
There was a close link between this change in executive
compensation and the wave of corporate scandals (Enron, World
Com etc.) that engulfed the USA after the stock market boom subsided in 2000: ‘a system that lavishly rewards executives for success
tempts those executives, who control much of the information
available to outsiders, to fabricate the appearance of success.
Aggressive accounting, fictitious transactions that inflate sales,
whatever it takes.’ (Krugman 2004: 111). An example helps to clarify
the potential benefits to top management of inflating current profits,
for example by somehow bringing hoped for future revenues into
this year’s accounts: ‘assume a CEO holds options on 2 m[illion]
shares of his company stock and that the company is trading at a
price to earnings ratio of 30 to 1 (both reasonable assumptions for this
era). On this basis, if a CEO can cause the “premature” recognition of
revenues that result in an increase in annual earnings by simply $1
per share, the CEO has caused a $30 price increase that should make
him $60 m richer. Not a small incentive!’ (Coffee 2005: 202).
WorldCom admitted in July 2002 that it had hidden some $7 billion
of operating expenses over the previous two years as capital expenditure, thereby inflating earnings by the same amount.8 A study by the
Financial Times of 25 major corporate bankruptcies calculated that
‘between 1999 and 2001 the senior executives at these doomed firms
pocketed some $3.3 billion in salary, bonuses, and the proceeds from
sales of stock and stock options’ (Cassidy 2002: 336).
Doing business with these companies was extremely important to
the auditors, lawyers and bankers involved, discouraging probing
questioning of deals and accounts. ‘Put as bluntly as possible, the
audit partner of a major client (such as Enron) is always conflicted by
the fact that such a partner has virtually a “one-client” practice.
Should the partner lose that client for any reason, the partner will
need to find employment elsewhere’ (Coffee 2003: 37). Fees from
Enron represented one-quarter of Arthur Andersen’s auditing revenue in Houston, thus making that branch of Andersen highly dependent on business from Enron. Moreover these auditing companies
60
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
frequently also provided lucrative consulting services to the firms they
were auditing; for example, Andersen earned a further $27 million
in consulting fees from Enron. Buying consulting services from the
auditor gave firms like Enron an effective but discreet additional
source of leverage. Whilst sacking an auditing firm which was
proving uncooperative in reporting rapid profit growth would lead to
plenty of unwelcome comment, threatening to shift consulting contracts away from the auditor was a ‘low visibility’ method of keeping
up the pressure. Rather chillingly, in view of Andersen’s collapse in
the wake of the Enron meltdown, Coffee (2003: 35) concludes ‘The
available evidence in fact suggests that Andersen was no different
from its peers (except possibly less lucky).’
Investment banks earned $125 million in underwriting fees from
arranging share or bond issues for Enron over the period 1998–2000.
Analysts working for investment banks, supposed to be advising
investors but eager to curry favour with Enron in the hope of future
business, forecast increases in Enron’s share price that were twice
as big as the increases forecast by analysts not working for investment banks.9 More broadly, as the Initial Public Offering (IPO) market
grew, analysts’ objectivity became increasingly compromised as they
became ‘the principal means by which investment banks competed
for IPO clients, as the underwriter with the “star” analyst could produce the biggest first-day stock price spike’ (Coffee 2003: 39).
Finally the financial press signally failed to act as an effective
counterweight to analysts’ hype and auditors’ timidity. A review of
the treatment of Enron in the business press reported ‘a parallel universe of cheer-leading and obsequiousness, a universe where
applause obliterated scepticism’. According to a Wall Street Journal
writer, financial journalists ‘outsourced their critical thinking to
Wall St analysts, who are not independent, and by definition were
employed to do nothing but spin positive company news in order to
sell stock’ (quoted Dyck and Zingales 2003: 88, 89).
But surely the increasingly important investment managers of
pension and other funds would invest in line with long-term
‘fundamentals’, and would thus act as a counterweight to the
‘momentum’ trading of investors who just pile in after the prevailing
trend. Unfortunately the highly competitive nature of the fund
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
61
management industry prevailed over what might have been their
better judgement:
Whilst investment management firms were selected on the basis of long-term
records kept by pension fund consultants, consultants naturally began to help
corporate [pension—AG] plan sponsors monitor the performance of investment managers by collecting quarterly performance results. As competitive
pressures built in the very profitable investment management business,
this quickly evolved into a quarterly performance derby . . . investment time
horizons collapsed, investment performance became defined relative to a
benchmark or index portfolio, asset allocation and market timing skills
were made obsolete by a monomaniacal focus on stock selection and risk
became defined solely in relation to departures made from benchmark
weightings. Each of these consultant-inspired moves had the unintended
consequence of enhancing herding dynamics among institutional investors.
(Parenteau 2005, p. 123, 126)
Equity bubbles become much more likely.
The discussion in this section has concentrated on the weaknesses
in the US system based on ‘outsider’ ownership by pension funds
and other financial institutions focussed on shareholder value. Just
before the system was engulfed by Enron and other scandals at
the end of the boom, the superiority of its shareholder-oriented corporate governance structure was pronounced as representing the
ultimate system—the ‘end of history’—for corporate law by a pair
of Yale and Harvard law professors.10 Their justification was the
superior performance of the US economy compared to Germany,
Japan or France. How rapidly fashions had changed is shown by a
1992 Harvard Business Review article called ‘America’s Failing
Capital Investment System’ by Michael Porter, one of the most
influential management writers. This argued that US ownership
structures and corporate governance optimized short-term private
returns whilst ‘[b]y focusing on long-term corporate position and
creating an ownership structure and governance process that incorporates the interests of employees, suppliers, customers and the
local community, the Japanese and German systems better capture
the social benefits that private investment brings’ (Porter 1992: 74).
Of course scandals are by no means unique to the US financial
system. Europe produced a worthy competitor to WorldCom in the
62
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
Italian company Parmalat where more than $17 billion mysteriously
vanished from the balance sheet, with huge sums apparently being
siphoned off by controlling shareholders. Although auditors should
presumably have detected fraudulent transactions, which apparently
stretched over a decade, a comparison of US and European scandals
notes that ‘one suspects they would have likely been dismissed at
the point at which they began to monitor earnestly’ (Coffee 2005:
208). Nevertheless what was so striking about recent US experience
was that there was such a comprehensive and systematic set of
incentives for all the many professional groups involved in the
financial markets to acquiesce in such widespread abuse.
Despite all its evident problems, are the systems of other countries
being forced by competition towards the US model? Indications that
this is the case include the spectacular takeover of the giant German
company Mannesman by Vodafone reflecting the sudden emergence
of a wave of hostile takeovers in Europe, the growing number of
European companies listing on the US stock exchange bringing with
it disclosure requirements and pressures for shareholder value and
the effects on French and German corporations of large ownership
stakes built up by US financial institutions.11 This latter development
has provoked a sharp reaction in Germany, with a senior official of
the ruling SPD denouncing the US financial institutions involved as
‘locusts’. The Chairman of Toyota explained to a finance industry
conference in 2001 that it would be irresponsible to run Japanese
companies primarily in the interests of shareholders as this would
result in the pursuit of short-term profits at the expense of employment and research and development (R&D) spending. This approach,
however frustrating to investment managers, may be much more
successful in the longer term, at least in some sectors. With its longterm perspective Toyota has recently been valued more highly by the
stock market than Ford, General Motors and Chrysler combined.12
This is hardly consistent with the proclaimed universal superiority
of the UK/US system—the battle of competing models for industrial
organization and corporate governance is far from over.
In the wake of all the scandals in the USA there was a flurry of
proposals about how the law on corporate governance should be
tightened. The Sarbanes–Oxley Act which passed in 2002 required
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
63
CEOs to disgorge any profits from bonuses or stock sales during the
12 months after a financial report which was subsequently ‘restated’
because of ‘misconduct’. More detailed disclosure is required of
off-balance sheet items and ‘special purpose entities’ (much used
by Enron), the power and independence of the company’s audit
committee was increased and criminal penalties for misreporting
were raised. The authorities, having sat on their hands whilst the
boom and the scandals were boiling up, acted to head off further
excesses. One assessment concluded that Sabanes–Oxley dealt with
‘some of deficiencies of US corporate governance’ and probably
helped to restore confidence (Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003: 21).
Who Bears the Costs?
The costs and benefits of the great drive for shareholder value and
the US stock market boom can be examined at two levels. First,
there is the impact of the frauds and scandals. Secondly, there is the
boom itself—what was its role in launching a major wave of new
innovations?
The cases of fraud and deliberate malpractice have often brought
financial disaster for tens of thousands of the employees involved
(lost jobs and frequently pensions). Moreover the companies concerned invested in assets which turned out to be useless. Enron spent
nearly $1 billion on information technology during its last three
years and there was heavy spending on R&D, broadband and IT technologies by other prominent manipulators such as WorldCom, Tyco
and Global Crossing. Such companies also acquired companies with
their inflated shares and often ran them into the ground. An analysis
of earnings manipulation suggested ‘waste, probably running into
hundreds of billions of dollars, is a direct result of accounting manipulations’ (Lev 2003: 43).
There was, of course, more to the great US stock market boom,
and the new economy it was supposed to reflect, than accounting
scandals. Venture capital partnerships grew spectacularly from
committing around $5 billion of new funds to start-up companies in
64
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
the mid-1990s to more than $60 billion in 2000, 60% of which went
to companies in the IT sector. The bloated stock market valuations
of such companies brought the prospect of mouth-watering returns
for the venture capitalists if the companies they financed could
be floated on the stock market. By 2000 venture capital portfolios
represented twice as much capital in the USA than in Europe and
20 times more than in Japan.13
Venture capitalists could boast of having supported many companies
which proved very successful (like Apple, Cisco, Microsoft or Sun)
but the collapse of the internet boom revealed a vast over-commitment
of resources. The momentum of rising investment was so strong that
capacity in the US telecommunications equipment sector doubled
between the beginning of 1999 and the end of 2002. However the
utilization of this capacity fell from the exceptional level of 94%
in mid-2000 to a bit less than 50% in the second half of 2002. The
whole high-tech sector (including computer and semi-conductor
manufacture) exhibits the same pattern in milder form with capacity
utilization subsiding by 20% as the boom collapsed.14
This contradictory picture—extraordinary successes in introducing new technologies combined with extremes of waste and
overinvestment—encapsulates the dynamic side of capitalism.
The finance theorist, Andrei Shleifer, recalls Keynes’s verdict on
the boom of the second half of the 1920s: ‘Whilst some part of the
investment which was going on . . . was doubtless ill-judged and
unfruitful, there can, I think, be no doubt that the world was
enormously enriched by the constructions . . .’ (Shleifer 2000: 189).
Shleifer argues in a similar vein that the internet stock price bubble
meant that ‘a large number of creative entrepreneurs have moved
into this line of activity . . . , which may well be efficient in light of
the possibly significant external benefits from innovation in this
area’ (Shleifer 2000: 189).
Even leaving aside the extreme effects of boom and slumps shareholder value is immediately increased by actions which cut costs
and raise profits. Cutting jobs is often the easiest route to ‘taking out
costs’, to use the slightly sinister management jargon. Job destruction was higher in US manufacturing in the 1980s and 1990s than
in the 1970s, with both more employment falls within continuing
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
65
plants and more job losses due to plant closures. The pattern of
involuntary job loss in the USA over the past 20 years is consistent
with there having been increasing pressure on management to cut
costs through rationalization of production. At the end of the
upswing (1997–9) the rate of job loss was higher than a decade earlier,
despite a tighter labour market. If anything plant closures were
more important in the 1980s, which may reflect the strength of the
takeover boom of that decade, whereas in the 1990s focus was on
‘positions abolished’ in continuing plants, which is consistent with
greater pressure on all managements to take out production costs.
Hostile takeovers, a prime means of pursuing shareholder value
in the USA, often boosted profits at the expense of workers who lost
out in terms of jobs, wages or pension levels.15
International Finance
The growth of international financial flows has been one of the
more notorious aspects of the expansion of finance, stimulated by
progressive abandonment throughout the OECD of the capital
controls. These had more or less severely constrained the extent to
which a country’s firms and residents could invest overseas through
purchasing shares, putting funds in a bank abroad or even financing
the setting up of factories overseas. There were often corresponding
restraints on overseas funds entering a country. This is an aspect
of financial liberalization which has been well documented and it
has broader significance as opening the borders up to financial
flows makes it much more difficult to maintain tight controls on
the domestic financial system. Amongst OECD countries, five out
of 19 were classified by the IMF as having open capital markets in
1976, including the USA and Germany. The UK and Japan followed
suit by 1980. By 1988 only one OECD country was classified as having
controls in one of the five strongest categories, compared to half
the countries in 1973. In the late 1980s and early 1990s the rest of the
OECD liberalized with Norway the last of the social democratic
strongholds to succumb in 1995.16
66
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
World foreign exchange trading reached $1,900 billion per day in
2004, more than three times the level of 1989. Massive two-way flows
of funds have built up as banks and other institutions simultaneously borrow and lend abroad. Estimates show the total value of
stock of foreign assets of a large sample of countries doubled from the
equivalent of 36% of GDP to 71% of GDP between 1980 and 1995,
having already more than doubled over the previous two decades.
By the early 2000s the ratio probably reached 100%, getting on for
double its peak in 1900. Transactions in overseas securities by US
residents increased 60 times in relation to GDP between 1977 and
2003.17
The theory is that all of this activity parcels out risks and returns
between holders of financial assets in an efficient way. Of particular
importance is the impact on payments balances. Has greater capital
mobility allowed countries to run balance of payments deficits on
current account and has this helped or hindered stability and
growth? Have capital flows facilitated rapid movement of exchange
rates towards appropriate levels or tended to exaggerate overvaluations and undervaluations which have serious consequences for the
real economy?
During the Bretton Woods period exchange rates were pegged
with devaluations only allowed in situations of ‘fundamental disequilibrium’. The current account of the balance of payments was generally regarded as a constraint to which domestic policy had to respond
and current account deficits were small. This constrained countries’
investment to their own level of savings.18 Since the early 1980s, and
especially in the 1990s, however, there has been a substantial increase
in the average size of balance of payments surpluses or deficits (in
relation to GDP).19 Is this a good thing? If larger deficits reflected
borrowing to invest productively by poorer OECD countries like
Portugal, or those particularly well endowed with natural resources
like Australia, then the effects would be beneficial. However deficits
have often been associated with the consumer booms discussed above.
In Portugal for example most of the increased deficit reflected reduced
savings rather than increased investment. The rising US deficit at the
end of the 1990s expansion could be regarded as facilitating the great
IT investment boom. However by 2004, with the current account
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
67
deficit at 5% of GDP, the deficit was funding high levels of consumption and military spending.
Free mobility of capital is supposed to ensure that exchange rates
smoothly offset trends affecting the competitiveness of a country’s
exports (rate of wage increases out of line with competitors’ for
example). This would mean that the real exchange rate—the nominal rate adjusted for price or wage cost inflation—would be maintained, or only adjust smoothly in response to long-run changes in
underlying competitiveness. Here the record must have been very
disappointing to free-marketers. On average the real exchange rate
of OECD countries changed by about 3% a year in the 1960s, and
then 6% per year in the 1970s as the Bretton Woods system
collapsed.20 Real exchange rate fluctuations subsided somewhat after
the 1970s, but in the 1990s these year to year movements were
still half as large again as in the 1960s. If these were merely random
fluctuations around satisfactory trends then they could hopefully
be absorbed by the real economy without undue costs, especially as
the greater sophistication of financial markets and its participants
made it easier to hedge (insure against) fluctuations in nominal
exchange rates. However, these year to year movements have also
coincided with longer-term swings in real exchange rates (and thus
the cost competitiveness of the traded goods sectors) of individual
economies which can have a lasting, distorting effect on the structure of the economy.
Confining attention to the three major currencies (dollar, yen and
the Euro superseding the German mark), Figure 3.2 shows the real
revaluation of the dollar of around 70% in the first half of the 1980s
followed by a sharp fall and then another substantial increase after
1995 (US policy towards the dollar is discussed in Chapter 4 below).
The Euro and the yen have also delivered large changes in real
competitiveness, generally mirroring the dollar. Such sustained
movements in the real exchange rate can be extremely damaging to
the capacity of the economy. Investment is discouraged by the extra
risk and adjustments are made which are not readily reversed if the
real exchange reverts to a more appropriate level.21 For example
sustained real appreciation causes companies to withdraw from
export markets and make workers redundant. A detailed study of
68
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
US manufacturing found that dollar appreciation substantially
increased job destruction (the rate of job loss in manufacturing
plants) and that was not compensated by correspondingly lower job
destruction or increased job creation (manufacturing plants increasing employment) when the dollar depreciated again. The authors
also noted the damaging effects of bursts of job destruction: ‘Workers
are likely to have an easier time finding suitable reemployment when
job destruction is gradual and diffuse than when an external shock
[e.g. dollar appreciation—AG] causes job destruction to spike and,
consequently, a glut of displaced workers are searching for new jobs
simultaneously’ (Klein et al 2000: 29).
200
USA
Japan
Germany
150
100
50
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Fig. 3.2. Real Exchange Rates, 1975–2004
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 1995 ⫽ 100.
The pathological case of exchange rate fluctuation is a full-blown
currency crisis. This is conventionally defined in the academic literature as a month when a combination of exchange rate and foreign
currency reserve changes exceeds a threshold level. One study found
that each of the OECD countries in the sample (four Scandinavian
countries and Spain) had experienced four or more crisis episodes
since 1970. As well as instances involving big budget deficits, current
account deficits or ‘financial excesses’, there were also crises caused
by sudden shocks in international capital markets and self-fulfilling
speculative attacks—‘crises also happen in economies with immaculate fundamentals’ (Kaminsky 2003: 2). The incidence of crises
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
69
with a currency element rose in the period of floating rates since 1973,
with the period up to 1987 being worse than the following decade.22
In an admittedly rough and ready calculation Eichengreen (2004) suggests that reimposing capital controls, with the presumed effect of
suppressing currency crises, could add as much as $100 billion dollars
per year to the growth of world GDP. However he did not favour such
a move since he estimated the costs, in terms of reduced depth of
financial intermediation, as 50% more than the benefits. It seems
unlikely that controls focused on short-term financial flows would
have such dire effects on the financial system and thus economic
growth. More fundamentally, the issue of who bears the costs or
receives the benefits from financial liberalization should be brought
into the calculation. The World Bank estimated that the Asian crisis
of 1997, discussed briefly below, increased the incidence of poverty
in the region by 22 million.
Financial Instability
Exchange rate crises were discussed in the previous section, but
financial crises customarily include banking crises as well—episodes
where there is severe ‘financial distress’ in the banking system. The
most comprehensive historical study of financial crises found that
crises involving banking crises, which had almost died out in the
Golden Age, reappeared in strength from 1973 onwards and became
practically as frequent after 1987 as during the interwar period.
These banking crises, in Scandinavia for example, caused very large
output losses estimated as adding up to 7% of the GDP of the country
over the period affected and, where they were combined with a
currency crisis, the output loss was some 16% of GDP.23
The Bank for International Settlements in Basle is the international
institution charged with maintaining stability in the financial system
through formulating rules on how banks and other financial institutions should meet standards on capital adequacy and so forth. Its
Annual Report for 2005 (BIS 2005: 5) noted that ‘The global financial
system seems to have become prone to financial turbulence of
70
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
various sorts’. A recent paper from the Head of the Monetary and
Economics Department of the BIS argued that there seems to be a
‘common structural thread’ linking the increasing number of financial crises: ‘Increased risk taking on the part of private sector
participants in financial markets has been facilitated by financial
market deregulation and technical change. Liberalized financial systems seem inherently more prone to . . . intermittent financial crises
than do repressed financial systems . . . Increased competition could
bring a “sharpening dilemma”. Financial institutions find it harder
to maintain rates of return even as shareholders demand that returns
rise.’ The author notes the tendency for the finance sector to take
greater risks: ‘Consider how the loan losses to emerging market
economies (EMEs) in the 1970s seemed to spark a series of risky initiatives to reconstitute profits. In turn banks went into leveraged
buyouts, property lending, proprietary trading and then lending to
EMEs all over again.’ He gloomily concludes that ‘the modern financial system seems to be subject to a wide range of problems: operational disruptions, institutional insolvencies, short-term market
volatility, medium-term misalignments and contagion across countries and markets’ (White 2004: 1, 2 n. 4, 24).
Amongst the many financial crises which have plagued the markets
two may be selected as exemplifying the problems. The crisis over
Long-Term Capital Management in 1998 emphasized that the
increasing sophistication of financial markets has widened the
scope for drastic miscalculation rather than simply parcelling out
risk in smaller and more manageable bundles. In this case prompt
coordinating action by the financial authorities saved the day.
Finally the Asian crisis of 1997–8 underlined the contagion in contemporary financial markets and the destructive role of the policies
of the ‘Washington Consensus’ pushed by the IMF.24
(a) Long-Term Capital Management
The collapse of Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) in 1998
involved a mixture of ‘institutional insolvencies, short-term market
volatility . . . contagion across countries and markets’, to quote from
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
71
the menacing BIS list. Moreover it featured the most threatening new
breed of financial institutions—hedge funds25—and the most alarming
new class of financial instruments—derivatives.26 LTCM was a US
hedge fund which in July 1998 held assets of $125 billion, financed
by $4.1 billion of its own capital and the rest by borrowing. It had
been extremely profitable and held more than 50,000 derivatives
contracts with a notional sum involved in excess of $1 trillion.
LTCM was betting heavily that the yields on certain bonds were out
of line with short-term interest rates and this ‘should’ have brought
it a tidy return when relative values returned to a more normal relationship. Unfortunately for LTCM the Russian government’s debt
default intervened to prevent the shifts in yields anticipated by
LTCM, which then started racking up losses.
‘As it made losses, it sold some assets, which put pressure on
prices, but more importantly the market perceived that liquidation
of its positions became more likely. Traders who knew about LTCM’s
portfolio could position themselves so that they would not get hurt
by a liquidation, and might even benefit from it. Their actions put
pressure on prices, reducing further the value of LTCM’s portfolio,
which made liquidation more likely . . . investors and banks which
under normal times would have bid for assets in the event of an
LTCM liquidation were facing problems of their own, as they had
also made losses on their positions. Some were forced to sell assets
that LTCM also held, putting further pressure on prices’ (Stultz 2004:
31–2). A compounding factor was that other financial institutions
had set out to copy the particular deals which had been proving very
lucrative for LTCM. This was a worrying example of the broader
problem of ‘herding’ behaviour in financial markets. ‘Hedge fund
investors are notorious for copying each other’s strategies, so it is
not unusual for similar momentum based bets to race through the
hedge fund community at the same time. On top of this . . . copycat
trades are initiated by the proprietary trading desks of investment
banks and sometimes leaked to the trading desks of institutional
investment managers as well’ (Parenteau 2005: 122).27
In the event LTCM was rescued from bankruptcy by a $3.6 billion
injection of funds from creditor banks. They were cajoled by the
New York Federal Reserve Bank into contributing to a rescue whilst
72
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
individually they would have opted to free-ride on other people’s
efforts. The President of the New York Fed later explained:
Had Long-Term Capital been suddenly put into default, its counterparties
would have immediately “closed out” their positions . . . [I]f many firms had
rushed to close out hundreds of billions of dollars in transactions simultaneously . . . there was a likelihood that a number of credit and interest rate
markets would experience extreme price moves and possibly cease to function for a period of one or more days or even longer (quoted MacKenzie
2003: 366– 7).
Alan Greenspan testified to Congress that if LTCM had failed this
could have triggered the seizing up of markets, threatening the economy of the USA and many other countries.
Although the bailout of LTCM prevented serious longer-term
repercussions the crisis brought into sharp focus the potential fragility
of the financial system at its most sophisticated end. This is a continuing worry for the financial authorities charged with regulating
the sector and minimizing the likelihood of major crises. A recent, very
sophisticated and elaborate analysis found that a conclusive assessment of the systemic risks posed by hedge funds required data that
was unavailable and likely to remain so. However the results of their
modelling suggested that ‘we may be entering a challenging period’
and that ‘systemic risk is increasing’ (Chan et al. 2005: 97). Moreover
the banks are heavily involved with the hedge funds. ‘With margins
in traditional business squeezed, big banks are falling over themselves
to provide prime brokerage services to hedge funds, which include
extending credit, securities dealing and settlement and so forth.
Competition has led to an erosion of credit standards . . . One respondent [to a recent survey] even refers to prime brokerage as “the crack
cocaine of the financial system” ’ (Plender 2005: 17).
Problems like those at LTCM seem endemic given the search for
ever more exotic ways of beating the market. In May 2005 there was
a ‘near systemic meltdown’ in the ‘Over the Counter’ derivatives
market, according to a senior figure in the securities industry. This
followed the reduced credit rating of GM and Ford bonds, which
affected several popular hedge fund trading ploys. Some funds had
arranged complicated deals based on these corporation’ bonds and
stock tending to move in the same direction. However, a takeover
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
73
bid for GM pushed its stock price up whilst its lower credit rating
pushed its bond price down. This left hedge funds that were holding
the bonds and committed to sell the stocks, which they did not yet
own, at a low price ‘doubly exposed and with leverged positions [having borrowed a lot]’ (Dodd 2005: 4). A number of major hedge funds
subsequently closed, including the one designated Hedge Fund of the
Year for 2004. Unfortunately very rich owners of, or investors in,
these funds are not the only people whose finances are put at risk by
such instability. As the OECD noted: ‘Public pension schemes are
being scaled down to reduce fiscal pressure and to increase space for
contributions to occupational and personal pension arrangements’
(OECD 2001: 13). If financial markets are made volatile then growing
numbers of workers will face increasingly risky retirement incomes.
(b) The Asian Crisis
The Asian crisis which developed in the second half of 1997 illustrated above all how inextricably intertwined the world’s financial
system had become. Speculative pressure against a previously
obscure currency, the Thai baht, spread from currency to currency
and threatened disaster for the world economy. Orthodox financial
policies, dogmatically applied by the IMF, became widely recognized as destructive in the circumstances and seriously undermined
the credibility of that institution.
The underlying cause of speculative pressure was the serious
overvaluation of these currencies, which were pegged to the dollar.
When the dollar appreciated in the second half of the 1990s their
manufacturing sectors became uncompetitive. This coincided with
the coming on stream of manufacturing capacity resulting from the
earlier high rates of investment. This investment, which extended
into speculative office building, was strongly encouraged by plentiful supplies of overseas finance. Firms and banks in these countries
took on huge levels of debts, denominated in dollars. The real value
of these debts, in terms of domestic production and exports, would
rise in proportion to any decline in their currency’s value against
the US dollar.
74
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
A brief chronology compiled from the Bank for International
Settlements, Annual Report for 1998 and 1999, illustrates the
contagious nature of financial market behaviour.
July 1997
August
October
November
December
January 1998
May
June
July
August
September
December
January 1999
Thai baht forced to float after exchange controls
failed to stem speculative pressure; wider
fluctuations for other Asian currencies.
Floating of Indonesian ruppiah. IMF-led support
package of $20.1 billion for Thailand.
Sharp falls in equity prices in Asia, Latin America
and Russia. Strong exchange rate pressure in
Brazil, Hong-Kong, Korea and Taiwan.
$40 billion IMF-led support package for Indonesia.
$57 billion IMF-led support package for Korea.
Korean won floated.
Rouble pegged to dollar with ⫹/⫺ 15% band.
Indonesian corporate debt ‘pause’.
Russian interest rates reach 150%.
Indonesian corporate debt restructured. South
African rand depreciates sharply.
$23 billion IMF-led support package for Russia.
Russia suspends payments on short-term
government debt and moratorium on commercial
debt payments to non-residents.
Rouble floated. Malaysia pegs exchange rate and
imposes stringent capital controls. Latin
American equity markets fall sharply; interest
rates double in Brazil to 50%. Chile widens bands
for exchange rate, increases interest rates and
tightens exchange controls.
$41.5 billion IMF-led support package for Brazil
after budget balancing programme.
Brazilian real floated.
The charge against the IMF (and the American Treasury whose views
they tended to follow to the letter) is that it had pushed countries
into capital market liberalization which, combined with fixed
exchange rates, encouraged firms and banks to borrow abroad
recklessly. As Joe Stiglitz, ex-chief economist at the World Bank and
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
75
scourge of the IMF, pointed out, the Managing Director of the IMF was
still repeating the call in September 1999 ‘after the global financial
crisis had so vividly demonstrated the risks of capital market liberalization’ (Stiglitz 2004: 58). In a remarkable volte-face the IMF as good
as admitted this when the Chief Economist of the IMF concluded
that ‘those countries that made the effort to become financially
integrated . . . faced more instability’ (quoted by Stiglitz 2004: 57).
All the countries concerned suffered serious output declines as
they raised interest rates and cut budgets as instructed by the IMF:
‘the initial demands for fiscal cuts on the part of the crisis countries
were excessive; by further compressing demand in an already depressed
environment, they made post crisis recessions worse’ (DeLong and
Eichengreen 2002: 227).
The increase in interest rates which the IMF claimed was necessary
to limit falls in currency values also had the perverse effect of further
weakening domestic economies at the very time that overseas
investors’ confidence had to be maintained. Companies with debts
owing to local banks faced higher interest costs which compounded
their having to pay more on their overseas loans as their currencies
depreciated. Instead of trying to sustain production and investment
in countries whose currencies were under pressure, the IMF’s focus
was on ‘structural reforms’. The very features of Asian economies,
particularly the close relation between banks and firms, that had
previously been heralded as contributing to rapid growth, were now
retitled ‘crony capitalism’ and blamed for the crisis.
The Asian economies suffered big falls in output in the wake of
the crisis, but mostly recovered quite rapidly. Even so in Korea the
lost growth was never made up and unemployment has remained 1
percentage point above the pre-crisis level. In Indonesia the consequences were much graver still as the financial crisis developed
into a full-blown political and social crisis.
Conclusions
This chapter has traced the remarkable shifts in the financial landscape over the past 25 years. The importance of financial activities
76
FINANCE AND OWNERSHIP
has grown spectacularly along almost every dimension of financial
activity. Consumer credit has boomed allowing consumption to
acquire temporary independence from the constraint of current
incomes. Particularly in the USA shareholdings have become more
concentrated in the hands of financial institutions, which pile on
remorseless pressure for the maximization of share prices. Corporate
management whose pay was extravagantly boosted by share options,
auditors, lawyers and analysts, were entangled in a mutually beneficial game of talking up profit prospects. Together with some genuine
investment opportunities in sectors in high-tech sectors, such
manipulation brought stock markets to record highs. International
capital flows brought extended periods of exchange rate misalignments. Financial crises have increased in frequency, both in the
most sophisticated financial markets of the rich countries and in
‘emerging market’ economies induced to liberalize regardless of
domestic circumstances. The most significant winners have been
chief executives and successful speculators on the domestic and
international financial markets. The losers were workers whose
jobs, working conditions and pensions were put at risk and investors
not in the know.
More volatile consumption, violent stock market and foreign
exchange swings in valuations, and periodic financial crises might
be expected to bring ‘boom and bust’—greater fluctuations of output
and employment. Whether the economies of the rich countries have
indeed become more unstable will be discussed in Chapter 6. First,
however, we need to examine developments in international economic relations which have added further elements of instability,
much debated under the broad heading of ‘globalization’.
4
Globalization and International
Economic Relations
Is that to say we are against Free Trade? No, we are for Free Trade,
because by Free Trade all economical laws, with their most
astounding contradictions, will act upon a larger scale, upon the
territory of the whole earth . . . .
(Karl Marx; text of a speech on Protection, Free Trade and the
Working Classes in 1847, reproduced in Engels (1847: 290)).
The economy is shot, Ma, we can’t hack it, we don’t have the
discipline the Germans and Jap[anese] do.
(Harry Angstrom in John Updike’s Rabbit is Rich (1981)).
So far economic relations between countries have played little
part in this account of the response of the most developed economies to the challenges of the 1970s. Subsequently globalization,
which we will take to mean international economic integration,
has claimed a leading place in economic discussion. This chapter
will examine first the changing economic fortunes of the USA,
now restored to its position of pre-eminence amongst the rich
countries. Then the challenge posed to the economies of the
most developed economies by the spectacular rise of China will
be discussed. Finally the broader issues of international economic
integration will be analysed, as a backdrop to the discussion of
the pressures on the labour movement, which is the subject of
the next chapter.
78
GLOBALIZATION
The USA and its Rivals
As discussed in Chapter 1, Europe and Japan made considerable
headway during the Golden Age in catching up with US levels of
productivity and this continued through the 1970s and 1980s. This
generated widespread concern in the USA, reflected in the setting up
of an MIT Commission on Industrial Productivity. The introduction
to its report, published in 1989, began:
To live well a nation must produce well. In recent years many observers
have charged that American industry is not producing as well as it ought to
produce, or as well as it used to produce, or as well as some of the industries
of some other nations have learned to produce. If the charges are true and
the trend cannot be reversed, then sooner or later the American standard
of living must pay the penalty.
. . . Products made in the United States are said to be inferior . . . .American
factories are accused of inefficiency; the work force is said to be indifferent
and ill-trained; and managers are criticized for seeking quick profits rather
than pursuing more appropriate long-term goals. (Dertouzos et al 1989: 1)
In each of the eight industry case studies carried out by the
Commission, including cars, computers and consumer electronics,
the seriousness of the competition posed by European, or more often
1
Europe
Japan
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Fig. 4.1. Manufacturing Productivity relative to USA, 1979–2003
Note: The series are for output per hour worked. USA ⫽ 1
Source: Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Bureau of Labour Statistics. See
Data Appendix.
GLOBALIZATION
79
Japanese, companies was stressed. In the light of the excitement
surrounding nimble US high-tech companies in the new economy
boom of the 1990s the Commission’s comment on US semiconductors is striking: ‘The contest was between small, single-product,
inexperienced under-financed American start-ups and the heavyweights of Japanese industry. David did not defeat Goliath’ (Dertouzos
et al 1989: 10).
The period after 1995 saw a striking turn-round. US productivity
growth accelerated and both Europe and Japan fell further behind
again as Fig. 4.1 brings out very starkly. These comparisons of
productivity levels, which can only be very approximate, suggest
that manufacturing industry in Europe and Japan having got within
striking distance (80–90%) of US productivity by the mid-1990s,
then sank back to around 65–75% of the US level. The factors behind
this change in fortunes are considered in Chapter 6 below; for the
present the important point is that the stronger productivity growth
helped bolster confidence in the US economy.
The Dollar and the US Balance of Payments
The improvement in US economic performance encouraged massive
inflows of capital into US financial assets. This drove up the value
of the dollar, which appreciated against the currencies of its main
trading partners by 29% between 1995 and 2001. The dollar plays
a pivotal role in the world monetary system as other countries
hold their foreign exchange reserves in dollars and it is used for
many international transactions between non-US firms and banks.
Its fluctuations, including the slide in 2004–5, need to be set in
longer-term context.
Figure 4.2 shows the shifts in both the nominal value of the dollar
against other currencies and the real exchange rate measuring the
cost competitiveness of US manufacturers. It is clear from the chart
that the overwhelming influence on the real exchange rate has been
the fluctuations in the nominal exchange rate of the dollar against
80
GLOBALIZATION
other currencies. The real dollar exchange rate appreciated by some
40% in the first half of the 1980s, fell rather more than that in the
later 1980s and early 1990s, before appreciating by around one-third
during the subsequent boom. The real depreciation in the early
1990s was a bit more than the nominal depreciation, as US costs
also rose relatively slowly. However for each of these big swings,
including the most recent dollar depreciation, shifts in the nominal
exchange rate have dominated.
160
Nominal effective exchange rate
Real exchange rate (RULC)
140
120
100
80
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Fig. 4.2. US$ Exchange Rate: Nominal and Real, 1975–2003
Source: IMF. See Data Appendix. 2000 ⫽ 100
The rise in the dollar in the early 1980s can be explained by the
attraction of the rise in US interest rates implemented by Volker at
the Fed (see Chapter 2), and then reinforced by a rising US budget
deficit. The US government maintained a policy of ‘benign neglect’
towards the exchange rate until in 1984 it pressurized the Japanese
government to open up their capital markets. This was supposed to
lead to a capital flow towards Japan (thus reducing the dollar’s value)
but it probably had a greater effect in making it easier for Japanese
investors to chase the rising dollar. The perverse effect on the dollar
was of little concern to Wall Street, which had wanted access to
Japanese markets. Indeed it appears that many US banks were
‘unsympathetic to industry’s problems in the early 1980s . . . some
bank CEOs hoped, with the Federal Reserve, that the appreciation of
the dollar would force rationalization and cost-saving upon what
GLOBALIZATION
81
they perceived to be a spendthrift and undisciplined manufacturing
sector’ (quoted by Frankel 1994: 325). However, by the beginning of
1985, the strength of the complaints from manufacturing about
the neglect of the dollar ‘had multiplied greatly’ and was ‘certainly a
major influence’ on the shift of the administration to a more activist
policy (Frankel 1994: 322). The (gross) profit share of US manufacturing value added was 24.8% in 1985, very close to the 24.3% level of
1979 before the recession and recovery. Given the extraordinary
decrease in US competitiveness implied by the rise in the dollar, a
sharp decline in profitability might have been anticipated. That it
did not materialize suggests that US manufacturers were rationalizing effectively.
The speculative nature of the dollar’s rise became hard to dispute
as it carried on into 1985 after US interest rates had begun to fall
relatively to those on competing investments. In February the
bubble deflated and the dollar fell back. In September 1985, and with
a less dogmatic team at the US Treasury, finance ministers of the
G5 meeting at the Plaza Hotel agreed that ‘some further orderly
appreciation of the non-dollar currencies is desirable’ and that they
‘stand ready to cooperate more closely to encourage this when it
would be helpful’. Background papers mentioned a 10–12% dollar
depreciation. The dollar fell by 4% immediately and then resumed
its downward slide, encouraged by sales of $10 billion dollars by
central banks including the Fed. By the end of 1986 Japanese exporters
were feeling the pinch and at the Louvre Accord in February 1987
the G7 finance ministers announced that the previous dollar decline
had brought currencies within the range ‘consistent with underlying economic fundamentals’ and that further changes could be
damaging. Though it was not made public, there were apparent
understandings that exchange rate fluctuations should be kept
inside a ‘reference band’ by central bank intervention in the foreign
exchange markets and, if necessary, by coordinated macro policies.
Heavy central bank intervention (including $100 billion purchases
of dollar securities by the Japanese government) restrained and
then halted the dollar’s fall. The fall in the dollar after 1985 helped
push up the manufacturing profit share by 5% points to reach 30%
in 1988–9.
82
GLOBALIZATION
% of GDP
The first two years of the Clinton administration saw a further
decline in the dollar and in 1995 policy switched with Clinton
announcing that he wanted a ‘strong dollar’. The G7 finance ministers
were persuaded to declare that a reversal of its decline against the
yen was now desirable and there was heavy foreign exchange intervention to support the dollar. Larry Summers, later Secretary of the
Treasury, justified the policy by arguing that pushing the dollar down
leads to a lack of confidence in financial markets and ‘undermines
the discipline needed to increase productivity’ (Summers 2002: 261).
As Figure 4.2 shows the dollar rose again, though to nowhere near the
level, in real terms, of the early 1980s.1 The ‘strong dollar’ policy may
have initially helped the dollar up but the more important influence
was the excitement surrounding the new economy boom. Overseas
purchases of US assets such as equities and bonds were four times as
high in 2000 as they were at the end of the 1980s boom. As one
observer put it: ‘The capital inflow is the way foreigners share in the
higher profits and future profits that new technology is expected to
bring’ (Meltzer 2002: 266). With both the stock market and the dollar
rising, returns on such investments in the USA were very high and
this in turn attracted more speculative inflows.
The gyrations in exchange rates noted above do more than simply
redistribute wealth between speculators. The real economy of exports
and jobs are involved, as noted in Chapter 3, and we next turn to the
10
8
6
4
2
0
–21980
–4
–6
–8
–10
1990
2000
Net non-residential fixed investment
Current account of BoP
Fig. 4.3. US Current Account and Domestic Investment, 1980–2003
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Data Appendix.
GLOBALIZATION
83
story of the US balance of payments. The US current account has
been in deficit every year since 1982 (Fig. 4.3). Whilst there was
an obvious improvement in the current account when the dollar fell
in the second half of the 1980s (compare Figs. 4.2 and 4.3), the deterioration through the 1990s looks quite inexorable. So the deficit
in 2003 was considerably larger as a percentage of GDP than it had
been in the mid-1980s when the real exchange rate was vastly more
appreciated and thus manufacturing less competitive.
The consumer boom of the late 1990s sucked in huge quantities
of consumer goods, from China in particular, and so the volume of
imports into the USA rose by 75% between 1995 and 2000. Imports
took 26% of the US market for manufactures in 2000, including 80%
for leather and shoes, 57% for apparel, 51% for computers and electronic equipment and 33% for cars and a wide swathe of machinery.2
The overvaluation of the dollar and the collapse of the high-tech
boom, which had boosted exports of ITC equipment, took their
toll on US exports which lost one-fifth of their world market share
between 2000 and 2003. The growing current account deficit
reflected a growing deficit in goods and even the services account
declined a little to near balance in the early 2000 s. By 2004 the
debts of the US government and firms overseas exceeded USowned foreign assets by the equivalent of some 30% of its GDP.
Even so it was still making a small net surplus on the returns from
its investments overseas, much of which had constituted high
return ‘direct’ investments by US companies with subsidiaries
overseas. Though there was a big inflow of direct investment into
the USA in the 1980s and especially during the new economy
boom, a good deal of this was invested in taking over existing
US assets, yielding a lower return than US multinationals earned
on their direct investments abroad in new production facilities.
Nevertheless if the current account decline persists and the overseas debts continue to pile up the investment income account
will inevitably go into the red pulling the current account further
into deficit. A persistent current account deficit of 5% of GDP
implies an overseas debt ratio rising towards 100% of GDP if the
underlying growth rate of the economy is 5% in nominal terms
(say 3.5% growth and 1.5% inflation).
84
GLOBALIZATION
So the prospect is of increasing indebtedness until the pattern of
growth can be twisted away from consumption and imports and
towards exports. Despite some decline in the dollar from its peak
value, detailed analysis in 2005 suggested that a further real depreciation of one-third was necessary to bring the USA into reasonable
balance; the nominal fall in the dollar would have to be considerably
greater than the ‘necessary’ real change since some of the competitive advantage would inevitably be eroded by faster US inflation as
the dollar price of imports rose.3
Figure 4.3 also plots the amount of net fixed investment in buildings and machinery by US business that is investment in excess of
depreciation. The current account deficit of the balance of payments
represents the amount that the economy as a whole is borrowing
from overseas. By 2002 the amount borrowed from overseas matched
net business investment. It was as though the whole of the meagre
US savings was absorbed by the government’s budget deficit and by
housebuilding, leaving all net business investment in the USA to
be financed by US corporations borrowing the savings of other
countries.4 This was an astounding position for the richest country
in the world.
If the USA was borrowing so much, who was doing the lending?
The first row of Table 4.1 shows the average size of the current
account deficit, building up to more than 5% of GDP from 2003. One
possible source of finance is from overseas firms investing more
in new factories in the USA or in purchasing US companies than US
firms were investing abroad. However this category of ‘direct investment’ (inflows minus outflows), having been small throughout the
1980s and 1990s, became a net outflow from 2003 on as US firms
were investing more overseas than their counterparts were doing in
the USA (Table 4.1 row 2). A second source of finance is if individuals
and financial institutions overseas buy US government or other
bonds, shares in US companies, or simply deposit money in US
banks. Again the issue is the balance between finance coming into
the USA like this and corresponding outflows by US residents and
financial institutions. In fact the private sector overseas provided
modest finance for the modest average US current account deficits
in the 1980s and 1990s, and provided almost all the extra finance
85
GLOBALIZATION
required when the deficit blew out over the years 2000–2 (row 3).
It seems surprising that the collapse of the US stock market and
of exaggerated expectations about the new economy boom did not
undermine the supply of private sector finance earlier. The third source
of finance is when foreign governments pile up foreign exchange
reserves in the form of US Treasury bills and bonds. Extra official
holdings were quite small until 2003–4 when Asian governments
in particular began to acquire huge amounts of dollars when they
intervened in foreign exchange markets to sell their own currencies
which were in heavy demand (row 4) They did this to prevent their
currencies from rising in value relative to the dollar, which would
have made their exports less competitive. In 2003–4 the dollar was
only prevented from free-fall by governments in the Far East being
prepared to accumulate seemingly endless piles of dollar assets as a
counterpart to export surpluses. By the end of 2003 overseas governments held 1.474 trillion dollar assets equivalent to 13% of US GDP.
The Bank for International Settlements underlined the precariousness
of the position of the dollar in 2005:
Table 4.1 Financing the US Balance of Payments Deficit, 1980–2004
Percentage of GDP
1980–9
1990–9
2000–2
2003–4
Current account
⫺1.7
⫺1.5
⫺4.3
⫺5.6
0.3
0.5
0.4
⫺0.1
1.0
0.7
0.4
3.3
0.6
⫺1.0
4.2
3.2
financed by
Direct investment (net)
Other private capital
Overseas governments’
holdings of US assets
Note: ⫺ means deficit or capital outflow; sources of finance are positive. Some
smaller sources of finance are excluded so rows 2–4 do not precisely offset the deficits in
row 1.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Data Appendix.
the widening current account deficit of the United States is a serious longerterm problem. That is, it could eventually lead to a disorderly decline of the
dollar, associated turmoil in other financial markets, and even recession.
Equally of concern, and perhaps closer at hand, it could lead to a resurgence
86
GLOBALIZATION
of protectionist pressure. The unprecedented size of the deficit, the speed with
which external debts are growing, the increasing reliance on the official
sector for deficit financing, and the fact that US borrowing has primarily
financed consumption (rather than investment) all suggest an eventual
problem. Moreover, given the interdependency of modern financial markets,
it is likely that problems would not be confined to the dollar alone. (BIS
2005: 144)
Capital Accumulation on a World Scale
Capital accumulation is the fundamental driving force of the economy.
Increases in investment are usually the most dynamic element in
aggregate demand expansions, particularly on a world scale where
one country’s exports are another’s imports. On the supply side the
growth of the capital stock is necessary to expand capacity. Investment
has a symbiotic relation with new technology, being made more
profitable by it and at the same time being the route through which
it enters the production system.5 Table 4.2 shows how the rate of
accumulation on a world scale slid back after the 1970s and how the
industrial countries are now accumulating at a slower rate than
the world as a whole, implying that the developing countries are
accumulating distinctly faster. It should be emphasized that the
calculations are based on partial information and many assumptions
so small differences in growth rates should not be taken literally.
Table 4.2 Capital Accumulation: Growth Rates of Fixed Capital Stock, 1960–2004
Average annual
percentage
changes
World
Industrial
countries
USA
Europe
1960s
1970s
1980s
1990s
2000–4
5.0
5.1
4.0
4.0
5.0
4.2
3.1
3.3
4.0
3.8
2.8
3.0
2.0
4.6
3.8
2.9
2.8
2.6
Source: Bosworth and Collins (2003). See Data Appendix.
Japan
12.5
8.5
6.1
4.0
2.1
Korea
China
India
Brazil
8.9
14.6
11.2
9.6
1.9
7.2
8.4
10.9
4.5
4.1
4.9
6.2
5.8
9.6
4.1
2.2
GLOBALIZATION
87
The numbers in bold are for substantial countries whose accumulation rate is estimated to be more than 1 percentage point above the
world growth rate for capital at the time. The fall in the capital stock
growth is clear across the OECD, and especially in Japan. The baton
of ‘super-accumulator’ was passed from Japan in the 1960s to Korea
(and Taiwan) in the 1970s and 1980s and then to China in the 1990s.
In the early 2000s the growth of capital stock in China could easily
be 12% or more.
In the early stages of China’s high growth period there was an
expansion of state employment, including in the dynamic and crucial manufacturing sector. However from the mid-1990s onwards
state employment began a sharp decline. ‘Through a combination
of management and worker buy-outs that converted firms from
public to private, some bankruptcies and a substantial workforce
downsizing in firms that remain state owned, manufacturing jobs in
the state sector have declined by almost three quarters from their
peak’ (Lardy 2003: 12).6 Thus, in its most recent phase, private capital
accumulation dominates the growth process in China, although
the state still strongly influences the pattern of investment through
its control of the credit system and its policy of creating ‘national
champions’ in sectors such as cars and steel.
A fast growth of the capital stock requires high ratios of investment
to GDP. Maddison (1998) adjusted official figures give a Chinese
investment share of about one-third for 1978–94, which is very close
to that reached in Japan and Korea.7 Indeed machinery and equipment investment, often seen as the main driver of growth, has been
running at around 20% of GDP—about 6% points less than in Korea
and Japan during their maximum growth periods and only 3–4%
points more than France and Germany in their Golden Age.8 So, even
with a further sharp rise in the investment share in 2003 and 2004,
China’s productive investment effort is not wholly unprecedented.
However it is playing out on a massive canvas and with vastly larger
supplies of surplus labour than its Asian predecessors in the catch-up
process.
After some decline in profitability in the later 1990s, industrial
profits in money terms rose by a factor of five between 1999 and 2004
and profits in the distribution sector rose at an even faster pace.
88
GLOBALIZATION
Conventional calculations for the rate of return to equity holders
suggest a higher return on capital in 2004 than in the mid-1990s.
Domestically funded companies have considerably lower reported
profits than foreign owned, with those owned in Hong Kong, Macau
and Taiwan most profitable of all despite a tendency to under-report
profits for tax reasons. Foreign-owned companies export around onethird of their sales, three times the share for domestic companies.9
Total employment in China is estimated at around 750 million, or
about one and a half times that of the whole of the OECD and nearly
ten times the combined employment of Japan and Korea. About a
half of China’s employment is still in agriculture. This constitutes
an enormous labour reserve available to flood in from the less developed interior of the country as labour markets tighten in the coastal
industrial areas. Estimates of the numbers who may be pulled out of
agriculture, where their incomes are very low, into industrial and
service jobs in the towns range as high as 150–300 million depending
on the time scale.10 There are already very large numbers of workers
making some kind of living in the informal sector of the urban economy, including both new recruits from the countryside and those
made redundant from state enterprises. They constitute an additional part of China’s huge reserve army of labour, to use Marx’s very
appropriate term.
Very rapid capital accumulation has brought a spectacular rise in
China’s share of world GDP, nearly tripling from 5% to 14% in a
quarter century. China on its own made up for all the collapsed output share of the ex-Soviet Union and Eastern Europe and much of the
downward drift in the share of Europe and Japan.11 It is easy to see
from Fig. 4.4 that, if current trends continued for another decade or
so, then China would be challenging the US’s title as the world’s
largest economy.
Whilst becoming the world’s largest economy will be a notable
development, China’s vast population means that this would occur
at less than one-quarter of the US level of GDP per head. Figure 4.5
sets the growth of China in the longer-term perspective of Asian
catch-up. Despite the doubling of the ratio of per capita GDP compared to the USA over the past 20 years, China is still as far behind
the USA as Korea and Taiwan were before their three decades of
89
GLOBALIZATION
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
1950
1960
China
1970
1980
USSR and EE
1990
USA
2000
OECD-USA
Fig. 4.4. Shares of World Output, 1950–2004
Source: Maddison (2001). See Data Appendix.
1
0.8
Japan
Korea/Taiwan
China
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 4.5. Catch-Up to USA in Asia—per capita GDP, 1950–2001
Source: Maddison (2001). See Data Appendix. USA ⫽ 1
rapid catch-up beginning in the late 1960s; it is still well below the
position from which Japan started its spectacular growth climb in
the mid-1950s.12
China is obviously far larger, in terms of population, than the earlier
examples of Asian catch-up. However it is also, after two decades of
spectacular growth, still far behind, in relative terms, the positions
90
GLOBALIZATION
from which their growth spurts were launched. Both aspects
contribute to China’s gigantic growth potential. Of course there is
nothing inevitable about China continuing along its present trajectory. If it does, the problems of adapting to this major shift in the
structure of world trade and output will be correspondingly severe.
The current and prospective development of China dwarfs all
other current trends in the world economy. For example it more than
accounts for all the reduction in the inequality of the distribution of
income on a world scale.13 Large numbers of poor Chinese people
have received increases in their real incomes which has pushed up an
important part of the bottom of the world income distribution.
Despite major increases in inequality within China, the improved
living standards of millions of poor Chinese have been more important in reducing income differences on a world scale. However the
latter issue, and the broader questions of China’s development
process, lie outside the scope of this book.14 Even world inequality is
an abstraction for people in the advanced countries. Where China
has a very real impact is in the shops and perhaps on the dole queue.
China’s Export Boom
Table 4.3 records the tenfold growth in Chinese manufactured
exports as a share of world exports over the past 25 years. Since 1990
the growth of Chinese exports has exceeded in absolute amount that
of the next largest nine low-wage manufacture exporters put
together.15 Ominously for them, since 2000 their combined export
share has fallen whilst China’s rose rapidly. An analysis of the
impact of Chinese exports on its Asian competitors found that countries producing consumer goods based on low wages were suffering
whilst capital goods producers, like Korea, were gaining from the
expanding market in China. Between 1980 and 2000 a half or more
of the increase in China’s export share in labour-intensive sectors
like clothing, travel goods, footwear and toys was at the expense
of Korea, Taiwan and Singapore, with the pressure now rising on
India and Indonesia. Up to one-third of Chinese manufactures are
91
GLOBALIZATION
produced from foreign owned plants, mostly Japanese, and this
generates a flow of machinery and component imports into China
from Japan to sustain export production. In 2003 China (including
Hong Kong) ran a trade surplus of nearly $100 billion with the USA,
whilst it was in substantial deficit with Japan, Korea and Taiwan.
Although foreign owned plants account for around one-half of Chinese
exports, more of their production is sold to the rapidly expanding home
market than is exported.16
Table 4.3 China’s Exports, 1980–2003
Percentages
1980
1990
2000
2003
Shares of world exports of manufactures
China
0.8
Nine other major low
6.8
wage exporters
1.9
10.5
4.7
16.1
7.3
15.0
Chinese share of
imports into:
North America
1995
2003
Europe
1995
2003
Japan
1995
2003
All manufactures
Toys and games
Clothing
Office etc equipment
7.6
52.3
14.9
5.4
2.2
26.0
7.9
2.5
4.7
39.8
12.2
10.0
15.1
26.4
56.6
5.8
29.3
56.7
80.0
28.0
15.9
76.9
16.9
23.7
Source: World Trade Organization. See Data Appendix.
China now makes nearly one-third of the comparatively limited
amount of manufactured imports into Japan (Table 4.3). It accounts
for a larger fraction of imports into both Europe and North America
than does Japan. In each case China’s market share has more or less
doubled in less than a decade. China dominates imports of toys and
games and has 40% of imports of clothing from low-wage countries
and is set to gain more market share for clothing now that quotas
have been phased out under the end of the Multi Fibre Agreement.
Its share in office equipment, several rungs up the technological
ladder, is already rising rapidly. In 2002 China displaced the EU and
Mexico as the biggest exporter to the USA of computers, consumer
electronics and other IT products,17 though a high proportion of
these exports involved assembly of high-tech components sourced
abroad. China’s is rapidly developing the capacity to produce more
92
GLOBALIZATION
sophisticated goods. By 2010 it is likely to be turning out more Science
and Engineering PhDs than the USA. Already China is ranked fourth
in the world, after USA, Japan and Germany, in research publications
in four emerging technologies and multinational companies are
locating research facilities there. Such activity is ‘moving to china
because China is graduating huge numbers of scientists and engineers’ (Freeman 2005b: 27)
12.0
%
9.0
Japan
China
Six East Asian NIEs
6.0
3.0
0.0
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 4.6. Shares of World Commodity Exports, 1948–2003
Source: World Trade Organization.
The growth of China’s involvement in world trade is spectacular
but, thus far, not without precedent. Just as the take-off of accumulation in China followed the pattern set by Japan and then Korea, so
has the trajectory of its exports. Figure 4.6 shows that China’s
exports have not yet reached the shares of world trade achieved by
Japan in the 1980s and 1990s, and then by the Asian NIEs (the Newly
Industrializing Economies including South Korea and Taiwan etc.).
Even though the rising share of Japanese exports was a more measured
and protracted process than China’s, the latter’s steep climb was
matched by the NIEs in the 1980s. Sharply rising competition
from the East has been a persistent trend over the past 40 years
and China’s export growth is its latest manifestation, rather than
a qualitatively new phenomenon.
However, as noted earlier, China’s size and current backwardness
means that it has the potential to carry this process a great deal further.
93
GLOBALIZATION
Another couple of decades of Chinese growth at something like current
rates must involve an enormous expansion of Chinese exports to pay
for the rising bill for imports of food, materials, fuel, semi-finished
manufactures, capital goods and even luxury brands of consumer
goods. Fast compound growth in China’s exports has a greater and
greater absolute impact on its low-wage competitors and on domestic
producers in the rich countries as its share of world trade grows.
Thus China’s share roughly doubled in the 1980s, increasing by
around 1.5percentage points; it doubled again in the 1990s, pushing
it up by 3%. If per capita GDP growth rates of around 6% per year in
China persist, a further doubling of the export share in the next
decade would probably be necessary to pay for the rising import
bill. This would raise China’s export share by another 6 percentage
points or so, more than the impact of the ‘Asian tigers’ in the 1980s
(see Fig. 4.6). Moreover, even after another decade of rapid growth,
China’s per capita GDP would not nearly have exhausted the possibilities of further rapid growth as China’s productivity would still
be far below that of the rich countries. Of course economic crises
can stifle growth of countries at any level of development, as the
stagnation in both Japan, after the collapse of its bubble, and
Indonesia in the wake of the Asian crisis illustrate all too well (see
Chapter 3). But barring a collapse into longer-term stagnation
70
Japan
Germany
Asian NIEs
China
% of US wages
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 4.7. Manufacturing Wages during Catch-Up, 1950–2003
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, China Statistical Yearbook. See Data Appendix.
94
GLOBALIZATION
China will continue to have a massive effect on the evolution of
the world trade structure.
A further huge expansion of Chinese exports will certainly increase
competition for markets in the OECD countries, causing serious problems for the other Southern industries in competition with them.
China will at some stage move up the ‘value chain’ in the same way as
did Japan and the Asian NIEs; when wage levels grow industries can
no longer compete so effectively in ‘low value’ markets where low
wages for unskilled workers are the main source of competitive
advantage. The historical experience is that at a certain stage in the
‘catch-up’ process wages do start rising substantially. At present, however, wages are still much lower in China than they were during the
boom periods in Japan and the Asian NIEs and are not yet threatening
China’s position as low-wage producer par excellence (see Fig. 4.7).
Real incomes have been rising in urban areas at over 5% per year
on average during the 1990s, though this exaggerates improvements
since residents faced much higher charges for education and health.
Moreover these estimates do not include rural migrants, who make
up much of the workforce for the exporting factories. In Guandong
province, where many export factories are situated, base wages
are reported at about $80 per month and working hours can be up to
80 per week. Wages are reported to have hardly risen in nominal
terms in a decade and inflation has eroded their real value by up to
30% despite the rapidly growing employment, suggesting that this
group of workers has not shared in the general urban prosperity.18
The migrants have to go through elaborate and expensive bureaucratic
procedures to obtain permission to work in the cities and it is
frequently made very difficult for them to change jobs. Labour discipline is very harsh, especially in Korean and Taiwanese owned
factories, where apparently in some cases: ‘workers are even marched
to and from meals and to and from dormitories in tight military style
squads’ (Chan 2003: 46).
Independent unions are banned, workers are often jailed for
organizing strikes and the official All-China Federation of Trade
Unions ‘for decades has aligned itself more with management
than with workers’ (Gough 2005). A senior provincial ACFTU official
explained the union’s attitude to poor conditions. ‘It’s better than
GLOBALIZATION
95
nothing’, he said.’Labor protections, working conditions and wages
are related to a country’s level of economic development. Of course
we want better labor protections but we can’t afford it. We need the
jobs. We need to guarantee people can eat’ (Goodman and Pan 2004).
Foreign firms locating in the Industrial Parks find ‘There is no union
representation in the plant. . . .There is no interference by unions in
operations management. The Labor union also seemed not to exert
influence in the area of wages’ (Jürgens and Rehbehn 2004: 17).
Despite all these obstacles, websites.19 regularly report on quite
major strikes and other actions, including disputes over unpaid
wages and compensation for redundancy.
There have been successive relaxations of the restrictions on migration to the towns, but labour shortages are reported in the coastal areas
giving ‘button-sewers and shoe stitchers a bit of bargaining power for
the first time. Factory owners cannot replace disgruntled employees
as easily as they once could; wildcat strikes can cripple output for
days or weeks. Almost imperceptibly workers are starting to win
concessions’ (Gough 2005).
Provided the boom keeps going and the labour reserves are
whittled away, then at some stage market forces will overwhelm the
repressive measures and wages will start growing for the exporting
factories just as they did in Japan and the Asian NIEs. Moreover, continued export success will bring currency appreciation of the yuan
which will further increase wages valued in terms of dollars, which
determines competitiveness. Rising wage costs will force Chinese
firms to switch to production and export of products requiring more
skilled labour. This will relieve the pressure on the other very lowwage exporters now suffering from Chinese competition. In their stead
it will be the producers of the more sophisticated goods into which
China moves, in the North and in the Asian NIEs, who will feel
increasing pressure.
China’s imports have been growing very rapidly and now comprise
around 5% of world imports of both agricultural products (food and
materials) and mining products (metals and fuel), including 12% of
world imports of iron and steel.20 Such imports of the basic inputs
into manufacturing have received much attention, with press stories
of shortages of steel capacity and China’s voracious demand for oil
96
GLOBALIZATION
and other inputs. However imports of manufactures into China are
currently worth about four times as much as its imports of agricultural and mining products. Imports of high-tech components, of
computers for example, for re-export play a very substantial role.
However imports of capital goods for domestic investment and consumer goods for domestic consumption are becoming increasingly
important. The fundamental point is that China is important for
the OECD countries not only as a source of cheap, and potentially
disruptive imports, but also as an increasingly important market for
exports. Although OECD countries have no monopoly on supplying
China, if Persian Gulf oil producers or Brazilian soy bean farmers
receive higher incomes through exporting to China they in turn will
tend to buy more imports. Thus, both directly and indirectly, China
is becoming an increasingly important influence on the economies
of the rich countries.
International Economic Integration
The arrival of wave after wave of Chinese exports in the shops of the
rich countries is the most dramatic manifestation of their increasing
integration into the world economy. This section examines the extent
to which their economies are affected by international competition
as a prelude to the discussion in the final chapter of whether such
competition is undermining regulation and egalitarian policies. The
flows of financial capital were discussed in the last chapter so the
focus here is on international trade, flows of foreign direct investment
(FDI) and international migration.21
Trade
Exports are the most visible form of production geared to the world
market. World exports have grown faster than world production
and this comparison is often used to measure rising globalization.
97
GLOBALIZATION
In fact the ratio of world exports to GDP has doubled since 1960 to
around 25% of world GDP,22 with the rate of increase being slower
in the second half of the period (having lost the boost from higher
oil prices). Much of the increase reflects rising export shares in
Europe and the USA (see Fig. 4.8); in both cases however, the ratio
of exports to GDP in 1913 was only exceeded at the end of the
1960s.23 Japan however shows an extraordinary stability of trade
shares since 1950 (with oil-price induced humps)—in striking
contrast to China.
The impact of international competition within domestic economies
is most clearly displayed in the degree of import penetration of the
domestic market for manufactures (see Table 4.4)
30
USA
Japan
Europe
China
%
20
10
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 4.8. Trade as a Percentage of GDP, 1950–2000
Source: Penn Tables. See Data Appendix.
Table 4.4 Import Penetration of Domestic Markets for Manufactures, 1913–2001
Percentage
1913
1950
1974
1991
2001
All
From ‘South’
USA
Japan
Europe
3
34
13
2
3
6
6
5
17
14
7
28
21
12
39
10
7
8
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
98
GLOBALIZATION
Increasing import competition was noticeable during the Golden
Age and, with the partial exception of Japan, it has continued unabated
with import market shares doubling in Europe after 1974 and rising
more than threefold in the USA. Most of this competition has traditionally come from other OECD countries. However imports from
the ‘South’ have grown rapidly and now take nearly one-tenth of
domestic markets in USA and not far short of that in the rest of
the rich countries, with China playing a major role as discussed
earlier.
The impression of dramatically increasing international integration through trade surely derives from this growing penetration by
imports of domestic manufacturing markets. But manufacturing
only constituted 18% of OECD employment by the end of the millennium (ranging from 15% in USA to 24% in Germany); for the
OECD this represents a decline of one-third as compared to 1974.
Does trade integration amount, therefore, to increasingly fierce
competition for a diminishing and relatively small, but highly visible, share of the economy?
The significance of manufacturing is in fact underplayed by its
share of employment since other sectors make a contribution as
suppliers of inputs to manufactured commodities. So part of the
output of agriculture, mining, energy, construction, transport and
finance and business services is, at one remove, subject to the international competition within manufacturing. Thus it is dependent
on the success of the country’s manufacturing sector in maintaining
its share of the domestic and world markets. If we extended the
calculation to include service inputs into manufacturing, and the
value of agricultural and mining output which is heavily traded
internationally, it would seem that around 30% of the UK economy
is directly or indirectly contributing to the production of internationally traded goods.
Of course some services are traded directly as well. In the late 1990s
exports of commercial services were about 20% of total exports for
the world as a whole and for high income countries.24 But these are
concentrated in a narrow range of specialized business services
(international transport, international finance, consulting, call centres
and so forth) and imports are practically irrelevant for the mass of
GLOBALIZATION
99
domestic service producers (distribution, education and health care
for example).
There is no obvious way of quantifying what part of services
is seriously internationalized in this sense; but any plausible
estimate would leave a majority of employment in OECD countries, possibly a substantial and even a growing majority, largely
untouched by international trade competition.25 Outside agriculture, mining and manufacturing only a small proportion of workers
are subject to international competition directly or indirectly
through services provided to traded goods sectors. Wholesale
and retail trade, community, personal and social services, utilities
and construction together comprise some 60% of employment in
the OECD as a whole, rather more in the USA. These sectors are
largely insulated from international trade competition. Recently
there has been much publicity about ‘outsourcing’ some service
activities, call centres or clerical work for the financial sector
being relocated in India for example. Available estimates suggest
that this activity is fairly limited in terms of its employment
effects—one estimate puts such new outsourcing at only 1% of
jobs destroyed and created annually in the USA. Outsourcing of
computing and business services in the USA had doubled in each
of the last two decades but is still only 0.4% of US GDP. Both the
USA and the UK, where there is more outsourcing, have substantial
overseas payments surpluses in these services and Japan and
Germany only have small deficits.26
The impact of internationalization through trade, therefore, is quite
complicated. For one section of the economy, comprising manufacturing production and its suppliers together with some specialized
enclaves in the services sector, international integration through
trade has grown considerably and this will continue if rapid growth
continues in China. Meanwhile large sections of the economy, including growing ones like social and community services and retail, are
highly insulated from international trade.
The impact of this rapid growth of trade on Northern workers is
mixed. Living standards have been boosted by low wage imports.
On the other hand there has been a substantial effect in terms of job
loss as discussed in the next chapter.
100
GLOBALIZATION
Foreign Direct Investment
Foreign direct investment (FDI), in factories and purchase of companies overseas, rose rapidly over the last three decades, especially
in the second half of the 1990s. Corporations in the rich countries
were both investing overseas (outward investment) and meeting
competition from overseas companies investing in their domestic
markets (inward). The quantitative importance of FDI may be
assessed by comparing the annual flow with the total amount of
domestic investment going on in the recipient country in that year.
If the inflow of FDI were to continue at a particular percentage of
investment, eventually it would constitute that percentage of the
accumulated capital stock. Table 4.5 suggests that should recent
trends continue, around 13% of the capital stock in both the developed and developing countries would be owned abroad. This would
bring the share of FDI above its previous historical peak before 1914,
though not by a large margin.27 Within the developed economies FDI
is exceptionally high in the EU, with much of the investment being
within the EU (and thus showing up as both inward and outward).
It is also exceptionally low in Japan, with the stagnant Japanese
economy attracting little inward FDI, and more surprisingly
Japanese firms investing abroad very modestly. The US economy
attracted more FDI than US multinationals invested abroad.
Although the Chinese figure for inward investment does not look
exceptional, the enormous share of gross investment in Chinese
GDP, approaching 50% by 2004, means that the FDI inflow was
Table 4.5 Foreign Direct Investment Flows, 1992–2003
Percentage
of gross
investment
Inward
Outward
World
Developed
countries
USA
1992–7
5.2
5.5
EU
Japan
Developing China
countries
0.7
2.7
12.5
3.7
1998–2003
12.7
12.0
Source: UNCTAD. See Data Appendix.
12.6
14.8
9.1
7.7
23.5
30.1
11.6
0.7
GLOBALIZATION
101
very large in relation to GDP—some 5%. Much FDI into China comes
from other overseas Chinese capitalists in other Asian developing
countries. Newspaper reports suggest that substantial inflows of
FDI into China actually originate within China itself, masquerading as FDI in order to obtain tax breaks. In addition, however,
Western multinationals were carrying out substantial investments
in industries like electronics and cars. Chinese companies have
also begun to make investments abroad, in search of supplies of
energy and other inputs or of brand names and manufacturing
expertise. Even though this is in effect reinvesting back the equivalent of a small part of the inflow of FDI, it created a furore, especially
when a Chinese bid went in during 2005 for a modestly sized US
oil company.
The sectoral composition of FDI is less biased towards manufacturing than is foreign trade. In the 1990s around one-half of outward FDI was in the services sector. Obviously FDI can reach into
parts of the service sector like retailing or restaurants immune
from direct competition from imports, as when McDonald’s or
Walmart invests in a new country. Well over half of FDI inflows
into OECD countries represent cross-border mergers and acquisitions rather than companies setting up factories or offices from
scratch. However this may still represent a heightening of competition for the other domestic firms. FDI represents an important
qualification to the remarks above about the insulation of large
parts of the services sector in the rich countries from international
competition. Countries, like the USA and UK, with strong service
sector companies have been pushing hard for the liberalization
of service provision, and the FDI required to support it, in international economic negotiations at the World Trade Organisation.28
Whilst the numbers presented above are useful to gain an impression
of the magnitudes involved, it may be that the most important
aspect of FDI is the enhanced potential for mobility of location for
companies in the rich countries. Even if the threat is only exercised
periodically it can still serve to weaken workers at the bargaining
table when it comes to wage or employment negotiations, as discussed further in the next chapter.
102
GLOBALIZATION
Migration
The labour market is surely the least integrated of global markets.
For the USA, despite a strong rise in the 1980s, inward migration in
the 1990s was still only at one-third of the rate seen during 1900–10
as a proportion of the population.29 The proportion of the world’s
population resident in countries where they were not born is estimated to have risen from a little over 2% to a little under 3% during
the last 30 years and is around 10% in both Europe and the USA.
Rising supply of migrants has been met in most developed countries
with a tightening of controls against most unskilled migrants.
In countries where unemployment is now relatively low, inward
migration of both skilled and unskilled workers is an attractive
option for employers worried about keeping down wages. As we
shall see in the final chapter, migration is being used as an argument
for cutting back generous welfare states for fear that they will attract
migrants. It is simultaneously being promoted as a solution to the
‘pensions crisis’ looming because of stagnating or declining populations in many rich countries. Policy on migration will be of
central importance in coming decades and is likely to continue to
be highly conflictual.
Conclusions
This chapter has reviewed the contradictory position of the USA,
which has been the most strongly growing amongst the rich countries, yet maintains its consumption by a huge amount of overseas
borrowing. The extraordinary rise of the Chinese economy has
also been outlined and its growing impact on world trade patterns
was described. The degree of international integration of the rich
economies varies from industry to industry along a continuum,
with extremely competitive electronics production at one end to
hairdressing at the other. Although exports of services, and FDI in
GLOBALIZATION
103
services, have been growing rapidly there is probably still a majority
of the workforce in the rich countries in sectors where international competition plays a relatively small role. Migration is likely
to be an increasingly important influence on employment, work
and pay patterns, which are the focus of the next chapter.
5
Labour’s Retreats
‘I wish it was the sixties.’
(From ‘The Bends’,
Radiohead (1995))
The rise in unemployment after 1973, evident in Figure 2.1, is a
powerful symbol of labour’s weakening position since very low
unemployment was the most fundamental gain that labour secured
during the Golden Age. Rising unemployment undermined labour’s
bargaining power, formally in collective bargaining, and informally
on the shop floor, with fear of the sack becoming much more potent.
The three previous chapters have discussed the succession of pressures to which labour has been subjected—the turn to restrictive
macroeconomic policies, the renewed emphasis on market forces
and profit maximization bringing privatization, deregulation and
the drive for shareholder value and finally the intensifying international competition in important sectors of the economy. Unions
were forced onto the defensive, if not into retreat, and this chapter
reviews the patterns of employment, wages and working conditions
which developed across the OECD countries.
Employment and Structural Change
As is clear from Figure 2.1, Europe presents the gloomiest employment picture with the unemployment rate rising by a factor of nearly
105
LABOUR’S RETREATS
five times between the 1960s and early 1990s, before a significant fall
in the second half of the 1990s. However it was only in the early
1990s that most European countries had much higher unemployment
than the USA. The Eurozone countries, including the unemploymentplagued quartet of France, Germany, Italy and Spain, experienced a
higher peak than the rest of Europe in the early 1990s and a smaller
decline thereafter. It is Eurozone joblessness which still (in 2005)
compares unfavourably with the USA.
It was noted in Chapter 1 that growth during the Golden Age
involved the rapid run-down of agriculture and a rising share of
employment in services. These trends continued after 1973, with
the addition of a rapid fall in the employment share in industry. This
deindustrialization was particularly severe in Europe. Figures 5.1
and 5.2 contrast US experience with that of Europe,1 a comparison
used repeatedly from the mid-1990s in policy debates to argue for
US-style deregulation. The experience of men and women was
rather different. Men in Europe lost more than one-third of their
industrial jobs (measured as compared to the population of working
age) as male jobs in industry converged down to the US level
(Fig. 5.1). Although service jobs for men grew rapidly, this was
not fast enough to make up for all the lost jobs in industry (and the
continuing drain out of agriculture) or to bring service employment
for men up to the US level.
50
Europe
USA
%
40
30
20
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
Fig. 5.1. Men’s Employment Rate in Industry, 1970–2001
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
1995
2000
106
LABOUR’S RETREATS
Women lost many fewer jobs in industry than men and employment
in services for women grew very rapidly, but not as fast as in the USA
until the 1990s (Fig. 5.2).
The net result of these trends was that men’s employment
declined in Europe and women’s failed to rise as fast as in the
USA (Fig. 5.3).
60
Europe
USA
%
50
40
30
20
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Fig. 5.2. Women’s Employment Rate in Services, 1970–2001
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
90
80
%
70
60
50
Europe men
Europe women
40
30
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
Fig. 5.3. Employment Rates, Men and Women, 1970–2001
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
1995
USA men
USA women
2000
LABOUR’S RETREATS
107
The shortfall in jobs was reflected in rising male unemployment,
especially in Europe. However more men became ‘inactive’ in Europe
than became unemployed. Some of this was welcome (staying on
longer in education or voluntary early retirement) but large numbers
of men who would otherwise have worked also dropped out of the
legitimate labour market. In some countries, like the UK and
the Netherlands, many found their way onto sickness benefit. But
the key issue here is that the rise in inactivity was very closely associated with lack of work. Across the UK, for example, there was a
strong positive correlation between numbers on sickness benefits
and the local unemployment rate.2 And the areas with the lowest
activity rates for men were those where deindustrialization, leading
to factory closures and major job loss in local areas, was most severe.
Much inactivity therefore flowed from employment decline. In this
sense the unemployment rate (for men especially) far underestimated
the true extent of joblessness and its increase in the 1980s. Women’s
labour market inactivity rates fell as they obtained jobs in the
expanding services sector. However, in less dynamic regions, inactivity fell less as women did not bother to enter the labour force
and look for work where jobs remained scarce.
The Low-Skilled
The declining position of the low-skilled has been an important
preoccupation in the OECD countries since 1979. Although the
relative supply of low-skilled workers has been declining as educational qualifications have increased, the demand for their work
appears to have declined even faster, leading to either falling pay
and/or lack of work.
It is extremely difficult to compare skill or educational levels
across countries or even to get comparable data over time within a
country. One way to get round this problem is to focus on the least
educated one-quarter, say, of the workforce. Their skill levels will
not be the same across countries or over time, but what happens
to the least educated quarter is a good measure of what is going on
108
LABOUR’S RETREATS
at the bottom end of the labour market.3 In the late 1990s in the typical
OECD country 84% of the most educated quarter of the population
aged 25–64 were working whereas 57% of the least educated quarter
had jobs. The differential in employment rates (proportion of working age population who are working) was 30 percentage points for
women and 19 percentage points for men. Figure 5.4 summarizes the
trends in Europe and the USA over the 1980s and 1990s.
% per year change employment/population
2
Europe
USA
1.5
1
0.5
0
Low-skilled men
Low-skilled women
All low-skilled
All middle-skilled
–0.5
–1
–1.5
Fig. 5.4. Employment Rate Changes by Skill Groups, 1980–2000
Source: Glyn (2001). See Data Appendix.
In Europe the percentage of low-skilled men who had work was
declining by around 1% each year, a very sharp decline. The least qualified women just held on to the existing number of jobs. So, overall, the
proportion of the less qualified in work fell by about 0.5 percentage
points per year—over a 20-year period this represents a 10 percentage
point fall. By contrast, employment rates for the middle group (middle
two-quarters of the distribution) rose. So the employment position of
the least qualified declined in Europe absolutely and by even more
relatively to those better qualified. In the USA, however, the least qualified men in work kept jobs and the least qualified women increased
employment as fast as did the better qualified.
It looks as though the least skilled did much better in the USA
than Europe. In fact the level of the employment rate for low-skilled
men was not that much higher in the USA than in many European
LABOUR’S RETREATS
109
countries since many low-skilled American jobs had disappeared
earlier in the 1970s. At the end of the 1990s the employment rate
for the least qualified quarter of men was 77% in the USA, which
was less than Switzerland and Japan and compares to 69% in West
Germany and over 70% in Netherlands, Austria, Sweden and Norway.
Moreover the US figures for employment rates of low-skilled men
are exaggerated to the tune of several percentage points by the very
large number of predominantly low-skilled men who were in prison
and not counted in the (non-institutional) population. The bigger
contrast is for low-skilled women where the USA provided many
more jobs than the typical European country (though Sweden has the
highest employment rate of all for low-skilled women).4
Why have the less skilled been falling behind in terms of jobs,
especially in Europe? Three important influences are believed to
have been technical progress favouring the employment of skilled
workers, the displacement of low skilled manufacturing by imports
from the low-wage South and the less qualified being ‘bumped down’
off the jobs ladder as weak demand for labour overall allowed
employers to be more choosy and recruit better qualified workers for
what had previously been jobs open to the least qualified.
A good deal of evidence has accumulated that technical advance
has favoured the employment of more qualified workers. Replacement
of the unskilled has taken place within individual industries
(manufacturing and services) across a range of OECD economies and
it has been strongest in industries producing machinery including
computers, electrical machinery and printing and publishing, where
there has been significant technological change. Detailed analysis
of occupational patterns has traced the link between skills and
computerization. Labour has been displaced mainly in tasks which
can be routinized. This includes many unskilled assembly line jobs,
which are repetitive and can easily be replaced by computerized
technology.5
However it is important not to conclude that unskilled work is
about to disappear. There are still large numbers of unskilled workers
which are very hard to replace: cleaning, restaurant work, shelf-filling
rely on ‘hand-eye co-ordination that virtually all humans find easy
but machines find enormously difficult’ (Goos and Manning 2003: 2).
110
LABOUR’S RETREATS
In the UK between 1979 and 1999 the fastest growing job category
was care assistants (nearly 400% increase and very poorly paid) beating software engineers into second place. Two of the largest lowest
paid groups in the UK (shelf-fillers and check-out operators) nearly
doubled their share of employment.
Moreover not all skilled work is insulated from the effects of
technical change. Some skilled craft and record-keeping jobs require
precision and so require skill if done by humans, but they are
repetitive and thus can be replaced by technology. However there
are rising numbers of professional and managerial jobs which
cannot easily be mechanized and there is no question but that on
balance the demand for skilled work has risen rapid relative to jobs
for unskilled workers.
The most debated issue is the impact of trade with the low-wage
economies of the South in hastening the replacement of low-skilled
jobs in the North by work requiring higher educational levels. At first
sight it seems implausible that imports of manufactures from lowwage countries could have played a very important role. After all
they took a bit under 10% of the domestic market for manufacturers
in the USA and Europe in 1999 (see Table 4.4).
These imports of manufactures are usually more or less balanced
by the expansion of manufactured exports, of machines for example,
to Southern producers like China and the countries which supply
them with raw materials. However, as Adrian Wood (1994) has
argued, many more jobs will be at stake from cheap imports than
will be gained from high value exports since the imports are so cheap
because labour is paid so much less than in the North. Thus even
balanced trade between North and South involves a substantial loss
of manufacturing employment. A recent comprehensive study6 supports this, estimating that for every job in high-skill manufactures
created by additional exports to the South there are as many as six
jobs displaced by the same money value of low-tech manufactured
imports from the South. This disparity is just a reflection of the
potential gains from trade. If it took as many workers in the North to
produce the machine tools which paid for the shirts as it would have
taken to produce the shirts at home, then there is no benefit to the
North from the trade.
LABOUR’S RETREATS
111
The qualification ‘potential’ to the gains from trade is important—
the realization of these gains depends on the workers concerned
being re-employed. A study of employment change in US manufacturing over the 1980s and 1990s found that the industries most
subject to import competition, including toys, clothing and electronic
goods, accounted for more than one-third of job losses. Around 40%
of those affected were out of work two years later, and of those with
jobs one-half suffered a wage cut of 15% or more. Over the decade
1992–2002 trade with the South may have accounted for one-quarter
of the loss of manufacturing jobs in the EU and nearly one-half of
the loss in the USA. These job losses can have such disruptive and
damaging effects because manufacturing employment tends to be
geographically concentrated. Where the plants comprise a significant
part of local labour markets it is particularly difficult to reabsorb
such displaced workers.7
This loss of manufacturing jobs through trade is substantial, but it
should be remembered that manufacturing accounts for one-quarter
or less of total employment. This has left the ‘non-traded sector’
(including retailing and many personal services) as the main source
of demand for unskilled labour. Whilst some of these services are
financed by the state (hospitals have to be cleaned and food cooked
in them), many are dependent on ‘physical proximity to richer highskill workers as it is the expenditure of these individuals that is
the main source of labour demand for low-skill workers’ (Manning
2004: 4). Spending in shops and restaurants and on care for the
elderly by managers, computer programmers and financial advisers
creates jobs for the unskilled, but not fast enough to absorb the loss
of other unskilled jobs in traded goods and in repetitive tasks in other
sectors.
The above explanations for declining demand for the less qualified
depend either on the decline of industries where the less qualified
are particularly concentrated (e.g. textiles) or on falling numbers of
jobs for the unqualified within individual industries (replacement of
assembly line workers by robots). It is possible, however, that part
of the problem is that the less qualified are being increasingly
bumped out of jobs that they could adequately carry out by an excess
supply of better qualified workers. Employers may prefer those
112
LABOUR’S RETREATS
with qualifications, believing them to be more adaptable, diligent or
reliable. If demand for labour was higher then workers would tend on
average to shift up the jobs ladder and more of the least qualified
would get back onto the lower rungs.
A detailed study of US occupations and qualifications has claimed
that such bumping down has been important:
Although the number of jobs requiring more education has risen considerably faster than the number with lower educational requirements, the number
of educated workers has risen even faster. Moreover, women have filled an
increasing proportion number of these jobs. These two circumstances have
initiated a chain reaction of job displacements. More specifically, universityeducated women have replaced men with a similar education, but with lower
cognitive abilities than others with the same education. Those displaced
have taken jobs previously held by workers with less education who, in turn,
have displaced those with even lower cognitive skills. Many of the least
educated workers have been knocked completely out of the labour force.
(Pryor and Schaffer 1999: 217)
Over the 1990s in the UK, increasing numbers of workers, especially
those in less skilled jobs, have reported that the educational qualification required for their job is not necessary to do it.8
Where the overall demand for labour does grow strongly, then those
at the bottom of the skill distribution tend to do relatively well as
employers cannot afford to be so choosy. Thus in the periods of
strong employment growth in the Netherlands and USA during the
1990s employment of the least qualified grew faster than employment of those in the middle. However bumping down is certainly
not the whole story and may rather be exacerbating the long-run
shift away from unskilled work connected with new technology and
international trade.
A final influence on employment prospects for the least qualified
has been the power of unions. In most OECD countries substantial
numbers of less educated industrial workers had been well organized
in trades unions and had achieved relatively decent wages. The
weakening of these unions in countries like the UK, as discussed
later in the chapter, left them less able to protect the jobs of their
members in the face of rationalization drives by employers facing
recession or heightened international competition. Jobs stacking
LABOUR’S RETREATS
113
supermarket shelves do not necessarily provide enough work for
redundant industrial workers.
Hours, Work Intensity, Employment
Protection, Unemployment Benefits
It was noted in Chapter 1 that average hours of work declined up to
the 1970s and this reflected longer holidays and a shorter working
week. The trend continued with average hours worked for employees
in 12 OECD countries falling from around 1,750 in 1979 to 1,625 in
2003. The picture is complicated by the growth of part-time work,
which reduced average working hours, particularly in Netherlands.
But French and German workers are now also working under 1,400
hours a year after considerable battles over working time. In France
the cut in working time from a 39 to 35 hour week (combined with
wage restraint and cuts in social security contributions) is estimated
to have increased employment by some 300,000 or 2%.9 However
the shorter working week has been under severe pressure in
Germany. The Economist (29 July 2004) reported that Siemens had
‘persuaded its workers, and their union IG Metall, to accept a week
of up to 40 hours, with no extra pay, to avoid the relocation of
Siemens’ mobile phone production to Hungary. “Blackmail” said a
union spokesman’.
Sweden was unusual amongst European economies in not recording
falls in working time after 1979 but hours there were already short.
The major contrast was between most of Europe where working
hours continued to fall steadily and the USA where the decline in
working hours virtually stopped. The European trend was often
presented by US writers as anomalous, with high taxation discouraging work effort frequently taking most of the blame. In fact the stability of US hours represented the real break with long-established
trends. Between 1870 and 1979 average hours worked fell by around
0.5% per year in both Continental Europe and the USA and this was in
the context of hourly productivity rising at about 1.5–2.5% per year.
114
LABOUR’S RETREATS
Thus about one-quarter of the rise in living standards was taken
in the form of reduced working hours.10 After 1979 trades unions
continued to press for hours reductions in Europe with fear of unemployment bringing additional impetus to the campaign. Hours
of work continued to fall at roughly the long-term average rate in
Europe but flattened out in the USA as average living standards
stagnated.
How hard people work has only recently been at all systematically
measured. A very careful and comprehensive survey of the evidence
(mainly derived from workers’ and managers’ answers to questionnaires) summarized the conclusions as follows:
work in Britain was being intensified, especially in manufacturing, in the
1980s . . . work intensification continued in Britain through the first part
of the 1990s . . . more workers were operating at high speeds and to tight
deadlines. By the end of the decade, however, work intensification had
apparently reached the point of satiation: there were no further increases
in work effort over the 1997 to 2001 period. . . . Work intensification was
also experienced by workers in almost all European Union countries during
the 1990s, though to a varying extent and with different timing. . . .
For France, the work intensification that took place in the 1990s was a
continuation of change that was already taking place in the 1980s . . . .
Almost certainly intensification also took place in Australia and in the
United States . . . (Green 2006: 64–5)
Work intensity apparently rose in Europe at a slower pace in the
second half of the 1990s, when unemployment was generally falling.
The rather widespread rise in employment protection up to the
late 1970s was noted in Chapter 1 as a reflection of labour’s stronger
bargaining position. The most detailed data for the 1980s show
reductions in the strength of employment protection in around
half the countries analysed. In most countries this involved relaxation of conditions on temporary (fixed-term) working or on the
related activities of temporary work agencies. The OECD has
examined employment protection since the late 1980s in great
detail. They found marked declines in employment protection in
eight countries including Germany, Italy, Spain, The Netherlands
and Sweden. In every case except Spain the relaxation referred to
temporary and not to regular employment. France was the most
115
LABOUR’S RETREATS
notable high-unemployment/tight-regulation absentee from this
list; temporary employment had been deregulated there to some
extent in the 1980s but this was reversed in the 1990s. In the
‘liberal’, more free market, economies (North America, the UK and
Ireland, Australasia), there was little regulation to begin with and
little change.11
Fear of losing one’s job—job insecurity—is widely regarded as having
risen in the rich countries. A comprehensive analysis of survey evidence for the UK, Germany and the USA concluded that feelings of
insecurity do fluctuate with unemployment. Not surprisingly, this
would suggest greater insecurity recently than during the 1960s
and 1970s. Insecurity, which has long been a feature of blue-collar
occupations, became more prevalent amongst white-collar workers
in the US in the 1990s and for finance workers in the UK. In the UK
in 2001 workers in foreign-owned enterprises, and in particular
workers subject to competition from low-wage country exports, felt
more than average levels of insecurity.12
For those workers who do lose their jobs the level of unemployment benefits is crucial for their living standards. Figure 5.5 shows a
rise in the replacement ratio—benefits divided by average earnings—
in the 1960s and 1970s which was particularly rapid in Europe.
By 1980 rates easily exceeded those typical of liberal economies.
Replacement rates were on average held steady in Europe after 1980,
0.6
Liberal economies
Europe
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
Fig. 5.5. Unemployment Benefits: Ratio to Earnings, 1960–1999
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
2000
116
LABOUR’S RETREATS
whilst in the liberal economies they fell quite markedly; Mrs Thatcher’s
indexation of benefits to inflation brought a steady decline in the UK
ratio which was not halted by the Blair government. A number of
countries have tightened eligibility criteria for unemployment
benefit; there was a tighter definition of obligation to accept suitable
work in Denmark and the UK, combined in the Netherlands with an
increase in the number of benefit sanctions.
Wages
It was already noted in Chapter 1 that real wages have grown very
slowly in OECD countries since 1979, an extraordinary turn-round
from the 3–5% growth rates of the 1960s (see Fig. 1.2). In the USA the
median wage, that is a wage half-way up the pay distribution, was
$13.62 in 2003; in 1979 it was $12.36 reckoned at 2003 prices.13
Indeed average wages actually declined until 1995, after which the
‘new economy’ boom of the late 1990s pulled them up a little, leaving
an average growth rate of less than half of a per cent a year. In Europe
and Japan average wages have done only a little better, having grown
around 1% per year.
What explains the stagnation of real wages? The most important
influence is the rather slow rate of productivity growth, which is
further discussed in the next chapter. But real wages do not automatically grow as fast as labour productivity. The general increase in
the share of profits discussed in Chapter 1 pulls real wage growth
behind productivity growth and this has been a significant influence
in many countries. Secondly, these earnings measures do not include
employers’ contributions to social security or to pension and healthcare schemes, which have been tending to rise. Thirdly consumer
prices, which determine the real purchasing power of wages, often grow
faster than the prices of domestic output as a whole, for example if
rents rise especially rapidly.
The fanning out of the pay distribution has been discussed more
than the slow growth in average wages. OECD collates changes in
the pay inequality for a number of countries for the 1980s and 1990s.
LABOUR’S RETREATS
117
Figure 5.6 compares pay at the top end with the middle (a worker 10%
from the top compared to a worker half-way down the distribution)
and compares the middle to the bottom end (a worker 10% from
the bottom). The evolution of pay differentials is shown for two
groups of countries—three liberal economy countries with deregulated labour markets at least by the end of the period (the USA, the
UK, Australia) and five countries (Finland, France, Germany, The
Netherlands and Sweden) representing continental Europe.
2.0
Liberal top/middle
Europe top/middle
Liberal middle/bottom
Europe middle/bottom
1.8
1.6
1.4
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 5.6. Wage Differentials, 1980–2000
OECD. See Data Appendix.
Wage differentials, in both halves of the distribution, are considerably higher in the UK/US group than in Europe. By 1998 the gap
between the top and the middle was about one-quarter higher in the
US/UK group than in Europe and the gap between middle and bottom was more than half as big again. Differentials between the top
and middle have grown generally but faster in the liberal group. Thus
in the USA real wages at the top grew by 27.2% between 1979 and
2003 as compared to 10.2% in the middle. The most surprising result
is that differentials between the middle and bottom have not grown
at all in Europe, implying that real wages grew at the bottom at a
similar rate to the average. In the liberal economies, differentials in
the bottom half have expanded, but considerably slower than in the
top half. Even so their relative decline means that US real wages at
the bottom (first decile) did not grow at all between 1979 and 2003.
118
LABOUR’S RETREATS
Since women make up a disproportionate share of the low paid,
one factor limiting the rise in pay inequality overall has been that
women’s pay has tended to grow relative to men’s. In the 1990s
women were catching up at a moderate rate; on average across OECD
countries the radio of womens to men’s pay rose from 74% to 80%
by the end of the decade. In many countries, especially Northern
European ones with comparatively high pay for women, catch-up
stopped completely in the second half of the 1990s. Part of the
pay gap reflects the lower educational qualifications of women on
average. However a study which matched pay differentials across
countries against attitudes suggested that discriminatory attitudes,
through declining, ‘continue to play an important role hindering
women’s quest for equality in the labour market’ (Fortin 2005: 21).
Although measuring the ‘top’ by somebody 10% down the distribution, as in Figure 5.6, shows a sizeable relative gain for that group,
especially in the USA/UK, it misses the more startling rises in some
countries for those really at the top. The extraordinary increase in
the compensation of top US executives, discussed in Chapter 3, is the
extreme case of this. However the phenomenon extends beyond this
tiny group. Piketty and Saez (2003) show the top 1% of wage-earner
households nearly doubling their share of total wage earnings in
the USA between 1979 and 1998 (from 6.2% to 10.9%) whilst the
top 0.1% of wage earners practically tripled their share to 4.1%
(where they were earning 41 times the average!). Virtually all of the
increase in the share of the top 10% occurred amongst the top 5%,
and about two-thirds of it within the top 1%. Comparable data seem
only to be available for France, but these show no trend at all in the
share of the top 1% in total wage earnings, which stayed at the same
6–7% share found in the USA at the beginning of the 1980s.14
One important influence on the pay distribution, and also a telling
indicator of attitudes, is a statutory minimum wage. There is a great
variation across the OECD over minimum wage policy.15 In a number of European countries without a statutory minimum wage
(Sweden, Germany) minimum rates are set by collective bargaining.
These tend to be in the range of 50–60% of average earnings, similar
to European statutory minima in countries which have them. With
the recent introduction of a minimum wage in the UK and Ireland all
119
LABOUR’S RETREATS
the liberal economies now have legal minimum wages. They tend to
have somewhat lower statutory minimum wages than in mainland
Europe; minimum wages in both groups have tended to drift down
compared to average earnings. As well as showing the average minimum wage for nine countries with a long run of data, Figure 5.7 takes
two of the most contrasting cases. France has had a high level of
minimum wages and has kept them high whilst in the USA there
has been a downward slide in what was a low rate to begin with.
0.7
France
USA
OECD
1965
1970
1975
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
1960
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Fig. 5.7. Minimum Wages—Ratio to Average Pay, 1964–2000
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
Less Pay or Fewer Jobs—The Nasty Trade-off
In the 1990s, as the share of profits rose in many countries (Fig. 1.3)
the emphasis in policy discussion shifted away from urging overall
wage restraint to a focus on greater wage flexibility for the less
skilled to overcome the decline in demand for their labour discussed
above. The ‘Unified View’, that rising unemployment in ‘Europe and
growing wage dispersion in the USA were two sides of the same
trade-off, offered a simple explanation of unemployment patterns
and one with obvious policy implications.16 In the face of technical
progress and structural change the less skilled had to accept lower
120
LABOUR’S RETREATS
relative pay if they were to keep in work (as in the USA); the alternative was unemployment.
However the evidence for the importance of this trade-off in
explaining European unemployment is quite weak. Bertola et al.
(2001) do report a negative correlation between unemployment and
wage dispersion patterns and Iversen (2001, fig. 2) shows a positive
relation for the growth of employment in the private services and the
level of wage inequality. More direct and thus convincing evidence
focuses specifically on less qualified workers. Nickell and Bell (1995:
46) examined decreasing demand for unskilled labour in the 1970s
and 1980s and found no evidence that ‘unemployment effects are
any more severe in countries where wage effects [increases in pay
dispersion] are small’. Howell and Huebler (2005, figs. 2.11, 2.12)
found no relation between earnings inequality and the level of
employment of the less qualified across OECD countries or between
changes in these measures. Card et al. (1999: 3) conclude from a very
detailed study of the USA, France and Canada that ‘it is very difficult
to maintain the hypothesis that the “wage inflexibility” in Canada
and France translated into greater employment losses for less-skilled
workers in these countries’.
There can be many partial explanations for the lack of a strong
trade-off relationship. One is that the lower wages for skilled labour
may have rather little effect on the extent to which employers switch
towards employing less skilled people and to which industries dependent on them expand in response to lower costs. Countries also differ
widely in just how ‘less skilled’ the bottom of the education distribution is—in Northern Europe there is a much smaller tail of
workers with extremely low numeracy and literacy than in the
liberal economies. Whatever the full explanation, the conclusion
should be that the impact of declining relative wages at the bottom
on generating jobs is quite unclear whilst the adverse effects on those
already in unskilled work is obvious.
The way in which reducing benefits, allowing the minimum wage
to erode and cutting employment protection, is supposed to generate
jobs is by forcing down wages in the part of the labour market where
these measures of social protection make a real difference—that is
the bottom. Thus the weakness of the evidence for the importance of
121
LABOUR’S RETREATS
the low wage/unskilled jobs trade-off should have given the advocates
of labour market deregulation cause to tread warily. Far from daunted,
however, and armed with the presumption that because economic
theory identifies the trade-off, then it must be important, OECD,
IMF and the EU have been unreservedly pushing for deregulation
or labour market reform as noted in Chapter 2. However if the
OECD’s own compilation of reforms is used to construct an index of
‘reform intensity’ across countries, there is no evidence that the
countries which carried out more reforms secured significant falls
in unemployment.17
Union Decline
Until the end of the 1970s a rising proportion of employees were
joining trade unions (and more and more workers were employees
rather than self-employed). Since 1979 the proportion of unionized
employees has fallen in many countries. Figure 5.8 shows strikingly
similar patterns of decline in the three most important advanced
economies, although from rather different starting points.18 The
halving of union membership in the USA is not untypical of the
six liberal economies. In Australia and New Zealand membership
60
50
%
40
30
20
10
0
1960
1970
Liberal economies
1980
Europe
1990
Germany
Japan
2000
USA
Fig. 5.8. Trade Union Membership as a Percentage of Employees, 1960–2001
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
122
LABOUR’S RETREATS
also declined by more than a half. In the UK, often derided as
exhibiting a particular destructive form of union organization and
militancy, union membership fell by 40%. The downward trend
has been less drastic in Europe, but still severe, with the unions
typically losing more than one-fifth of their membership rate. The
trend in Germany is particularly striking—a cut in union membership of one-third of employees even if we discount the spike associated with unification due to initially higher union membership
in East Germany. In some of the smaller North European countries
unions have an important role in unemployment insurance and
in several of these membership rates grew.19 In Italy and France
(the latter with very low membership to begin with) membership
fell by one-third and a half respectively. In a number of countries
unionization is very much higher in the public sector than in
the private sector (more than double in the UK and Germany for
example).
In one respect at least, the data for membership may exaggerate the
decline of union influence. Whilst the average union membership
in the OECD fell from 47% to 36%, the average proportion of
employees covered by collective agreements negotiated by unions
declined from 67% to 64%. There were drastic declines in coverage
in the UK (from around 70% to around 30%), in New Zealand (60%
to 25%) and the US (26% to 14%), but in many European countries
there was an increase in coverage (France from 80% to the 90%, the
Netherlands from 70% to 80%) and there were even increases in
some countries (like Australia) where membership fell heavily.
In about half the countries the extension of agreements to other
firms is by some form of legal or administrative extension; in the
other half it is a voluntary extension by employers. How long unions
can sustain very high coverage of collective agreements with falling
membership seems an open question.
The way in which wage bargaining takes place varies enormously
across OECD countries. In the UK wage bargaining is predominantly
at the company or plant level, it is fragmented with little or no
co-ordination by the TUC or CBI, collective agreements are not
legally enforceable and there is no tradition of ‘peace obligations’
whilst the agreement is in force. In Finland bargaining is centred at
LABOUR’S RETREATS
123
the national level between highly coordinated employers and unions
and collective agreements are legally enforceable and with automatic
peace obligations. The general trend has clearly been towards decentralization of bargaining. In the early 1970s, out of 19 countries, six
countries had rather decentralized bargaining (predominantly or
importantly at the company level) whereas in seven countries
central-level agreements were of overriding or periodic importance
(with bargaining otherwise at the industry level). By the late 1990s
ten of the 19 countries were in the decentralized groups and three
in the centralized ones. Ireland stands out as the only country which
made a major move towards greater centralization of bargaining
when national wage agreements were reinstated in the late 1980s.
However a move towards decentralizing bargaining does not necessarily undermine coordination and in a number of countries including
Denmark and Italy, there was more coordination in the bargaining
process in the 1990s. In the later 1990s a majority of countries
were ranked by OECD as having a high degree of coordination in the
bargaining process, with only the UK, USA, Australia and France
having distinctly low levels.20
Although the general level of strikes has been at a low level
(see Fig. 1.1) there have been an average of two general political
strikes in Europe per year since the late 1980s, mainly over such
issues as public spending cuts or reforms to the pensions, employment protection or unemployment benefit systems.21 Obviously
each country has its own complex history of union influence over
the past 25 years and space precludes attempting a survey here. What
follows is therefore a brief account of developments in the UK
where, in addition to all the pressures from mass unemployment and
deindustrialization, the unions were under sustained legislative
attack in the 1980s from the Conservative government.
Union membership declined in the UK from 51.6% of employees
in 1979 to 30.4% in 2002, with the private sector unionization rate
being below 20% by 1999. Although the manual unions have been
heavily hit by deindustrialization, this has been offset by rapid
expanzion of heavily unionized public services like heath and in
the UK at least ‘changes in industrial structure are not a principal
explanation for the decline in unionism’ (Pencavel 2004: 199). Added
124
LABOUR’S RETREATS
to the members, some 14% of employees are ‘free-riders’—covered
by collective agreements but not union members—whilst 7% are
union members not covered by a collective agreement (Metcalf
2004: 19). In the private sector the 1990s saw the total abandonment
of collective bargaining in one out of every three workplaces that had
practised collective bargaining in 1990, indicating that ‘it was the
exercise of managerial power which led to the removal of bargaining’
(Charlwood 2003: 13). Unions have also failed to gain recognition in
newly formed workplaces.
This anti-union attitude of increasing numbers of employers
was encouraged by legislative changes under Conservative
governments. Unions’ legal immunities became more qualified,
picketing became more circumscribed, notice had to be given
before strikes, strike ballots became essential to protect the
unions from financial liability. Employers could no longer refuse
to hire or dismiss a worker because of their non-membership of a
union, leading to the virtual extinction of the closed shop, which
had previously covered a quarter of workplaces and nearly 90% in
nationalized industries. In 2000 the Labour government changed
the law which now gave the unions the right to a ballot on representation which required a majority of those voting and 40% of
the workforce to vote yes.
An important milestone in the weakening of unions was the
defeat of the epic miners’ strike of 1984–5 over the issue of colliery
closures. The state used police on an unprecedented scale to combat
miners’ pickets and to allow the Nottingham coalfields to continue
working and power stations to receive coal. The secret services
were heavily involved in undermining the strike (see Milne 1994).
The wider union movement itself was bitterly divided over the
NUM’s failure to call a nationwide ballot on the strike. Its defeat
after a year spelt the virtual elimination of the industry (described
in Chapter 4) and demoralization amongst union activists (‘if the
miners can’t win . . .).
Unions in the UK have struggled to maintain any premium in the
wages they negotiate as compared to those received by comparable
non-union workers. Two recent studies conclude ‘there are real
questions as to whether there is a significant union wage premium
LABOUR’S RETREATS
125
for workers at the beginning of the 21st century’ (Blanchflower and
Bryson 2003: 18) and ‘For men it used to pay to be in a union [in the
early 1990s] and it used to pay to join a union, but by the end of
the 1990s it does not. For women the answer is: it does still pay to be
in a union, but not by as much as it used to, and it does not pay to
newly join’ (Machin quoted by Metcalf 2004: 7).
Unions were widely blamed in the 1970s for the low level of labour
productivity in UK manufacturing, and there is some evidence that
in 1980 productivity levels were lower in unionized plants.
Productivity growth in the 1980s was faster in these same plants,
consistent with the notion that the pressure of the recession and
weakening unions was greatest where they previously had greatest
effect. A study of the most recent data for the end of the 1990s
concluded that there was only any productivity shortfall in the
very small number of plants where bargaining was still fragmented,
with many unions bargaining separately (suggesting demarcation
between different trades may have been inhibiting productivity).22
It will be recalled that work has intensified considerably in the UK
since 1979, which again is quite consistent with the weakening of
union influence over speed of production lines and so forth. It is
a salutary reminder that productivity growth frequently involves
harder work for those involved.
The example of the decline of unionism in the UK shows how
the norm for industrial relations can be undermined (in this
case by legislation and the miners’ strike). Whereas previously
employers in new workplaces, in industry at least, were expected
to bargain collectively, this changed decisively in the 1980s, bringing a steady decline in union membership in the private sector.
The remaining union members were left with less bargaining
power, less able to use the strike weapon and with declining
political influence even when the Labour government was finally
elected in 1997.
It might be assumed that these developments in the UK represent
the neo-liberal offensive against unions in unvarnished form, and
that the only factor holding back employers elsewhere from following suit is some combination of political circumstances and union
strength. This is probably an oversimplification, however. In a
126
LABOUR’S RETREATS
number of European economies coordination between employers
permits a training system where large employers invest heavily in
the skills of their workforce and take full advantage of the workers’
expertise in the firm’s specific system of production. This gives
such skilled workers a particularly strong objective interest in the
competitive success of their firm, especially if their skills would be
of less value to other employers. This can lead to ‘enterprise egoism’
in the workforce, as it is termed in Germany, which has long been a
feature of Japanese industrial relations in the big exporting firms.
The need to respond to international competition has apparently
seen a trend towards greater cooperation between labour and management within this type of firm in countries such as Germany and
Sweden. In this situation unions or works councils could continue to
play a more important role at the firm level than more authoritarian
employers in more free market economies would ever contemplate.
However such a development can in turn heighten the problem of
maintaining union solidarity between different groups of workers,
such as the employees of large firms and those in small firms less
involved in international trade or between industrial and public
sector workers.23
A Balance Sheet
The period since 1979 provides an extraordinary contrast with the
gains made by labour over the previous 30 years which covered jobs,
pay, working conditions and worker representation. In the Golden
Age unemployment fell to very low levels and workers moved out of
agriculture into better paid jobs in industry and services. Pay levels
rose steadily, differentials were often narrowed, hours of work fell
and legal protection for workers was extended. Unions became
stronger and exerted this strength in industrial action. Since 1979
labour markets have slackened and the unskilled men who lost jobs
in industry have shifted into poorly paid service jobs, unemployment or even out of the labour force. For women job opportunities
LABOUR’S RETREATS
127
have improved but many of these jobs are still low paid. Average
pay levels rose in real terms slowly if at all. Those at the top of the
pay distribution tended to gain substantially relative to the middle.
Work intensity typically increased. Employment protection legislation, particularly affecting temporary workers, was scaled back.
Outside Scandinavia the proportion of employees in unions fell
substantially.
Superimposed on this generally bleak picture, labour’s position
tended to be more eroded in the more free market economies like
the USA and UK than in European economies where social protection was already stronger. Thus unemployment benefits fell
somewhat in the liberal economies but hardly in most European
countries. Those at the bottom of the pay distribution lost out in
the liberal economies but not generally in Europe where minimum
wages tended to decline less in relation to average wages. The extraordinary gains at the very top of the income distribution, such a
striking feature of the USA and UK, were not repeated in those
European countries for which data are available. Coverage of union
agreements generally held up even in those European countries
where union membership fell, whilst coverage fell rapidly in most
of the liberal economies, and the impact of unions on pay and conditions was measurably lessened there. However even in countries
like Germany and Sweden, traditionally seen as bastions of union
power, international competition may be making union solidarity
more difficult to sustain.
It seems impossible to depict all of this as signalling anything
other than a major retreat for labour. As noted in Chapter 1 demands
to extend control over the operation of firms were abandoned and
replaced by the defensive stance of holding the line over basic terms
and conditions of work. Whilst the retreat was headlong in some
liberal economies like New Zealand and the UK, in some Scandinavian
countries it appears more like a tactical withdrawal. The latter
countries are small, however, and with a strong social democratic
tradition. How far their experience could be generalized and
extended is far from clear. We return to these difficult issues again in
Chapter 7 which looks more broadly at equality and welfare across
128
LABOUR’S RETREATS
the OECD. First however we need to examine how the rich countries
have fared, and are likely to fare, in terms of growth and stability.
These macroeconomic conditions constitute the background against
which struggles over labour issues, income distribution and the
welfare state take place.
6
Growth and Stability
Even if the crises that are looming up are overcome and a new
run of prosperity lies ahead, deeper problems will still remain.
Modern capitalism has no purpose except to keep the show
going.
(Joan Robinson, Professor of Economics, Cambridge
University, writing in 1971 (Robinson 1971: 143))
The previous chapters reviewed first the challenges faced by
capitalism in developed economies in the 1960s and 1970s and then
the responses. Chapter 2 recounted the return of macroeconomic
policy to financial orthodoxy, with control of inflation taking over
from high employment as the primary objective. It also described the
retreat of governments from intervention in industry through privatization and deregulation of product markets. Chapter 3 analysed the
increasing role of the financial sector and the reassertion of profit
maximization as the overriding objective of corporate management.
Chapter 4 covered the increasing international economic integration and enhanced competition in the traded goods sectors. Chapter
5 analysed the weakened position of labour, reflecting its reduced
organizational and political strength in the face of the heightened
competitive pressures.
The story is not one of universal triumph for free market orthodoxy. For example, earlier chapters have recounted the difficulties in
achieving sustained fiscal consolidation, the scandals over corporate
governance especially in the USA, the erratic behaviour of exchange
rates and stubbornly high coverage of collective bargaining even in
130
GROWTH AND STABILITY
some countries where union membership was declining. Even so,
the rich countries have followed the orthodox prescriptions with
more vigour than could possibly have been anticipated by neo-liberals
in the 1970s. How should their economies have responded and have
such expectations been borne out?
A supporter of this fundamental shift to the right in economic
policy-making would have hoped that
(a) the strengthening of the position of employers and the weakening of organized labour would have brought rationalization of
existing activities and a restoration of profitability;
(b) the response to intensification of product market competition
domestically and internationally, combined with heightened
surveillance by capital markets, would have been increased
investment in new products and processes.
In short there should have been renewed dynamism in the economies
of the advanced countries, bringing faster growth. Realistic assessments would have conceded that a likely by-product would be
greater instability as financial liberalization brought with it busts as
well as booms, with governments less ready to intervene to shore up
demand. More intense competition in product markets would also
bring greater instability in the market shares of established large
producers. All this instability would be seen as an aspect of ‘creative
destruction’ in Schumpeter’s famous phrase, the destructive but
unavoidable side of dynamic capitalism. The task of this chapter is
to assess how far the unleashing of market forces over the past
quarter century conforms to these patterns.
Dynamism in the Rich Countries?
The growth of output per head of the population is a simple indicator of the dynamism of the economy. The slowdown in growth
during the turbulent 1970s comes as no surprise given the oil
shocks, profit squeeze and vacillating macroeconomic policies
(Fig. 6.1). The fact that there was no general improvement in growth
131
GROWTH AND STABILITY
in the 1980s could be explained away by the fact that the deflationary policies, giving priority to inflation, were being pursued quite
fiercely and that the policies of privatization and deregulation,
initiated under Reagan and Thatcher, were only picking up steam.
But the real puzzle is the 15 years since 1990. Why has the
combination of macroeconomic stabilization, involving the return
to low inflation and the freeing up of market forces, failed to bring
an increase in the growth rate?
8
% per year
6
1960 – 73
1973 – 9
1979 – 90
1990 – 2004
4
2
0
OECD
USA
Europe
Japan
Fig. 6.1. Growth of Output per Head of the Population, 1960–2004
Source: Groningen Growth and Development Centre. See Data Appendix.
Before turning to developments in the different parts of the OECD,
one looming global issue should be brought into play, namely environmental constraints. As noted in Chapter 1 these have long been
forecast as threatening to tighten and drag down growth. Has this
begun? In an authoritative estimate Nordhaus (1992) concluded that
resource depletion and pollution reduction had shaved some 0.25%
per year off productivity growth. If environmental constraints had
been biting harder in the 1990s as minerals and energy became
scarcer, this should be reflected in their prices. Moreover traders
have a strong interest in forecasting scarcities and these become
priced into current market values. Strong rises in oil and some other
commodity prices did not really emerge until 2004 when the impact
of prolonged Chinese industrial growth, absorbing increasing volumes
of energy and materials, became widely noticed. These price rises
132
GROWTH AND STABILITY
could portend persistent scarcities, rather than temporary supply
problems. However it is unlikely that environmental pressures have
played a major part in holding back a growth rebound over the past
decade or two.
The USA and the New Economy
Of the growth patterns in Figure 6.1 that of the USA is perhaps the
most surprising. The 1990s brought the new economy boom and a
productivity rebound which apparently re-established the US
economy as top of the league. Yet the growth of per capita GDP in the
USA taking the whole period since 1990 is not outstanding. It was
only from the mid-1990s that US expansion became at all exceptional. Before examining productivity, a simple decomposition of
US growth from 1992 to 2000, as compared to two earlier periods
with sustained expansion (Fig. 6.2), is quite revealing about the
character of that expansion.
Although the growth of consumption was not exceptional it
contributed a higher proportion of overall growth in the 1990s
(70% as compared to 60% in the 1960s expansion). As noted in
4
1961 – 9
1982 – 90
1991 – 2000
% per year
3
2
1
0
Consumption
–1
Private investment
Government
Net exports
Fig. 6.2. Contributions to US GDP Growth: Three Long Expansions
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Data Appendix.
GROWTH AND STABILITY
133
Chapter 4 the US balance of payments deteriorated drastically,
reflected in the figure in declining net exports, and this represented
a substantial drag on US growth (but a stimulus to the rest of the
world). Private investment (and specifically business investment)
made a bigger contribution to growth in the 1990s. This was
despite fears that pressures from financial markets were forcing
companies to disgorge more and more of their cash flow to shareholders as dividends or buy-backs of shares, thus starving them of
investment funds.1
Government spending on goods and services grew unusually
slowly. Military spending declined as a share of GDP and civil spending grew relatively slowly. Given that the budget balance was also
moving into underlying surplus at the rate of more than half a per
cent of GDP per year, government spending and taxation overall was
contributing nothing to the expansion. Arguably this was the first
prolonged expansion in the USA since the 1920s that did not include
a major stimulus from public budgets, usually involving greater
military spending.2 This expansion was overwhelmingly generated
within the private sector, and as we noted in earlier chapters, it came
to a sticky end.
The much-heralded productivity growth in the late 1990s (2.5% per
year growth in hourly productivity in the non-farm business sector)
represented a decent improvement over the past 25 years’ average of
1.7% per year. However the really spectacular productivity growth
occurred after the bust in 2000. The average growth rate of hourly
labour productivity in the non-farm business sector was 3.8% per
year for 2000–4. So the usual productivity slowdown in a recession
never happened in the early 2000s and instead there occurred the
fastest four-year growth rate since 1951.
Since so much hangs on it, the acceleration of US productivity has
been closely examined, though as yet most of the analysis focuses
on 1995–2000. Despite spectacular productivity growth in computer production, the glamorous new economy sectors as a whole
(computers, machinery, telephone and telegraph and software) only
accounted directly for around one-fifth of the productivity acceleration in the second half of the 1990s. A rise in productivity growth in
mundane wholesale and retail trade was about twice as important.
134
GROWTH AND STABILITY
Purchases of new economy goods (computers, software) must also
have boosted productivity in these ‘old economy’ sectors. One
widely quoted study estimates that the accumulation of ICT capital
was responsible for nearly half the acceleration. Such estimates are
based on specific assumptions. The impact of ICT investment could
really be less than this, since much of it was underused especially
after the boom collapsed, as noted in Chapter 3; alternatively it
could be greater, if its impact on the technological level and thus
productivity was greater than its weight in the capital stock would
suggest.3
6
5
%
4
3
2
1
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 6.3. US Capital Stock Growth: Private Business, 1950–2003
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Data Appendix.
As noted above private investment increased very rapidly and thus
contributed substantially to the demand increase during the 1990s.
Although this meant a very sharp increase in the growth rate of the
capital stock, as Figure 6.3 demonstrates, it did not drive the growth
rate of the capital stock to unprecedented heights. This is because
capital stock growth started from an exceptionally low point in the
early 1990s. The most positive conclusion from Figure 6.3 would be
that the investment boom of the later 1990s halted the seemingly
inexorable downward trend in the growth rate of the capital stock
which had begun in the late 1960s. Moreover when the boom came
to an end in 2000 capital stock growth plummeted more steeply than
ever before.
GROWTH AND STABILITY
135
Apart from a delayed effect of the new investment in the late 1990s
coming on stream, it does not seem that investment and new technology can account for the continuing rapid productivity rise since
2000. A plausible explanation lies in the character of the earlier
boom. As we saw in Chapter 3, the structure of corporate ownership
and executive compensation led to widespread exaggeration of company profits (current and prospective) in order to bolster share prices.
While actual company profits (measured in the national accounts)
were stagnating between 1997 and 2000, reported profits rose by
70%, and then fell by more than half up to the beginning of 2001 as
companies made provision against earlier exaggerations and other
write-offs. This brought unprecedented pressure to try to limit the
reported profit slide by cutting costs as aggressively as possible. After
succumbing to the ‘temptation to engage in accounting tricks during
1998–2000 to maintain the momentum of earnings growth’, there
followed ‘sheer desperation to cut costs in response to the post-2000
collapse’ (Gordon 2003: 249). The result was a slashing of employment, which continued as the mild recession turned in 2002–3 into
quite a rapid recovery. Three million jobs went in manufacturing
between 2000 and 2003 (as compared to 1 million in the recessions of
the early 1980s and early 1990s) and proportionately as many in the
much smaller information sector. ‘Genuine’ corporate profits (as
measured in the National Accounts) dipped sharply in 2000 and 2001
both in manufacturing (with huge losses by the computer industry)
and the information sector and this compounded the pressure on
companies to rationalize.
However productivity continued to rise very fast in US retail,
wholesale and finance, which had not been so severely affected by
the recession. A comparison of US and European productivity
growth found that in the late 1990s all the difference was accounted
for by these sectors—the very ones which explained most of the US
acceleration after 1995. A study of US retailing found that, rather
than emerging from upgrading existing stores, productivity growth
came entirely from new shops, like Walmart, entering with very
high productivity and driving out less efficient competitors. A
McKinsey study of US retailing also argued that new technology was
not the whole story. Rapid growth in retail productivity came about
136
GROWTH AND STABILITY
through organizational improvements, the advantages of large-scale
Big Box stores, and the shift to higher value goods associated with the
growth in the number of high-income consumers.4
Whatever the precise explanation of the rapid productivity
growth after 2000 it resulted in a sharp recovery in profitability
(Fig. 6.4).
15
Pre-tax
Post-tax
%
10
5
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 6.4. US Profit Rates: Non-financial Corporations, 1950–2004
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Data Appendix.
The US pre-tax profit rate had peaked in 1997 at a higher level than
had been achieved since the 1970s; given the long-run corporate tax
reductions, the post-tax profit rate was higher than in any post-war
year apart from a brief period in the 1960s.5 The profit rate began to
fall in 1998 well before the boom petered out. The fall was centred in
manufacturing, which was being hard hit by the overvaluation of the
US dollar and overcapacity in some sectors.6 By 2004 the profit rate
overall had regained its average level of the previous 30 years, and
exceeded it after tax. So the savage cost-cutting, reflected in rapid
productivity growth, had restored profitability considerably.
By 2004 this recovery provoked a rise in investment spending but
over the whole period since 2000 private consumption accounted for
most of the increase in demand, much of which flowed overseas with
the ever-widening trade deficit. In a sharp reversal from the 1990s,
government direct spending pumped in an extra 0.6% of GDP per
year and tax cuts made up the rest of the massive fiscal boost which
saw the underlying government deficit rising by nearly six percentage
GROWTH AND STABILITY
137
points of GDP over the four years. Alan Greenspan, at the Federal
Reserve, also weighed in with unprecedented interest rate cuts after
the stock market crash and September 11. Apparently he made only
mild protests about the rising budget deficit in contrast to his dire
warnings to Clinton (see Chapter 2).
The USA attracted much attention in the later 1990s as providing
a model for rapid new economy growth focused on information and
communication technologies from which, it was claimed, the US
financial and entrepreneurial system was uniquely placed to benefit.
The lesson was clear; other countries should shift their economies in
the US direction (lower taxes, less regulation) as quickly as possible.
As was noted in Chapter 3, some take a rather fatalistic view of the
sharper booms and slumps which may flow from a very flexible
financial system which can mobilize resources into new areas with
great vigour. Perhaps ‘creative destruction’ which Schumpeter
regarded as the ‘essential fact’ about capitalism, is more effective
when booms are sharp, encouraging the most dynamic to enter the
new industries, and slumps are severe, which gets rid of the weak
competitors. Evidence from the UK suggests, however, that poor
firms enter in booms, and the new economy period must provide
many US examples. The worst firms do not seem to be disproportionately affected by slumps, but under these conditions firms in
general focus on rationalization at the expense of innovation.7
From a later vantage point the US experience indeed looks very
mixed. Much of the productivity increase appeared to come from the
combination of sustained consumer boom, bringing economies of
scale at least in the retailing sector, plus a ferocious rationalization
after 2000 when the bubble burst. Sustained by ballooning budget
deficits, and relying on massive inflows of funds to finance the balance of payments deficit, the overall macroeconomic pattern looks
distinctly frail.
In particular the US economy, and thus the world economy as a
whole, is very vulnerable to a sudden reversal of the US consumption
boom. What can happen is illustrated by the earlier experience of
some other countries. After financial deregulation in Sweden had
brought a sharp consumer boom at the end of the 1980s, a reversal
of the loose monetary policy and a severe banking crisis brought
138
GROWTH AND STABILITY
a 12 percentage point rise in the savings ratio and three years of GDP
decline. As OECD notes (2002: 150) ‘The larger financial exposure of
households has increased the sensitivity of domestic demand to
asset prices’ at the same time as financial deregulation has increased
the ‘risk of excessive asset-price cycles’. The US economy avoided a
‘hard landing’ in 2001–2 largely because the government pumped in
additional demand and US consumers never held back. However the
vulnerability of the US economy would become very clear if the
consumer boom were to weaken suddenly.
Stagnation in Japan
Japan dropped from being the most dynamic of the major OECD
countries in the 1980s (growth averaging some 4% a year until 1991)
to the most stagnant (some 1% growth) thereafter. The long stagnation was set in train by the collapse of gigantic bubbles in land prices,
which had risen by a factor of five times between 1980 and 1990, and
stock prices (up more than six times). By the early 2000s land prices
were back to the 1980 level, and stock prices had also crashed. This
had severe and prolonged depressing effects on bank lending and the
investment of industrial firms, all of whose balance sheets were hit
by asset price declines.
There were some specific features behind the bubble, including
taxes which favoured land investment. It is also widely agreed that
the Bank of Japan was remiss in not raising interest rates until the
middle of 1989. Financial deregulation, stimulated by the need to
finance big budget deficits in the late 1970s and by the internationalization of financial markets, also played a central role in the pumping up of Japanese asset markets. The following account has a
familiar ring from the discussion of finance in Chapter 3:
Ceilings on bank deposit interest rates were liberalised gradually . . . from
1985 to 1994. Restrictions on the issuance of corporate bonds were gradually liberalised during the 1980s. As a result, large listed companies, which
are traditional customers of Japanese banks, gradually shifted their funding
GROWTH AND STABILITY
139
from banks to the capital market. Banks faced a prospect of profit squeeze
due to rising funding cost and a declining customer base . . . In view of the
declining rent from the traditional business of retail deposit taking and
commercial lending to large firms . . . most banks started to increase real
estate lending. In expanding such lending, banks relied exclusively on
collateral and paid little attention to the cash flow of underlying business.
This was because the nominal land price in Japan had been on a rising trend
since the end of World War II . . . Thus, financial liberalisation created a
perfect environment for an asset price bubble. (Fukuo 2003: 367–8)
The collapse of the bubble ushered in a decade of stagnation. This
was despite extremely expansionary macroeconomic policy. Interest
rates were pushed down to 0.5% by 1995 and effectively zero by the
end of the decade and the government cut taxes and raised spending,
which imparted a fiscal expansion worth 1% of GDP per year on
average between 1991 and 1999. One estimate puts the eventual bill
for the Japanese taxpayer of bailing out the banks and other financial
institutions at 20% of GDP.8
It became commonplace to blame Japanese consumers for failing
to generate expansion, in comparison with the USA in particular.
This is absurd. Certainly consumption has grown slowly (around
1.4% per year over the period 1991–2002), but this is because household disposable income was virtually stagnant (growth of only 0.5%
per year). The savings ratio (proportion of income saved) fell by
nearly one percentage point per year, as workers strove to keep consumption growing in the face of the stagnation.9
The real villains of the piece seem to be exports and business
investment. Japan’s share of world exports fell from some 8.25% in
the early 1990s to 5.5% a decade later—a fall of one-third. If Japanese
exports had grown as fast as its export markets in the 1990s and
early 2000s its exports would have grown nearly 4% per year faster.
This would have directly contributed nearly 0.5% per year more to
GDP growth with additional effects on domestic consumption and
investment. Some fall in Japan’s market was to be expected given the
rise in the export capacity of China in particular, and the weakness
of some of Japan’s local markets after the Asian crisis, but the decline
is much greater than can be explained simply by this. An important
additional factor here was the trend appreciation in the yen which
140
GROWTH AND STABILITY
saw the real exchange rate more than 50% higher in real terms in the
second half of the 1990s than it had been in the first half of the 1980s
(see Fig. 3.2). Despite very poor export performance and an appreciating real exchange rate, Japan was persistently in surplus on the
current account of its balance of payments by some 2–3% of GDP
over this period. The explanation for this surprising result is that the
feeble growth rate of GDP was pulling in imports at a comparatively
slow rate. To a considerable extent export performance reflects other
factors internal to the economy. If growth is rapid, imports are
sucked in and the exchange rate depreciates in the long run and this
generates a (roughly) equivalent rise in exports; such a rise in exports
is greatly facilitated by the rapid growth of the capital stock which
brings on new products and cost-reducing processes.
In the last instance, therefore, all trails lead back to business
investment. In contrast to a modest rise in consumption, business
investment was no higher at all in 2002 than it had been when the
boom collapsed in 1990. There was just no rise in the level of investment to drive up demand.10 Many features of Japanese institutions
and policy have been blamed as contributing to the prolonged investment stagnation (see Saxonhouse and Stern 2003). One example is
‘evergreening’—the tendency for Japanese banks to keep extending
credit to firms with little prospect of repayment, apparently under
pressure from government not to force clients into bankruptcy and
not themselves wishing to admit to a high level of bad debts. It is
claimed that this has created a penumbra of ‘zombie firms’ in industries like construction whose presence depresses new firm creation
and deepens stagnation with ‘inefficient firms crowding out new,
more productive firms’ (Hoshi and Kashyap 2004: 7).
It is hard to evaluate the importance of such influences on investment. Motonishi and Yoshikawa (1999) argue that reluctance to borrow has been more important in explaining weak investment over
the 1990s (for large firms in particular) than reluctance of banks to
lend. These authors blame lack of demand, but this tends to circularity since an important reason that demand was rising slowly was
the reluctance of business to invest!
It seems very likely that the collapse of the bubble played a
substantial role here and some supporting evidence comes from the
141
GROWTH AND STABILITY
behaviour of the profit rate (see Fig. 6.5). The series going back to
the early 1950s is a conventional profit rate on capital employed, that
is profits net of depreciation as a percentage of the replacement value
of the stock of assets (buildings, machinery and inventories) calculated for the non-financial companies. Thus measured, the profit
rate rose to great heights at the end of the 1960s boom, before falling
back under the pressure of a very tight labour market and a rising
yen, which affected manufacturing particularly. Profitability recovered a little in the 1980s, before slipping again in the 1990s as growth
stagnated.
25
20
%
15
10
5
0
1950
Reproducible capital
With land
With capital gains/losses on land
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 6.5. Japan Profit Rates: Non-financial Corporations, 1952–2003
Source: Japan Annual Report on National Accounts. See Data Appendix.
From the early 1980s the figure shows two extended measures of
profitability. The first simply includes in capital employed the value
of land as well as the machinery, buildings and inventories. Land
is conventionally excluded by economists because it is not ‘reproducible’ and is thus not part of the real cost to society of new
productive capacity. However, to a capitalist sizing up the prospects
of new investment, the cost of the land required (for the offices or
factories) is part of the overall capital outlay which affects the profitability of the project. At the height of the land price explosion the
market value of the land owned by the non-financial corporations
(NFCs) exceeded the value of the machinery, buildings and inventories,
thus halving the profit rate and bringing it to a very low level by the
end of the boom.
142
GROWTH AND STABILITY
The third series includes a rough estimate of capital gains or losses
on holdings of land. When the land price rose sharply in the second
half of the 1980s, and this is added to profits, the total rate of return
from the productive investment plus the holdings of land was
pushed up. At the peak, NFCs were making more in capital gains on
their land holdings than from their ordinary commercial activities.
No doubt this encouraged additional investments, especially in
projects where land was important and thus opportunities for speculative gains seemed good. When the bubble burst, capital losses
replaced capital gains and the overall rate of return slumped to a
feeble 2–3%. Although nominal interest rates were very low, a slow
fall in prices overall meant that the real rate of interest was substantially positive. From the point of view of the likely return on new
investment, declining land prices were a distinct turn-off as they
held out the prospect of capital losses in the future. From a financing
point of view a fall in land prices means reduced collateral against
which to borrow, making firms more reluctant to take on debt. In
this way it seems likely that the financial boom and bust had an
important influence on the continuing stagnation. Once it had set
in, the lower rate of accumulation was strongly self-reinforcing as
Japanese firms felt less pressure from their domestic competitors
who were not investing at such a high rate.
There has been a tendency to blame Japan’s financial system for
prolonging the stagnation by its reluctance to admit the losses on
‘non-performing’ loans and to foreclose on bankrupt customers. If
the banks had rapidly cut their losses, this would have made for a
steeper recession and sharper rise in unemployment, but at the same
time the excesses of the boom would have been ‘cleansed’ from
the system more quickly, encouraging a renewed upswing before the
gloom had settled in. There may be something to this argument but
it requires some nerve to blame insufficient financial liberalization
for Japan’s problems. For it was financial liberalization, an assault on
the traditional financial system, that caused the mess in the first
place by fuelling the speculative behaviour which pumped up the
asset bubble and brought the subsequent collapse. These ‘domestic’
problems were then exacerbated by the international capital flows
which supported the overvaluation of the yen. However, it is
143
GROWTH AND STABILITY
a feature of hard-line free market analysis that when liberalization
does not work the reason is always timidity and the solution is
obvious. Complete the job.
Europe’s Woes
The weak growth of the European economies in the 1990s has
already been seen (Fig. 6.1). A more startling comparison begins in
1995 and focuses on output per hour worked which has slipped back
seriously in Europe at the very same time as productivity growth
recovered in the USA (Table 6.1).
This striking reversal of fortunes has brought European institutions and policies under the spotlight in just the same way as poor US
performance in the 1970s and 1980s was the subject of soul searching there (see Chapter 4). A wide spectrum of explanations for
Europe’s poor growth has been offered in the literature.11 One of the
more intriguing suggestions, with strong echoes in Japan, has been
that the ageing of the population and labour force has reinforced caution and an aversion to risk taking, in contrast to the youthful and
dynamic USA. Amongst the more mainstream, economic explanations, at one extreme the liberalizers have argued that the whole set
of European institutional arrangements between firms, banks and
workers are to blame. These generated stability and predictability
whilst Europe was catching up to US productivity levels but are no
longer functional now that growth must be based on innovation and
Table 6.1 Labour Productivity Growth in Business Sector, 1976–2003
Average annual
percentage changes
USA
Eurozone
Japan
USA–Euro
gap
USA–Japan
gap
1976–86
1986–95
1995–2003
1.1
1.2
2.5
2.0
2.1
0.8
2.6
2.2
1.5
⫺0.9
⫺0.9
1.7
⫺1.5
⫺1.0
1.0
Sources: OECD. See Data Appendix.
144
GROWTH AND STABILITY
responsiveness to shifting global trends. A wholesale opening up to
market forces is required, moving Europe in the direction of the US
system.
As discussed earlier in this book, there has in fact already been a
very considerable liberalization and reform in Europe. Germany
reduced product market regulation more over the period 1978–98, and
France nearly as much, as did the USA. Over the period 1998–2003 the
EU on average, and almost every country within the EU, reduced
product market regulation more than the USA, and in the cases of
Italy, France and Spain very much more.12
A similar story applies to labour market regulation where the
OECD has analysed reforms undertaken in the 1990s in response to
its Jobs Strategy. The OECD recommended many more pieces of
labour market deregulation for the Continental European countries
than for the USA—for example Germany received 23 recommendations and Italy nine as compared to four for the USA. Moreover
whereas the USA hardly acted on the recommendations at all, Italy
and Germany were estimated by the OECD as implementing nearly
half. Combining both these results, and using the OECD’s weighting
of the importance of the various changes,the ‘volume’ of labour market reform in these two countries was roughly ten times as great in
the USA.13 In the previous chapter the lack of relationship between
labour market reforms and falls in unemployment was noted. Here
the point is that the reforms should have boosted productivity
growth in Europe.
Since Europe remains more regulated than the USA, both in terms
of labour markets and product markets, it is always possible to claim
that even more deregulation is required, an echo of the discussion of
Japanese finance above. However, if regulation was the fundamental
problem, some positive impact on labour productivity growth
should have come already from the very substantial deregulation
already undertaken. Deregulation should have contributed to an
acceleration in productivity growth in Europe whereas actually
productivity growth declined. It is hard to see how regulation, which
was declining, could be the source of Europe’s slowdown.
At the other extreme Keynesians blame the excessively tight
policies of the European Central Bank and the Growth and Stability
GROWTH AND STABILITY
145
Pact which have constrained demand expansion and led to a
cumulative decline in confidence and business expectations. The
discussion in Chapter 2 suggests that a strong influence on demand
restraint is the memory of the turmoil of the 1960s and 1970s and the
fear that this could return if caution was abandoned and unemployment fell too low. Although the unions are weaker and under the
competitive pressures described in earlier chapters, in most of
Europe they have not suffered the kind of decisive defeat inflicted on
the miners in the UK by Mrs Thatcher’s government.
An important finding, emphasized by Gordon (2004) and
Blanchard (2004), is that most of the difference in productivity
performance between Europe and the USA from the mid-1990s is
located in wholesale and retail trade (see the earlier discussion of the
USA). Specific influences such as restraints on developments of
supermarkets have played an important role, reflecting in part different preferences over lifestyle (shopping in city centres rather than
supermarkets and malls). This could be a case where a higher level of
regulation, even if it is falling, impedes productivity acceleration in
the face of new possibilities (in this case Walmart-style supermarkets). As emphasized by these authors, however, such US-style productivity growth can come at a high cost in terms of lifestyles.
One further difference helping to explain faster productivity
growth in US distribution is the far faster growth of consumption.
Between 1994 and 2004 US private consumption grew on average
3.8% per year. This was twice as fast as consumption growth in the
Euro area, with rapidly rising flows of goods through the distributive
chain bringing economies of scale in the USA.
Over and above these influences are there fundamental problems
with labour costs and productivity which can explain Europe’s
stagnation? Earlier sections on the USA and Japan have shown the
course of the profit rate on capital employed as an indicator of how
propitious are the conditions for capital accumulation. Figure 6.6
presents the comparable data for UK, Germany and Italy.
The rate of profit had declined substantially in Germany from the
1960s onwards and to a somewhat lesser extent in the UK. The
1980s saw very rapid recovery in the UK, with the rationalization
under Mrs Thatcher (see Chapter 2) aided by the boost to profits
146
GROWTH AND STABILITY
from North Sea Oil. In Germany the recovery was slower, but
substantial by 1990. The evolution in France (not shown here)
appears to be similar to that in the UK whereas in Italy there had
already been some recovery in the later 1970s. In the 1990s profit
trends were fairly flat apart from a fall-back in Germany just after
unification.14
25
UK
Italy
20
West Germany
Germany
%
15
10
5
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Fig. 6.6. Europe Profit Rates: Non-financial Sector, 1950–2003
Sources: Office of National Statistics; German National Accounts; Torrini (2005). See
Data Appendix.
It is hazardous to compare such estimates of the profit rate across
countries due to differing assumptions used by the national income
statisticians about the rate at which capital depreciates. Nevertheless,
from the available data, it appears that profit rates in Europe in the
1990s were no lower on average than in the USA—though Germany
may be an important exception given the fall in profitability in the
early 1990s following reunification.15 Data for the manufacturing
sector tell a rather different story. In the 1990s profits were much
lower in the UK, Italy and Germany than in the USA.16 Profitability
in European manufacturing seems to have been decidedly low as
compared to the US rates and compared to the rest of the economy.
This must have discouraged investment, preventing manufacturing
from acting as the economy’s powerhouse even to the extent that
it was in the USA. Furthermore, with the exception of the UK,
these countries did not have such a sharp consumer boom as in the
USA, so they also missed out on that stimulus to investment in the
GROWTH AND STABILITY
147
wholesale and retail sector. This adds up to feeble business investment
overall.
Germany appears to exemplify this stagnant pattern and, given its
pivotal position in the European economy, its lack of dynamism has
infected much of the region. It is important to appreciate the
sharp break in German performance associated with reunification.
The German economy grew at 4% per year over the four-year period
1987–91 with a general European upswing prolonged by the preunification boom; business investment grew nearly twice as fast.
Unemployment in West Germany fell to 4.1% and domestic inflation, though rising, was only 3.5%. Since 1991 Germany has only
once exceeded 3% growth (and narrowly at that). The unification
with East Germany represented an increase of around one-sixth in
the population but the average productivity of its workforce turned
out to be one-third of the West German level. The expected ‘catch-up’
to West Germany has stalled after 1995 with productivity at 60% of
the Western level whilst wages are 65–75% of West German wages.
Employment in the Eastern states has declined more or less continually since reunification, pushing up unemployment for the whole
country by some 1%.
Adding a substantial and extremely unproductive segment to the
West German economy was bound to drag down average productivity
and push up average unemployment in the unified state. But the
costs of unification, put at some 4–5% of West German GDP every
year, have put tremendous pressure on the functioning of the western part of the economy as well. After initial rises in government
deficits, the majority of these costs are paid for in higher taxation
which has tended to be passed on in wage increases by the relatively
strong trade unions. Germany has had an overvalued exchange rate
(cost competitiveness in German manufacturing has been around
15% lower since 1995 than it was in the late 1980s). This originated
in the response to unification when interest rates were forced up by
the Bundesbank to contain inflationary pressure and a temporary
current account deficit was considered desirable, as a means of borrowing some of the resources required for reconstructing the East.
The result has been squeezed profits, especially in manufacturing as
noted earlier. Since 1990 Germany has lost export market share in
148
GROWTH AND STABILITY
ten out of 14 years cutting off Germany until recently from its usual
escape route out of post-war recessions via rapid export growth.17
There are aspects of German unification which could have been
handled differently, but the fundamental problem was that the enormous costs in the West were absorbed in a haphazard and chaotic
way rather than via a process of social consensus and negotiation.
The old distributional struggles, which Germany had been relatively
successful in containing in the 1960s and 1970s, re-emerged in a very
damaging way in response to this sudden shock; the response from
business was calls for financial discipline and deregulation with
strong echoes from the Thatcher period. Additional pressure is being
exerted by Germany’s proximity, and old links, to Eastern European
countries with labour costs a fraction of those in Germany and now
members of the EU.
Unstable Growth?
Chapter 3 outlined a number of respects in which developments in
finance have promoted instability, including the encouragement of
consumption and housing booms, stock price overvaluations, major
misalignments of real exchange rates and competitive pressure on
financial institutions to sacrifice risk in the search for shareholder
value. All of these trends would be expected to combine to make
economies more vulnerable to financial crises and generally
unstable, leading to greater fluctuations in output.
Table 6.2 Global Growth Volatility, 1954–2003
World
of which:
15 industrial
economies
91 other economies
1954–73
1974–83
1984–93
1994–2003
4.3
5.3
4.3
3.0
2.1
2.1
1.8
1.2
4.7
5.9
4.7
3.3
Note: Standard deviation of annual % GDP growth.
Source: Martin and Rowthorn (2004). See Data Appendix.
GROWTH AND STABILITY
149
Table 6.2, however, shows that the period after 1993 has been the
most stable post-war decade, with the output of both advanced and
less developed economies being around one third less volatile than
during the 1950s and 1960s. Less volatility does not guarantee
dynamism. In Japan output growth was much more stable in the
1990s when the economy was stagnating than during earlier decades
of much faster growth. Nevertheless the comparative stability of out
put growth is somewhat paradoxical. Possible explanations are
either that greater instability deriving from the financial system has
been offset by fewer problems with the supply side of the economy,
particularly wage pressure, or that policy has become better at
cushioning the economy from all such shocks.
We do know that throughout the OECD monetary policy in
particular has become less accommodating of inflation but if anything this would tend to make output more variable as Central Banks
squeeze hard on any signs of inflationary pressure. However wage
explosions are no longer a source of instability in the most developed
economies. So if commodity prices increase rapidly, which lowers
real wages, this does not provoke much of a rise in money wages to
restore living standards. Correspondingly governments do not
squeeze so hard on demand in order to keep the lid on wages.18
It has become widely assumed that the US Fed will intervene
actively to attempt to offset fluctuations in stock markets (as well
as the market for government bonds). In 2000, near the peak of the
equity bubble, comments from bank analysts of the stock market
included ‘we know Greenspan always comes to the defense of the
stock market when it sells off’ and ‘if the market moves up 20 per
cent over the year, then the market declines by 20 per cent, the
Fed is likely to react to the 20 per cent decline and not the 20 per
cent increase’ (quoted Parenteau 2005, p. 143). Whilst provision
of liquidity to financial markets may limit the effects of crashes,
as when the US stock market fell after 2000, it may also engender
overconfidence, increasing levels of risk taking, and thus greater
financial fragility in the longer term—the problem of moral
hazard.
Moreover there are fears that attempts to improve bank regulation
may be making economies more unstable. Goodhart et al. (2004)
150
GROWTH AND STABILITY
suggest that the new internationally agreed regulations (‘Basel II’) by
incorporating more sophisticated analyses of risks could force
individual banks into more cautious behaviour in bad times. This
makes perfectly good sense in relation to the solvency of individual
institutions. However, simultaneous attempts by many banks to
meet the more demanding regulations on ‘capital adequacy’ could
well be counter-productive for the stability of the whole system. If
banks try and meet tighter capital requirements by selling assets and
restricting lending in a recession, they could end up making the
recession, and thus their collective position, worse. This is because
if they all restricted lending the result would be reduced real investment and thus aggregate demand. Company profits would fall and
the banks would be less likely to receive interest and repayments of
existing loans.
It seems likely that the greater stability of total production in the
economy as a whole would translate into greater stability of output
and employment at the level of the firm, where it most impinges on
individual workers. However Comin and Philippon (2005) document a striking increase in the volatility of output the firm level in
the USA even as output in the economy overall has been fluctuating
less. One aspect of this is that major firms in an industry are several
times more likely to be toppled from a leading position than was the
case in the 1970s. This supports the common perception that more
intense product market competition has generated greater economic
greater instability and insecurity. Macroeconomic stability provides
some kind of cushion, in that workers who lose their jobs in one firm
are more likely to find alternative work if the economy as a whole is
not in recession. However this does not eliminate the costs of instability to the individuals concerned and as argued above, current
macroeconomic stability is highly vulnerable to financial crises.
Prospects
This chapter has examined whether the great reversal in economic
policy over the past 25 years has rekindled economic dynamism in
GROWTH AND STABILITY
151
the rich countries and how the stability of output has been affected.
Excitement over the new economy boom in the USA has dissipated
with the collapse of the bubble amidst a welter of scandal. The apparently impressive US recovery from the ensuing recession was only
obtained by massive government intervention, fierce rationalization
in workplaces, an unsustainable consumer boom and unprecedented
borrowing abroad by the world’s richest country. Meanwhile Japan
has been stuck in a low growth quagmire for 15 years reflecting in part
the after-effects of precipitate financial liberalization. Europe’s economy, battered by the effects of German unification, has been growing
only feebly, with mass unemployment in the large Continental
economies, and with little response to repeated doses of deregulation.
The fact that output per head has been growing more slowly since
1990 than it did in the turbulent period 1973–9, never mind the
Golden Age, must be a severe disappointment to those who believed
that unleashing the free market would restore rapid growth. But does
this constitute a ‘crisis’ for capitalism in the rich countries? Only by
diluting the original meaning of the term which refers to ‘the point
in the progress of a disease when an important development or
change takes place which is decisive of recovery or death’ (Oxford
English Dictionary, as quoted by Itoh 1990: 4). As argued in earlier
chapters the decisive change took place in the 1980s with the implementation of traditional free market policies. Aided by the collapse
of central planning and the political system which supported it,
demands for greater state intervention, let alone for transformation in
a socialist direction, have been beaten back. The fact that economic
performance overall has been unspectacular does not imply that the
system is in crisis. Capitalism as a system in the rich countries is not
at present threatened by serious competitors.
Productivity per hour growing in the range 1% to 2.5% per year
has been typical of the most developed capitalist economies since
1870 with the exception of European and Japanese catch-up in the
1950s and 1960s.19 Performance over recent decades is within this
‘normal’ range, and memories of the Golden Age growth are too
faded to still cause frustrated expectations. Nor does there seem
compelling evidence for presuming that there will be a decisive shift
in productivity growth from these long-run norms over the next
decade or two.
152
GROWTH AND STABILITY
From Smith, who believed that countries would reach the ‘full
complement of their riches’, to Keynes, who asserted that capital
accumulation would exhaust investment opportunities ‘without
great difficulty’, there is a long history of economists predicting
declines in the long-run growth rate of capitalist economies. One
current trend acting in that direction is the rising share of employment in the service sector in general and in personal and collective
services in particular, where meaningful productivity growth can
only be minimal. This tends to drag down the average rate of productivity growth in the economy as a whole.20 Such effects are slow
but could reduce average labour productivity growth by up to half of
1% per year over the next 40 years. If ICT turns out to have as
far-reaching effects on productivity as some analysts believe such a
trend decline would not happen. A recent analysis of the centrality
of the process of innovation in capitalist economies sees no compelling reasons for this process slowing down.21 Predictions one way
or the other seem futile. What is more clearly wired into the longerrun trend is a substantial decline in population growth in the rich
economies and a bigger still decline in employment growth as the
population ages. Thus the growth rate of GDP per head of the population will decline quite substantially in the rich countries, perhaps
to little more than half a per cent per year in two or three decades.22
Whilst changes on the ‘supply side’ tend to be slow acting, economic
prospects are much more dramatically affected by demand fluctuations. The genie of financial competition and expansion has been
released by deregulation and financial innovation. Whilst the worst
effects of the resulting financial fragility have been felt in the Asian
countries hit by the crisis of 1998, it would be wrong to assume that
the greater sophistication of financial markets in OECD countries
insures them against financial problems. As this chapter has documented, the real economies of the USA and especially Japan have
been scarred by financial excesses and the whole financial system
can be threatened by the unrelenting search for ‘value’ though ever
more complex financial trades. Regulators are trying to secure the
benefits from liberalization whilst limiting the risks, but this is
formidably difficult and the chances of a major financial crisis must
certainly have increased. The April 2005 issue of the IMF’s regular
GROWTH AND STABILITY
153
Financial Stability Report whilst reporting a ‘benign scenario’ at present expressed the worry ‘The combination of low risk premiums,
complacency, and untested elements of risk management systems
dealing with complex financial instruments could ultimately
become hazardous to financial markets’ (IMF 2005:1).
Potentially dwarfing in significance even the rise in density, international entanglement and fragility of financial markets is the
growth of China, India and other developing countries. Until the
1980s the developing countries were economically significant for
the rich economies only as suppliers of commodities and above all
oil. Developing countries never constituted serious competition for
more than a few Northern producers. However, as discussed in
Chapter 4, these countries are now ‘emerging’ on to the world economic stage with great momentum. Since the mid-1990s the majority of world GDP has been produced outside the old OECD countries
whilst their share is declining. The centre of capital accumulation,
the driving force of the system is shifting away from the rich countries. For the North this has a number of quite contradictory effects.
First, rapid growth in the rest of the world will bring buoyant
demand for exports of those goods where the rich countries maintain
an advantage. This will in turn encourage capital accumulation in
those industries and help to keep aggregate demand rising. This
would be the South helping to sustain demand in the most developed
economies, as envisaged 100 years ago by the Polish Marxist Rosa
Luxemburg. In order to maintain that advantage in the face of rising
competition from the South in increasingly sophisticated products,
the currencies of the rich countries would have to depreciate. Living
standards in the rich countries would no longer benefit so much
from the import of cheap consumer goods.23
Secondly, there is the impact of surplus labour in China and
elsewhere, significant segments of which will be highly educated
but with much lower wages than in the North. Access to this cheap
labour could encourage a much higher level of direct investment
from the North, in effect an investment drain away from the rich
countries. In effect the capital–labour ratio would decline on a world
scale, by one-third or more according to one estimate, as the vast
reserves of labour in those countries become inserted into the world
154
GROWTH AND STABILITY
economy. The result could be a major fall in the share of wages in the
rich countries as workers find their bargaining position weakened.24
The political consequences of such developments are hard to
foresee. Growing demands for forms of protection for Northern
workers from Southern competition seems very probable.
The other side of a declining wage share is obviously rising profits.
However wages play a dual role in capitalism, as both cost of production and source of consumer demand, as emphasized nearly 200 years
ago by Robert Malthus, better known for his pessimistic views on
population. ‘Excessive’ wages can threaten profitability and accumulation as the account of the 1970s in Chapter 1 shows. Conversely
wages growing slower than productivity threatens the buoyancy of
consumer demand; with investment attracted elsewhere by Southern
wages, maintaining demand in the North would then rely on
increasing dollops of consumer credit or expanded government
spending. Such a pattern looks unstable economically and challenging politically. To repeat the point made in Chapter 4, the development of new low cost sources of supply is not a new phenomenon.
In that sense China and India are following the path of Japan and
then the Asian NICs. What makes the present position different is
that the population of these countries offers the potential for a far
larger, and thus more disruptive, process of catch-up.
China itself could be a further major source of instability in
the world economy. Its credit system is notoriously shaky, raising the
possibility of a credit crisis and recession with severe impact on the
North. The rate of absorption of labour could generate wage pressure
and industrial conflict which the Communist Party would find it
difficult to restrain. A severe recession could develop in China if
interest rates were raised sharply to try and restore discipline—a
rerun possibly on a grand scale of the ‘overaccumulation’ crisis in the
OECD countries in the 1970s discussed in Chapter 1.
China’s and India’s appetite for energy and materials could precipitate spiralling prices, as markets try to anticipate long-run trends.
The higher real costs of these inputs transfer additional real income
to the producers of energy and materials who receive the higher
prices for all their output. These effects would further increase pressure on the growth of living standards in the North. Nordhaus,
GROWTH AND STABILITY
155
a leading authority on the macroeconomic effects of environmental
constraints, estimated that their impact on economic growth would
be around 0.3% per year over the period to 2050, only slightly more
than over the recent past.25 However there is a great deal of uncertainly about such figures and, combined with the other influences
discussed above, tightening environmental constraints could leave
the rich countries with very low per capita growth indeed.
The fundamental point is that having beaten off the challenges of
the 1970s the capitalist system in the North has not reached the ‘end
of history’ where growth and stability are assured. Trying to work
out more or less likely long-term scenarios is just peering into a
highly uncertain future. A more immediate question is whether we
have much choice left in the economic and social policies which our
governments can implement. Are the economies of the rich countries rapidly converging under pressures from globalization on the
US model with an increasingly inegalitarian income distribution,
minimal welfare state and long working hours? Within the confines
of capitalism are there still real choices about who gets what and
who does what? The final chapter examines what has been happening to the welfare state and income distribution and speculates
briefly on what might happen in the future.
7
Welfare and Income Inequality
Much of classical economics, with its [concept of the] long-run
‘stationary state’, had a fairly well-developed limits-to-growth
argument . . . the argument that growth would have to stop
because of limiting factors—most notably land—was definitely
there.
Furthermore, the writings of our esteemed colleagues of the
past are full of references to the idea that society will achieve
general satiation in the distant future. . . .With more than enough
to go around, people will work less and enjoy leisure more. This
vision is expressed in the writings of Marx, of Mill, of Keynes
and of many others.
It can be argued that these economists underestimated the
potential of technical change, or that they did not really understand human nature. Maybe that is true. But I must say it gives
me some pause in trying to think about the distant future.
Maybe it is we who are now overestimating the potential of
technical change or it is we who do not really understand human
nature. If we mainstream economic thinkers reversed ourselves
so strongly over the last century, why shouldn’t we reverse ourselves again over the next century?
(Martin Weitzman, Professor of Economics at Harvard,
commenting in 1992 on the Limits to Growth
controversy (Weitzman 1992: 54))
The period from the 1950s to the 1970s was the golden age for
welfare state expansion bringing wider access to and improved
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
157
quality of health, education and social services. It was no coincidence that this was also the period of growing organizational
strength and influence of organized labour, since extension of the
welfare state has long been at the forefront of trades union and social
democratic party demands. Improved coverage of social security also
contributed to reductions in income inequality in a number of
OECD countries. Since then, as noted in earlier chapters, the drive
for budget retrenchment has kept state spending under sustained
pressure and wage inequality has increased, especially at the top
end of the pay scales. This chapter reviews what has happened to
welfare spending and inequality in the OECD countries since 1980.
A central question is whether the heightened international competition involved in globalization is compromising the nation state’s
ability to fund welfare spending. Could it really be true that globalization means that ‘Europe can no longer afford its welfare state’?
The discussion of how the economy’s output is distributed raises the
further question as to whether the current emphasis on this output,
as measured by GDP, really meets the needs of people when average
living standards are already high. So the book concludes with a
brief discussion of the pursuit of growing production and whether a
redesign of the welfare state could bring about a more desirable
balance of work in the formal economy and other activities.
Welfare State Spending
It is worth recalling what the welfare state is supposed to do before
discussing the pressures to which its financing has been subjected.
Historically, the first function of the welfare state was insurance for
working people and their families against loss of earnings due to
unemployment, sickness and old age. The system of compulsory
social security contributions meant that the redistribution involved
was primarily within the (broadly defined) working class—from
those working to those out of work or sick or to the retired. The case
for the state being involved in requiring such insurance was that
poverty or irresponsibility would mean that some people would
158
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
underinsure and risk destitution. The case for the state being
involved in providing the insurance, rather than making private
insurance compulsory, was cheapness of centralized administration
combined with the fact many groups (chronically sick, workers in
highly cyclical industries) would be unable to find affordable private
insurance.
The second pillar of the welfare state is provision of education,
health and other social services. Here the case for state finance out
of general taxation was the egalitarian argument that all should
have access to these fundamental services irrespective of family
income, together with the fact that all society benefits from a
healthy, well-educated population. The efficiency case for state
provision of these services was that this reduced administrative costs for universal services plus the harnessing of the public
service ethos that motivates many people more effectively than if
they were doing the same job for a profit-making company (as noted
in Chapter 2). Welfare states have developed in very different ways
across the OECD countries, with varying emphasis on support
through cash benefits or on direct provision of services, as discussed
by Esping-Andersen (1990). However the pressures to improve provision and the problems of financing such improvements were felt
across the different systems.
Pressures for improved cash transfers meant that they often
increased faster than average incomes. For example, the ratio of
unemployment benefits to wage incomes rose substantially to the
end of the 1970s (see Fig. 5.5). Additional factors which increased
social security spending were higher levels of unemployment and
more people on sickness benefit. The rise in the proportion of
pensioners is a further cause of higher ‘demand’ for welfare spending.
In the provision of services like health and education there are strong
social pressures for higher and higher levels of service (smaller class
sizes, newly available drugs). If labour productivity was easy to
increase in the public services then such improvements could be
paid for out of higher productivity. However in many public
services productivity is hard to raise. Smaller class sizes or more
intensive nursing more or less automatically imply lower ‘productivity’ as crudely measured by pupils per teacher or patients per nurse.
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
159
The implication of minimal increases in productivity in the provision of these services is that their costs tend to rise systematically as
compared to goods and services generally (the ‘relative price effect’)
and these costs have to be covered from taxation.
Who Pays for Welfare Spending?
The strong pressures making for growing welfare spending are
clear enough. However they come head to head against the age-old
problem of ‘where will the money come from?’
In a closed economy, with no investment or international links, an
economy cannot consume more than it produces. This means that
any resources devoted to public services must be paid for out of
reduced personal consumption. Similarly, a redistribution of consuming power through the tax and benefit system must be paid for
with lower consumption by those paying the higher taxes. Within
this constraint an economy can afford any level of welfare spending
its citizens are prepared to pay for. The fundamental issue is political
support and collective discipline. The latter is important. The temptation is to try to both ‘have one’s cake’ (better welfare services) and
‘eat it’ (no less personal consumption). Increases in welfare spending
may be supported at elections, but that is not sufficient if workers
attempt to offload the impact of the higher taxes via an increase in
money wages.
The situation becomes even more difficult if an increase in
benefits and thus taxation reduces the size of the cake through
people choosing to work or invest less. Any resulting reduction in
the total amount of production would cause a potential squeeze on
welfare spending as tax revenue declined. Such disincentive effects
are emphasized by conservatives. Their own design for the welfare
state is strongly biased towards means-tested benefits. These have
the attraction of being focussed on the poorest people, but they
inevitably have to be ‘withdrawn’ as a person’s income rises. This
can lead to very high combined rates for taxation and loss of benefits
on extra income. This creates much worse incentive problems for
160
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
those with low incomes than more generous universal benefits.
The UK pension system is a notorious example where a niggardly
basic state pension is topped up by means-tested additional benefits,
which cuts the incentive for modest additional personal provision
for old age.
Much more noise tends to be heard about alleged disincentive
effects by the higher paid who quite simply do not want to pay the
tax. The American economist Arthur Okun offered the image of
redistributive taxation being a ‘leaky bucket’ as for every dollar
transferred to the poor the post-tax income of the rich would fall by
more than the dollar due to their working less. The ultimate leaky
bucket would be where higher tax rates yield less tax in total—the
famous Laffer curve conjecture. To be set against such modest
disincentive affects as may realistically arise from taxation, much
welfare spending has beneficial effects on efficiency and thus contributes to higher tax revenue in the future. For example better
health and education increase productivity, higher unemployment
benefits can allow workers the time to find a job more appropriate to
their skills. The countries with more state spending, on child care
and education in particular, have fewer people entering the labour
force with very poor educational attainment—in Sweden 6–8% of
the population of working age had only achieved the lowest level of
numeracy and literacy in 1994–5 whereas in the USA and UK the
proportions were 20–23%.1 Lindert (2003: 11) concludes from his
study of the economic costs of the welfare state: ‘Once we draw back
from [such] extrapolations [to extreme tax rates—AG] to the historical range of policies actually tried, no expansion of taxes and transfers lowers (or raises) GDP.’ This suggests that adverse incentive
effects are usually not the binding constraint on welfare spending;
gaining the political support for higher taxation is the issue.
Investment complicates the picture since higher welfare spending
could be at the expense of capital accumulation rather than current
consumption. This could occur if the spending was financed directly
by increasing taxation of profits. Alternatively, if extra taxation on
labour brings wage pressure and reduced profits, this has the same
effect by passing on the extra tax to profits. The problem is that
reduced profits jeopardize investment both because retained profits
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
161
are a preferred source of finance and because expectations of the
return to new investments will decline; higher taxation of profits
may also be interpreted as an anti-capitalist measure presaging other
threats to capital’s freedom of manoeuvre and weakening confidence
(see Chapter 1).
Maintaining consumption in the face of a rising share of welfare
spending by a squeeze on investment could only be a short-term
solution to the problem of excessive claims on national output. By
slowing growth, weaker investment is likely to exacerbate distributional conflict in the future, especially if the expectations of wage
earners and other sections of society are based on the experience
of growing consumption. It is a fundamental problem for left-wing
governments that ‘making the bosses pay’ by higher corporate taxation or a profits squeeze risks killing the goose that lays the golden
egg of investment and growth. That is a feature of capitalism in
general, not specific to its current globalized stage. As German
Chancellor Helmut Schmidt, from the social democratic SPD, noted
in 1976, well before globalization had been heralded: ‘The profits of
enterprises today are the investments of tomorrow and the investments of tomorrow are the employment of the day after’ (quoted
Bhadhuri 1993).
This helps to explain why corporation tax constitutes only a small
proportion of tax revenue in the typical OECD country (see below).
Indeed countries with more welfare expenditures do not tax incomes
from capital more highly than the liberal market economies; if
anything the reverse is the case. Additional tax revenue in the generous welfare states comes from extra taxation of labour incomes and
of consumption.2
Is it possible to ‘make the rich pay’ for an expansion of the welfare
state by stiffer taxation of high personal incomes, without jeopardizing corporate investment? In the typical high income country the
top 10% of households receive around 30% of total incomes.3 Tax
systems as a whole are barely progressive.4 Social security contributions are often capped and indirect taxation is typically regressive,
counterbalancing generally progressive income taxes. Thus, as a
broad figure, the top 10% typically contribute some 30% of total tax
revenue. Increasing the taxation of this group by one-third would be
162
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
a stiff, but far from confiscatory, increase in taxation. It would
contribute an extra 10% to total tax revenue. Of course political
opposition from those affected would be fierce, with threats of
top earners emigrating. However self-serving such arguments, it is
important not to exaggerate the extent to which the costs of welfare
expansion can realistically be pushed up the income distribution.
Even though a substantially more progressive tax system than
currently applies in most countries would yield a very worthwhile
extra contribution to total tax revenue, this would still leave the
majority of taxation contributed by those with less than top incomes.
This underlines the continuing degree to which the welfare state,
which constitutes the major use of tax revenue, is financed by
the mass of wage and salary earners and thus represents social
insurance.
The discussion above has been couched in terms of higher taxes
required to finance welfare spending. Exactly the same argument
applies to forms of labour market regulation which in one way or
another increase firms’ costs. If Health and Safety Regulations
reduce work speeds through adherence to safety procedures then the
reduced national output must be paid for out of reduced consumption, or other welfare spending or investment. If Employment
Protection Legislation reduces firms’ freedom to hire and fire at will
and moderates work intensity, then the effect must be lower profits
or real wages, which translates into less consumption or investment
or welfare spending. A cut in the working year will tend to reduce
total production and annual real wages must decline if profits are
not to be squeezed. Such measures may enhance productivity in
other ways, by reducing labour turnover or encouraging training for
example. But ‘win-win’ outcomes cannot usually be guaranteed;
when the net effect on production is negative, this cost has to be
borne by some part of national expenditure.
The general point, therefore, is that international competition,
and the freedom of manoeuvre brought by globalization, do not
import constraints on welfare spending where none existed before.
Once underutilized resources are mobilized and the total amount of
production constrained, welfare spending has to compete with the
demands of personal consumption and investment. Given the need
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
163
to maintain investment, the fundamental question is whether it is
possible politically to persuade wage earners to accept higher taxes
to pay for an extended welfare state. Globalization can only be
blamed for making the welfare state unaffordable if it has severely
tightened these constraints.
Constraints on the Tax Burden
Before looking at what has happened to sources of tax revenue
and welfare spending over the past 25 years there are two trends
encountered earlier in the book which have played a significant role
in constraining tax revenues.
The generalized slowdown in labour productivity growth,
discussed in the previous chapter, has implied that any increase in
the tax share of GDP, required to finance increasing real costs of the
welfare state, has to reduce what is already a slow growth of living
standards. Real pre-tax wages have been rising at less than 1.5% per
year in Europe since 1990 as compared to nearly 4.5% over the period
1960– 73. Increasing the total tax share (including indirect taxes) of a
worker’s income from 40% to 41% say would soak up all the current
rate of real wage increase leaving real take-home pay unchanged. At
1960s rates of real wage growth, however, such a tax increase would
still leave workers with 3% extra to spend on consumption. It must
be easier to raise the tax share when incomes are growing fast.
A second important trend bearing on redistribution is the increasing inequality of pre-tax incomes. As was noted in Chapter 5 much of
the increase has been at the top end of the pay distribution, and the
effect of this has been compounded by rising profits and dividends,
which go disproportionately to higher income groups, as detailed
later in this chapter. So, even with little or no progression in the tax
system, the higher income groups are tending to contribute a greater
share to total tax revenue. Thus just maintaining an existing welfare
state structure implies a greater degree of redistribution. Those making a bigger contribution, and resenting it, may be able to mobilize
political support against redistribution from middle income groups
164
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
by agitating against those sections in society who benefit most from
redistribution. There is some empirical support for this idea. Across
OECD countries, greater inequality in the top half of the distribution
tends to be associated with lower redistributive transfers. The study
suggests that ‘As the “rich” become more distant from the lower and
middle classes, they find it easier to opt out of public programs and
either to self-insure or buy substitutes in the private market . . . they
have little need for redistributive cash and new cash social benefits
because they are very unlikely to benefit’ (Schwarbish et al. 2004: 33).
The slower growth of labour productivity is certainly not the
result of globalization in any straightforward way. Indeed the
cheaper import prices promised by globalization, resulting for
example from the expansion of low-wage Chinese exports, tend to
boost the purchasing power of real incomes in the North and thus
act to offset the productivity slowdown. Globalization has been
implicated in the rise in income inequality. It has played a role in
contributing to falling relative demand for unskilled labour, thus
increasing wage differences, as discussed in the previous chapter. It
has also contributed to weakening the bargaining power of trade
unions, contributing to the rise in profit incomes. However it is one
amongst a number of factors explaining these trends, along with
skill-biased technical progress and mass unemployment.
Perhaps the most celebrated effect of globalization on taxes is ‘tax
competition’ between countries, competing for foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows and seeking to circumvent FDI outflows. This
has certainly added to the usual domestic pressures to cut corporation tax rates.5 Amongst OECD countries there has been a substantial reduction in corporation tax rates on average and a distinct
convergence of rates between countries (as indicated by the fall in
the standard deviation of the rates—see Table 7.1). However the significance of this for welfare state financing is limited. Corporation
tax has never been a major source of tax revenue, for reasons
discussed in the previous section. As a proportion of total taxation it
was on a declining trend in the later 1960s and 1970s, reflecting the
profits squeeze. However it stabilized in the 1980s and, bolstered by
rising profits, corporation taxes contributed the same share of OECD
tax revenue (around 9%) in 2000 as in 1980.
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
165
The international organizations have campaigned hard for welfare
state retrenchment, though generally in a guarded way. The OECD,
in the context of the Jobs Study, not only warned against high benefit
replacement ratios but also called for reductions in the total ‘tax
wedge’ between employers’ cost of labour and workers’ net wages.
This wedge comprises social security contributions by employer and
worker, income taxes plus (in most formulations) indirect taxes.
Thus the wedge constitutes the great bulk of the tax take. So calling
for it to be cut, in the name of lowering labour costs and stimulating
employment, implies a fall in welfare spending. In 2005 the OECD’s
paper on Economic Policy Reforms singled out cutting the tax wedge
as one of the key measures to increase employment in as many as ten
member countries, and in the case of Canada even suggested public
health care costs should be reduced to fund the tax cut.
Table 7.1 Corporation Tax Rates: OECD Countries,
1982–2001
Percentage
Corporation Tax Rate
1982
2001
France
Germany
Japan
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
41
56
48
54
36
39
30
34
37
23
26
33
OECD mean
Standard deviation
40
13
29
7
Source: Institute for Fiscal Studies. See Data Appendix.
In the light of all these pressures it might be expected that
spending on the welfare state, at least as a share of GDP, would have
stagnated, if not declined, with reductions taking place where the
welfare state was largest and thus most ‘in need’ of trimming. This
has not happened. As Table 7.2 indicates, social spending has kept
increasing as a share of GDP, if at a slower rate than in the 1960s
and 1970s. There has been some convergence between countries’
spending—the standard deviation of social spending shares has moved
down.6 However, the Northern European countries, with higher
166
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
social spending in 1980 frequently reflecting strong social democratic influences, actually increased social spending more than the
liberal economies. An interesting exception is the Netherlands
where responsibility for payment of sickness benefits to those off
work was shifted to employers, a measure which cut government
spending by 3% of GDP. Overall, however, the convergence which
has occurred reflects the Southern European countries catching up
their Northern neighbours rather than any collapse of social spending towards US levels. This confirms the conclusion of Navarro et al.
(2004: 151) that the welfare systems ‘have not converged during the
globalization period towards a reduced welfare state’.
Table 7.2 Social Spending: OECD Countries,
1980–2001
Social Spending (% GDP)
1980
2001
France
Germany
Japan
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
21.1
23.0
10.2
28.8
17.9
13.3
28.5
27.4
16.9
28.9
21.8
14.8
OECD mean
OECD std. dev.
18.3
5.8
22.5
4.6
North Europe
South Europe
Liberal
economies
22.6
14.2
26.4
22.4
15.2
17.4
Source: OECD. See Data Appendix.
Why has social spending been so resistant to cuts? The most
important influence was surely the wide degree of popular support
for many of these services, especially where they are well financed
and of high quality as in the social democratic welfare states such
as Sweden. In that country a majority of people are dependent for a
majority of their incomes on employment by the state and/or
benefits paid by the state.7 Better off salary earners are less likely to
be attracted to private provision where public education is excellent and public pensions substantial. In these countries there is a
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
167
strong political commitment to equality: ‘Such political preferences can prevent the most efficient outcomes from happening but
a neoclassical economist can hardly criticise a nation for having
inadequate preferences. There is no ethical imperative to grow
faster than other nations, and seen from the perspective of the least
advantaged Sweden is an extremely successful society’ (Vartiainen
2001: 52).
The high share of taxation in Sweden did not prevent Swedish
manufacturing from increasing productivity faster than any other
industrialized country including the USA. Between 1990 and 2003
hourly labour productivity in Swedish manufacturing grew at 6%
per year. This compared to 5.2% per year in the USA and only 3.2%
per year in the UK, often held up as a deregulated model for Europe.
Sweden also had the highest ratio of Research and Development
spending to GDP in the 1990s of any OECD country, half as big again
as in the UK.8 Obviously high levels of social spending and taxation
are not inconsistent with dynamism. Martin Wolf, a strong supporter of globalization, reaches a similar conclusion:
There is no sign that highly taxed countries in general suffer from a huge
unrequited outflow of corporate capital . . . .The conclusion is that lack of
competitiveness is nowhere to be found in these highly taxed countries.
Particularly important is the finding that they are not suffering a haemorrhage of capital or of skilled people. (Wolf 2004: 260)
Globalization can even on occasion work to the benefit of the public
services. The winter 1999 influenza crisis in the UK health service
brought unflattering comparisons with the performance of the much
better funded French system. With strong political support for the
NHS, Tony Blair was bounced into suddenly promising to raise UK
health spending to the EU average, implying real increases in spending of 30% over five years; an example of a race to the middle.
Income Inequality
Liberalization of markets tends to bring greater inequality. At one
end of the income distribution, restraints are lifted on high salaries
168
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
and executive pay and dividends rise under pressure from the financial markets. At the other end of the distribution, wages may be
made more flexible in the name of generating more jobs. In terms
of the structure of taxation the liberalizers call for lower income tax
on high incomes and a switch to regressive indirect taxes, whilst
benefits may be under pressure in the name of improving incentives.
If such pressures were irresistible then the impact might well be
greatest in the most regulated and coordinated economies where
market forces had been most repressed. This section examines
what has happened to income inequality and poverty in the 1980s
and 1990s.
A review of the international studies of income distribution
suggests significant increases in inequality have occurred in the
majority of OECD countries since 1979.9 Spain appears to be an
exception with a strong decline in inequality from the mid-1980s.
In a number of countries, including Denmark and France, changes
were rather small. The decade from the mid-1980s seems to have
produced the strongest wave of increases in inequality, with some
slackening in the later 1990s . The rise in the UK was strongest in
the 1980s, the Thatcher period; New Zealand, also notorious for its
degree of deregulation, saw as big an increase in inequality as the
UK.10 Sweden, with a very egalitarian starting point, also saw a
substantial increase in inequality in the 1980s and 1990s. The USA
maintained its position as the most unequal country with inequality
increasing in both decades (see Table 7.3).
Table 7.3 also shows that there are still very large differences
between countries. The ratio of incomes 10% from the top to 10%
from the bottom of the distribution is nearly twice as high in the
USA compared to the most egalitarian Scandinavian countries. The
90 : 10 ratio is also about twice as high in Mexico as in the USA. So
you could say that the difference in income inequality between the
USA and Scandinavia is broadly comparable to the difference
between Mexico and the USA. Given that most people would regard
Mexico as massively more unequal than the USA, the fact that
this difference is comparable to the difference between the USA
and Scandinavia underlines that even within the rich countries
differences in inequality are very large indeed.11
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
169
The idea of a ‘race to the bottom’ is that those at the top tend to fall
fastest as they have further to go. However the increase in inequality
has been noticeably greater in the inegalitarian liberal economies
than in Northern Europe. Thus, although the more redistributive
countries have been unable always to preserve the rather low levels
of income inequality achieved by the end of the 1970s, the subsequent rise has been generally fairly modest and differences across
countries are as large as ever.
Table 7.3 Income Inequality: OECD Countries, 1980–2000
Ratio of post-tax incomes at 10%
from top of the distribution to
incomes 10% from bottom
c.1980
c.2000
France
Germany
Denmark
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
3.5
3.1
2.8
2.4
3.5
4.7
3.4
3.3
2.7
3.0
4.6
5.4
OECD mean
OECD std. dev.
3.4
0.8
3.7
0.8
North Europe
Liberal economies
2.9
3.9
3.1
4.5
Source: Luxemburg Income Survey. See Data Appendix.
The increase in wage inequality, particularly in the top half of the
pay distribution, was discussed in Chapter 5. Another important
influence on inequality at the bottom end of the distribution is the
proportion of workers with low pay. In the mid-1990s 20–25% of
workers in the UK, Canada and USA were earning less than 65% of
median earnings, whereas in Scandinavia and Belgium the proportion was 5–8%. These differences are systematically related to the
institutions of the labour markets. There is a robust correlation
between earnings inequality and the decentralization of wage bargaining.12 Lack of work has obviously also been a reason for poverty;
there is a rather close relation between the proportion of the working
age population without work and the proportion who are poor in
170
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
terms of their market incomes. Relatively generous unemployment
benefits counteract this influence.
Another contributory factor to rising inequality has been a rise in
the importance of property incomes in the form of dividends and
interest. The rise in interest rates in the early 1980s, the boom in
dividends in the 1990s as companies were under increased pressure
to distribute more of their income to shareholders and finally
increased profitability in a number of countries, have combined to
make property incomes rather buoyant across most countries, with
Japan a notable exception. The ratio of property income (dividends,
interest and rent) to labour income (wages and self-employment
income) rose from about 15% in the USA in 1979 to 18% in 2002 and
from 7% to 12% in France.13 Scandinavian countries have low shares
of property incomes (about 8% in Norway and Finland on this
measure). The true rise was certainly greater than is suggested by
these statistics because inflation was much higher in 1979. Thus
much of the money interest included in these figures was not real
interest in 1979 in the sense of a real return in excess of inflation. By
2002 inflation was very low and most interest payments represented
a real return.
Even though property incomes are more widely spread through the
population in rich countries than was the case 50 years ago, they are
still disproportionately held by top income groups. On average in the
rich OECD countries the top one-fifth of the population received
53% of property income compared to 40% of earnings. Thus an
increase in share of property incomes contributed to rising income
inequality.14
Poverty and the Tax and Benefit System
Of particular concern within the income distribution is the extent of
poverty. To make international comparisons, this is conventionally
measured by the proportion of people with incomes (on a household
basis adjusted for family size) which are less than a half the country’s
median income (see Table 7.4 below)
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
171
The liberal countries have larger proportions of their populations
in poverty than the North European countries. Poverty rates are
twice as high in the UK and Canada as they are in the Scandinavian
countries and roughly three times as high in the USA. The fact that
Finnish poverty was about one-third the US level in 2000 brings out
the difference clearly, since the USA was at the end of a strong boom
whilst Finland had very high unemployment. New Zealand and the
UK had the biggest increases in numbers in poverty between the
mid-1980s and 2000, contributing to a modest rise in the OECD
total.
Table 7.4 Poverty and Impact of the Benefit and Tax System, 2000
USA
UK
Canada
Australia
The Netherlands
Germany
Belgium
France
Sweden
Finland
Percentage of
population in
poverty, 2000 or late
1990s
Tax/benefits effect
in reducing
poverty
(% fall in
numbers)
Tax/benefits effect
in reducing
inequality
(% fall in Gini)
17.0
12.3
11.9
11.2
8.9
8.2
7.9
7
6.4
5.4
⫺25
⫺61
⫺52
⫺55
⫺59
⫺71
⫺75
⫺70
⫺78
⫺70
⫺18
⫺24
⫺24
⫺31
⫺40
⫺42
⫺48
⫺41
⫺42
⫺40
Sources: Smeeding (2004); Forster and d’Ercole (2005). See Data Appendix.
The tax and benefit system plays a major role in accounting for
differences in poverty rates, with many North European economies
deploying benefits to offset ‘market poverty’15 by around threequarters; in the USA only one-quarter of those left poor by the
market are taken out of poverty by tax and benefits (Table 7.4, second
column) Sweden and Germany apparently had considerably higher
market poverty rates than the USA in 2000, but much lower postbenefit poverty rates since their benefit systems are so much more
extensive and generous.
172
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
The final column shows the impact of taxation and benefits on
income inequality as a whole as measured by the widely used Gini
coefficient which reflects inequality across the whole income distribution. Tax and benefit systems achieve a much greater degree of
redistribution in Northern Europe than in the liberal economies. It
would be imagined that countries with a flat rate system of benefits,
like the UK where state pensions or unemployment benefits are
the same for everybody, would have generated more equality than
countries like Sweden where such benefits are related to previous
earnings. The opposite is the case however reflecting what has been
termed the ‘paradox of redistribution’. ‘The more we target benefits
at the poor and the more we are concerned with creating equality
via public transfers, the less likely we are to reduce poverty and
inequality’ (Korpi and Palme 1998: 681). The explanation is that
middle-class support for the system of benefits is much stronger
when the system meets their own aspirations. For example, flat rate
state pensions leads to widespread dependence on private schemes
by middle income receivers and, as in the UK, the state pension is
likely to erode to became a residual safety net at a pitiful level. The
welfare state clearly has to adjust to the situation where many more
people have some level of financial independence. In many OECD
countries two-thirds or more of households own their own house
and even in Germany, a laggard in this respect, home ownership is
expected to rise from 40% to around 60% as enormous numbers of
apartments are sold off by the companies which own them.16
Despite the pressures on the welfare state the impact of the
tax/benefit systems in reducing inequality has remained pretty
stable in the developed economies over the past 20 years. Ginis for
the market income of working age households were generally
reduced by similar proportions at the end of the 1990s as in the
early 1980s. As Kenworthy and Pontusson (2004: 24) note, ‘Although
almost all European countries introduced some cutbacks in the
generosity of various transfer programs in the 1980s and 1990s, in
most instances they were relatively minor.’ Huber and Stephens
(2001: 306) come to a similar conclusion: ‘Not only have the cuts
in entitlements and services in all but a few cases been modest, the
achievements of the welfare state in terms of income equalisation
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
173
and poverty reduction have been largely preserved, despite the
increases in unemployment’. They emphasize, however, that major
welfare state retrenchments in the UK, under Mrs Thatcher, and in
New Zealand were associated with big increases in inequality.
Another example of substantial cutbacks is Japan where the proportion of an individual’s medical expenses met by state medical insurance was cut from 90% to 70% over the period 1997–2003.17
Many would regard income inequality as especially objectionable
if it is passed on within families, since an individual’s position in the
social and economic rankings should be as independent as possible
of family circumstances. It is economically inefficient, as well as
unfair on the individuals concerned, for talent to be wasted. Equality
of opportunity has became a particular focus for politicians like
Tony Blair who are reluctant to campaign for greater equality of
outcomes for fear of losing middle-class support. However it is
highly likely that unequal outcomes in the form of child poverty,
lack of child care and poor schools, tend to reproduce themselves
through the generations. Moreover the proportion of children living
in poor families (average income less than half the median) is
frequently higher than the proportions of the poor in the whole
population as shown in Table 7.4. Thus in the USA around 22% of
children were reckoned to be in poverty in 2000, some 16% in Italy,
the UK, Ireland and New Zealand but only 2–4% in the Scandinavian
countries.18
Position in the income distribution is just one measure of outcome and a far from perfect indicator of the extent to which a person
has been able to use their talents in the most satisfying way.
However being stuck in the lower reaches of the income distribution, especially in the more unequal societies, clearly imposes
multiple disadvantages. Thus the extent to which position in the
income distribution is passed on from parents to children is significant. As an example of the effects of family circumstances, in the UK
men whose parental income had been in the bottom quarter of the
income distribution were four times as likely themselves to be in the
bottom quarter than the top quarter in 2000. Those with parental
income in the top quarter were twice as likely to be in the top quarter
themselves as in the bottom quarter.
174
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
A very careful attempt to compile internationally comparable
data of the extent to which a father’s position in the income hierarchy is transmitted to sons suggests the following. If father A earns
double father B, in the USA A’s son would tend to earn about 29%
more than B’s son, whereas in Scandinavian countries the difference
would be about 14%. This implies there is far less mobility in the
USA than in Scandinavia. As Figure 7.1 shows, Germany and Canada
are much closer to Scandinavia than to the USA.19 Probably the most
dramatic finding is the severe decline in social mobility between
people in the UK who were 30 at the end of the 1980s as compared
with those who were 30 in 2000. One obvious difference between the
two groups is that the former group experienced the conditions of the
1960s when children, whereas the latter group were still young in
the 1980s. Between these two periods the influences limiting social
mobility in the UK seem to have become much stronger. Broadly,
social mobility in the UK seems to have fallen from North European
to something close to US levels.
Esping-Andersen (2004) concludes from his review of the
literature that, whilst minimizing child poverty through income
support plays a role in improving the chances for low income
children, it is far less important than public social service provision. He notes that ‘Scandinavian day care is basically of uniform,
0.3
0.2
0.1
ina
via
Sc
an
d
na
da
Ca
Ge
rm
an
y
A
US
UK
0
Fig. 7.1. Correlation between Sons’ and Fathers’ Incomes, 2000
Source: Blanden et al. (2005). See Data Appendix.
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
175
high pedagogical standards, meaning that children from disadvantaged families will benefit disproportionately. Day care in the
United States is of extremely uneven quality, and children from
disadvantaged families are concentrated at the low end’ (EspingAndersen 2004: 208).
The Size and Persistence of Differences
This chapter has briefly reviewed evidence on differences across
the most developed economies in welfare state spending, in income
inequality, in tax systems, in poverty levels and in social mobility.
Two conclusions stand out. Despite the pressures on welfare state
financing, the differences in distributive patterns between these
economies are very large indeed, along almost every dimension
considered here. Moreover the ranking of countries is pretty consistent. The Scandinavian countries show up as the most egalitarian
in almost every respect, with the liberal economies, above all the
UK and USA, at the other end of the scale and Continental Europe
scattered between. So relatively generous welfare states, high
benefits and well-funded social services combine with low wage
inequality and a lesser importance for property income to generate
low levels of income inequality and poverty and life chances less
dependent on a child’s family circumstances.
The second conclusion is that although there have been cuts in
some aspects of the welfare state and increases in income inequality,
these shifts have not swept away the more egalitarian patterns of
distribution. The shift towards greater inequality has in fact been
strongest in the more inegalitarian economies. Thus far there seems
no clear tendency for the differences between countries to be eroded
by a scramble to the bottom. Differences between patterns of distribution have actually become greater. This shows that, even with
capitalism off the leash, it has still been possible to significantly
affect the most fundamental of all economic outcomes—who gets
what? The final section of this chapter, and of the book, considers
whether this can continue to be the case.
176
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
Will Egalitarianism Survive?
Previous chapters have suggested that there is a prospect of real
incomes growing rather slowly in the rich countries over the
medium term as a result of structural change, slower population
growth, environmental constraints and the unprecedented problems
of adjustment if China and India grow rapidly. Moreover the latter
trend will also tend to shift the distribution of income further away
from wages and towards profits.
Slow growth tends to make redistribution more difficult since it
involves stagnation or even cuts in the real incomes of the groups
paying for the redistribution. If, in addition, profits rise faster than
wages then it would be highly desirable to claw back some of the
higher profits through international agreements on corporation tax
rates and an assault on the inexcusable scandal of tax havens. Such
agreements are particularly tricky as they require all or almost all
of the major economies to sign up.20 Realistically most revenue for
redistribution will have to continue to come from tax on wage and
salary earners though this may be done in a more or less progressive way.
There is one further aspect of globalization which might reduce
support for the welfare state. Sinn (2002: 11) suggests that migration
of groups particularly likely to be welfare recipients into generous
welfare states will slowly force a progressive scaling back of such
generosity to avoid being welfare magnets—a ‘successive dismantling of the European welfare state is the likely outcome’. Such fears
are probably much exaggerated, but the impact of migration on
welfare may have longer-term significance. One study detected a
tendency for countries with a larger proportion of foreign-born
residents to have smaller redistributive transfers suggesting that
‘more open (less homogeneous) societies are willing to spend less on
social goods’ (Schwarbish et al. 2004: 29). In similar vein Alesina
et al. conclude from an international study of welfare states:
Racial fragmentation in the United States and the disproportionate representation of ethnic minorities amongst the poor clearly played a major role
in limiting redistribution, and indeed racial cleavages seem to serve as a
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
177
barrier to redistribution throughout the world. This history of American
redistribution makes it quite clear that hostility to welfare derives in part
from the fact that welfare spending in the United States goes disproportionately to minorities. (2001: 247)
Patterns such as these are employed by some people to buttress the
idea that a redistributive welfare state is simply incompatible with
an open multi-ethnic society. But, as I have argued throughout this
chapter, the erosion of egalitarianism is not an irresistible consequence of any of the economic changes taking place in the world,
large though these changes are. The welfare state was created by
political action and has been defended by political action under the
already difficult circumstances of the past three decades. Neither the
industrialization of Asia nor a rising volume of migration means that
political action to defend and expand the welfare state is now futile.
Of course it will require plenty of ingenuity to develop the new
forms of solidarity and political mobilization necessary to sustain
the more global conception of egalitarianism appropriate to today.
Fortunately there is good evidence that popular support for
egalitarianism is very much alive. The OECD reports results from
the International Social Science Programme that in every OECD
country surveyed more than 60% of respondents agreed with the
statement that ‘differences in income are too large’ in the country in
which they lived, with proportions ranging from over 60% in the
USA to nearly 90% in Spain, Italy and France and 75–80% in
Germany and the UK. Only in the USA do substantially less than
half the respondents agree or strongly agree with the statement that
‘it is the responsibility of governments to reduce inequalities’ and in
the UK the number is over 60%. Swedes and Norwegians believed in
the early 1990s that a doctor should be paid about twice as much as
an unskilled factory worker and the chairman of a large national
company should earn just less than 2.5 times; in the USA legitimate
income differences were felt to be six times an unskilled worker’s
pay for doctors and 11 times for CEOs.21 Ideology and political
history clearly engender big differences in attitudes to and patterns
of distribution. The adverse shifts in income distribution which
have occurred cannot be blamed as simply the inevitable, natural
result of market forces; politics are as important as ever.
178
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
Going for Growth?
How the cake is divided up cannot be divorced from the issue of its
growth rate. No sooner had economic growth risen to prominence as
a central economic objective in the 1960s than sceptical voices were
raised. These stressed variously the costs of rising pollution and congestion and physical limitations to growth as natural resources were
depleted. But do we really benefit from growth in the volume of
production anyway?
Social surveys have for some time asked people how happy or
satisfied they are and comparisons of their answers over time suggest
a striking conclusion. Over the long term, levels of personally
reported well-being have not increased significantly despite the
substantial long-term rise in GDP per head. Thus for Japan ‘Between
1958 and 1991 its per capita income rose six fold. Nevertheless, the
Japanese people report a satisfaction with life which remains largely
unchanged’ (Frey and Stutzer 2002: 8). In the USA since 1945, and
with slower but still substantial growth, the average level of reported
happiness was broadly flat and the same appears true of the UK.
Although several European countries, especially Italy, show some
increase in average happiness since 1975, the rise is ‘small relative to
the huge increase in incomes’ (Layard 2005: 30).
The plot thickens because survey answers also show that, at a
particular point in time, those with higher incomes in a country
experience markedly higher levels of satisfaction than those with
lower incomes. This seems to imply that if incomes rise on average
so will average well-being.22 There are two types of explanation for
why this has not happened. It is very likely that my absolute level of
income may be less important to my feeling of well-being than my
income relative to those around me or to the average or to some other
reference group. In that case if all incomes rise broadly together
I would feel no better off once I had recognized that my relative
position had not improved. Alternatively some other trend could be
offsetting the effect of higher incomes.
In fact the pattern of economic growth itself may well be
having other detrimental effects on a number of central important
influences on our well-being. The US General Social Survey lists
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
179
financial situation as second most important contributor to reported
personal happiness, with family relationships first and work third.
Relationships may be put under additional strain by pressures for
more and more of a household’s time to be spent working, especially
in the USA where not only are there more and more households with
all adults working but also working hours have stopped falling. This
has led to what Juliet Schor (1992) termed ‘the insidious cycle of work
and spend’. Moreover it appears that in a number of countries including the UK, Germany and possibly the USA job satisfaction, as
revealed in surveys, has tended to decline over the last 30 years. This
seems surprising given the increasing skill level in the labour force,
which might be supposed to make work more interesting. However
many jobs for qualified workers involve a frustratingly low utilization of these skills, whilst insistent demands for greater ‘flexibility’ at
work can lead to low job satisfaction and feelings of personal insecurity as Richard Sennett has vividly documented. Being out of work is
far worse, of course, leading to a reduction in reported well-being
that is far greater than can be accounted for simply by the loss of
income.23
There are real debates about how to interpret such survey-based
evidence. However, taken at face value, it does support the idea that
in the rich countries workers/consumers are on a treadmill where
they have to run to avoid falling behind. We would all benefit if we
agreed to strive less vigorously for higher consumption, but very few
of us dare for fear of falling behind the Joneses.
Further, it has been suggested that declining attachment to
communities and jobs and the increasing influence of the media
encourages comparisons with the rich and famous rather than those
around us.24 Since the majority are falling increasingly behind those
at the top in many countries, as documented in earlier chapters, such
comparisons must yield increasing dissatisfaction. They may also
explain the extraordinary Time/CNN poll finding in 2000 that 39%
of Americans believe that they are either in the wealthiest 1% or will
be there ‘soon’.25
The fundamental point, however, is that the benefits from higher
productivity per hour worked, which capitalism seems capable
of continuing to deliver, offers society a menu of choices. Higher
180
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
output per head of the population is one option; reducing hours of
work is another. As we have seen, the USA opted for growing material living standards, though these have mainly accrued to the best off
in recent decades. In Europe working time per person has continued
to decline and a recent study finds a ‘negative relationship between
hours worked across countries and life satisfaction’ (Alesina et al.
2005: 30). Noting that the 1948 US standard of living could be reproduced in less than half the working time Schor (1992: 2) posed the
issue in an arresting way: ‘. . . imagine this: every worker in the
United States could now be taking off every other year from work,
with pay.’
A reorientation of priorities away from growth would require a
major shift for most of the left. Twentieth-century socialist thinking
claimed that common ownership would improve material living
standards more rapidly, as well as distributing-them more fairly,
than crisis-prone capitalism. But the longer-term objective of socialism was always to facilitate the development of people’s lives in
a more fulfilling direction. Is it possible to make serious moves
in this direction even within what is still a predominantly capitalist
economy?
The idea that economic growth could provide the material basis
for a society with very different priorities has not been confined
to socialists. Keynes in his remarkable discussion of Europe before
the 1914–18 war in The Economic Consequences of the Peace speculated that with continued economic growth ‘perhaps a day might
come when there would at last be enough to go round, and when
posterity could enter into the enjoyment of our labours. In that day
overwork, overcrowding and underfeeding would come to an end
and men, secure of the comforts and necessities of life, could proceed
to the nobler exercises of the faculties’ (Keynes 1919: 18). GDP per
head in the UK is more than four times as high as when Keynes was
writing. Has capitalism, having developed the productive potential
of the rich countries to a degree unimaginable a century ago, laid the
basis for a new balance between work and other activities? The most
innovative policy suggestion to encourage moves in this direction is
the proposal for a Basic Income.
Under a Basic Income scheme each person would receive a
regular and unconditional cash grant from the state. It would be
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
181
unconditional in the sense of being received by everyone irrespective of other income or whether they were in work or not, and it could
be spent on whatever the recipient wished. At one level it would
replace many means-tested benefits which are becoming an increasingly important feature of some welfare states as governments
strive to both reduce poverty and restrain social security budgets.
Means-tested benefits have very well-known problems. First, takeup amongst those in need and eligible is often low as a result of the
stigma attached to claiming and the complexity of so doing.
Secondly, means-tested benefits impose very high effective rates of
taxation as a claimant has a proportion of these benefits withdrawn
as her/his income rises, as well as paying income tax and social
security contributions. So Basic Income would involve a big saving
in costs of administering social security and would tend to increase
the incentive for those on existing benefits to take paid work, especially part-time work, which would at present leave them stuck in
the ‘unemployment trap’ of benefit withdrawal. Certainly marginal
tax rates across the board would have to increase to pay for Basic
Income, but for the low-paid the fact that they were no longer losing
benefits would more than compensate.26 Even if it was introduced
at a very modest level so that the unemployed for example still
received an extra benefit whilst out of work, the fact that they would
still receive the basic income if they took a job would mean they
gained more from working for any job above a few hours a week.
Viewed in this light Basic Income would involve a recasting of
elements of the welfare state in an egalitarian direction which would
be extremely worthwhile. This is especially the case in the current
context where supporters of the welfare state have been continually
on the defensive trying, with some success as we have seen, to preserve its egalitarian effects. However to really contribute to an alternative vision the effects of the scheme must extend beyond those
currently dependent on state benefits. Basic Income does indeed
hold out the possibility of a much more fundamental reorientation
of priorities for society as a whole.
Under capitalism work does not have to involve the satisfaction of
some intrinsic need and for many people is mainly instrumental.
‘Working to live’ was expressed by a US automobile worker who,
being absent from work most Mondays, explained to his exasperated
182
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
manager that he worked for only four days a week ‘Because I can’t
make a living working three days’ (quoted Halberstam 1987: 495).
Lack of any intrinsic interest in the work applies to many, but by no
means all, low-paid jobs. Conversely professional jobs may be more
varied and interesting but as noted earlier they can still engender
alienating insecurities, especially in workplaces where the search for
flexibility is in full swing. Provided Basic Income could be set at a reasonable level it would give workers, especially the low-paid, greater
bargaining power in relation to their employers as they would have a
financial cushion against the consequences of the sack or of quitting
voluntarily in order to find more rewarding work. More
fundamentally it would allow people the economic security to spend
less time working for pay, perhaps none for the few with very austere
needs, and more time for pursuing more intrinsically satisfying activities. This could include emulators of J. K. Rowling writing children’s
stories, political activists, rock musicians honing up their guitar
technique, computer buffs contributing on line to the development of
freely available ‘open source’ computer programs (Kogut and Metiu
2001), students, people looking after children or gardening.
Such a scheme invites two fundamental questions. Is Basic
Income feasible politically, especially if those receiving it were
absolutely free to do what they liked with all their time? Would
people accept that even surfers, to borrow a famous example, should
receive Basic Income and in effect live off the work of others? Full
unconditionality from the outset may be a step too far. To justify
Basic Income even at a very modest level it might be necessary to
limit its distribution somewhat. Atkinson (1996) has proposed a
‘Participation Income’ which could cover everybody involved in a
very wide range of paid work, household, retirement, educational
and voluntary activities, that is the great majority of the population.
This would recognize the very wide range of activities, not limited to
paid work, which contribute to society. Surfers would then have to
work or study part time in order to receive the payment. Eventually
it could very well turn out to be more trouble and expense to exclude
the fairly small minority of people who would not qualify for the
Participation Income—full Basic Income would then be implemented as an administrative matter.
WELFARE AND INCOME INEQUALITY
183
At first sight Basic Income seems to violate the ‘paradox of redistribution’ noted above whereby flat rate benefits tend to achieve less
effective redistribution than benefits which rise with incomes at work
and thus command the support of middle income earners. Obviously a
flat rate benefit is of less significance the higher up you are in the
income scale. However the option-expanding character of the Basic
Income means that it fulfils a very different function from many existing state benefits. Even reasonably well-off couples, both of whom
work, at first sight a group who have much to lose from the higher
taxation to fund the Basic Income, could find that receiving it made it
easier for one of them to work part time at certain stages in their lives.
Of course many of the other dilemmas with existing welfare arrangements would still have to be confronted, such as how long somebody
would need to live in a country to receive Basic Income. Clearly it is no
magic wand with which to solve all society’s problems.
Most fundamentally, however, for a book about the economy, where
will the money come from? Alongside the personally rewarding activities which may be fostered by Basic Income, will there be enough
work done to produce the goods and services which fulfil basic needs?
If it relieves the necessity for the unskilled to work such long hours and
if the highly qualified are deterred from overexerting themselves by
the high tax rates to pay for the scheme, might not the system implode
as insufficient time was devoted to conventional production? For
reasons of political acceptability, Basic Income would probably have to
be introduced at a relatively austere level. This would have modest
effects on the labour supply as most people would still want to spend
plenty of effort on formal sector activities. Whilst some low-paid
workers would choose to work less, others, at presently caught in
unemployment or poverty traps, would work more. But the fundamental point is that if the scheme discourages moderately the total
amount of formal sector work, as well as sharing it out more equally,
then these effects are wholly to the good. For many formal sector jobs
as presently constituted are loaded with severe ‘negative externalities’.
They crowd out time for personal relationships and other activities
which people find intrinsically satisfying, in contrast to the alienating
aspects of much formal sector work, and much of the consumption
they finance imposes a heavy toll on the environment.
Data appendix
Figure 1.1 Strikes: Days on Strike per 1,000
Industrial Workers
Series is five-year moving average of median annual strike rate for the 16
OECD countries. Note that the long run of data is only available for
industrial workers excluding utilities for most countries, but including
transport and communication up to 1988. Thus services and notably
most public sector workers are not included. The median is used rather
than the mean, which is heavily influenced by extreme values (such
as May 1968).
Source: Labour Market Trends, April 2005, p. 163 and earlier articles in the series.
Figure 1.2 Inflation and Real Wage Increases
Inflation is measured by change in consumer price.
Real wage is index of wage earnings, with varying definitions across
countries, deflated by consumer price index, five-year moving average of
median changes for 13 OECD countries.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics (IFS) website, plus early data from
annual volumes.
Figure 1.3 Manufacturing Gross Profit Share
Gross profits adjusted for self-employment incomes as share of gross value
added. Figure shows unweighted average for 15 OECD counties, linked on
to the series for the unweighted average for ten (including all G7) countries
prior to 1970.
Sources: Author’s calculations from OECD STAN Database 2003 edition, supplemented with national account sources and linked to data from Glyn (1997 ) for years
before 1970.
DATA APPENDIX
185
Figure 1.4 Real Commodity Prices
Real oil price is crude petroleum price deflated by US consumer prices.
Real non-energy commodity prices are average of food, agricultural raw
materials and metals price indices deflated by US consumer prices.
Source: IFS International Financial Statistics website.
Figure 1.5 Consumer Prices in Germany, and Italy
relative to USA
Consumer price index for Germany, Italy divided by index for USA.
Source: IFS International Financial Statistics website.
Figure 1.6 Mark and Lira Exchange Rates versus Dollar
Deutschemarks and Lira per US dollar.
Source: IFS International Financial Statistics website.
Figure 1.7 Growth in Labour Productivity, Whole Economy
Output per hour worked.
Source: Groningen Growth and Development Centre and The Conference Board,
Total Economy Database, January 2005, http://www.ggdc.net.
Figure 1.8 OECD Government Expenditure
Total government spending on goods and services and transfers as a
percentage of GDP at current prices.
Source: OECD National Accounts website and OECD, Economic Outlook series for
total government outlays, linked back from 1970 to series calculated from OECD
National Accounts for total government spending excluding interest and transfers
for G7 countries.
Figure 1.9 Share Prices compared to Average Wages
Index of share prices divided by index of average earnings and expressed as
an index with 2000 ⫽ 1; average of 10 countries.
Source: Share price and wage earnings series from IMF International Financial
Statistics database.
186
DATA APPENDIX
Figure 2.1 Unemployment Rates
Unemployment as a percentage of the labour force.
Source: OECD standardized unemployment rates from Economic Outlook for
1985–2003, linked to IMF International Financial Statistics data for earlier
years. The series for Europe is an unweighted average of 15 countries whilst the
Eurozone series is weighted (by labour force); since the bigger countries had higher
unemployment this accounts for about 1.5 percentage points of the excess of
Eurozone unemployment over the series for Europe shown here.
Figure 2.2 US Short-Term Interest Rates
Nominal interest rate is rate on Treasury Bills. Real rate is nominal rate
minus inflation rate (consumer prices).
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.
Figure 2.3 Long-term Real Interest Rates
Nominal yield on long-term government bonds less the inflation rate
(consumer prices).
Source: Rowthorn (1995, table 3), updated from IMF, International Financial
Statistics, and OECD, Economic Outlook.
Figure 2.4 Unemployment and Strikes
Strikes refers to number of days lost per 1,000 industrial workers; source as
for Figure 1.1. Unemployment rates are OECD standardized series from
OECD, Economic Outlook.
Figure 2.5 Structural Unemployment and
Unemployment Benefits
Structural unemployment rates are OECD estimates of NAIRU in OECD,
Economic Outlook.
Unemployment Benefits are OECD calculations of net replacement ratio
(benefits after tax as percentage of average earnings after tax) from OECD
Benefit Replacement Ratio Database.
The net replacement ratio is preferable to the gross measure used in
Table 2.1 since it takes account of post-tax income and any taxation falling
on benefits.
DATA APPENDIX
187
Figure 3.1 US Financial Sector Corporate Profits
Corporate profit is return to equity owners, after payments of interest, depreciation (capital consumption) and inventory valuation adjustment, but
before tax. Measure is ratio of financial sector profits to non-financial sector
profits. Profits from financial activities are underestimated by these figures
for profits of financial companies since some non-financial corporations
have significant financial operations; however this hardly affects the trend.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), National Income and Product
Accounts (NIPA), table 1.14 (line 11–27)/line 27. http://www.bea.gov/bea/dn/
nipaweb/TableView.
Figure 3.2 Real Exchange Rates
The real exchange rate is measured by relative unit labour cost (RULC),
which includes both the impact of exchange rates and relative changes in
wages and labour productivity. Comparison is with dollar wage cost
changes in trading partners. A rise in the index represents real appreciation.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.
Figure 4.1 Manufacturing Productivity Relative to USA
The series is for output per hour worked
Source: The relative productivity levels come from Groningen Growth and
Development Centre, ICOP Database 1987 Benchmark (for Japan), 1997 Benchmark
(for Europe), http://www.ggdc.net; linked to US Bureau of Labor Statistics hourly
labour productivity series for Japan (from 1987) and for Europe from 2001 http://
www.bls.gov/fls/prodsupptabletoc.htm
Figure 4.2 US$ Exchange Rate: Nominal and Real
The nominal exchange rate measures the US dollar against currencies of
trading partners. The real exchange rate is measured by relative unit labour
cost (see Fig. 3.2).
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.
Figure 4.3 US Current Account and Domestic Investment
Current account of the balance of payments and net non-residential fixed
investment both as percentage of GDP at current prices.
Source: BEA, International Transactions, table 1 and NIPA, tables 1.1.5, 5.2.5.
188
DATA APPENDIX
Figure 4.4 Shares of World Output
Output is GDP at Purchasing Power Party (PPP) exchange rates (Maddison’s
version).
Source: Calculated from Maddison (2001) database. Data is extended to 2004 from
IMF World Economic Outlook Database. OECD refers to ‘old’ OECD (i.e. excluding
Korea, Mexico etc.).
Figure 4.5 Catch-up to USA in Asia—Per Capita GDP
GDP at PPP per head of the population divided by US figure for the year.
Source: Calculated from Maddison (2001) database.
Figure 4.6 Shares of World Commodity Exports
Commonly exports excludes services.
Source: World Trade Organization (WTO), International Trade Statistics, 2004; table II.2.
Figure 4.7 Manufacturing Wages during Catch-Up
Hourly dollar compensation of manufacturing workers.
Source: Bureau of Labour Statistics (BLS) series for http://www.ftp.bls.gov/pub/
special.requests/ForeignLabor/prodsuppt08.txt
China’s wages estimated from Statistical Yearbook series for annual manufacturing earnings in non-state enterprises divided by 2,500 to give an hourly wage and
deflated by exchange rate for yuan from IMF International Financial Statistics to put
into dollar terms.
Figure 4.8 Trade as a percentage of GDP (average of imports
and exports)
These series are the Penn tables current price openness indicators
(exports ⫹ imports at current prices as percentage of GDP, all at PPP prices)
divided by 2. http://www.pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php_site/pwt61_form.php
Figure 5.1 Men’s Employment Rate in Industry
Employment rate is ratio of employment to population of working
age, 15–64.
Europe is average of France, Germany, Netherlands, Spain and the UK.
Source: OECD, Labour Force Statistics.
DATA APPENDIX
189
Figure 5.2 Women’s Employment Rate in Services
As for Figure 5.1
Figure 5.3 Employment Rates, Men and Women
As for Figure 5.1.
Figure 5.4 Employment Rate Changes by Skill Groups
Low skilled refers to lowest quartile by educational qualification, middle
skilled refers to average of second and third quartiles. Employment rate is
ratio of employment to population of working age.
Source: Glyn (2001, table 3). Europe refers to median average annual percentage
change for 11 countries for various periods spanning 1979 and 2001.
Figure 5.5 Unemployment Benefits: Ratio to Earnings
Liberal economies comprise Australia, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand, the
UK and the USA. Europe is the mean of 13 Continental countries.
Source: Calculated from OECD’s pre-tax replacement rate database; refers to first
year of unemployment.
Figure 5.6 Wage Differentials
Top/middle refers to ratio of earnings at 90th percentile (10% from top of
pay distribution) to median (half-way down).
Middle/bottom refers to ratio of earnings at median to 10th percentile
(10% from bottom).
Country groups are given in the text.
Source: Calculated from the OECD’s pay dispersion database. A small amount of
interpolation for missing years was necessary. These calculations involve taking
some liberties with the data, since OECD warns against cross-country comparisons
due to different coverage across countries. The pay distributions exclude part-time
workers although they are typically for hourly earnings. The series shown in the
figure are mean values for the groups of countries and give a broad picture of
developments.
Figure 5.7 Minimum Wages—Ratio to Average Pay
Series for OECD refers to 9 countries.
Source: Calculated from OECD, Minimum Wage Database.
190
DATA APPENDIX
Figure 5.8 Trade Union Membership as a
percentage of employees
Liberal economies refers to median membership for six countries; Europe
refers to 10 countries and excludes Germany. Series for Germany includes
former GDR from 1991.
Source: OECD, Trade Union Membership database linked to earlier series from
Nickell–Nunziata database as used in Baker et al. (2005).
Figure 6.1 Growth of Output per Head of the Population
Europe refers to average of 16 countries, OECD to average of 21 countries.
Source: Groningen Growth and Development Centre and the Conference Board:
The Total Economy Database, http://www.ggdc.net.
Figure 6.2 Contributions to US GDP Growth: Three Long Expansions
Source: BEA NIPA, tables 1.12, 3.1.
Figure 6.3 US Capital Stock Growth: Private Business
Series is for real net capital stock; private business covers corporations and
unincorporated enterprises.
Source: BEA Fixed Asset, table 4.2.
Figure 6.4 US Profit Rates: Non-financial Corporations
Profits expressed as percentage of net capital stock.
Pre-tax profits are operating surplus, calculated after capital consumption
and inventory valuation adjustment (BEA NIPA, table 1.14, line 24) less
business transfers (line 26). Post-tax profits subtract taxes on corporate
income (line 28).
Net capital stock is average of beginning and end year net stock of fixed
assets at current prices (Fixed Asset tables 4.1, line 28) plus inventories.
Non-financial corporations (NFC) inventories estimated as same percentage of non-farm inventories as NFC fixed capital stock is of non-farm business capital stock (NIPA, table 5.5.7A, line 3).
Figure 6.5 Japan Profit Rates: Non-financial Corporations
Three profit rates are shown. The standard series is profits expressed as percentage of net reproducible capital stock (fixed assets and inventories).
DATA APPENDIX
191
Second series adds value of land in with capital stock. Third series includes
capital gains and losses on land (estimated as change in land values in
balance sheets); this series is shown as a three-year moving average centred
in year in question because of sharp year to year fluctuations. To the extent
that NFCs were buying land from other sectors, then capital gains are
overestimated. It seems unlikely that such effects were very big.
Sources: Net operating surplus from Operating Account of Private NFCs, Annual
Report on National Accounts, table 1.2.(2); stock of net fixed assets, inventories and
land from (table 2.2.1(a). The profit rate on the reproducible capital series was linked
back from 1970 to the business net profit rate series in Armstrong et al. (1991, table A2).
Figure 6.6 Europe Net Profit Rates: Non-financial Sector
UK Office of National Statistics series for net rate of return for private nonfinancial companies, http://www.statistics.gov.uk/statbase/tsdtables1.asp?
vlnk ⫽ prof (series LRWW), linked back from 1965 to Armstrong et al. (1991,
table A2).
Germany Net operating surplus, with adjustment for self-employment
incomes, of non-agricultural business as a percentage of net capital
stock. Source: German National Accounts as described in Armstrong et al.
(1991, data appendix). Series break in 1991 represents combined effects of
unification (which appear to be rather small) plus a new system of national
accounts which accounts for most of the lower profit rate in the new
series, for unexplained reasons. Inventories have to be estimated in the
new system and some parts of the services sector are excluded.
Italy Business sector profit rate taken directly from Torrini (2005).
Figure 7.1 Correlation between Sons’ and Fathers’ Incomes
The measure is the ‘intergenerational partial correlation’ between fathers’
and sons’ incomes. Scandinavia is the average of estimates for Denmark,
Finland, Norway and Sweden.
Source: Blanden et al. (2005, table 2).
Table 1.1 Labour Market Trends
Employment Protection is an index of employment protection stringeney
from the Nickell–Nunziata database.
Sources: Unemployment benefit, Union membership and unemployment rate as for
figures 5.8, 5.5, and 2.1.
192
DATA APPENDIX
Table 2.1 Budget Deficits
General government budget balance as a percentage of GDP at current
prices.
Sources: OECD, National Accounts, Historical Statistics, Economic Outlook.
Table 2.2 Production and Incomes in UK Utilities
Sector covers gas, electricity and water. Labour productivity is output per
worker. Real wages and real profits are calculated by deflating money wages
and money profits by the consumer price deflator.
Source: National Accounts data from Office of National Statistics website.
M. O’Mahoney series for employment linked to ONS workforce employees.
Table 4.1 Financing the US Balance of Payments Deficit
Calculated from BEA Balance of Payments table 1. Lines 76, (51⫹64),
(50⫹63⫺51⫺64), 56.
Table 4.2 Capital Accumulation: Growth Rates of Fixed Capital Stock
Calculated from background data for Bosworth and Collins (2003), kindly
supplied by Susan M. Collins, except series for USA, Europe and Japan from
OECD, Economic Outlook, table 22 database, business capital stock.
Europe data for 1960s and 1970 s are the unweighted average growth rates
for 10 countries.
Table 4.3 China’s Exports
Calculated from WTO, International Trade Statistics, 2004; table II.3–5,
III.7.5, IV.26.
Table 4.4 Import Penetration of Domestic Markets for Manufactures
Import penetration is measured by value of imports as a percentage of apparent consumption (production plus imports less exports).
Data for Europe are simple averages of the UK, Germany, France and Italy
Sources: 1913–63: Batchelor et al. (1980, table 3.3); 1974–2001: author’s calculations
from OECD, Stan Database, 1998 and 2004 editions. There are minor breaks in the
series after 1950 and after 1963 and for Germany after 1989. The figure for imports
from the South (comprising all sources other than Western Europe, North America,
Japan and Australia/New Zealand) are derived from total imports for 2001 and share
DATA APPENDIX
193
of the South in manufactured imports in 2003 from WTO International Trade,
table IV.25.
Table 4.5 Foreign Direct Investment Flows
Source: UNCTAD (2004, annex table B.5).
Table 6.1 Labour Productivity Growth in Business Sector
Source: Calculated from OECD, Economic Outlook, June 2004, annex table 12.
Table 6.2 Global Growth Volatility
The measure of volatility is calculated as the average across countries
of growth volatility within each country, with the latter measured by the
standard deviation of the country’s real growth rate.
Source: Martin and Rowthorn (2004, table 6).
Table 7.1 Corporation Tax Rates: OECD Countries
Measure used is effective average tax rate on new investment (including
investment incentives).
Mean and standard deviation refer to 14 OECD countries.
Source: Institute for Fiscal Studies Corporation Tax Database (see Devereux et al. 2002).
Table 7.2 Social Spending: OECD Countries
Social expenditure includes health, social services and unemployment and
pension benefits, but not education.
OECD median and standard deviation refer to 21 countries; North Europe
refers to 10 countries from Scandinavia to Switzerland; South Europe refers
to Greece, Spain, Portugal and Italy; Liberal Economies refer to Australia,
New Zealand, Ireland, Canada, the USA and UK.
Source: OECD, Social Expenditure Database.
Table 7.3 Income Inequality: OECD Countries
90:10 ratios for household disposable income.
North Europe refers to nine countries, Liberal Economies to six countries,
OECD to 19 countries.
Source: Luxemburg Income Survey website http://www.lisproject.org/techdoc.htm
and Forster and d’Ercole (2005) Annex Table A.3.
194
DATA APPENDIX
Table 7.4 Poverty and Impact of the Benefit and Tax System
Numbers in poverty are those with household income adjusted for family
size which is less than 50% of the median income.
Tax/benefit effects show extent to which povery is reduced or the Gini
coefficient measure of overall income inequality is reduced by the effect of
the tax and benefit system. The comparison is with what poverty would
have been or what inequality would have been without taxes and benefits
but with market incomes not affected.
Source: Smeeding (2004 figs. 8 and 9) plus Forster and d’Ercole (2005, fig. 14,
annex table A7).
Notes
Preface
1. Glyn and Sutcliffe (1972), Armstrong et al. (1991) and Glyn et al. (1990).
2. Quoted in Armstrong et al. (1991: 85–100) where post-war reconstruction is analysed in some detail.
3. The rise of neo-liberal ideas is discussed in Harvey (2005).
Chapter 1
1. This group of countries comprises original members of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. In the remainder
of this book this group will also be referred to interchangeably as the
OECD countries, the ‘rich countries’ and the ‘North’ (particularly
when the context is relations with the less developed ‘South’).
2. See, for example, Bruno and Sachs (1985), Brenner (2002), Arrighi (2003),
Dumenil and Levy (2004).
3. Maddison (1991, table C.5).
4. See the vivid description of these trends in Italy in Ginsburg (1990, ch. 7).
5. See Rowthorn and Wells (1987).
6. The rise in female labour force participation in urban areas was masked
in the national statistics of those countries where large numbers of
women had been counted as employed in agriculture (so that the shift
out of agriculture initially tended to reduce women’s participation).
These trends are presented and discussed in more detail in Erdem and
Glyn (2000).
7. Armstrong et al. (1991), ch. 8.
8. Calculated as the fall in median hours worked for 15 OECD countries
from Maddison (1995, table J-4).
9. See Soskice (1978) for a description of the economic and policy circumstances around the strike waves and wage explosions and Ginsburg
(1990) for a graphic account of the Italian developments.
196
NOTES TO PAGES 5–31
10. Allsopp (1982, table 3.4).
11. Profit rate data are presented in Glyn (1997) but are available for fewer
countries than those with profit share data used in Fig. 1.3.
12. Glyn and Sutcliffe (1972).
13. Armstrong et al. (1991, table 10.1).
14. Productivity data on US Bureau of Labor Statistics website plus additional BLS archived data for the USA.
15. Inklaar et al. (2003, table 6).
16. Meadows et al. (1972).
17. The real exchange rate is measured by cost competitiveness and is
calculated from the IMF series of relative unit labour costs in a
common currency (RULC). Source: IMF, International Financial
Statistics website.
18. Nordhaus (2004, table 8).
19. There is a brief discussion of the idea of Fordism and evidence of
the productivity problems encountered in the motor industry and
elsewhere even before 1973 in Glyn et al. (1990).
20. Maddison (1995, table D).
21. Bacon and Eltis (1976) was the classic exposition of this line of
argument in the UK.
22. Gorton and Schmid (2000), whose article on German co-determination
is colourfully entitled ‘Class struggle inside the firm’, do find significant negative effects on share prices and on profits in the early 1990s
where worker representatives constitute a half of the boards.
Chapter 2
1. Friedman (1968).
2. Dore et al. (1994).
3. In a similar vein the presentation of US policy in terms of controlling
the money supply meant that politically unpopular increases in interest rates could be blamed on market pressures (Mussa 1994).
4. Blanchard and Muet (1993).
5. For example, Ball (1999).
6. The reserve army was supposed by Marx to keep the real wage in check.
He argued that a sharp rise in real wages cuts into profits and thus
reduces capital accumulation and the demand for labour. This reduces
employment and the rise in the reserve army pushes real wages back
down. The NAIRU by contrast is usually discussed in terms of holding
NOTES TO PAGES 31–39
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
197
down money wage increases and inflation. However as we saw earlier
(Fig. 1.2 and 1.3) rising inflation and squeezed profits coincided in the
1970s, indicating that the wage pressure was partly reflected in faster
inflation and partly in profit squeeze. Exactly the reverse happened in
the 1980s and 1990s.
This chart follows Blanchard and Philippon (2004) who find a significant relationship using different periods and a different strike measure.
They interpret the strike measure as reflecting an underlying lack of
‘trust’ in industrial relations. The measure for strikes used here is the
median across countries of days occupied per 1,000 workers in industry
and transport (which typically is more organized and with higher strike
levels than most of the service sector).
Over the period 1960–73 Denmark, Sweden, Norway and Finland ran
budget surpluses averaging more than 3% of GDP.
There are differing recollections as to how gracefully Clinton acceded
to bond market pressures. Robert Rubin, having moved from Wall
Street to head Clinton’s National Economic Council, recalls Clinton’s
response at the crucial meeting as ‘ “I get it”. Deficit reduction he said
had become the threshold issue . . . this is what we need to get the economy back on track’ (Rubin 2003: 119). An alternative account has
Clinton responding to discussion of the impact of deficit reduction on
interest rates: ‘You mean to tell me that the success of the program and
my re-election hinges on the Federal Reserve and a bunch of fucking
bond traders’ (Woodward 1994: 84).
For example, European Commission (2000: 21).
The Financial Times commented on the 2003 Bush tax cut: ‘the
lunatics are now in charge of the asylum . . . Proposals to slash federal
spending, particularly on social programs is a tricky electoral proposition, but a fiscal crisis offers the tantalising prospect of forcing such
cuts through the back door’ (quoted by Krugman 2004: 446).
Bortolotti and Siniscalco (2004) and Megginson et al. (2005).
Card and Freeman (2004, table 1.1).
See Green and Haskel (2004) for a recent review of UK privatization,
which is relied on in the next few paragraphs.
Willner (2003) provides a sceptical review.
Reported in OECD (2003a: 36).
In 1979 in the UK the real rate of return on the replacement cost
capital of the nationalized industries was 0.6% as compared to 8.4%
in the private sector (public corporations calculated from tables 6.2,
14.3 and 14.7 of UK National Accounts, 1990 edition: private
198
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
NOTES TO PAGES 40–53
non-financial companies profit rate from ONS company profitability
release).
The most dramatic case of pre-privatization rationalization was coal
mining where only 12 pits were functioning by the time of privatization in 1994 compared to 172 before the 1984–5 miners’ strike (see
Chapter 5), and productivity on the remaining pits had doubled (Glyn
and Machin 1997).
This does not refer to the whole price of gas or electricity, but only to
the value added by the industry to the coal and gas supplies. Data for
prices of the energy and water shown in Green and Haskel (2004,
fig. 2.1) suggest that the price fall took place in gas and electricity with
water prices rising substantially.
Green and Haskel (2004: 74, 99) for these points.
The immediate gain for subscribing to BT shares was not untypical.
Megginson and Netter (2001, table 8) report a study suggesting that UK
privatizations generated an average immediate price increase over the
offer price of about 40%.
Itoh (2005).
OECD (1983, table 18).
Nicoletti et al. (2001, table 12).
OECD (2005 fig. 4.4).
Joumard et al. (2003).
Domberger and Jensen (1997: 72–5).
HM Treasury (2003b: 13).
Grout and Stevens (2003: 230).
ONS (2004).
This is detailed in Pollock (2004, ch. 1).
OECD (1999).
Baker et al. (2005).
Agell (1999).
Chapter 3
1. US National Income and Product Accounts, tables 1.12, 2.1
2. Another illustration of the fact that income is less of a short-term
constraint on consumption: the correlation between the annual change
in real consumption and the annual change in real household disposable (post-tax) income fell in UK from 0.82 in the period 1948–73 to 0.56
for 1979–2003.
NOTES TO PAGES 54–66
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
199
OECD Economic Outlook, June 2004, Annex tables 23, 58.
Lazonick and O’Sullivan (2000).
Gugler et al. (2004, table 2).
Shiller (2000: 8).
These data on executive compensation are from Hall and Murphy
(2003), Coffee (2005), Bebchuk and Fried (2003) and Coffee (2003)
respectively. The authoritative survey of research into CEO compensation and stock options noted the paucity and contradictory
results of research into the impact of compensation on firm
performance. It concluded that it was difficult to demonstrate that
‘the increase in stock-based incentives has led CEOs to work harder,
or smarter, or more in the interests of shareholders’ (Murphy 1999:
2255–6). One recent study found that schemes for encouraging
managers to own more of the company’s shares raised share prices
and were associated subsequently with higher reported profits (Core
and Marker 2002). Given widespread massaging of earnings this is
far from conclusive.
Lev (2003).
Healy and Palepu (2003).
Hansmann and Kraakmann (2001) quoted by Blair (2003).
Gugler et al. (2004), Morin (2000) and Financial Times, 31 Mar. 2005.
Listing in New York evidently led to some overseas companies engaging in the same sort of exaggeration of earnings prevalent among US
corporations (see Coffee 2005).
Hall and Soskice (2001), Allen (2005).
Gompers and Lerner (2001), Allen and Song (2003, table 6.1).
Federal Reserve Board: industrial production and capacity utilization
series.
Davis et al. (1996 table 2.1 and fig. 2); Farber (2003 fig. 1–3); Pontiff
et al.(1990).
Edison et al. (2003, tables 2 and 3).
Financial Times, 29 Sept. 2004; Obstfeld and Taylor (2003, table 2);
Stultz (2005, fig. 1 and p. 8).
Except where limited by exchange controls individual companies
could borrow abroad, but the country as a whole borrows abroad only
if it is running a deficit on the current account of the balance of
payments.
The standard deviation of current account balances roughly doubled
between the mid-1980s and the early 2000s (Blanchard and Giavazzi
2002, fig. 1).
200
NOTES TO PAGES 67–84
20. Calculated from the IMF, International Financial Statistics series for
relative unit labour costs.
21. Changes in the real exchange rate may act in a stabilizing way if they
offset adverse real trends or ‘shocks’. The HM Treasury (2003a) has
attempted to argue, not very convincingly, that this was typically true
of UK swings in the real exchange rate.
22. Kaminsky (2003, table 4); Bordo et al. (2001, fig. 1 and p. 58).
23. Bordo et al. (2001, fig. 1, table 1 and p. 55).
24. Stiglitz (2002).
25. See, for example, the article ‘How Hedge Funds are destabilising the
markets’ in the Financial Times (29 Sept. 2004) by Paul Woolley, the
chairman of an investment management firm.
26. Derivatives are described by the legendary US investor Warren Buffett
as ‘Financial weapons of mass destruction, carrying dangers that, while
now latent, are potentially lethal’ (quoted in Stultz 2004: 3). Robert
Rubin remarks that ‘Throughout my career I had seen situations where
derivatives put additional pressure on volatile markets’ (2003: 288). He
says that he was more concerned about derivatives than his then
deputy Larry Summers, which is striking given the latter’s earlier
involvement in the academic literature critical of conventional
assumptions of financial market efficiency.
27. In October 1998, shortly after the LTCM crisis, the dollar fell by 15% in
a week. Conventional wisdom that the dollar would keep on rising relative to the yen, combined with higher interest rates in the USA, had
generated huge speculative inflows into dollar assets, which were then
reversed en masse when sentiment changed. ‘The logic of mutually
reinforcing sales meant that the harder they tried to swim away, the
more they provoked the feeding frenzy. The sense of fear was palpable
during the turbulent trading of 8 October’ (Morris and Shin 1999: 58).
Chapter 4
1. The profit share in manufacturing increased from 30% at the beginning
of the decade to 35% in 1999 but this rise would have been bigger without pressure from the high value of the dollar. Estimated from Bureau
of Economic Analysis (BEA) Gross Product by Industry tables.
2. US Government (2002, table 7.1).
3. Godley, et al. (2004); Obstfeld and Rogoff (2004).
NOTES TO PAGES 84–91
201
4. The proviso ‘net’ investment and savings is important here. Much business investment is financed by depreciation, but it is net investment
which expands capacity in the economy.
5. The precise causal relationship between capital accumulation and
growth is hotly contested. A recent study (Bond et al. 2004) argued that
the econometric evidence confirms the importance of accumulation in
determining growth.
6. Apparently those made redundant from the state firms are reluctant to
take up jobs in the new export oriented factories: ‘It is said that in the
cities, especially those in state enterprises, workers are accustomed to
the idea that “workers are masters” and “there is no exploitation in
socialism”, therefore they want jobs close to their home, with high
wages, short work hours and easy work’ (Imamura 2003: 59). On actual
pay and working conditions see below.
7. Maddison excludes large repair costs and military investments which
are not usually classified with investment. Stockbuilding was also
extremely high in China and housing investment was high as well. The
broad pattern of the capital stock growth figures for Korea, Japan and
China shown in Table 4.2 is consistent with that shown by Maddison
(1998).
8. Maddison (1998, table 3.9).
9. CSFB (2005, fig. 24, 27–9).
10. Brooks (2004).
11. Europe and Japan make up most of the ‘non-USA OECD’ category. Not
included in the chart is the mass of oil producers, developing and
middle income countries like India, which, together, have also gained
share over the last decade.
12. In terms of the absolute level of GDP per capita, according to
Maddison’s measure China is at the level of Japan in the later 1950s and
Korea/Taiwan in the mid-1970s. Such measures should be taken as no
more than broadly indicative.
13. Sutcliffe (2004, fig. 2).
14. Qian (2003) provides a fascinating discussion of how the incentives for
China’s growth have evolved despite a path of reform which has defied
the conventional wisdom.
15. 6 Asian countries including not-so-low-wage Korea, plus Poland,
Czech Republic and Mexico.
16. Eichengreen et al. (2004); Boltho (2004, table 6); Ito and Yoshida (2004);
Rumbaugh and Blancher (2004).
17. Lardy (2003).
202
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
NOTES TO PAGES 94–111
Meng et al. (2004, table 2); Gough (2005).
China Labor Bulletin and China Labor Watch.
Calculated from WTO International Trade (2004, tables IV.1 and A.19).
This section draws on Sutcliffe and Glyn (2003).
World Bank (2003). The comparison between exports and GDP is frequently made in constant prices. However exports of manufactures
tend to fall in price relatively to GDP since productivity growth is considerably faster in manufacturing than in the rest of the economy. Thus
the share of employment engaged directly in exporting grows less
rapidly than the volume comparison suggests; the current price ratio of
exports to GDP reflects better the evolution of the share of employment engaged in exports.
These series are the Penn tables openness indicator (exports plus imports
at current prices as a percentage of GDP, all at PPP prices) divided by 2.
Findlay and O’Rourke (2003, table 7).
The Financial Times (Beattie 2004) quotes Kenneth Rogoff, recently
chief economist at the IMF, as claiming that only one-fifth of the US
economy was subject to international competition Bhagwati et al.
(2004) quote an estimate that 70% of US jobs are in service industries,
requiring that the consumer and producer be in the same place, to
which might be added construction which is not tradable. Even so the
estimate of one-fifth seems on the low side, not least because a number
of these jobs provide inputs into manufacturing.
Bhagwati et al. (2004); Amiti and Wei (2004, tables 4, 6).
Bairoch and Kozul Wright (1996).
See Epstein (2003) and Sinclair (2003).
Chiswick and Hatton (2003).
Chapter 5
1. Europe is represented here by the sum of Germany, UK, France, The
Netherlands and Spain. This section is based on Glyn et al. (2004).
2. Webster (2000).
3. This is just an extension of the standard practice when looking at the
pattern of wages which is to compare the top 10% and bottom 10% of
the pay distribution.
4. Glyn (2001, table 2); Freeman (1995).
5. Berman et al. (1998); Autor et al. (2003).
6. Rowthorn and Coutts (2004).
7. Bhagwati et al. (2004); Rowthorn and Coutts (2004, table 2).
NOTES TO PAGES 113–136
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
203
Goos and Manning (2003, table IX).
OECD (2004a); Pisani Ferry (2002).
Alesina et al. (2005); (Maddison 1995).
Belot and Van Ours (2000); OECD (2004a, table 2.A2.4).
Green (2006, ch. 7).
Mishel et al. (2005, table 2.6).
Piketty (2003). Data in Atkinson and Salverda (2004) suggest that the
share of the top 1% in the UK behaved similarly to that in the USA
whilst the Dutch pattern was similar to that of France.
Dolado et al. (1996).
Howell and Huebler (2005).
OECD (1999); Baker et al. (2005, fig. 3.7).
In addition there has been an increase in numbers of self-employed in
the OECD since 1979. However self-employment has only grown from
9.8% of non-agricultural employment in 1979 to 11.9% and fallen in
agriculture (see OECD 2000, table 5.1). It is striking that in the USA,
thought of as the model for entrepreneurial opportunity, the share of
self-employment in non-agricultural employment fell in the later
1980s and 1990s and is probably no higher than in 1973.
In the ‘Ghent’ system where unions administer benefits, high unemployment encourages membership (see Cecchi and Lucifora 2002).
Note that the series shown here is for the median, which falls more
than the mean as the latter reflects the rising membership in a few
small countries, which is not typical.
This and the previous paragraph are based on OECD (2004a, ch. 3).
Kelly (2005).
Pencavel (2004).
Soskice (1994); Thelen and Kume (2005).
Chapter 6
1. Crotty (2002).
2. Vatter and Walker (2001).
3. Nordhaus (2002, tables 6, 7); Oliner and Sichel (reported in Gordon
2003, table 10).
4. Sharpe (2004); Foster et al. (2002); Baily (2002).
5. These comparisons refer to non-financial companies. As noted in
Chapter 2 financial companies’ profits were increasing exceptionally
fast but calculating their profit rates is fraught with problems.
6. Brenner (2004) has detailed discussion of profitability movements.
204
NOTES TO PAGES 137–154
7. Carlin et al. (2001) is the source of the Schumpeter quotation and the
UK results.
8. Hoshi and Kashyap (2004).
9. Horioka (2004).
10. Because the level of investment was high in 1990 even maintaining it
kept the capital stock growing by some 4% per year over the 1990s (see
Table 5.1). This was considerably faster than the growth of output, contributing to further pressure on profitability.
11. See Boltho (2003), Gordon (2004) and Blanchard (2004) for example.
12. Nicoletti et al. (2001, table 12); OECD (2005, fig. 4.8).
13. Baker et al. (2005).
14. See Dumenil and Levy (2004, fig. 9.2) for France. The earlier trends are
discussed in Armstrong et al. (1991). The gap in the two German series
in 1991 is due more to a changed system of national accounts than to
the immediate impact of including East Germany in the figures.
15. The data suggest average pre-tax profit rates for non-financial business
over the period 1991–2001 of 5.6% for Germany, 11.2% for Italy and
12.2% for the UK as compared to 7.9% in the USA. French profit rates
appear to be similar to those in the USA (Dumenil and Levy 2004,
fig. 9.2).
16. Germany’s manufacturing earned 5% on capital employed on average
during 1991–2001, UK manufacturing 9.2%, Italy’s 8.3% and US
manufacturing 13.8%.
17. See Sinn (2003) and Carlin and Soskice (1997) for effects of unification.
18. The OECD notes that ‘The evolution of aggregate wages suggests a
trend towards wage moderation in the majority of OECD countries
since the 1970s’ (OECD 2004a: 129). The factors behind this trend
are discussed in Chapter 5.
19. Maddison (1995, table 2.6).
20. Baumol (2001) gave these services the alarming title of ‘asymptotically
stagnant’ because within them employment would become increasingly concentrated on activities where productivity could not increase
(care workers rather than record keepers).
21. Baumol (2002).
22. Glyn (1994, fig. 3.2, 3.3).
23. Such a process whereby the ‘gains from trade’ for the North are reduced
by development in the South is discussed by Samuelson (2004).
24. The estimate of the change in the capital-labour ratio is in Freeman
(2005a). A shift to profits is floated as a possibility by Bhagwati et al.
(2004). Commenting on the results of a simulation of the effects of
NOTES TO PAGES 155–168
205
outsourcing of US service jobs Baily and Lawrence (2004: 267) write: ‘It
is not surprising to find that, if the US economy becomes more exposed
to low cost labour, the result will be to shift the distribution of income
towards capital’. The effects of such a shift on income distribution and
the welfare state are taken up in the final chapter.
25. Nordhaus (1992).
Chapter 7
1. OECD (1997, table 1.20).
2. Lindert (2003, fig. 1–5).
3. Atkinson et al. (1995, table 6.9) shows shares of the top 10% in incomes
earned in the market (i.e. excluding government transfers) in the later
1980s typically in the range 25–30%. Since then the share of the top
10% has tended to grow. Piketty and Saez (2003), using more comprehensive data but rather different definitions, estimate a share for the
USA of more than 41% in 1998 for the top 10%, and a few percentage
points higher still if capital gains are included.
4. Compare the income and tax estimates in tables 6.9 and 7.3 in
Atkinson et al. (1995).
5. Rodrik (1997).
6. Adema’s (2001) analysis of ‘net social spending’ (deducting taxation of
benefits which are high in some Scandinavian countries and adding
‘tax expenditures’ like the US Earned Income Tax Credit) shows a
considerably smaller dispersion than the gross shares shown in
Table 7.2. However it is unlikely that the trends would be much different.
7. Lindbeck (1997).
8. Productivity data is from Bureau of Labor Statistics website; R&D from
OECD (2002, fig. 2.2).
9. The various studies are far from unanimous about these trends
(Atkinson 2003, fig. 1–9; Smeeding 2004, fig. 3 and 2002, fig. 4). Data for
benchmark years for many countries are presented in Forster and
d’Ercole (2005) and the Luxemburg Income Surveys website and these
are used in Table 7.3.
10. Forster and d’Ercole (2005, Annex table A3) also report a surprising
increase in the 90:10 ratio in Japan from 3.9 to 4.9 between 1985
and 1994.
206
NOTES TO PAGES 168–176
11. Smeeding (2002, fig. 1) is the source for these comparisons. If the
absolute difference in the 90:10 ratio is felt to be a better indicator, then
the difference between the USA and Scandinavia (a difference of around
2.5 in the 90:10 ratio) is similar to that between Russia and the USA.
12. Smeeding (2004, fig. 10); OECD (2004 a, table 3.7).
13. Household receipts of rent, dividends and interest as percentage of
employee compensation plus self-employment incomes (‘Operating
Surplus and Mixed Incomes’) from OECD, National Accounts Volume
II 2004, OECD website.
14. Forster and d’Ercole (2005, Annex table A.4). Real capital gains on
assets such as equities should also be included in income distribution
figures but there are no cross-country data available. Piketty and Saez
(2001, table A7) show that realized nominal capital gains constituted
some 18% of the receipts of the top 10% of income earners in the USA
in 1998.
15. ‘Market poverty’ refers to the proportion of the population with
incomes before tax and transfers which are less than a half of the
national median income. Countries with strong welfare states will
tend to have greater market poverty and inequality to the extent that,
for example, pensioners are more dependent on state benefits and feel
little need to save independently and thus have market income. The
reductions in poverty for the whole population shown in Table 7.4
seem pretty similar to the corresponding data (Forster and Pearson
2002, fig. 3) for the working age population (i.e. excluding pensioners).
The one exception appears to be Germany where market poverty was
exceptionally low and the effect of taxes and benefits in reducing
poverty was comparatively small.
16. Scanlon and Whitehead (2004, table 1).
17. Itoh (2005).
18. Forster and d’Ercole (2005, fig. 18).
19. Blanden et al. (2005, tables 1, 2 and 5) is the source for these data. Their
ranking of countries is broadly consistent with the results of the earlier
literature reviewed by Corak (2004).
20. The usual analysis of a high degree of capital mobility is that it forces
countries to ensure that employers earn the going rate of return and
that this will limit corporate taxation. However Bowles (2002) points
out that such competition also implies that employers cannot earn
more than the going post-tax ‘world rate of profit’. The workforce then
becomes the ‘residual claimant’ on production and would receive all
NOTES TO PAGES 177–183
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
207
the benefit of greater work effort for example rather than having to
share the gains with employers.
Forster and d’Ercole (2005, fig. 2 and 3); Svallfors (1997, table 3).
Layard (2005: 31; Frey and Stutzer (2002, fig. 4.3, 4.4). The data replies
also suggest that the gap in terms of reported well-being is far greater
comparing the bottom of the distribution and the middle than is the gap
between the top and the middle. This implies that a more equal income
distribution, especially reducing differences between top and bottom,
will increase average happiness, which confirms a very old line of argument for egalitarianism.
Layard (2005: 63); Schor (1992); Green (2006, ch. 8); Sennett (1998).
Schor (2004).
Runciman (2005).
Van Parijs (2003) has a very clear exposition of these and related points
and many references on Basic Income. Van Parijs (2001) contains a very
helpful set of comments on Basic Income by a wide range of authors.
See also the website: http://www.basicincome.org.
This page intentionally left blank
References
Adema, W. (2001), ‘Net Social Expenditure 2nd edition,’ OECD Labour
Market & Social Policy Occasional Paper No. 52.
Agell, J. (1999), ‘On the Benefits from Rigid Labour Markets: Norms, Market
Failures and Social Insurance’, Economic Journal, 109: F143–64.
Alesina, A., E. Glaeser, and B. Sacerdote (2001), ‘Why Doesn’t the US have a
European-Style Welfare State’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
2:107–77.
—— —— —— (2005), ‘Work and Leisure in the US and Europe: Why So
Different?’ Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper No.
2068.
—— and R. Perotti (1995), ‘Fiscal Expansions and Adjustments in OECD
Countries’, Economic Policy, 21: 207–48.
Allen, F. (2005) ‘Corporate Governance in Emerging Economies’, Oxford
Review of Economic Policy, 21: 164–77.
—— and W. Song (2003), ‘Venture Capital and Corporate Governance,’ in
P. Cornelius and B. Kogut (eds.), Corporate Governance and Capital
Flows in a Global Economy, New York: Oxford University Press.
Allsopp, C. (1982), ‘Inflation’ in A. Boltho (ed.) The European Economy:
Growth and Crisis, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Amiti, M. and S-J. Wei (2004), ‘Fear of Service Outsourcing: Is it Justified?’
NBER Working Paper 10808.
Arrighi, G. (2003), ‘Tracking Global Turbulence’, New Left Review,
Mar./Apr.: 5–72.
Armstrong, P., A. Glyn, and J. Harrison (1991), Capitalism since 1945,
Oxford: Blackwells (1st edn. published in 1984 by Fontana as Capitalism
since World War II).
Atkinson, A. (1996), ‘The Case for a Participation Income’, The Political
Quarterly, 67(1): 67–70.
—— (2003), ‘Economic Inequality in OECD Countries; Data and
Explanations’, CesIFO Discussion Paper.
210
REFERENCES
Atkinson, A., L. Rainwater, and T. Smeeding (1995), Income Distribution in
OECD Countries, Paris: OECD.
—— and W. Salverda (2004), ‘Top Incomes in the United Kingdom and the
Netherlands over the Twentieth Century,’ Nuffield College, Oxford.
Autor, D., F. Levy, and R. Murnane (2003), ‘The Skill Content of Recent
Technological Change: An Empirical Investigation,’ Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 118(4): 1279–323.
Bacon, R., and W. Eltis (1976), Britain’s Economic Problem: Too Few
Producers, Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Baily, M. (2002), ‘The New Economy: Post-Mortem or Second Wind’,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(2): 3–22.
—— and R. Lawrence (2004), ‘What Happened to the Great U.S. Job
Machine: The Role of Trade and Electronic Offshoring’, Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, 2: 211–84.
Bairoch, P., and R. Kozul-Wright (1996), ‘Globalization Myths: Some
Historical Reflections on Integration, Industrialisation and Growth in
the World Economy’, in R. Kozul-Wright and R. Rowthorn (eds.),
Multinational Corporations and the Global Economy, Basingstoke:
Macmillan.
Baker, D., A. Glyn, D. Howell, and J. Schmitt (2005), ‘Labour Market
Institutions and Unemployment: A Critical Assessment of the CrossCountry Evidence’, in D. Howell (ed.), Fighting Unemployment: The
Limits of Free Market Orthodoxy, New York: Oxford University Press.
Ball, L. (1999), ‘Aggregate Demand and Long-Run Unemployment’,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 189–251.
Bank for International Settlements (1998), Annual Report, Basle: BIS.
—— (1999), Annual Report, Basle: BIS.
—— (2005), Annual Report, Basle: BIS.
Bank of England (2005), Inflation Report, London: Bank of England.
Batchelor, R., R. Major, R. Morgan, and A. Morgan (1980), Industrialisation
and the Basis for Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Baumol, W. (2001), ‘Paradoxes of the Services: Exploding Costs, Resistent
Demand’, in T. ten Raa and R. Schettkat (eds.), The Growth of Service
Industries: High Costs, Strong Demand, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
—— (2002), The Free Market Innovation Machine: Analysing the Growth
Miracle of Capitalism, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Beattie, A. (2004), ‘Why are US economists so optimistic?’ Financial Times,
11 Jan.
Bebchuk, L. A., and J. M. Fried (2003), ‘Executive Compensation as an Agency
Problem’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3): 71–92.
REFERENCES
211
Belot, M., and J. Van Ours (2000). ‘Does the Recent Success of some OECD
Countries in Lowering their Unemployment Rate Lie in the Clever
Design of their Economic Reforms?’ IZA Discussion Paper No. 147.
Berman, E., J. Bound and S. Machin (1998), ‘Implications of Skill-Biased
Technical Change: International Evidence’, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 113(4): 1215–44.
Bertola, G., F. Blau, and L. Kahn (2001), ‘Comparative Analysis of Labor
Market Outcomes: Lessons for the US from International Experience’,
NBER Working Paper 8526.
Besley, T., and M. Ghatak (2003). ‘Incentives, Choice and Accountability in
the Provision of Public Services’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
19(2): 235–49.
Bhadhuri, A. (1993), ‘The Economics and Politics of Social Democracy’ in
P. O. Bardhan, M. Datta-Chaudhuri, and T. Krishnan (eds.) Development
and Change: Essays in Honour of K. N. Raj, Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Bhagwati, J., A. Panagariya, and T. Srinivasan (2004), ‘The Muddles over
Outsourcing’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(4): 93–114.
Blair, M. (2003), ‘Shareholder Value, Corporate Governance, and Corporate
performance’, in P. Cornelius and B. Kogut (eds.), Corporate Governance
and Capital Flows in a Global Economy, New York: Oxford University
Press.
Blanchard, O. (2004), ‘The Economic Future of Europe’, NBER Working
Paper 10310.
—— and F. Giavazzi (2002), ‘Current Account Deficits in the Euro Area: The
End of the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle?’, Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 2: 143–210.
—— and P.-A. Muet (1993), ‘Competitiveness through Disinflation: An
Assessment of the French Macroeconomic Strategy’, Economic Policy,
16: 11–56.
—— and T. Philippon (2004), ‘The Quality of Labor Relations and
Unemployment’, NBER Working Paper 10590.
Blanchflower, D. and A. Bryson (2003), ‘The Union Wage Premium in the US
and UK’, LSE Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper No.6.
—— and A. Oswald (2004) ‘Well-being over time in Britain and the USA’
Journal of Public Economics 88: 1359–86.
Blanden, J., P. Gregg, and S. Machin (2005), ‘Intergeneration Mobility in
Europe and North America’, Centre for Economic Performance, Apr.
Boltho, A. (2003), ‘What’s Wrong with Europe’, New Left Review, 22
July/5–26 Aug.
212
REFERENCES
Boltho, A. (2004), ‘China—Can Rapid Economic Growth Continue?’, The
Singapore Economic Review, 49(2): 255–72.
Bond, S., A. Leblebicoglu, and F. Sciantarelli (2004), ‘Capital Accumulation
and Growth: A New Look at the Empirical Evidence’, mimeo, Nuffield
College, Oxford.
Boone, L., and N. Girouard (2002), ‘The Stock Market, the Housing Market
and Consumer Behaviour’, OECD Economic Studies, 2: 175–200.
Bordo, M., B. Eichengreen, D. Klingebiel, and S. Pereia (2001), ‘Is the Crisis
Problem Growing More Severe’, Economic Policy, 32: 51–82.
Bortolotti, B., and D. Siniscalco (2004), The Challenges of Privatisation: An
International Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bosworth, B., and S. Collins (2003), ‘The Empirics of Growth: An Update’,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 113–206.
Bowles, S. (2002), ‘Globalisation and Redistribution: Feasible
Egalitarianism in a Competitive World’, in R. Freeman (ed.), Inequality
around the World, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Brenner, R. (1998), ‘The Economics of Global Turbulence’, New Left
Review, 1(229): 1–265.
—— (2002), The Boom and the Bubble, London: Verso.
—— (2004), ‘New Boom or New Bubble’, New Left Review, Jan./Feb.: 57–102.
Brooks, R. (2004), ‘Labor Market Performance and Prospects’, in E. Prasad
(ed.), China’s Growth and Integration into the World Economy, IMF
Occasional Paper 232.
Bruno, M., and J. Sachs (1985), The Economics of Worldwide Stagflation,
Oxford: Blackwell.
Card, D., and R. Freeman (2004), ‘What have Two Decades of Economic
Reform Delivered’, in D. Card, R. Blundell, and R. Freeman, Seeking a
Premier-League Economy: The Economic Effects of British Economic
Reforms, 1980–2000, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
—— F. Kramarz, and T. Lemieux (1999), ‘Changes in the Relative Structure
of Wages and Employment: A Comparison of the US, Canada and France’,
Canadian Journal of Economics, 32(4): 843–77.
Carlin, W., J. Haskel, and P. Seabright (2001), ‘Understanding the “Essential
Fact about Capitalism”: Markets, Competition and Creative
Destruction’, National Institute Economic Review, 175: 67–84.
—— and D. Soskice (1997), ‘Shocks to the System: The German Political
Economy under Stress’, National Institute Economic Review, 1: 57–76.
Cassidy, J. (2002), Dot-Con. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Cecchi, D., and C. Lucifora (2002), ‘Unions and Labour Market Institutions
in Europe’, Economic Policy, 35: 363–408.
Chan, A. (2003), ‘Race to the Bottom’, China Perspectives, Apr.: 41–9.
REFERENCES
213
Chan, N., M. Getmansky, S. Haas, and A. Lo (2005), ‘Systemic Risk and
Hedge Funds’, NBER Working Paper 11200.
Charlwood, A. (2003), ‘The Anatomy of Union Decline in Britain:
1990–1998’, Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper 601,
London School of Economics.
Chiswick, B., and T. Hatton (2003), ‘International Migration and the
Integration of Labour Markets’, M. Bordo, A. Taylor, and J. Williamson
(eds.), Globalisation in Historical Perspective, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Coffee, J. (2003), ‘What Caused Enron? A Capsule Social and Economic
History of the 1990s’, in P. Cornelius and B. Kogut (eds.), Corporate
Governance and Capital Flows in a Global Economy, New York: Oxford
University Press.
—— (2005), ‘A Theory of Corporate Scandals: Why the USA and Europe
Differ’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(2): 198–211.
Comin, D., and T. Philippon (2005), ‘The Rise in Finn-Level Volatility:
Causes and Consequences’, NBER Working Paper 11388.
Corak, M. (2004), ‘Do Poor Children become Poor Adults’, UNICEF
Innocenti Research Centre.
Core, J., and D. Marker (2002), ‘Performance Consequences of Mandatory
Increases in Executive Stock Ownership’, Journal of Financial Economics,
64: 317–40.
Crotty, J. (2002), ‘The Effects of “Financialisation” and Increased
Competition on the Performance of Non-Financial Companies in the
Neo-Liberal Era’, mimeo, UMASS Amherst.
CSFB (2005), ‘Understanding China’s profit cycle’, in China Market
Strategy, Mar.
Davis, S., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Schuh (1996), Job Creation and
Destruction, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
DeLong, B., and B. Eichengreen (2002), ‘International Finance and Crises in
Emerging Markets’ in J. Frankel and P. Orszag (eds.), American Economic
Policy in the 1990s, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Dertouzos, M., R. Lester, and R. Solow (1989), Made in America: Regaining
the Competitive Edge, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Devereux, M., R. Griffith, and A. Klemm (2002), ‘Corporate Income Tax
Reforms and International Tax Competition’, Economic Policy, 35: 451–95.
Dodd, R. (2005), ‘Credit Derivatives Trigger Near Systemic Melt down’,
Derivatives Study Centre Special Brief 25, http://www.financial policy.org.
Dolado, J., F. Kramarz, S. Machin, A. Manning, D. Margoilis, and C. Teulings
(1996), ‘The Economic Impact of Minimum Wages in Europe’, Economic
Policy, 23: 317–72.
214
REFERENCES
Domberger, S., and P. Jensen (1997), ‘Contracting out by the Public Sector:
Theory, Evidence, Prospects’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 18(4):
67–78.
Dore, R., R. Boyer, and Z. Mars (1994), The Return of Incomes Policy London:
Pinter Publishers.
Dumenil, G., and D. Levy (2004), Capital Resurgent, Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press.
Dyck, A., and L. Zingales (2003), ‘The Bubble and the Media’, in P. Cornelius
and B. Kogut (eds.), Corporate Governance and Capital Flows in a Global
Economy, New York: Oxford University Press.
Edison, H., M. Klein, L. Rici, and T. Slok (2003), ‘Capital Account
Liberalisation and Economic Performance: Survey and Synthesis’, at
http://fletcher.tufts.edu/faculty/klein/pdfs/CALandEP_aug2204.pdf
Eichengreen, B. (2005), ‘Financial Instability’, in B. Lomborg (ed) Global
Crises, Global Solutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
—— Y. Rhee, and H. Tong (2004), ‘The Impact of China on the Exports of
Other Asian Countries’, NBER Working Paper 10768.
Engels, F. (1847/1976), ‘The Free Trade Congress in Brussels’, in K. Marx and
F. Engels, Collected Works, vol. 6, London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1976;
1st pub. 1847.
Epstein, G. (1981), ‘Domestic Stagflation and Monetary Policy: The Federal
Reserve and the Hidden Election’, in T. Ferguson and J. Rogers (eds.), The
Hidden Election, New York: Pantheon Press.
—— (2003), ‘The Role and Control of Multinational Corporations in the
World Economy’, in J. Michie (ed.), The Handbook of Globalisation,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Erdem, E., and A. Glyn (2000), ‘Employment Growth, Structural Change
and Capital Accumulation’, in Thijs ten Raa and Ronald Schettkat (eds.),
Services: High Costs, Strong Demand, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar,
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990), Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism,
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
—— (2004), ‘Unequal Opportunities and Social Inheritance’, in M. Corak
(ed.), Generational Income Mobility in North America and Europe,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
European Commission (2000), Public Finances in EMU 2000, European
Economy No. 3.
Farber, H. (2003), ‘Job Loss in the United States 1981–2001’, Princeton
University Industrial Relations Section Working Paper No. 471.
Findlay, R., and K. O’Rourke (2003), ‘Commodity Market Integration
1500–2000’, in M. Bordo, A. Taylor and J. Williamson (eds.), Globalisation
in Historical Perspective, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
REFERENCES
215
Fforde, J. (1983), ‘Setting Monetary Objectives’, Bank of England Quarterly
Bulletin, June.
Forster, M., and M. Mira d’Ercole (2005), ‘Income Distribution and Poverty
in OECD Countries in the Second Half of the 1990s’, OECD Social,
Employment and Migration Working Papers No. 22.
—— and M. Pearson (2002), ‘Income Distribution and Poverty in the OECD
Area: Trends and Driving Forces’, OECD Economic Studies, 34: 7–39
Fortin, N. (2005), ‘Gender Role Attitudes and Labour Market Outcomes of
Women across OECD Countries’ Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(3).
Foster, L., J. Haltiwanger, and C. Krizan (2002), ‘The Link between Aggregate
and Micro Productivity Growth: Evidence from Retail Trade’, NBER
Working Paper 9120.
Frankel, J. (1994), ‘Exchange Rate Policy’, in M. Feldstein (ed.), American
Economic Policy in the 1980s, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Freeman, R. (1995), ‘The Limits of Wage Flexibility to Curing Unemployment’,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 11(1): 63–72.
—— (2005a), ‘What Really Ails Europe (and America): The Doubling
of the Global Workforce’, The Globalist http://www.theglobalist.com
3 June.
—— (2005b), ‘Does Globalisation of the Scientific/Engineering Workforce
Threaten US Economic Leadership’, NBER Working Paper 11457
Frey, B., and A. Stutzer (2002), Happiness and Economics, Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Friedman, M. (1968), ‘The Role of Monetary Policy’, American Economic
Review, 58 (Mar.): 1–17.
Fukuo, M. (2003), ‘Japan’s Lost Decade and its Financial System’, World
Economy, 26(3): 365–84.
Ginsburg, P. (1990), A History of Contemporary Italy, Harmondsworth:
Penguin Books.
Glyn, A. (1994), ‘Northern Growth and Environmental Constraints’, in
V. Bhaskar and A. Glyn (eds.), The North, the South and the Environment,
New York: St Martins Press.
—— (1997), ‘Does Aggregate Profitability Really Matter’, Cambridge
Journal of Economics, 21: 593–619.
—— (2001), ‘Inequalities of Employment and Wages in OECD Countries’,
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Special Issue 63: 697–714.
Glyn, A., A. Hughes, A. Lipietz, and A. Singh (1990), ‘The Rise and Fall of
the Golden Age’, in S. Marglin and J. Schor (eds.), The Golden Age of
Capitalism: Lessons for the 1990s, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
—— and S. Machin (1997), ‘Colliery Closures and the Decline of the UK
Coal Industry’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 35(2): 197–214.
216
REFERENCES
Glyn, A., Salverda, W., Moeller, J., Schmitt, J., and Sollogub, M. (2004),
‘Employment Differences in Services: The Role of Wages, Productivity
and Demand’, DEMPATEM Working Paper 12, Amsterdam Institute of
Advanced Labour Studies.
——and B. Sutcliffe (1971), ‘The Critical Condition of British Capital’, New
Left Review, 1(66): 3–33.
—— —— (1972), British Capitalism, Workers and the Profits Squeeze,
Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Godley, W., A. Izurieta, and G. Zezza (2004), ‘Prospects and Policies for the
US Economy’, Strategic Analysis, Aug. Levy Economics Institute of Bard
College.
Gompers, P., and J. Lerner (2001), ‘The Venture Capital Revolution’, Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 15(2): 145–68.
Goodhart, C., B. Hoffmann, and M. Segoviano (2004), ‘Bank Regulation and
Macroeconomic Fluctuations’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(4):
591–615.
Goodman, P., and P. Pan (2004), ‘Chinese Workers pay for Wal-Mart’s Low
Prices’, Washington Post Foreign Service, 8 Feb. p. A01.
Goos, M., and A. Manning (2003), ‘Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising
Polarisation of Work in Britain’, LSE Centre for Economic Performance
Discussion Paper No. 604.
Gordon, P., and S. Meunier (2001), The French Challenge, Washington:
Brookings Institution.
Gordon, R. (2003), ‘Exploding Productivity Growth: Context, Causes and
Implications’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 207–98.
—— (2004), ‘Why was Europe Left at the Station when America’s Productivity
Locomotive Departed’, at http://www.faculty-web.at.northwestern.edu/
economics/gordon/P368-CEPR.pdf
Gorton, G., and F. Schmid (2000), ‘Class Struggle inside the Firm: A Study of
German Codetermination’, NBER Working Paper 7945.
Gough, N. (2005), ‘Trouble on the Line’, Time Asia Magazine, Jan.
Green, F. (2006), Demanding Work: The Paradox of Job Quality in the
Affluent Economy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Green, R., and J. Haskel (2004), ‘Seeking a Premier-League Economy: The
Role of Privatisation’, in D. Card, R. Blundell, and R. Freeman, Seeking a
Premier-League Economy: The Economic Effects of British Economic
Reforms, 1980–2000, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gregory, P. and R. Stuart (1986), Soviet Economic Structure and
Performance, 3rd edn., New York: Harper & Row.
Grout, P., and M. Stevens (2003), ‘The Assessment: Financing and Managing
Public Services’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 19(2): 215–34.
REFERENCES
217
Gugler, K., D. Mueller, and B. Yurtoglu (2004), ‘Corporate Governance and
Globalisation’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(1): 129–56.
Halberstam, D. (1987), The Reckoning, London: Bantam Books.
Hall, B. J., and K. J. Murphy (2003), ‘The Trouble with Stock Options’
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3): 49–70.
Hall, P., and D. Soskice (2001), ‘An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism’,
in P. Hall and D. Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Hansmann, H., and R. Kraakmann (2001), ‘The End of History for Corporate
Law’, Georgetown University Law Review, 89: 439–68.
Harvey, D. (2005), A Brief History of Neoliberalism, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Healy, P. M., and K. G. Palepu (2003), ‘The Fall of Enron’ Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 17(2): 3–26.
HM Treasury (2003a), The Exchange Rate and Macroeconomic
Adjustment, EMU Study.
—— (2003b), Meeting the PFI Challenge, www.hm-treasury.gov.uk./
media//648B2/PFI_604.pdf.
Holmstrom, B., and S. Kaplan (2003), ‘The State of US Corporate Governance:
What’s Right and What’s Wrong’, NBER Discussion Paper 9613.
Horioka, C. (2004), ‘The Stagnation of Household Consumption in Japan’,
mimeo, NBER, Cambridge, Mass.
Hoshi, T., and A. Kashyap (2004), ‘Japan’s Financial Crisis and Economic
Stagnation’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1): 3–26.
Howell, D., and F. Huebler (2005), ‘Wage Compression and the
Unemployment Crisis’, in D. Howell (ed.), Fighting Unemployment: The
Limits of Free Market Orthodoxy, New York: Oxford University Press.
Huber, E., and J. Stephens (2001), ‘The Social Democratic Welfare State’, in
A. Glyn (ed.), Social Democracy in Neoliberal Times, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
IMF (2003). ‘Unemployment and Labor Market Institutions: Why Reforms
Pay Off’, World Economic Outlook, Apr.: 129–50.
—— (2005), Global Financial Stability Report, Apr.
Imamura, H. (2003), ‘Unemployment Problem and Unemployment
Insurance in China’, Far Eastern Studies, Mar. 45–67.
Inklaar, R., H. Wu, and B. van Ark (2003), ‘Losing Ground: Japanese Labour
Productivity and Unit Labor Costs in Manufacturing in Comparison to
the US’, Groningen Growth and Development Centre Research
Memorandum GD-64.
Ito, H. and Y. Yoshida (2004), ‘How does China compete with Japan in the US
market’, www.etsg.org
218
REFERENCES
Itoh, M. (1990), The World Economic Crisis and Japanese Capitalism,
Basingstoke: Macmillan.
—— (2005), ‘The Japanese Economy in Structural Difficulties’, Tokyo.
Iversen, T. (2001), ‘The Choices for Scandinavian Social Democracy’ in
A. Glyn (ed.), Social Democracy in Neoliberal Times, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Jenkinson, T. (2003), ‘Private Finance’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
19(2): 323–34.
Jensen, M. (2003), ‘The Agency Costs of Overvalued Equity’, CES ifo Forum,
14–16.
Joumard, I., P. Kongsrud, Y.-S. Nam, and R. Price (2003), ‘Enhancing the
Cost Effectiveness of Public Spending: Experience in OECD Economies’,
OECD Economic Studies, 37(2): 109–61.
Jürgens, U., and R. Rehbehn (2004), ‘China’s Changing Role in Industrial
Value Chains’, WZB Discussion Paper SP III 2004302, Berlin.
Kalecki, M. (1990, 1943), ‘Political Aspects of Full Employment’, 1st pub.
Political Quarterly, 14: 322–31; repr. in J. Osiatynski (ed.), Collected
Works of Michal Kalecki, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990.
Kaminsky, G. (2003), ‘Varieties of Currency Crises’, NBER Working Paper
10193.
Kelly, J. (2005), ‘The Resurgence of Political Strikes in Western Europe’,
Birkbeck College.
Kenworthy, L., and J. Pontusson (2004), ‘Rising Inequality and the Politics of
Redistribution in Affluent Countries’, mimeo. Cornell.
Keynes, J. (1919), The Economic Consequences of the Peace, London:
Macmillan.
Klein, M., S. Schuh, and R. Triest (2000), ‘Job Creation, Job Destruction and
the Real Exchange Rate’, NBER Working Paper 7466.
Kogut, B., and A. Metiu (2001), ‘Open-Source Software Development and
Distributed Innovation’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 17(2): 248–64.
Korpi, W., and J. Palme (1998), ‘The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies
of Equality’, American Sociological Review, 63(5), 661–87.
Krugman, P. (2004), ‘Greed is Bad’, in The Great Unravelling, New York:
Norton.
Lardy, N. (2003), ‘Liberalisation and its role in China’s Economic Growth’,
http://www.imf.org/external/np/apd/seminars/2003/newdelhi/lardy.pdf
Layard, R. (2005), Happiness, London: Allen Lane.
Lazonick, W., and M. O’Sullivan (2000), ‘Maximising Shareholder Value—A
New Ideology for Corporate Governance’, Economy and Society, 29(1):
12–35.
REFERENCES
219
Lev, B. (2003), ‘Corporate Earnings: Fact and Fiction’, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 17(2): 27–50.
Lindbeck, A. (1997), ‘The Swedish Experiment’, Journal of Economic
Literature, 35(3): 1273–319.
Lindert, P. (2003), ‘Why the Welfare State Looks like a Free Lunch’. NBER
Working Paper 9869.
Lundberg, E. (1985), ‘The Rise and Fall of the Swedish Model’, Journal of
Economic Literature, 23: 1–36.
Lundsgaard, J. (2002), ‘Competition and Efficiency in Publicly Funded
Services’, OECD Economic Studies, No. 35: 79–126.
MacKenzie, D. (2003), ‘Long-Term Capital Management and the Sociology
of Arbitrage’, Economy and Society, 32(3): 349–80.
Maddison, A. (1991), Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
—— (1995), Monitoring the World Economy, 1820–1992, Paris: OECD.
—— (1998), Chinese Economic Performance in the Long Run, Paris: OECD.
—— (2001), The World Economy: Historical Statistics. OECD: CD rom.
Mankiw, G. (1999), Comment on Ball (1999), Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 2: 237–41.
Manning, A. (2004), ‘We Can Work It Out: The Impact of Technological
Change on the Demand for Low-Skill Workers’, LSE Centre for Economic
Performance Discussion Paper 640.
Martin, B., and Rowthorn, B. (2004), ‘Will Stability Last’, mimeo. Cambridge.
Marx, K. (1867, 1968), Capital, vol. I, London: Lawrence and Wishart.
Meadows, D., D., Meadows, J., Randers and W. Behrens (1972), The Limits
to Growth, New York: Universe Books.
Megginson, W., and J. Netter (2001), ‘From State to Market: A Survey of
Empirical Studies on Privatisation’, Journal of Economic Literature, 39:
321–89.
—— —— and C. Chahyadi (2005), ‘Size and Impact of Privatisation—A
Survey of Empirical Studies’, CESifo DICE Report 3(1): 3–11.
Meltzer, A. (2002), ‘Comment on Between Meltdown and Moral Hazard’ in
J. Frankel and P. Orzag (eds.), American Economic Policy in the 1990s,
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Meng, X., R. Gregory, and Y. Wang (2004), ‘Poverty, Inequality and Growth
in Urban China, 1986–2000’, ANU, August.
Metcalf, D. (2004), ‘British Unions: Resurgence or Perdition? An Economic
Analysis’, in S. Fernie and D. Metcalf (eds.), British Unions: Resurgence
or Perdition, London: Routledge.
Milne, S. (1994), The Enemy Within, London: Verso.
220
REFERENCES
Mishel, L., J. Bernstein, and S. Allegretto (2005), The State of Working
America 2004/2005. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Morin, F. (2000), ‘A Transformation of the French Model of Shareholding
and Management’, Economy and Society, 29(1): 36–53.
Morris, S., and H. Shin (1999), ‘Risk Management with Interdependent
Choice’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15(3): 52–62.
Motonishi, T., and H. Yoshikawa (1999), ‘Causes of the Long Stagnation in
Japan during the 1990s: Financial or Real?’ NBER Working Paper 7531.
Murphy, K., (1999), ‘Executive Compensation’ in O. Ashenfelter and
D. Card, Handbook of Labor Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Mussa, M. (1994), ‘Monetary Policy’, in M. Feldstein (ed.), American
Economic Policy in the 1980s, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Navarro, V., J. Schmitt, and J. Astudillo (2004), ‘Is Globalisation Undermining
the Welfare State’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28: 135–52.
Nicoletti, G., A. Bassanini, E. Ernst, S. Jean, P. Santiago, and P. Swaim (2001),
‘Product and Labour Market Interactions in OECD Countries’, OECD
Economics Department Working Paper No. 312.
Nickell, S., and B. Bell (1995), ‘The Collapse in Demand for the Unskilled
and Unemployment across the OECD’, Oxford Review of Economic
Policy, 11(1): 40–62.
Nordhaus, W. (1992), ‘Lethal Model 2: The Limits to Growth Revisited’,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 1–60.
—— (2002), ‘Productivity Growth and the New Economy’, Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 211–65.
—— (2004), ‘Retrospective on the Post-War Productivity Slowdown’,
Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1494.
Notermans, T. (1993), ‘The Abdication from National Policy Autonomy’,
Politics and Society 21(2): 133–67.
Nove, A. (1977), The Soviet Economic System, London: George Allen & Unwin.
Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff (2005), ‘Global Current Account Imbalances and
Exchange Rate Adjustments’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:
67–146.
—— and A. Taylor (2003), ‘Globalization and Capital Markets’, in M. Bordo,
A. Taylor, and J. Williamson (eds.), Globalisation in Historical
Perspective, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
OECD (1977), Towards Full Employment and Price Stability, Paris: OECD.
—— (1983), Economic Survey of France, Paris: OECD.
—— (1990), National Accounts of Member Countries, Paris: OECD.
REFERENCES
221
—— (1994a), OECD Jobs Study Evidence and Explanations, Part I: Labor
Market Trends and Underlying Forces of Change. Part II: The Adjustment
Potential of the Labor Market, Paris: OECD.
—— (1994b), OECD Jobs Study: Facts, Analysis, Strategies, Paris: OECD.
—— (1997), Literacy Skills for the Knowledge Economy, Paris: OECD.
—— (1999), Implementing the Jobs Study, Paris: OECD.
—— (2000), Employment Outlook, Paris: OECD.
—— (2001), Ageing and Income, Paris: OECD.
—— (2002), Economic Outlook, June, Paris: OECD.
—— (2003a), Privatising State Owned Enterprises, Paris: OECD.
—— (2003b), The Sources of Economic Growth in OECD Countries, Paris:
OECD.
—— (2004a), Employment Outlook, Paris: OECD.
—— (2004b), Economic Outlook, June, Paris: OECD.
—— (2005), Economic Policy Reforms, Paris: OECD.
Ofek, E., and M.Richardson (2002), ‘The Valuation and Rationality of
Internet Stock Prices’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 18(3): 265–87.
Office of National Statistics (various dates), Labour Market Trends.
—— (2004), ‘Jobs in the Public Sector—mid 2003’, Labour Market Trends,
112(7).
Parenteau, R. (2005), ‘The late 1990s US Bubble: Financialisation in the
Extreme’, in G. Epstein (ed.), Financialisation and the World Economy,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Pencavel, J. (2004), ‘The Surprising Retreat of Union Britain’, in D. Card,
R. Blundell, and R. Freeman, Seeking a Premier-League Economy: The
Economic Effects of British Economic Reforms, 1980–2000, Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Piketty, T. (2003), ‘Income Inequality in France, 1901–1998’, Journal of
Political Economy, 111(5): 1004–42.
—— and Saez, E. (2001), ‘Income Inequality in the USA, 1913–98’, NBER
Working Paper 8467.
—— —— (2003), ‘Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–98’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1): 1–39.
Pisani Ferry (2002), ‘The Surprising French Employment Performance’,
CESifo Working Paper No 1078.
Plender, J. (2005), ‘Shock of the New: A Changed Financial Landscape may
be Eroding Resistance to Systemic Risk’, Financial Times, 16 Feb.
Pollock, A. (2004), NHS plc, London: Verso.
222
REFERENCES
Pontiff, J., A. Shleifer, and M. Weisbach (1990), ‘Reversions of Excess
Pension Assets after Takeovers’, Rand Journal of Economics, 21: 600–13.
Pontusson, J. (1987), ‘Radicalisation and retreat in Swedish social democracy’, New Left Review, 1(165): 3–33.
—— (1992), The Limits of Social Democracy, Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press.
Porter, M. (1992), ‘Capital Disadvantage: America’s Failing Capital
Investment System’, Harvard Business Review, Sep.–Oct.: 65–82.
Pryor, F., and D. Schaffer (1999), Who’s Not Working and Why, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Qian, Y. (2003), ‘How Reform Worked in China’, in D. Rodrik (ed.), In Search
of Prosperity, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rajan, R., and L. Zingales (2003), Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists,
London: Random House.
Robinson, J. (1971), Economic Heresies, Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Rodrik, D. (1997), ‘Trade, Social Insurance and the Limits to Globalisation’,
NBER Working Paper 5905.
Romer, C., and D. Romer (2002), ‘The Evolution of Economic Understanding
and Post-War Stabilisation Policy’, NBER Working Paper 9274.
Rowthorn, R. (1995), ‘Capital Formation and Unemployment’, Oxford
Review of Economic Policy, 11(1): 26–39.
—— and K. Coutts (2004), ‘Deindustrialisation and the Balance of Payments
in Advanced Countries’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28(5): 767–90.
—— and J. Wells (1987), Deindustrialisation and Foreign Trade, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Rubin, R. (2001), Comment on ‘Fiscal Policy’ in J. Frankel and P. Orszag
(eds.), American Economic Policy in the 1990s, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT
Press.
—— (2003), In An Uncertain World, New York: Random House.
Rumbaugh, T. and N. Blancher (2004), ‘International Trade and the
Challenges of WTO accession’, in E. Prasad (ed.), China’s Growth and
Integration into the World Economy, IMF Occasional Paper 232.
Runciman, D. (2005), Review of Death by a Thousand Cuts: The Fight over
Taxing Inherited Wealth by Michael Graetz and Ian Shapiro, London
Review of Books, 27(11) (2 June).
Sachs, J., and C. Wyplosz (1986), ‘The Economic Consequences of President
Mitterrand’, Economic Policy, 2: 262–322.
Samuelson, P. (2004), ‘Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm
Arguments of Mainstream Economists Supporting Globalisation’,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3): 135–46.
REFERENCES
223
Sachdev, S. (2004), ‘Paying The Cost: Public Private Partnerships and the
Public Service’. Catalyst Working Paper.
Saxonhouse, G., and R. Stern (2003), ‘The Bubble and the Lost Decade’,
World Economy, 26(3): 267–82.
Scanlon, K., and C. Whitehead (2004), ‘Housing Tenure and Mortgage
Systems: A Survey of 19 Countries’, mimeo. London School of
Economics.
Schor, J. (1992), The Overworked American, New York: Basic Books.
—— (2004), ‘Understanding the New Consumerism: Inequality, Emulation
and the Erosion of Well Being’, http://www.2.bc.edu/~schorj/
Schwarbish, T., T. Smeeding, and L. Osberg (2004), ‘Income Distribution
and Social Expenditures: A Cross National Perspective’, http://wwwcpr.maxwell.syr.edu/faculty/smeeding.
Sennett, R. (1998), The Corrosion of Character, New York: W. W. Norton.
Sharpe, A. (2004), ‘Ten Productivity Puzzles Facing Researchers’, International
Productivity Monitor No. 9, http://www.csls.ca/ipm/ipm9.asp
Shiller, R. (2000), Irrational Exuberance, Princeton: Princeton University
Press.
—— (2003), ‘From Efficient Markets Theory to Behavioural Finance’,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1): 83–104.
Shleifer, A. (2000), Inefficient Markets, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sinclair, S. (2003), ‘The WTO and its GATS’, in J. Michie (ed.), The
Handbook of Globalisation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Sinn, H.-W. (2002), ‘The New Systems Competition’, NBER Working Paper
8747.
—— (2003), ‘The Laggard of Europe’, CESifo Special Report 1/2003.
Smeeding, T. (2002), ‘Globalisation, Inequality and the Rich Countries of
the G-20’, Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper No. 320.
—— (2004), ‘Public Policy and Economic Inequality: The United States in
Comparative Perspective’, Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper
No. 367.
Soskice, D. (1978), ‘Strike Waves and Wage Explosions, 1968–70: An Economic
Interpretation’, in C. Crouch and A. Pizzorno (eds.), The Resurgence of Class
Conflict in Western Europe, Basingstoke: Macmillan.
—— (1994), ‘Reconciling Markets and Institutions: The German
Apprenticeship System’ in L. Lynch (ed.), Training and the Private Sector,
Chicago: Chicao University Press.
Stiglitz, J. (2002), Globalisation and its Discontents, London: Allen Lane.
—— (2004), ‘Capital Market Liberalisation, Globalisation and the IMF’,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(1): 57–71.
224
REFERENCES
Stultz, R. (2004), ‘Sould we Fear Derivatives’, NBER Working Paper 10574.
—— (2005), ‘The Limits of Financial Globalisation’, NBER Working Paper
11070.
Summers, L. (2002), ‘Comment on Between Meltdown and Moral Hazard’,
in J. Frankel and P. Orzag (eds.), American Economic Policy in the 1990s,
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Sutcliffe, B. (2004), ‘World Inequality and Globalisation’, Oxford Review of
Economic Policy, 20(11): 15–37.
—— and A. Glyn (2003), ‘Measures of Globalization and their
Misinterpretation’ in J. Michie (ed.), The Handbook of Globalisation,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Svallfors, S. (1997), ‘Worlds of Welfare and Attitudes to Redistribution: A
Comparison of Eight Western Nations’, European Sociological Review,
13(3): 283–304.
Thelen, K., and I. Kume (2005), ‘Coordination as a Political Problem in
Coordinated Market Economies’, forthcoming in Governance.
Torrini, R. (2005), ‘Profit Share and Returns on Capital Stock in Italy: The
Role of Privatisations behind the Rise of the 1990s’, CEP LSE Discussion
Paper 671.
UNCTAD (2004), World Investment Report 2004, Geneva: UNCTAD.
US Government (2002), Economic Report of the President, Washington.
Van Parijs, P. (2001), Whats Wrong with a Free Lunch, Boston, Beacon Press.
Van Parijs, P. (2003), ‘Basic Income: A Simple and Powerful Idea for the 21st
Century’, in E. Wright (ed.), Redesigning Distribution: Basic Income and
Stakeholder Grants as Designs for a More Egalitarian Capitalism,
London: Verso.
Vartiainen, J. (2001), ‘Understanding Swedish Social Democracy: Victims of
Success’, in A. Glyn (ed.), Social Democracy in Neoliberal Times, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Vatter, H., and J. Walker (2001), ‘Did the 1990s Inaugurate a New Economy’,
Challenge, Jan./Feb.: 90–115.
Webster, D. (2000), ‘The Geographical Concentration of Labour-market
Disadvantage’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 16(1): 114–28.
Weitzman, M. (1992), Comment on Nordhaus (1992), Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 2: 50–4.
White, W. (2004), ‘Are Changes in Financial Structure Extending Safety
Nets?’ Bank for International Settlements Working Paper No. 145.
Willner, J. (2003), ‘Privatisation: A Sceptical Analysis’, in D. Parker and
D. Saal (eds.), International Handbook of Privatisation, Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
REFERENCES
225
Wolf, M. (2004), Why Globalisation Works, New Haven: Yale University
Press.
Wood, A. (1994), North South Trade, Employment and Inequality, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Woodward, B. (1994), The Agenda, New York: Simon and Schuster.
Woolley, P. (2004), ‘How Hedge Funds are Destabilising the Markets’,
Financial Times, 29 Sept.
World Bank (2003), World Development Indicators, Washington: World
Bank.
This page intentionally left blank
Index
agriculture 3, 105
Alchian, A. 19
Alesina, A. 35, 176, 180
Armstrong, P. 3
Arthur Andersen 59–60
Asian crisis 69, 73–5, 139, 152
Atkinson, A. 182
Australia 53
Austria 109, 121–2, 123
automatic stabilizers 33
Baker, D. 47
balance of payments 10, 66, 133, 195
Bank for International Settlements
(BIS) 69–70, 74, 85
bank regulation 149–50
banking crises 69–70
Basic Income 180–3
Belgium 169
Bell, B. 120
benefits:
disincentive effects 47–8, 159–60
means-tested 159–60
and poverty 171–3, 198
sickness 107
unemployment 115–16, 187
see also Basic Income; welfare state
Benn, Tony 20
Berle A. 55
Bertola, G. 120
Besley, T. 45
Blair, Tony 116, 167, 173
Blanchard, O. 145
Bretton Woods 10–11, 66
Brown, Gordon 32
budgetary consolidation 35–6
Bush, George 57
Bush, George W. 35
Canada 53, 120, 165, 169, 171, 174
capital
accumulation 4, 13–14, 40, 52–3,
86–90, 134, 195
controls on 65, 69
flows 66
and profits 8
venture 63–4
see also investment
capital-labour ratio 153
Card, D. 120
Cassidy, J. 59
Central Bank, independence 32
Chan, A. 94
Chan, N. 72
China 16, 139
exports and imports 90–6, 195
foreign direct investment 100
growth 87–90
impact on the North 153
investment 87
labour 153–4
profits 87–8
share of world GDP 88
source of instability 154
trade unions 94–5
wages 93–4
yuan 95
Clinton, Bill 34, 137
Club of Rane 10
Coffee, J. 59–60, 62
Comin, D. 150
commodity prices 9–10, 185
competition:
and instability 150
international 8, 97–8
and investment 130
and privatization 39
228
competitive tendering 43
competitiveness, and exchange
rates 67
consumption:
and growth 52–4, 132, 136, 139
corporate governance 58–63
corporate scandals 59–63
corporation tax 161, 164, 176, 196
see also taxation
creative destruction 130, 137
crisis of capitalism 2, 151
crony capitalism 75
currency crisis 68–9
deindustrialization 105, 123
DeLong, B. 75
demand 15, 53, 134, 136
Denmark 123, 168
deregulation 42, 144
financial markets 51, 54, 65, 70,
137–9,142–3
labour markets 45–8, 144
product markets 144
see also liberalization
derivatives 71, 72
Dertouzos, M. 78, 79
disincentive effects 159–60
distribution see Gini coefficient;
inequality; redistribution
Dodd, R. 73
dollar 67–8, 79–86
earnings see wages
Economist viii, ix, 113
Eichengreen, B. 69, 75
employment 3, 88, 105
effects of outsourcing 99
law-skilled 107–9, 120
male\female 3, 106–7, 190
manufacturing 64–5, 98, 105
public sector 18, 44
self-employment 3
and structural change 104–7
employment protection legislation
(EPL) 4–5, 46, 114–15
Enron 59–60, 63
enterprise egoism 126
environmental concerns 178–9
environmental constraints 131–2,
154–5
INDEX
equality of opportunity 173
Esping-Andersen, G. 174
Euro 67, 145
Europe
deregulation 144
employment 105–9
productivity 14, 78–9, 143–5
profits 145–6
European Central Bank 30, 144
European Union 121
foreign direct investment 100
Growth and Stability Pact 33, 36,
144–5
exchange rates 12, 147, 185, 188
Bretton Woods 10–11
and capital flows 66
and competitiveness 67
real and nominal 12–13, 67–9,
79–80
exports 96–7, 139–40
Fforde, J. 28
finance, international 65–9
financial markets:
allocation of capital 54–5
deregulation 51, 54, 65, 70, 137–9,
142–3
discipline 32–6
instability 69–75
international 65–9
financial press 60
financial sector 51–2
Financial Times 21, 59
Finland 53, 122–3, 170, 171
fiscal policy 28, 33–6
Ford 72–3
Fordism 14
foreign direct investment (FDI)
100–2, 164, 196
foreign exchange reserves 85
Fortin, N. 118
France 36, 87
deregulation 144
employment protection 114–15
‘Franc fort’ policy 28
inequality 168, 177
inflation 30
nationalization 21
pension funds 56
privatization 41
INDEX
profit rate 146
property incomes 170
savings ratio 53
strikes 5
trade union 122, 123
wages 118–19
working hours 113
Frankel, J. 81
Frey, B. 178
Friedman, M. 25, 31, 53
Fukuo, M. 139
Germany 36, 87
co-determination 18–19
deregulation 144
employment protection 114
exchange rates 147
industrial relations 126
inflation 11, 27, 29
job satisfaction 179
low-skilled labour 109
Mannesman 62
outsourcing 99
pension funds 56
poverty 171, 172
prices 185
productivity 9, 147
profit rate 145–6
reunification 147–8, 151
savings ratio 53–4
social mobility 174
strikes 5
trade unions 122
welfare state 177
working hours 113
Ghatak, M. 45
Gini coefficient 172
globalization:
and capital accumulation 86–90
definition 77
effect on USA 78–9
and welfare spending 162–4
world trade 96–9
see also exports; foreign direct
investment (FDI); imports;
international trade
GM 72–3
Golden Age 1, 78, 87, 98, 105, 126, 151
Goodhart, C. 149–50
Goodman, P. 95
229
Goos, M. 109
Gordon, P. 145
Gough, N. 94, 95
government:
deficits 32–6
employment 18
private procurement 42–5
spending 17, 133, 136–7, 186, 194,
196
Green, F. 114
Green, R. 114
Greenspan, Alan 34, 72, 137, 149
Gregory, P. 16
growth: 192
and distribution 176
in China 87–90
in Europe 143–8
future of 150–5
in Japan 138–43
New Economy in USA 132–8
in rich countries 130–2
in Soviet Union 16
unstable 148–50
Guardian 43
happiness 178–80
Haskel, J. 39
hedge funds 71, 72–3
Holmstrom, B. 58, 63
hours of work 5, 113–4, 180
Howell, D. 120
Hoshi, T. 140
Huber, E. 172
Huebler, F. 120
IMF 20, 121
Financial Stability Report 152–3
orthodox policies 46–7, 73–5, 85
imports:
impact on low-skilled labour 109,
110–11
manufactures 195
penetration 97–8
incomes policies 25
India 153
Indonesia 75
inequality 197
attitudes to 177
bottom of distibution 169
and liberalization 167–8
230
INDEX
inequality (cont.)
international companies 167–70
top of distribution 169, 170
and unemployment 119–20,
169–70
see also Gini coefficient;
redistribution
inflation:
dispersion 11, 28
increase in 2, 5–6
and interest rates 26–7, 29–30
and real exchange rates 12–13
and real wages 6, 184
unpredictable 51
instability, macroeconomic 148–50
interest rates 186–7
and inflation 26–7, 29–30
rising 25–7
and unemployment 26–7
see also monetary policy
international competition 8, 97–8
international finance 65–9
international payments, imbalances 11
international trade 96–9, 190
see also exports; globalization;
imports
Intitial Public Offering (IPO) 60
investment 133, 134, 189
and competition 130
falling 139–40
institutional 56–7, 58
and productivity 13–14
and welfare state 160–1
see also capital
investment banks 60
investment managers 60–1
Ireland 123, 173
Italy
deregulation 144
employment protection 114
happiness 178
inflation 11
prices 185
profit rate 146
savings ratio 53
strikes 5
trade union 122, 123
Itoh, M. 23, 151
Iversen, T. 120
Japan
capital 80, 87
consumption 139
deficit 36
exports 92, 97, 139–40
financial deregulation 138–9, 142–3
foreign direct investment 100
happiness 178
imports 91
incomes policies 25
industrial relations 126
inflation 29
investment 139–40
outsourcing 99
pension funds 56
poverty 173
productivity 9, 14, 78–9
profits 141–2, 193
savings ratio 139
stability 148–9
stagnation 138–42, 151
trade unions 41
Jenkinson, T. 44
Jensen, M. 56
job satisfaction 179, 181–2
Jospin, Lionel 41
Jurgens, U. 95
Kalecki, M. 31
Kaminsky, G. 68
Kaplan, S. 58, 63
Kashyap, T. 140
Kenworthy, L. 172
Keynes, J M 33, 52, 64, 152, 180
Klein, M. 68
Korea 75, 87
Korpi, W. 172
labour 3–8, 39–40
dismissals 46
low-skilled 107–13
productivity 9
qualified 111–12
surplus 153–4
labour market:
unskilled 110, 111
deregulation 45–8, 144
regulation 162
rigidities 47
INDEX
Laffer curve 160
land price bubble 138–9, 140,
141–2
Lardy, N. 87
Layard, P. 178
Lev, B. 63
liberalization 51, 167–70
see also deregulation
Lindert, P. 160
Long-Term Capital Management
(LTCM) 50, 70–3
Lord Chalfont 8
Louvre Accord 81
Lundberg, E. 19
Luxemburg, Rosa 153
McCraken Report 13
Macmillan, Harold 38
Maddison, A. 87
Malthus, Robert 154
management pay 58–9
Mannesman 62
Manning, A. 109
manufacturing:
employment 98, 111, 135
profit share 7, 184–5
Marx, Karl viii, 31, 52, 77, 88
Means G. 55
Meidner, R. 19
Mexico 168
migration 3–4, 102, 176–7
Miller, M. 50
Mitterand, François 21, 28, 41
monetary policy 27, 28, 149
see also interest rates
Motonishi, T. 140
Multi Fibre Agreement 91
Mussa, M. 24
nationalization 20, 21, 41
Navarro, V. 166
Netherlands 17, 53, 109, 113, 114, 166
New Economy 132–8
New Zealand 121–2, 168, 171, 173
Nickell, S. 120
Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of
Unemployment (NAIRU) 30–1
Nordhaus, W. 131, 154
North-South trade 97–8, 110, 153
231
Norway 109, 170, 177
Nove, A. 16
OECD
Economic Policy Reforms 165
Jobs Strategy 144
Jobs Study 45–6, 165
and deregulation 45–6, 121
Ofek, E. 57
oil price hike 2, 9–10, 33
Okun, A. 160
OPEC 2, 9–10, 33
optimism 21–3
outsourcing 43, 99
Palme, J. 172
Pan, P. 95
paradox of redistribution 172, 183
Parmalat 62
Parenteau, R. 61, 77, 149
part-time work 113
Participation Income 182
pension funds 55–6, 73
Perotti, R. 35
Philippon, T. 150
Piketty, T. 118
planned economies 2, 16
Plender, J. 72
Pontusson, J. 19, 172
population growth 152
ageing 143
Porter, M. 61
Portugal 66
poverty 198
child 173
international comparisons 170–5
price regulation 39
prices:
commodity 9–10, 185
consumer 116
land 138–9, 140, 141–2
stock market 21–5
private finance initiatives (PFIs)
43–4
private procurement 42–5
privatization 37–42
gainers and losers 38, 40–1
motivation for 38–9
productivity effects 38–40
232
productivity 2, 39–40, 78, 151
China 93
and deregulation 144
Germany 147
and globalizaton 164
and investment 13–14
labour 9, 116, 125, 143, 185,
196
manufacturing 188
New Economy 133–4
retail sector 135–6, 145
services 3, 158–9
slowdown 13–15
and taxation 163, 167
profits 7, 39–40, 141, 145–6, 154,
192–3
exaggerated 135
financial sector 187–8
maximization 55
rate of 8
restoration 130
share of 116, 184–5
and wages 8
property incomes 170
Pryor, F. 112
Radiohead, 104
Rajan, R. 56
Reagan, Ronald 131
redistribution:
and growth 176
paradox of 172, 183
of spending power 17–18
see also inequality; taxation
regulation 42, 152
and firms’ costs 162
Rehbehn, R. 95
relative price effect 159
replacement ratio 115–16
research publications rankings 92
Richardson, M. 57
risk-taking 70, 143
Robinson, J. 129
Rowling, J. K. 182
Rubin, Robert 34–5
Sachs, J. 28
Saez, E. 118
savings ratio 53, 139
INDEX
Schaffer, D. 112
Schmidt, Helmut 161
Schor, J. 179, 180
Schumpeter, Joseph 130, 137
Schwarbish, T. 164, 176
Sennett, R. 179
services 3
employment 106
exports 98–9
foreign direct investment 101
labour demand 110, 111
shareholder value 55, 58, 63–5
Shiller, R. 57
Shleifer, A. 64
sickness benefits 107
Sinn, H.-W. 176
Smith, Adam 50, 152
social mobility 174–5, 194
social pacts 30
social welfare see welfare state
Soviet Union 2, 16
Spain 114, 144, 168, 177
stagflation 25
state see government
Stephens, J. 172
Stiglitz, J. 74–5
stock markets:
high 56–7
internet boom 57, 64
prices 21–3
stock options 58–9
strikes 5, 31, 123–4, 184
miners 8, 124, 145
and unemployment 32, 187
see also trade unions
Stuart, R. 16
Stutzer, A. 178
Summers, Larry 82
Sweden
financial deregulation 137–8
incomes policies 25
industrial relations 126
inequality 168, 177
inflation 30
low-skilled labour 109
monetary policy 28–9
poverty 171, 172
savings ratio 53
social welfare 166–7
INDEX
state share in GDP 17
wage-earner funds 19
working hours 113
takeovers, hostile 58, 62, 65
tax revenue:
constraints on 163–7
and productivity growth 163
tax wedge 165
taxation 46, 161–2, 167
competition between countries 164
and poverty 171–3, 198
see also corporation tax
technical progress 109–10
Thatcher, Margaret 27, 39, 116, 131,
145, 168, 173
The Times 8
Toyota 62
trade unions 145
China 94–5
coverage 122
declining influence 112, 121–6
membership 4, 123, 191
power 2, 15
see also strikes
unemployment 4, 126, 186, 194
and benefits 46–8, 107, 115–6, 187
and industrial conflict 31, 187
and inequality 169–70
and inactivity 107
and interest rates 26–7
and labour market deregulation
45–8
and monetary policy 28
Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of
Unemployment (NAIRU) 30–1
rising 25, 104–7
unemployment benefits 46–7
and earnings 158, 191
replacement ratio 115–16
unions see trade unions
United Kingdom 194
capitalization ratio 52
exports 98
happiness 178, 179
health spending 167
import controls 21
incomes policies 25
233
inequality 168, 177
inflation 30
Labour Party 20
low pay 169
low-skilled labour 110
monetary policy 27
nationalization 20
NHS 44–5
outsourcing 99
pension funds 56
poverty 171, 172, 173
private procurment 43–5
privatization 37–40
productivity 167
profit rate 145–6
public sector employment 44
savings ratio 53–4
social mobility 174
strikes 5, 8, 124
trade unions 122–3, 123–5
utilities 38
United States of America
balance of payments 9, 79–86,
82–4, 133, 195
budget deficits 34–6
consumption 82, 145
corporate scandals 59–62
current account deficit 83–4
direct investment 9, 83, 84
dollar 67–8, 79–86
employment 105–7, 111–2
exports 9, 83, 97
Federal Reserve 25, 80, 149
financial sector 52
government spending 133, 136–7
happiness 178, 179
household consumption 53
inequality 168, 177
inflation 30
interest rates 25–7, 80, 186
international leader 2, 8–9
investment 84, 133, 134, 189
low pay 169
low-skilled labour 108–9
management pay 58, 118
manufacturing employment 64–5
migration policy 102
MIT Commission on Industrial
Productivity 78
234
INDEX
United States of America (cont.)
monetary policy 27, 149
New Economy 132–8, 151
outsourcing 99
payments deficits 66–7
pension funds 56
poverty 171, 173
prices 185
productivity 9, 14–5, 78–9, 133–5,
167
profits 81, 135–6, 192
property incomes 170
recession 36
Sarbanes-Oxley Act 62–3
savings ratio 53–4
social mobility 174
stock market boom 56–7
strikes 5, 27
trade union 121–2, 123
wages 116, 117
working hours 113
Updike, J. 77
urban population expansion 3–4
Vartiainen, J. 167
venture capital 63–4
Vodafone 62
Volker, P. 25–7, 80
wage bargaining 122–3, 124, 169
wages 5–6, 39–40, 116–19, 189
in China 93–4
differentials 117, 191
distribution 116–19, 163
dual role 154
flexibility 119–21
and inflation 184
low 169
management pay 58–9
and profits 8
and share prices 22, 186
minimum 46, 118–19
top end 118, 163
and unemployment benefits 158
union premium 124–5
women’s 118
Wall Street Journal 60
Weitzman, M. 156
welfare state:
cuts 35–6; resistance to 165–7, 177
function of 157–8
and investment 160–1
source of revenue for 159–63
spending on 17–18, 157–9
see also Basic Income; benefits
White, W. 70
Wolf, M. 167
Wood, A. 110
work:
hours of 5, 113–14, 180
insecurity 115
intensity 114, 125
Wyplosz, C. 28
yen 67
Yoshikawa 140
yuan 95
Zapata 57
Zingales, L. 56